Dynamic budgetary consequences of the 1991 NFC award.
Ghaus, A.F. Aisha ; Pasha, Hafiz A.
1. INTRODUCTION
The National Finance Commission (NFC) award of 1991 has been
acclaimed to be a historic achievement of the previous elected
government. It has come after a gap of many years (due since 1979) and
some abortive attempts earlier. (1) Meanwhile, the provinces had run
into large, chronic deficits on the current account, indicating the
growing inadequacy of divisible pool transfers as per the provisions of
the 1974 award. Consequently, as an ad hoc provision, deficit grants and
other subventions had been used increasingly to support the on-going
operations of the provinces. At their peak in 1987-88, these grants were
Rs 17 billion (see Table 1), equivalent to about 2 percent of the Gross
Domestic Product (GDP) and financed over one-fourths of the provincial
current expenditure. Also, the federal government took over the
responsibility of provision of some provincial responsibilities as
contained in the Concurrent List of the Constitution like SCARPS, flood
control, fertiliser subsidy, universities, etc.
There had, however, been growing dissatisfaction with the existing
pattern of inter-governmental fiscal relations in the country. On the
one hand, the high and growing dependence on discretionary fiscal
transfers had mitigated against financial autonomy and, on the other
hand, the implied residual access to grants had left provinces with
little incentive either to mobilise their own resources or to economise on their expenditure. Provincial own revenues grew only modestly, at
about 11 percent, while provincial current expenditures increased at a
rapid rate, approaching 18 percent. Contrary perhaps to expectations,
rapid growth in federal transfers had not improved the fiscal status of
the provincial governments. There was fast growth simultaneously both in
divisible pool transfers and in grants and the increasing inability of
the provincial governments to generate revenue surpluses for
self-financing part of their development programme. Furthermore, these
ad hoc arrangements had resulted in significant budgetary strains on the
federal government also. In the 80s, upto 1987-88, almost one-third of
the incremental federal budgetary deficit was due to the increase in
deficit grants to the provinces.
In 1987-88, a ceiling was imposed on deficit grants to the
provinces which led to some restraint in expenditures and additional
fiscal effort. But in the absence of expanded divisible pool transfers,
provinces had run into unsustainable deficits, with the use of cash
balances (overdraft with State Bank of Pakistan) rising to over Rs 4.5
billion by 1990-91. Consequently, it had become essential to review the
fiscal relations between the federation and the provinces to promote the
process of decentralisation, to expand the availability of resources of
lower levels of government and to improve generally the efficiency in
the mobilisation and utilisation of resources. This has become
especially important in the current context when the country is
confronted with high and rising budget deficit and higher resource
mobilisation by all levels of government has assumed vital importance.
The purpose of this paper is to review if the recently announced
NFC award helps in meeting these objectives. Using a theoretical model,
it aims to study (2) historically the nature of provincial fiscal
response to federal transfers and borrowings from the viewpoint of their
impact on the level of own revenue generation expenditure. Also, it
attempts to answer a number of questions relating to the magnitude of
the increase in the transfers to the provinces as a whole and the
implications of the new provisions on the fiscal behaviour of provinces.
Section 2 describes the salient features of the new NFC award. Section 3
presents the theoretical framework of the analysis followed by the
estimation methodology. Section 4 quantities the dynamic consequences of
the award on the four provinces combined. Finally, in Section 5, we
present the major conclusions and policy implications emanating from the
results.
2. DESCRIPTION OF THE AWARD
The NFC Award of 1991 expands the size of the divisible pool of
taxes to include two additional taxes, excise duties on tobacco and
tobacco manufactures and sugar. These taxes are to be shared between the
federation and the provinces on a 20:80 basis after allowing for costs
of collection and distributed among the provinces on the basis of
population. The award also transfers proceeds from development surcharge on natural gas, royalty on crude oil and net profits on hydel power
generation to the province of collection. On top of this, special annual
grants of Rs 700 million for five years to Sindh, one billion to Punjab,
Rs 200 million to NWFP and Rs 100 million to Balochistan for three years
each has also been announced.
The 1991 NFC award, distinguishes itself from the previous awards
in a number of ways. First, it enhances provincial financial autonomy
through a large increase in constitutionally mandated federal transfers,
thereby reducing dependence on ad hoc grants and subventions from the
federal government. In 1991-92, federal transfers were Rs 64 billion or
45 percent of total federal tax revenues. In the absence of the award,
these transfers would have been Rs 39 billion, equivalent to 28 percent
of federal tax revenues (see Table 2).
