The determinants of rates of octroi tax in Pakistan.
Ghaus, A.F. Aisha ; Khan, Rauf ; Ghaus, Rafia 等
Octroi is a tax imposed by local governments in Pakistan on
commodities imported into the municipal limits for local use, sale, or
consumption. It is levied generally by urban local councils on goods
coming in by all modes--sea, land, and air transport. The point of
assessment is alongside roads at octroi posts situated at or before
municipal boundaries, at railway stations, seaports or airports.
Octroi is currently the largest source of revenue to urban local
councils in the country and contributes 86 percent to total tax revenues
and over 59 percent to total local revenue receipts (see Table 1). Its
revenue significance (in terms of share in total receipts) has increased
over the years. In 1987-88, it accounted for about 57 percent of total
local receipts. Also, revenue generation from octroi is higher than that
by any provincial tax. In 1991-92, total national collection from octroi
was Rs 5.5 billion as compared to Rs 3.5 billion from stamp duties, the
largest provincial tax source.
Despite its obvious revenue importance, octroi remains a
controversial tax, and has been subjected to a series of criticisms.
Important among these are that it is regressive in its income
distributive effects, inelastic, and inefficient [Karachi Master Plan
(1974)]. Some work has been done to show that the former two may, to
some extent, be valid. Pasha et al. (1988) and Iqbal (1986) suggest that
the incidence of octroi collected from land posts tends towards
regressivity. Similarly, Pasha et al. (1988), Iqbal (1986) and Ghaus and
Pasha (1989) show that this component of octroi has limited revenue
elasticity. No formal analysis has, however, been undertaken to
establish the efficiency of the tax. The objective of this paper is to
see whether octroi is an efficient tax in Pakistan through its adherence
to certain principles of optimal commodity taxation. This involves an
analysis of the determinant of octroi rates in Pakistan.
The paper is organised as follows: Section I briefly describes the
tax as administered in Pakistan. Section 2 discusses the existing octroi
rates. Section 3 presents the theoretical framework of the analysis;
while in Section 4, the results of econometric analysis of the
determinants of octroi rates are presented. Finally, a summary of
conclusions is presented in Section 5.
1. DESCRIPTION OF OCTROI
Octroi is assessed on consignments entering by road and rail
transport on the basis of weight in terms of 100 kilogram units. Flat
rates of octroi are imposed and these rates vary between commodities.
However, in the case of sea consignments destined for consumption within
the city of Karachi, and an advalorem system of assessment of octroi
with respect to the value of consignment has been in operation since
1972-73.
The largest contribution to octroi revenues is by food items. It
ranges from 62 percent of total octroi revenues in the case of town
committees to 18 percent in Metropolitan Corporations. In general,
octroi in the bigger cities appears to be more broad-based. The
dependence of octroi revenues on basic commodities like foods, textiles,
drugs, medicines, building material, etc., particularly in the smaller
cities, implies that the incidence of this component of octroi is likely
to be regressive in character. Also, buoyancy of revenues may be low
because of the relatively slow growth in the demand of basic items like
food, clothing, etc. Therefore, it seems that part of the problem of
regressivity and inelasticity in the tax arises due to the composition
of its tax base.
Municipal Governments have, in general, handed over octroi
collection to private contractors. Auctioning of octroi collection to
private contractors was introduced in the 1970s and had led to
substantial revenue gains to local councils due to stricter supervision
of octroi collection.
2. EXISTING OCTROI RATES
The presence of a specific rate octroi structure implies that in
the absence of discretionary changes in tax rates, revenues respond only
to changes in quantities and not to a rise in prices of goods imported
into municipal limits. Local governments have, therefore, attempted to
preserve the growth of revenues by periodically escalating rates to, at
least partially, re-establish the link with prices. However, the
strategy has been small, across-the-board rate escalations. The
consequence is that octroi rates are very low as compared to the price
of commodities, and there appears to be a certain degree of ad-hocism in
the structure.
Table 2 presents the average effective octroi rates [EOR] for a
sample of twenty-three cities in Pakistan for 89 commodities, which
account for the bulk of octroi revenues. EOR is defined as the specific
rate as percentage of the price. The table shows that EORs are very low,
at about 0.3 percent, of the wholesale consumer prices. A large
proportion of items, about 37 percent, in the octroi schedule have EORs
of less than 0.3 percent. 38 percent of the commodities have rates
between 0.31 and 0.5 percent while only about one-fourth of the
commodities have rate equivalent to more than 0.5 percent of the price.