Second, the 1991 NFC award significantly improves the incentive
environment and encourages financial discipline by the provinces. The
discretionary element in grants has been eliminated and a system of
fixed, special grants to each province has been instituted. This implies
that provinces no longer have access to residual fiscal deficit grants.
Furthermore, any surplus generated can be retained by the province.
Therefore, by and large, provinces have been made responsible for their
deficits/surpluses. In the absence of increase in borrowing powers the
provinces are now compelled to exercise strict financial discipline.
We now proceed to set up the theoretical framework within the
context of which the fiscal behaviour of the provincial governments to
federal transfers in Pakistan can be explained. This will enable formal
analysis of the effects of the 1991 NFC award.
3. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
The approach generally adopted for modelling the fiscal response of
a government to transfers from a higher level of government is to assume
that politicians/officials of the former maximise the utility of the
typical citizen living in their jurisdiction subject to a budget
constraint [Slack (1980); Henderson (1968)]. Utility is assumed to
depend positively on the quantity of goods and services provided by the
government and on the level of consumption of private goods. Therefore,
the utility function can be stated as (3)
U = U [y - R, E] ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (1)
where y = real per capita income, R = real per capita revenue and E
= real per capita expenditure of
[partial derivative] U/[partial derivative] (y - R) > 0,
[[partial derivative].sup.2] U/[[partial derivative] (y - R).sup.2] <
0, [partial derivative] U/[partial derivative] E > 0, [[partial
derivative].sup.2] U/ [partial derivative] [E.sup.2] < 0
the provincial government (y-R) corresponds to the level of
consumption of private goods.
R includes both tax and non-tax revenues while E consists both of
current and development expenditure. Aggregation is justified on the
grounds that the difference between these two types of expenditure is
not clear in practice. For example, current expenditures on education
and health could legitimately be treated as development expenditure as
they expand the productive capacity of the economy. Alternatively, a
component of development expenditure is shown in the recurring budget
and consists mostly of salaries and allowances of project related gaff.
We exclude, however, from expenditure payments for servicing of debt as
these do not benefit citizens directly through provision of services.
The budget constraint (at current prices) can be expressed as;
[p.sub.2] E = [p.sub.1] R + [bar.T] + [bar.B] + G ... ... ... ...
... ... (2)
where [p.sub.2] = price index of public expenditure, [p.sub.1] =
consumer price index, T = per capita total intergovernmental transfers
from the divisible pool of federal taxes as per the provisions of NFC
award, [bar.B] = per capita borrowings by the provincial government.
These are also assumed to be exogenous as, under the Constitutional
provisions, borrowings on behalf of the provincial governments consist
of federal loans as part of the annual development programme (ADP), net
capital receipts and use of cash balances with the State Bank of
Pakistan. (4)
G consists of grants from the federal government. Prior to the 1991
NFC award these consisted of two types of grants, lump sum grants and
deficit grants. The former were given as subventions for performance of
various agency functions, for special development programmes, etc.
Deficit grants had increasingly been given, as highlighted earlier, to
cover budget deficits of provincial governments due to the paucity of
resources caused by the delay in the updating of revenue sharing arrangements. Therefore, total flow of grants was given by
G = [G.sub.0] + m[[p.sub.2]E - [p.sub.1] [R - [bar.T] - [G.sub.0]],
0 < m < 1 ... ... ... ... (3)
Over time, provinces had begun to operate in a framework of
'rational expectations' about these deficit grants and base
their decisions about the level of taxation and expenditure on these
expectations.
Substituting (3) into (2) we obtain,
[p.sub.2] E - [p.sub.1] R - [bar.T] - [G.sub.0] = [bar.B]/1 - m ...
... ... ... ... ... (4)
This is the revised formulation of the budget constraint in the
presence of deficit grants. The stimulatory effect of these grants on
the level of expenditure and the negative impact on fiscal effort can be
seen from (4) as follows:
as m [right arrow] 1, E [right arrow] [infinity], R [right arrow]
-[infinity]
This explains why the resort to ad hoc deficit grants by the
federal government had led to a profligacy in expenditure on the part of
provincial governments and poor mobilisation of resources from own
revenues.
The budget constraint can be written as
[p.sub.1] (y - R) + [p.sub.2] E = [p.sub.1] y + [bar.T] + [G.sub.0]
+ [bar.B]/1 - m
Based on (1) and (4) we can set up the utility maximisation problem
as follows:
L (R, E, [lambda]) = U (y - R, E) + [lambda][I - [p.sub.1] (y - R)
- [p.sub.2] E] ... ... (5)
where I = [p.sub.1] y + [bar.T] + [G.sub.0] + [bar.B]/1 - m.
The first order conditions are as follows:
[partial derivative]L/[partial derivative]R = -[partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative](y - R) + [lambda][p.sub.1] = 0 ... ...
... ... ... ... (16)
[partial derivative]L/[partial derivative]E = [partial
derivative]U/[partial derivative]E - [lambda][p.sub.2] = 0 ... ... ...
... ... ... (7)
[partial derivative]L/[partial derivative][lambda] = I - [p.sub.1]
(y - R) - [p.sub.E] = 0 ... ... ... ... ... ... (8)
In particular it may be noted from differentiation of Equation (4)
that
[partial derivative] (p.sub.2] E)/[partial derivative]T - [partial
derivative]([p.sub.1] R)/[partial derivative]T = 1 ... ... ... ... ...
... (9)
This is the standard result and highlights the fact that a one
rupee increase in transfers due to NFC provisions is distributed
partially in increased expenditure and partially in reduced taxation.
The precise sharing of the impact is an empirical question to which we
turn to in the next section.
4. ESTIMATION
For estimation purposes, we specify the utility function explicitly
as follow:
U = [(Y - R - [y.sub.0]).sup.[alpha]] [(E -
[E.sub.0]).sup.1-[alpha]], 0 < [alpha] < 1 ... ... ... (10)
This is analogous Stone-Geary utility function. Substituting the
derivatives of this function into (6) and (7) respectively, we obtain
-[alpha]U/Y - R - [Y.sub.0] + [lambda] [p.sub.1] = 0 ... ... ...
... ... ... (11)
(1 - [alpha])U/E - [E.sub.0] - [lambda] [p.sub.2] = 0 ... ... ...
... ... ... (12)
This yields
[p.sub.1] (y - R) = [alpha]U/[lambda] + [p.sub.1] [y.sub.0] ... ...
... ... ... ... (13)
and
[p.sub.2] E = (1 - [alpha])U/[lambda] + [E.sub.0][p.sub.2] ... ...
... ... ... ... (14)
Substituting into (4) gives
U/[lambda] = I - [p.sub.1] [y.sub.0] - [p.sub.2] [E.sub.0] ... ...
... ... ... ... (15)
Substitution into (14) yields the following equation for public
expenditure,
[p.sub.2] E = [alpha] [E.sub.0] [p.sub.2] - (1 - [alpha]) [p.sub.1]
[y.sub.0] + (1 - [alpha]) ([p.sub.1] y + [bar.T] + [G.sub.0]) + (1 -
[alpha])/(1 - m) [bar.B]
At this stage we make the assumption that the minimum bundle,
[y.sub.0], rises with income. That is,
[y.sub.0] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1]y
Therefore, we have finally the expenditure equation for estimation
purposes as follows:
[p.sub.2]E = ([alpha][E.sub.0])[p.sub.2] - [(1 -
[alpha])[a.sub.0]][p.sub.1] + [(1 - [alpha]) (1 -
[[alpha].sub.1])]([p.sub.1]y) + (1 - [alpha]) + (T + [G.sub.0]) + (1 -
[alpha])/(1 - m) B ... ... ... ... ... (16)
Substitution into (4) yields the revenue function as follows:
[p.sub.1]R = ([alpha][E.sub.0])[p.sub.2] + [(1 -
[alpha])[a.sub.0]][p.sub.1] + [(1 - [alpha])(1 -
[[alpha].sub.1])][p.sub.1][y - [alpha]]
([bar.T] + [G.sub.0]) - [alpha]/(1 - m) [bar.M] ... ... ... ... ...
... (17)
It may be noted from (16) and (17) that
[partial derivative] (p.sub.2]E)/[partial derivative] T = (1 -
[alpha]), [partial derivative]([p.sub.1]R)/[partial derivative] T =
-[alpha]
and condition (9) is satisfied. Also, estimation of Equation (16)
will yield the coefficients of Equation (17).
The above model has been estimated for the four provincial
governments combined. Individual province level analysis was not
possible because of basic data limitations, for example, the
non-availability of estimates of provincial gross regional products.
Annual Budget Statements of the individual provinces have been used to
generate the aggregate data base for key provincial budgetary magnitudes
like total expenditures (recurring + development), federal transfers and
borrowings.