Also, octroi rates vary significantly by type of commodity as shown
in Table 3. Commodity groups with the lowest octroi rates are consumer
durables with the average EOR of 0.26 percent. As opposed to this, food
and drinks are among the highest octroi rate category with an average
EOR of about 0.35 percent. EOR on sugar is 0.91 percent; on salt 0.71
percent; while on consumer durables like refrigerators, air
conditioners, and cars, it ranges from 0.1 percent to 0.45 percent.
Therefore, there are initial indications of the existence of fiscal
anomalies in the octroi structure which may exacerbate the regressivity
of the tax incidence, reduce its buoyancy, and may have an impact on the
efficiency of the tax. We next turn to a formal analysis of the
determinants of octroi rates.
3. THEORETICAL ANALYSIS OF THE DETERMINANTS OF OCTROI
Analysis of optimal octroi rates can potentially be undertaken by
application of the Ramsey (1927) type of principles of optimal indirect
taxation. The technical analysis is presented in the Appendix to the
paper. It appears that the basic choice for municipal governments
between octroi taxation of imported consumer goods or intermediate goods
depends upon their relative concern for the impact on residents'
welfare via taxation of consumer goods versus the impact on profits (and
employment) of the taxation of intermediate goods. The theoretical
framework developed by us enables a formal analysis of the determinants
of the relative effective rates of octroi on consumer and intermediate
goods respectively. Some of the principal conclusions which emerge from
the theoretical analysis of the determinants of optimal octroi rates are
as follows:
(1) If local councils are relatively more concerned about the
impact of octroi rates on the profitability of industry and trade within
the city than on the utility levels of residents arising from their
consumption of goods, they are more likely to have lower octroi tax
rates on intermediate: goods than on consumer goods. This, of course,
hinges on whether changes in the rates are seen as local or global in
character. In the latter case, the impact on profitability of industry
will be less.
(2) Given a certain revenue target, the level of octroi rates
depends on the size of the tax base. Councils where imports of consumer
or intermediate goods are high in relation to resident income will have
lower tax rates, other things being equal.
(3) If the price elasticity of demand for imports of consumer goods
is higher, then tax rates for such goods would tend to be lower, other
things being equal. The same conclusion applies in the case of
intermediate goods.
(4) If the revenue target of octroi is higher, then, other things
being equal, tax rates on both consumer and intermediate goods will be
higher.
Econometric analysis has been undertaken of octroi rates in a
sample of councils to determine their degree of consistency with the
theoretical principles enunciated above.
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Given the qualitative nature of some of the above factors and data
limitations, the impact of some of these factors on octroi rates has
been captured through the use of dichotomous variables and proxies.
Dummy variables for each type of good (basic consumer goods/luxury
consumer good/intermediate goods/capital good) and different types of
local councils (metropolitan corporation/municipal
corporations/municipal committees/town committees) have been used. The
latter are used to capture the impact of the size of the tax base on
rates along with per capita industrial value-added since a major
component of octroi tax base consists of industrial import.
The criterion related to economic efficiency implies that, other
things being equal, lower octroi rates should be specified on those
commodities the import demand for which is relatively price-elastic.
Price elasticities for major food and non-food items in the urban areas
of Pakistan have been estimated by Tariq (1994). As expected, these
price elasticities are, by and large, low for most food items.
Analysis of the recent data on national imports and the income
elasticity of the demand of different commodities has been undertaken to
rank different commodities in terms of the buoyancy of demand. Income
elasticity of major food and non-food items has been estimated by Tariq
(1994) using a linear expenditure system. The study shows that, broadly
speaking, income elasticity of major food items in urban areas ranges
from 0.2 to 2.0. Some of the high income elasticity items include bakery
products, poultry, fruits, butter and coffee/ovaltine, etc. Dummy
variables have also been used to see if there are inter-provincial
differences in octroi rate.
Based on the above, the following equation has been specified.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
K = 1 ... 3 for type of goods.
L = 1 ... 3 for provinces.
M = 1 ... 3 for type of municipal status.
where;
[RATE.sub.ij] = The octroi rate on the 'ith' commodity in
the 'jth' local council.
[TYPE.sub.kj] = Type of good (basic consumer/luxury
consumer/intermediate).
[PE.sub.i] = Price elasticity of the 'ith' commodity.
[IE.sub.i] = Income elasticity of the 'ith' commodity.
[PROV.sub.Lj] = Province (Balochistan/NWFP/Sindh).
[MSTAT.sub.m] = Type of local council (municipal
corporation/municipal committee/ town committee).
[PRICE.sub.ij] =Price of the ith commodity in 'jth' local
council.
[PCIND.sub.j] = Per capita industrial value-added in the
'jth' city.