Equation (16) is estimated for the period, 1972-73 to 1990-91,
prior to the 1991 NFC award. Results of estimation are as follows:
[P.sub.2]E = 0.0299([P.sub.1]y) + 0.6137([bar.T] + [G.sub.0]) +
(3.276) * (6.602) *
0.8967[bar.B] + 90.0497[P.sub.2] - 83.2280[P.sub.1]
(7.345) * (7.003) * (-2.646) *
+ 51.7889 D
(3.461) * ...... ... ... ... ... (18)
[[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.997 D-W Statistic = 2.60
* Significant at 1 percent level.
Equation (18) shows that a one-rupee increase in federal transfers
leads to as much as a 61 paisas increase in provincial expenditure. The
remaining 39 paisas are absorbed in a reduction of provincial fiscal
effort. This result is in contrast to the earlier results of Slack
(1980) for Canada in which bulk of the adjustment due to increased
transfers is on the revenue side. The result indicates that in Pakistan
a higher premium is placed on the increase in expenditure rather than on
a reduction in fiscal effort.
The other result of interest is the high stimulatory impact of
borrowings on expenditure. A rupee of borrowing leads to almost a 90
paisas increase in provincial expenditure. This is because of the
non-zero value of m in Equation (16) which gives the proportion of the
revenue deficit financed by revenue deficit grants. The estimated
magnitude of m is about 0.30. This implies that prior to the 1991 NFC
award about 30 percent of the basic budget deficit of the provinces was
met through deficit grants.
Furthermore, increase in the unit costs of public administration,
primarily due to periodic pay awards, also has had a significant
positive impact on provincial liabilities. Finally, the mid 80s
witnessed a spur in expenditures by the provincial governments due to
the Five Point programme announced by the Janejo Government. The average
growth rate of provincial governments during this period was about 21
percent. The growth in current expenditures was particularly high. This
phenomenon is reflected by the positive and significant dummy (5)
variable, D, for the period in Equation (18). On the whole, increase in
GDP, federal transfers, provincial borrowings, unit cost of public
administration and the implementation of the five point programme
largely explain the increase in provincial expenditures during the
period of analysis. The model successfully explains bulk of the
variation in provincial expenditure.
5. DYNAMIC CONSEQUENCES OF AWARD
Given the above results, we are now in a position to derive the
consequences of the 1991 NFC award on various budgetary magnitudes. Two
years have elapsed since the award was announced and emerging trends
have become visible. Table 3 compares the growth rates during the decade
of 1980s under the previous regime of inter-governmental fiscal
relations and those observed in the immediate aftermath of the award.
Contrary to expectations, there is little change either in the growth
rate of expenditure or of provincial own revenues. As highlighted above,
there was a quantum jump in divisible pool transfers in 1991-92. The
question is why this has not been translated into a corresponding
increase in expenditure or decline in own revenues. This requires
analysis of the various factors affecting expenditure and taxation
decisions in the post-1991 NFC era.
Given the cessation of deficit grants following the 1991 NFC award
we have that, since 1991-92, m=0. Substituting this into Equation (16)
we can derive the difference in expenditure in the presence and in the
absence of the 1991 NFC award as follows:
E' - E (1 - [alpha]) [bar.T]' - [bar.T] + (1 - [alpha])
[[bar.B'] - [bar.B]] + (1 - [alpha]) [bar.B] [1-1/1 - m] ... ...
(19)
Equation (19) presents the decomposition of the difference in
expenditure in the presence and in the absence of the 1991 NFC award.
The first component gives the impact of the increase in divisible pool
transfers (plus lump sum grants) from [bar.T] to [bar.T'] due to
the expansion in revenue-sharing arrangements. The second term captures
the effect of any decline in borrowings by the provincial governments
from [bar.B] to [bar.B']. It is likely that given the large
expansion in divisible pool transfers the federal government has limited
its transfers on other accounts. This is confirmed by Table 3. Large
declines have occurred in the post 1991 NFC period in growth rates of
non-development grants, development revenue receipts and of cash
development loans as part of the ADP.
The third component of Equation (19) highlights the change in the
incentive environment following major changes in the pattern of
inter-governmental fiscal relations in 1991. The cessation of deficit
grants has removed one major factor contributing to fast growth in
expenditure by provincial governments. The resulting fall in m to zero
is likely to limit the level of expenditure.
Results of the decomposition exercise are presented in Table 4. As
expected, the impact of increase in transfers on the current account on
expenditure in sizeable. However, this is largely neutralised by the
decline in borrowings and, more importantly, by behavioural changes
caused by the removal of deficit grants from the provisions of the 1991
NFC award. In fact, the difference between projected expenditures in the
presence and in the absence of the award appears to have narrowed
significantly in the first two post-1991 NFC years. Contrary to
perceptions, therefore, the award has begun to exert a restraining effect on provincial expenditures despite the large expansion in the
divisible pool. The primary reasons for this are lower transfers on the
capital account and the pressure now on provincial governments to keep
down the revenue deficit due to lack of access anymore to deficit grants
from the federal government.
Table 5 gives the projected levels of expenditure according to Equation (16) in the absence and in the presence (with m = 0) of the
1991 NFC award. The latter are compared with the actual magnitudes.
Actual expenditures following the award appear to be somewhat higher by
about 3 percent than these projected by the equation. This can largely
be attributed to the fact that the Pay Committee award was implemented
in 1991-92. The price index for the public administration and defence
sector in the national income accounts does not appear to fully reflect
the impact on wage levels of this award. The average increase in salary
and allowances in different grades was over 15 percent whereas the index
showed an increase of 9 percent in 1991-92.
As highlighted above, we also observe a narrowing of the difference
between actual expenditure following the NFC award and the projected
expenditure in the absence of the award. It was 6-5 percent in 1991-92
and has fallen to 4 percent in 1992-93. On this basis, expenditure in
the absence of the award may even be higher by 1995-96, the last year
for which the award is operative.
Budget Deficit
We are finally in a position to derive the impact on the overall
national budget deficit, as well as the effect separately of the NFC
award on the budgetary position of the federal and provincial
governments respectively. For this purpose we define the following:
[E.sub.F] = expenditure by the federal government, [E.sub.P] =
expenditure by the provincial governments, [R.sub.F]. = revenues
collected by the federal government, (6) [R.sub.P] = revenues collected
by the provincial governments. Then, the overall budget deficit, BD, is
given by,
BD = [E.sub.F] + [E.sub.P] + [R.sub.F] - [R.sub.P] ... ... ... ...
... ... (2O)
If we allow for intergovernmental transfers then
BD = [[E.sub.F] + G + T - [R.sub.F]] + [[E.sub.P] - [R.sub.P] - G -
T] ... ... ... (21)
where T = federal transfers from divisible pool plus lump sum
grants and G = deficit grants to provincial governments. The first part
of Equation (21) is the budget deficit, [BD.sub.F], due to the federal
government and second part is [BD.sub.P], the budget deficit due to
provincial governments. Therefore, changes due to the NFC award can be
expressed as follows:
[DELTA][BD.sub.F] = [DELTA][E.sub.F] + [DELTA]G + [DELTA]T -
[DELTA][R.sub.F] ... ... ... ... ... (22)
[DELTA][BD.sub.P] = [DELTA][E.sub.P] - [DELTA][R.sub.P] - [DELTA]G
- [DELTA]T ... ... ... ... ... (23)
and [DELTA]BD = [DELTA][E.sub.F] - [DELTA]R.sub.F] +
[DELTA]E.sub.P] - [DELTA]][R.sub.P] ... ... ... ... ... (24)
On the basis of Equations (3), (6) and (17) we derive the
magnitudes of [DELTA]G, [DELTA][E.sub.P] and [DELTA][R.sub.P]
respectively. Behavioural changes by the federal government due to the
NFC award are outside the purview of this paper. Therefore, we assume
that [DELTA][E.sub.F] = 0 and [DELTA][R.sub.F] = 0. In fact, there is
some indication that the federal government has raised its level of
fiscal effort in 1991-92 and 1992-93.
Given the above accounting identities and assumptions, the impact
of the NFC award on the federal budget deficit consists primarily of the
increase in unconditional transfers on the current account less the
savings due to the cessation of deficit grants. For the provincial
governments, the change in budget deficit is due to change in
expenditure, own revenues, transfers and deficit grants. The combined
change on the national budget deficit is primarily the change in
provincial expenditure and own revenues caused by the award.
The estimated changes are presented in Table 6. The major
conclusion is that the overall impact of the 1991 NFC award on the
national budget deficit is not large, at about 0.4 percent of the GDP in
1991-92 and marginal in 1992-93. However, the impact on the federal
deficit is sizeable at close to I percent of the GDP in both years.