[PTYPE.sub.kj] = Price of the 'ith' commodity in
'jth' city interacted with 'kth' type of good.
[PROV.sub.Lj] = Price of the 'ith' commodity in
'jth' city interacted with 'lth' province.
[PMSTAT.sub.mj] = Price of the 'ith' commodity in the
jth' city interacted with 'mth' type of municipal status.
Price variable has been interacted to see if effective octroi rates
vary by type of good, type of local council, and provinces.
The above model has been applied to octroi rates of 86 commodities
in 23 cities of varying population size and municipal status. (1) The
results are presented in Table 4. The model specified is only able to
explain less than half the variation in octroi rates. This indicates
that for a large number of items, the fates diverge significantly from
what would be implied on the basis of the application of above
principles. Some of the key conclusions from the table are as follows:
(i) Intermediate goods appeal" to have somewhat lower rates
than non-food consumer goods, while the lowest rates are observed for
food items. This indicates that local councils do attach importance,
first, to protecting local industry from decline in profitability levels
and, second, to insulating lower income groups from the burden of octroi
to the extent possible.
(ii) The industrial value-added per capita variable has a negative
coefficient, as expected. This implies that in municipal jurisdictions
where the level of import of intermediate goods is relatively high
(because of greater industrial presence), octroi tax rates are lower.
(iii) Economic efficiency criteria appear to be implicit in the
rate setting and some effort has been made, other things being equal, to
specify lower rates for items which have relatively high price
elasticity of demand.
(iv) A significant finding is that, other things being equal, rates
are lower in the larger councils, and that rates tend to rise with a
fall in municipal status, with town committees on the average having the
highest rates. This may be a reflection partly of the restricted tax
base and partly of lack of access to revenues from property tax which
compel local governments in small towns and cities to resort to higher
octroi taxation. Similarly, rates are higher on average in Balochistan,
followed by Sindh, Punjab, and the NWFP. There is evidence that per
capita expenditures in Sindh and Balochistan are relatively high [Pasha
(1986)]. Therefore, higher rates may be necessitated by more ambitious
revenue targets.
(v) Local councils do not appear to have a major concern for
buoyancy of revenues in the fixation of octroi rates. The income
elasticity variable does not emerge as significant, although it has the
right sign.
(vi) Effective rates appear to rise initially with respect to
price, then fall and rise again. Also, there appears to be a minimum
flat rate imposed irrespective of the price. This diminishes the
neutrality of the effective tax rate with respect to price.
Altogether, we have the conclusion that while on the average there
is broadly some adherence to the principles of optimal indirect taxation
in the context of octroi rate setting, there are still large deviations
from these principles in the case of a number of commodities. Therefore,
rationalisation of the octroi structure will require changes in the
rates for such commodities which bring them closer to the level
predicted by the regression line. More fundamental restructuring would
require changes in the regression equation to reflect more effectively
the considerations of economic efficiency, equity, and buoyancy.
Table 5 indicates commodities where rates at current levels are
'outliers' in relation to the predicted levels. These
commodities ought to be targeted first in any effort at rationalisation
of the octroi structure. The list includes consumer durables (like air
conditioner, refrigerator, deep freezer, television, etc.), other
consumer goods (like cigarettes, milk powder, ready-made garments, tea,
etc.), and some intermediate goods (like bricks, acids, leather, tiles,
etc.).
5. CONCLUSION
This paper analyses the determinants of octroi rates on major
commodities for a sample of cities (in Pakistan) of varying population
sizes and municipal status, and it formulates a judgement on the extent
to which norms of optimal indirect taxation have been followed. The
results indicate that while octroi rates are broadly in line with the
contours of optimal taxation, and vary broadly with respect to prices,
the nature of good, size of tax bases, municipal status, considerations
of equity, buoyancy, and minimisation of distortion have not adequately
been taken into account. Criteria of fixation of octroi rates, based on
norms of optimal taxation, are specified, and a rationalisation of
octroi rates is accordingly suggested.
Comments
This is an interesting paper on the question of the determinants of
rates of Octroi taxes, an area which has been greatly neglected in the
empirical work in Pakistan. Octroi is a tax imposed by local governments
in Pakistan on certain commodities imported into the municipal limits
for local use, sale or consumption. These taxes are indirect in nature
and generally are supposed to be inefficient. Hence they are not popular
in most of the developed countries.