SUMMARY OF CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
This paper has analysed the fiscal response of the provincial
governments to transfers from the federal government. Results of
estimation within the framework of a theoretical model reveal that for a
one-rupee increase in transfers, there is, on the average, a 61 paisas
increase in current expenditure and a decline in own-revenues of about
39 paisas. Results further indicate that a corresponding increase in
borrowings has a greater stimulatory impact, of about 90 palms, on
provincial expenditure. Consequently, the sizeable increase historically
in divisible pool transfers accompanied by the increase in borrowings
and grants has actually led to a deterioration in the budgetary position
of the provinces.
However, contrary to expectations, the 1991 NFC award exerts a
restraining effect on provincial expenditures despite the large
expansion in the divisible pool of taxes. This is primarily due to lower
transfers on the capital account and elimination of revenue deficit
grants. Indications are that expenditure in the presence of the award
may even be lower by 1995-96, the last year for which the award is
operative, than would otherwise have been the case.
Another major conclusion is that even though the impact of the 1991
NFC award on the federal budget deficit is sizeable, close to 1 percent
of the GDP, from the viewpoint of the overall national budget deficit it
is marginal.
The above consequences are largely due to the change in the
incentive environment and a degree of financial discipline introduced by
the NFC award. It is therefore important that the spirit of the award be
preserved and the federal government must resist in particular any
pressure to give deficit grants once again to the provinces.
Also, given that bulk of the adjustment of increased federal
transfers is on the expenditure side, regulatory measures are required
to ensure efficient utilisation of resources. These include, for
example, a general ban on social employment. Special permission to hire
additional staff should only be given for project related employment as
new facilities are constructed and commissioned. The decision by the
federal government to give matching development grants to provincial
governments for higher fiscal effort [measured by revenues generated
from taxation proposals during a particular fiscal year] is also a step
in the right direction and may help in sustaining provincial revenues in
the presence of a large increase in divisible pool transfers.
Finally, the paper has attempted analysis of the consequences of
the 1991 NFC award for the four provinces combined. If reasonable
regional income estimates or proxies become available then the analysis
may be extended to determine the differential impact on each provincial
government. This will enable appropriate corrective action to be taken
in the next award, due after 1995-96.
Comments on "Dynamic Budgetary Consequences of the 1991 NFC
Award"
The paper is quite interesting and topical as it examines the
effect of the 1991 NFC award on the budgetary deficits of the provincial
governments. It comes up with interesting conclusions regarding the
impact of the transfers of the federal government on the expenditures
and resource mobilisation efforts of the provincial governments. My
comments on the paper relate to the specification of the model,
econometric estimation and the conclusion drawn from the analysis.
The model specifies a utility function in terms of revenue and
expenditure diverging from a specified limit. Notwithstanding the fact
that development and non-development expenditures have different
implications for growth, they have been pooled together. How the
distinction between these two types of expenditures would affect the
results needs to be explored. Even more importantly, there are problems
with the specification of the model. It assumes that the utility
function is homogenous of degree zero but no attempt has been made to
test the degree of homogeneity. Moreover, the utility function taken as
the differential in the revenue and expenditures from the base values
can explode if both the expenditure and revenues have the same
coefficient. The implications that the two coefficients would diverge are not less serious either. Similarly, the specification of the
constraint is a little odd. It is a constraint, which can also be
modified as soon as expenditures increase. Probably, the constraint
needs to be reformulated. Moreover, the lag adjustments have been
completely ignored.
In the econometric specification the variable p appears on both
sides of the equation, though they have a different subscript. Are the
two prices not necessarily the same? And if they are then would it not
lead to spurious results and as such the high [[bar.R].sup.2] may be
just a reflection of the specification.
The paper makes a comparison of federal transfers as a percentage
of total tax revenues. Since grants were the major component prior to
1990-91, a proper comparison would be the total amount of federal
resources transferred to provincial government including grants and
share in revenue to the NFC award.
The paper comes to the conclusion that an increase in one rupee of
provincial transfer would reduce the resource mobilisation by 39 paisas.
If the conclusions are accepted, the provincial government's
non-revenues by now would have had been zero, but they are not. Another
interesting result is that borrowing one rupee leads to an increase of
90 paisas in the provincial expenditure. Since the government borrows
money after the expenditure has been incurred, one wonders why the
provincial governments on average would like to borrow ten percent more
than the demand.
A. R. Kemal
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
REFERENCES
Henderson, James M. (1968) Local Government Expenditures: A Social
Welfare Analysis. The Review of Economics and Statistics 50: May 156-63.