The authors have tried to determine the efficiency of octroi taxes
through their adherence to certain principles of optimal commodity
taxation. The authors have also tried to see whether or not the
regressivity, inelasticity, and inefficiency (if any) in octroi are due
to its rate structure. The main exercise of the study is the analysis of
the determinants of octroi rates in Pakistan. Based on the regression
equation reported on Page 9 of the paper (as presented in the
conference), the major conclusion drawn by the authors is that the
octroi taxes are broadly in line with the contours of optimal taxation.
This is a somewhat surprising result, given the existing methods of
octroi tax collection and the auction procedure by itself. Tax evasion and irregularities in the collection procedures are largely reported in
this source of revenues along with the high collection and compliance
(transport and delay) costs relative to the revenue generated. Hence the
conclusion that it is in line with the contours of optimal taxation is
not convincing.
Maybe there are some other ways to analyse the main hypothesis of
the paper. First, since the conclusion is based on the assumption that
for each locality/district/town the prices are exogenous, one can use a
little relaxed assumption of exogenous prices and prove that the octroi
taxes are really inefficient in Pakistan. Secondly, it is very hard to
relate the regression equation reported (on page 9 of the paper
presented at the conference) with the overall model derived in the
Appendix. In the Appendix, the equations derived from the model are
non-linear in parameters. It is not mentioned nor clear from the paper
that the equation specified (on page 9 of the paper as presented at the
conference) is some form of transformation of the equation derived in
the Appendix. Alternatively, one can try the non-linear regression
techniques, which can reverse the conclusion drawn in the paper: that
the octroi taxes in Pakistan are in fact inefficient.
There are some other minor observations about the paper which are
as follows. (a) None of the sections in the paper describes the data set
used in the study, making it impossible to comment on the validity and
reliability of the data used. The authors should include a small section
on the description of the data used, and the sampling flame and methods.
(b) Most of the tables in the text do not indicate the year or source of
the data used.
Overall. the authors have addressed a problem which is very hard to
analyse. I congratulate them for doing such a disaggregate analysis of
Octroi taxes.
Syeda Fizza Gillani
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Appendix
THE THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK OF OPTIMAL OCTROI RATES ANALYSIS
The optimal octroi rates problem is set up in the context of a city
which is small in relation to the rest of the country/world and,
therefore, faces exogenously given (metropolitan) border prices. These
prices can be enhanced at the point of entry into the city by levy of
octroi. The import supply curve is perfectly elastic. In other words, we
do not allow lot the existence of import quotas.
(a) Types of Goods
Four types of goods are distinguished, as follows:
Imported Consumer Good
This is a composite good of consumer goods imported into the city
either internationally or from the rest of the country. It is assumed
that these goods are noncompetitive in character with respect to
production within the city. Such an assumption has been made at the
national level by Ahmed and Stern (1991). It seems even more likely in
the context of an individual city which is likely to show greater
specialisation in its economic activities, depending upon locational
factors, etc.
Included in this category are food items like wheat (atta), rice,
sugar, fruits, tea, vegetables, etc. It is unlikely that a significant
quantum of food production takes place within the metropolitan
boundaries. Other non-competitive goods could include various types of
consumer durables. In addition, if we allow for product differentiation between imports and domestic production, then the assumption of the
non-competitive nature of imports is likely to be more valid. This
category of goods is referred to as good 1.
Imported Intermediate Good
It is also assumed that this is a composite good of non-competitive
intermediate good imports. Imports of edible oil, POL products,
chemicals, building materials, etc., fall into this category. This
composite good is defined as good 2.
Domestic Consumer Good
This is a composite good of consumer goods produced within the city
and partially exported either to the rest of the country or abroad.
Textile products, for example, fall into this category. This composite
good is referred to as good 3.
Domestic Intermediate Good
This is a composite good of intermediate goods produced within the
city and partially exported to the rest of the country or abroad.
Production of cotton yarn may fall into this category in the context of
Karachi. This composite good is referred to as good 4.
(b) Input-Output Relationships
As a simplifying assumption regarding input-output relationships
within the city, we assume that only intermediate goods are used in the
production of other goods. That is, consumer goods enter final
consumption by households only. Therefore, we specify the input-matrix
as follows:
Liput of Output of
Good 2 Good 2 Good 4
Good 4 [m.sub.32] [m.sub.42]
[m.sub.34] [m.sub.44]
The m's are input-output coefficients.
(c) Nature of Market Equilibrium
For the imported consumer good, the market equilibrium is depicted
below:
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
In the absence of octroi, it may be noticed that initially the
import price is normalised to unity. E represents the equilibrium
following the imposition of octroi at the rate of [t.sub.1]. [M.sub.1]
is the quantity imported and the shaded area is the octroi revenue.
For the domestic consumer good, the equilibrium is shown below:
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
In this case, the export price is unaffected by the imposition of
octroi at the import stage. There is no octroi revenue directly from
such goods as the level of import is zero. The level of export (to the
rest of the country or abroad) is represented by [X.sub.3].
Market equilibrium for the domestically produced intermediate good
can essentially be characterised in the same manner as that for the
domestic consumer good. In the case of imported intermediate good, there
is derived demand from production within the city of consumer and
intermediate goods.
(d) Prices
As indicated above, in the absence of octroi all consumer/user
prices are initially normalised to unity. Octroi is collected only from
imported consumer and intermediate goods. We designate the octroi rates
as follows:
[t.sub.1] = octroi rate on the composite imported consumer good.
[t.sub.2] = octroi rate on the composite imported intermediate
good.
It may be noted that at this stage we do not allow for any
difference in octroi rates between sea, air, and land dues on the same
commodity. (2)
The basic problem is one of determining the optimal magnitudes of
[t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2]. In this analysis, we are concerned with the
determination of octroi rates only in the case of commodities which are
actually imported. The octroi schedules, of course, cover all goods but
there is some redundancy in the rate fixation as not all of these goods
are imported in any significant quantity.
Given the imposition of octroi, the prices in the city are as
follows:
For the For the
Imported Imported
Consumer Intermediate
Good Good
Type of Price
Consumer/User Price [P.sub.1 = 1+[t.sub.1] [P.sub.2 = 1+[t.sub.2]
Local Producer Price -- --
For the For the
Domestic Domestic
Consumer Intermediate
Good Good
Type of Price
Consumer/User Price 1 1
Local Producer Price [p.sub.3] [p.sub.4]
where [p.sub.3] = 1-[m.sub.32](1+[t.sub.2])-[m.sub.34] and [p.sub.4]
= 1-[m.sub.42](1+[t.sub.2])-[m.sub.44].
Therefore, it may be noticed from above that the levy of octroi on
imported intermediate good does not affect local consumers directly. It.
however, reduces the profitability of local industry by reducing
[p.sub.3] and [p.sub.4.]
(e) Consumer Equilibrium
The process of utility maximisation for the typical consumer is
given by
Max U = U ([q.sub.1], [q.sub.3])
subject to [p.sub.1][q.sub.1] + [q.sub.3] = y, where v is
essentially treated as an income endowment.
This yields: [q.sub.1] = [q.sub.1] ([p.sub.1], y)
[q.sub.3] = [q.sub.3] ([p.sub.1], y)
and V = V ([p.sub.1], y) is the indirect utility function.
Applying the envelope theorem to the Lagrangian function we have
[partial derivative]V/[partial derivative][t.sub.1]
-[lambda][q.sub.1], where [lambda] is the Lagrangian multiplier and
[lambda] = [partial derivative]V/[partial derivative]y.
It is obvious that [partial derivative]V/[partial
derivative][t.sub.2] = 0.
A levy on imported intermediate good does not affect the consumer
directly.
(f) Industry Equilibrium
The process of profit maximisation in a typical industry is given
by:
[[pi].sub.i] = [P.sub.i][Q.sub.i]([K.sub.i], [L.sub.i]) -
w[L.sub.i], - [tau][K.sub.i] i = 3, 4
Maximisation of [[pi].sub.i] with respect to [L.sub.i] and
[K.sub.i] with exogenously given w and [tau] and application of the
envelope theorem leads to
[partial derivative][[pi].sub.i]/[partial derivative][P.sub.i] =
[Q.sub.i] where [Q.sub.i] = [S.sub.i]([P.sub.i])
and [S.sub.i] is supply by industry i. Therefore,
[partial derivative][[pi].sub.i]/[partial derivative][t.sub.i] =
[Q.sub.i] [partial derivative][p.sub.i]/[partial derivative][t.sub.i]
This leads to
[partial derivative][[pi].sub.3]/[partial derivative][t.sub.1] =
[m.sub.32] [S.sub.3]
[partial derivative][[pi].sub.4]/[partial derivative][t.sub.2] =
[m.sub.42] [S.sub.4]
(g) Octroi Revenue Function
The octroi revenue T is given by
T = [t.sub.1] [M.sub.1] + [t.sub.2] [M.sub.2]
where [M.sub.1] = [D.sub.1] and [M.sub.2] = [m.sub.32] [S.sub.3] +
[m.sub.42] [S.sub.4]
(h) Social Welfare Function
We assume that elected representatives/officials of the city
government are concerned both about the utility level of households
(tile electorate) living in their jurisdiction and also about the profit
level of trade and industry in the city. The relative importance of
these two factors depends upon the degree of representation in the house
of the local council of different interests.