Slack, Enid (1980) Local Fiscal Response to Inter-governmental
Transfers. Review of Economics and Statistics.
(1) According to Article 160 of the 1973 Constitution, the
President of Pakistan is expected to constitute a NFC every five years
to make recommendations on the distribution between the federation and
provinces of the net proceeds of divisible pool taxes (as specified by
the President), the making of grants-in-aid, and exercise of borrowing
powers by the provinces. Two NFCs were constituted in 1979 and 1985 but
no consensus could be reached among the provinces on the distribution
formula.
(2) Study of the revenue-sharing formula for allocation among
provinces from the divisible pool of taxes is outside the purview of
this paper.
(3) For the typical citizen or median voter. These are the same
given the assumption of identical households.
(4) Provincial governments have a limited over-draft facility with
the State Bank of Pakistan.
(5) The value of the dummy is as follows: 1 for 1985-86; 1.5 for
1986.87; 2.0 for 1987-88; 1 for 1988.89 and 0 otherwise.
(6) Including self-financing by autonomous bodies.
A. F. Aisha Ghaus and Hafiz A. Pasha are Research Economist and
Director respectively at the Applied Economics Research Centre,
University of Karachi, Karachi.
Table 1
Key Budgetary Magnitudes of the Provincial Governments
Combined, 1972-73 to 1992-93
(Rs in Million)
Budgetary Magnitudes 1972-73 1977-78 1982-83 1987-88
General Revenue Receipts 2342 7644 17410 45217
Federal Tax Assignments 857 3250 9318 15130
Provincial Tax Receipts 703 1509 2586 4036
Provincial Non-Tax Receipts 743 1515 3219 8841
Federal
Non-Development Grants (a) 39 1370 2287 17210
Current Expenditure 2647 7745 17421 46138
Debt Servicing 320 1470 3727 10711
Service-related
Expenditure (b) 2327 6275 13685 35427
Revenue Surplus(+)/Deficit(-) -305 -101 -2 -921
Development Revenue Receipts 296 821 1017 9156
Net Capital Receipts 1630 3140 6569 5490
Federal Loans 1489 2807 5496 5867
Others 141 333 1099 -377
Development Expenditure 1961 3989 7365 16968
Development
Revenue Expenditure 851 1190 2390 5870
Development
Capital Expenditure 1110 2799 4974 11098
Use of Cash Balances (c) 340 129 -246 3243
Population (in Million) 65.89 76.60 89.12 103.82
Budgetary Magnitudes 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92
General Revenue Receipts 48391 49162 57027 80617
Federal Tax Assignments 23783 30648 33526 63987
Provincial Tax Receipts 4547 5014 6764 7794
Provincial Non-Tax Receipts 4814 5807 6188 6392
Federal
Non-Development Grants (a) 15248 7692 10550 2443
Current Expenditure 48468 52022 63261 75448
Debt Servicing 11491 13149 15626 19010
Service-related
Expenditure (b) 36977 38873 47635 56438
Revenue Surplus(+)/Deficit(-) -77 -2860 -6234 5169
Development Revenue Receipts 9611 2944 6569 5633
Net Capital Receipts 171 13242 18413 13800
Federal Loans 5194 12715 15990 16167
Others -5023 527 2423 -2376
Development Expenditure 15391 16704 23270 27982
Development
Revenue Expenditure 5309 5561 9908 11021
Development
Capital Expenditure 10082 11143 13362 16962
Use of Cash Balances (c) 5686 3378 4522 3380
Population (in Million) 107.04 110.36 113.78 117.32
Budgetary Magnitudes 1992-93
General Revenue Receipts 91650
Federal Tax Assignments 71919
Provincial Tax Receipts 8915
Provincial Non-Tax Receipts 6673
Federal
Non-Development Grants (a) 4143
Current Expenditure 86877
Debt Servicing 21425
Service-related
Expenditure (b) 65452
Revenue Surplus(+)/Deficit(-) 4773
Development Revenue Receipts 4215
Net Capital Receipts 16336
Federal Loans 16306
Others 29
Development Expenditure 30398
Development
Revenue Expenditure 12321
Development
Capital Expenditure 18077
Use of Cash Balances (c) 5074
Population (in Million) 120.84
Source: Annual Budget Statements of Provincial Governments.
Totals may not add up due to rounding.
(a) Mostly deficit grants or special grants after 1990-91
as part of 1991 NFC award.
(b) Expenditure on general administration; economic,
social and community services.