The utility level of all residents is give by
W = [N.summation over (i=1)] [U.sub.i]
where there are N households in the city. Utilities are assumed to
be additive in this specification. The profit level of economic
activities in the city is given by
[pi] = [[pi].sub.3] + [[pi].sub.4]
The Social Welfare Function, F, then is given by
F = F (W, [pi])
F has the properties of a conventional utility function. From the
previous sections we have that
[partial derivative]W/[partial derivative][t.sub.1] = [n.summation
over (i=1)](- [lambda][q.sub.1])
On the assumption that all households are indentical,
[partial derivative]W/[partial derivative][t.sub.1] = -
[lambda][M.sub.1]
(Since domestic production is zero)
Of course, [partial derivative]W/[partial derivative][t.sub.2] = 0
Similarly [partial derivative][pi]/[partial derivative][t.sub.2] =
- [m.sub.32] [S.sub.3] - [m.sub.42] [S.sub.4] = - [M.sub.2]
In summary,
[partial derivative]W/[partial derivative][t.sub.1] = -
[lambda][M.sub.1] and Similarly [partial derivative][pi]/[partial
derivative][t.sub.2] = - [M.sub.2]
(i) The Optimisation Problem
We are finally in a position to set up the optimisation problem as
follows:
[l.sub.2] ([t.sub.1], [t.sub.2], [mu]) = F(W, [pi]) + [mu] [bar.R]
- [t.sub.1][M.sub.1] - [t.sub.2][M.sub.2]]
where [bar.R] is the exogenously given revenue target for octroi.
The first-order conditions are,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[partial derivative][l.sub.2]/[partial derivative]t = [bar.R] -
[t.sub.1][M.sub.1] - [t.sub.2][M.sub.2] = 0
Substituting the earlier results we have,
[partial derivative]F/[partial derivative]W (-[lambda][M.sub.1] +
[mu] [-[t.sub.1][partial derivative][M.sub.1]/ [partial
derivative][t.sub.1] - [M.sub.1]] = 0
This can be transformed to
+ [lambda][partial derivative]F/[partial derivative]W + [mu]
[+([[t.sub.i]/[P.sub.1])[[epsilon].sub.1] + 1] = 0 [[epsilon].sub.1] =
price elasticity of demand for import of consumer good (A)
Similarly,
[partial derivative]F/[partial derivative][pi]([M.sub.2]) + [mu]
[[t.sub.2] [partial derivative][M.sub.2]/[partial derivative][t.sub.2] +
[M.sub.2]] = 0
This can be transformed into
[partial derivative]F/[partial derivative][pi] + [mu]
[[t.sub.2]/[P.sub.2]) [[epsilon].sub.2] + 1], [[epsilon].sub.2] = price
elasticity of demand for import of Intermediate good ... (B)
Also, we can write the revenue constraint as
([t.sub.1]/[P.sub.1]) ([P.sub.1][M.sub.1]) + ([t.sub.2]/[P.sub.2])
(([P.sub.2][M.sub.2]) = [bar.R] ... (C)
Then we have a three equation system (A), (B) and (C)--which can be
solved to yield [mu] and the optimal values of [t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2].
(j) Simulations
Suppose that the utility function for the typical local household
is given by
U = [[q.sub.1.sup.[alpha]] [[q.sub.2.sup.1-[alpha]]
Then it can be derived in this case that the indirect utility
function is given by
V = Ay/(1 + [[t.sub.1]).sup.[alpha]] where A =
[[alpha].sup.[alpha]] [(1 - [alpha]).sup.1-[alpha]]
[partial derivative]V/[partial derivative]y = A/[(1 +
[t.sub.1].sup.[alpha]]
and a Cobb-Douglas social welfare function, F,
That is F = [W.sup.[beta]] [[pi].sup.1-[beta]]
[partial derivative]F/[partial derivative]W = [beta]F/W
[partial derivative]F/[partial derivative][pi] = (1 - [beta])F/[pi]
where W = NV. V is the utility level attained by each household.
Then, dividing Equation (A) by Equation (B) we have,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Substituting [partial derivative]V/[partial derivative]y and V from
above we obtain
[beta][pi]/(Ny)(1 - [beta]) = [[tau].sub.1] [[epsilon].sub.1] +
1/[[tau].sub.2] [[epsilon].sub.2] + 1
Where [[tau].sub.1] = [t.sub.1]/[P.sub.1] and [[tau].sub.2] =
[t.sub.2]/[P.sub.2] are the effective octroi rates on the consumer
price.
Suppose that we designate as s the share of profits in income
i.e., s = [pi]/Ny
Then [beta]s/(1 - [beta]) = [[tau].sub.1] [[epsilon].sub.1] +
1/[[tau].sub.2] [[epsilon].sub.2] + 1
This leads to
[beta]S[[epsilon].sub.2]/(1 - [beta]) [[tau].sub.2] +
[[beta].sub.3]/(1 - [beta]) = [[tau].sub.1] [[epsilon].sub.1] + 1
Therefore,
[[epsilon].sub.1] [[tau].sub.1] - [beta]S[[epsilon].sub.2]/(1 -
[beta]) [[tau].sub.2] + [beta]s/(1 - [beta]) - 1 ... (1)
We have from the revenue constraint that
[[tau].sub.1] ([P.sub.1][M.sub.1]/[bar.N]y) + [[tau].sub.2]
([P.sub.2][M.sub.2]/[bar.N]y) = ([bar.R]/[bar.N]y)
We designate the following,
[m.sub.1] = [P.sub.1][M.sub.1]/[bar.N]y), [m.sub.2] =
[P.sub.2][M.sub.2]/[bar.N]y), [r.sup.*] = [bar.R]/[bar.N]y
Then the equation is transformed to
[m.sub.1][[tau].sub.1] + [m.sub.2][[tau].sub.2] = [r.sup.*] ... (2)
Therefore, Equations (1) and (2) constitute a two-equation system
which can be solved to yield the values of [[tau].sub.1] and
[[tau].sub.2], as follows:
[[tau].sub.1] [m.sub.2]{[beta]S(1 - [beta])} +
[beta]s[[epsilon].sub.2][tau]*/[epsilon][m.sub.2](1 - [beta]) +
[beta]s[[epsilon].sub.2][m.sub.1] ... (3)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
which leads to
[[tau].sub.2] = [[epsilon].sub.1][[tau].sup.*](1 - [beta]) -
[m.sub.1]{[[beta].sub.s] - (1 - [beta])}/[[epsilon].sub.1][m.sub.2](1 -
[beta]) + [beta]s[[epsilon].sub.2][m.sub.1] ... (5)
[[tau].sub.1] in (4) and [[tau].sub.1] in (5) are the optimal
octroi rates, given the revenue target, [[tau].sup.*] The results of
comparative statistics on Equations (1) and (2) are as follows:
Changes in
[[tau].sub.1] [[tau].sub.2]
Due to Change in [Consumer Goods] [Intermediate Goods]
[beta] - +
s - +
[m.sub.1] - -
[m.sub.2] - -
[epsilon] + -
[[epsilon].sub.2] - +
[tau] * + +
Authors' Note: The authors acknowledge the comments of Prof.
Dr Hafiz A. Pasha and the research assistance of Ms Naveed Hanif. Any
defects that remain are, however, the responsibility of the authors.
REFERENCES
Ahmed, E., and N. Stern (1991) The Theory and Practice of Tax
Reforms in Developing Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ghaus, A., and H. A. Pasha (1989) A Model of Municipal Finances.
Karachi: Applied Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi.
(Research Report.)
Iqbal, Qamar (1986) An Economic Analysis of Octroi. Unpublished MAS
Thesis. Karachi: Applied Economic Research Centre, University of
Karachi. Karachi Master Plan 1974.
Pasha, H. A., et al. (1988) Municipal Finances in Pakistan.
Karachi: Applied Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi.
(Research Report.)
Ramsey, F. P. (1927) A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation.
Economic Journal. Tariq (1994) Utility-constant Cost of Living Index in
Pakistan. Karachi: Applied Economics Research Centre, University of
Karachi. Unpublished MAS Thesis.
(1) Sample cities include: Lahore, Karachi, Peshawaf, Quelta,
Hyderabad, Faisalabad, Rawalpindi. Sialkot, Bahawalpur, Gujranwala,
Sargodha, Nawabshah, Charsadda, Kasur, Vehari, Rahim Yar Khan,
Sheikhupura, Shabqadar, Raiwind, Mansehra and Shikafpur, Larkana.
A. F. Aisha Ghaus is Research Economist at the Applied Economics
Research Centre, University of Karachi. Rauf Khan and Rafia Ghaus are
both Economist at Social Policy and Development Centre, Karachi.
Table 1
Revenue Significance of Octroi
(For all Urban Local Councils Combined)
Octroi Revenue Share in Total
Year (Rs in Million) Revenue (%)
1987-88 2892 57.2
1988-89 3185 57.4
1989-90 3906 58.5
1990-91 4659 59.0
1991-92 5466 59.6
Source: National Centre for Rural Development Data Base.
Table 2
Effective Octroi Rate * in Pakistan **
% of Commodities ***
Effective Rate (EOR) in the Octroi Schedule
0-0.10% 2.3
0.11-0.20% 15.1
0.21-0.30% 19.8
0.31-0.40% 25.6
0.41-0.50% 12.8
0.51 % and above 24.4
Total 100.0
Average Rate 0.31%
* Effective Octroi Rate Octroi Rate = Specific Octroi
Rate/Consumer/wholesale price x 100.
** For a sample of 23 cities.
*** For 86 commodities in the Schedule
Table 3
Average Effective Octroi Rates by Type of Commodity
Type of Commodity Average Effective Octroi Rate (%)
Consumer Goods 0.30
Food and Drinks 0.35
Consumer Durables 0.26
Others 0.25
Raw Materials/ Intermediate Goods 0.36
Capital Goods 0.36
Overall Average 0.31
Table 4
Determinants of Octroi Rates (a)
Variable Coefficient t-statistics
CONSTANT -0.2186 -0.17
Type of good [TYPE)
Food items 2.2223 1.57 **
Intermediate goods 4.5600 2.49 *
Luxury consumer goods 7.3910 3.72 *
INCOME ELASTICITY [IE;] 1.0563 0.61
PRICE ELASTICITY [PE;] -2.6100 -1.63 **
PER CAPITA INDUSTIRAL VALUE-
ADDED [PCIND] -7.69x[10.sup.5] -1.11
MUNICIPAL STATUS [[MSTAT.sub.m]]
Municipal corporation 0.0002 1.61 **
Municipal committee 0.0003 2.00 *
Town committee 0.0006 2.76 *
PROVINCE [[PROV.sub.L]]
Balochistan 5.9367 2.18 *
NWFP -1.3569 -0.81
Sindh 2.6308 1.87 *
[PRICE.sub.ij2] 0.0039 10.25
[PRICE.sub.ij3] -1.62x[l0.sup.7] -6.71
[PRICE.sub.ij] 1.68X[10.sup.12] 4.04 *
INTERACTIVE TYPER
Food items -0.0009 -2.72 *
Intermediate goods -0.0013 -3.45 *
Luxury consumer goods 0.0002 1.50
INTERACTIVE [PRICE.sub.ij]/
[MSTAT.sub.m]
Municipal corporation 0.0002 1.61
Municipal committee 0.0003 2.00 *
Town committee 0.0006 2.76 *
INTERACTIVE [PROV.sub.L]
Balochistan 0.0040 15.55 *
NWFP -8.80x[10.sup.5] -0.55
Sindh 0.0005 3.84 *
CITY-SPECIFIC DUMMIES
Shikarpur -9.0127 -4.01
Rahim Yar Khan 5.3218 2.48 *
Sialkot 5.2816 2.47 *
No. of observation = 1901
[[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.478
F-stat = 73.55
(a) Tested for homoskedasticity.
* Significant at 5 percent level.
** Significant at 10 percent level.
Table 5
Candidate Commodities for Octroi Rate Rationalisation
S. Names of Number of Local Positive Negative
No. Commodities Councils Outlier * Outlier *
1 Air conditioners 7 7 --
2 Bricks 1 1 --
3 Cigarettes of all kinds 2 2 --
4 Combs, brushes, etc. 1 1 --
5 Commercial acid,
sulphuric acid, etc. 1 1 --
6 Cotton cloth 2 2 --
7 Electric bulbs & tubes 2 2 --
8 Hosiery of all kinds 1 1 --
9 Jute bags, etc. 1 1 --
10 Leather 1 1 --
11 Milk powder, glucose,
etc. 1 1 --
12 Motor-cycles,
scooters, etc. 6 6 --
13 Pepper (black), etc. 1 1 --
14 Pickles, etc. 1 l --
15 Poultry 1 l --
16 Perfumes, etc. 6 6 --
17 Ready-made garments,
etc. 3 2 1
18 Refrigerators & deep
freezers 7 7 --
19 Sewing-machines,
knitting-machines 1 - 1
20 Shaving creams &
blades 2 1 1
21 Silk cloth 1 1 --
22 Tables, chairs,
sofas, etc. l 1 --
23 Tablets of all kinds 3 3 --
24 Tea, coffee, cocoa,
etc. l 1 --
25 Television 2 2 --
26 Tiles & glazed tiles 3 3 --
27 Washing machines 5 5 --
28 Woollen cloth 3 3 --
* An outlier is an observation whose value exceeds the value of other
observations in the sample by perhaps two standard deviations away
from the mean value of all the observations.