(c) Positive figures indicates higher overdraft
with State Bank of Pakistan.
Table 2
Revenues Sources and Magnitude of Transfers to Provinces (Combined)
With and Without NFC Award of 1991 in 1991-92
(Rs in Billion)
Without 1991 NFC Award With 1991 NFC Award
Transfers Share(%) Transfers Share(%)
(A) Revenue Sources
Shared on the
Basis of
Population 37.3 95.3 47.6 74.4
Income Tax 19.4 49.4 19.4 30.3
Sales Tax 16.3 41.7 16.3 25.5
Export Duty on
Cotton 1.5 3.9 1.5 2.4
Excise Duty on
Tobacco
Manufactures -- -- 6.8 10.7
Excise Duty on
Sugar -- -- 3.5 5.4
(B) Revenue Sources
Shared on the
Basis of
Collection 1.8 4.7 16.4 25.6
Excise Duty
and Royalty on
Gas 1.8 4.7 1.8 2.9
Surcharge on Gas -- -- 7.4 11.6
Royalty on Crude
Oil -- -- 1.1 1.8
Profits on
Hydro-electricity -- -- 6.0 9.4
Total 39.1 100.0 64.0 100.0
(C) Divisible Pool
Transfers as %
of Federal Tax
Revenues 27.6% 45.1%
Source: Annual Budget Statements, of Provincial Governments.
Table 3
Pre-and-Post-1991 NFC Award Rate of Growth in Key
Budgetary Magnitudes (Provincial Governments Combined)
(Annual Growth Rate %)
Pre 1991 Post 1991
NFC Award NFC Award Difference
(1982-83 to (1990-91 to in Growth
1990-91) 1992-93) Rate
General Revenue Receipts 16.0 26.8 10.8
Federal Tax Assignments 17.4 46.5 29.1
Provincial Own Receipts (a) 10.6 9.7 -0.9
Federal Non-development Grants 12.1 -37.3 -58.4
Current Expenditure 17.5 17.2 -0.6
Debt Servicing 19.6 17.1 -2.5
Service-related Expenditure 16.9 17.2 0.3
Development Revenue Receipts 26.3 -19.9 -46.2
Net Capital Receipts 13.7 -5.8 -19.5
Federal Loans 14.3 1.0 -13.3
Others -- (b) -89.1 --
Development Expenditure 15.5 143.0 -1.2
Total Expenditure (c) 16.4 162.0 -2.0
Use of Cash Balances -- (b) 5.9 --
Source: Derived from Table 1.
(a) Provincial Tax + Non-tax Receipts.
(b) Negative Value in Base Year.
(c) Current Expenditure + Development Expenditure--Debt Servicing.
Table 4
Decomposition of the Difference in Provincial Expenditure in the
Presence and in the Absence of the 1991 NFC Award
(Rs per Capita)
1991-92 1992-93
[bar.T]' 451.5 485.7 [alpha]
[bar.T] (a) 227.8 245.7 (1 - [alpha]) [[bar.T]' - [bar.T]]
[bar.B]' 146.4 177.2 (1 - [alpha]) [[bar.B]' - [bar.B]]
[bar.B] (b) 225.9 278.8 (1 - [alpha]) [bar.B] [1 - 1/1-m]
m' 0 0 E' - E
m 0.316 0.316
1991-92 1992-93
[bar.T]' 0.386 0.386
[bar.T] (a) 137.4 147.4
[bar.B]' -48.8 -62.4
[bar.B] (b) -64.1 -79.1
m' 24.5 5.9
m
(a) Revenues from sharing of taxes which were part o the
divisible pool prior to 1991.
(b) Borrowings by provincial governments in the absence of
the 1991 NFC award are estimated from the following equation:
ln [bar. B] = 4.2341 + 0.5581 t - 0.0309 [t.sup.2] + 0.00078
(12.234) (3.600) (-1.329) (-1.841)
[t.sup.3] - 0.849ln [bar.T] + 0.7549[D.sub.2]
(-5.194) (2.132)
[bar.R] = 0.887, D-W = 2.021
where t is a time variable with a value of 1 in 1972-73. [D.sub.2] is a
dummy variable with a value of 1 from 1990-91 onwards, zero otherwise.
Table 5
Projected and Actual Levels of Provincial Expenditure
and Revenues, 1991-92 and 1992-93
(Rs in Million)
1991-92 1992-93 Growth Rate (%)
Projected
In Absence of NFC Award[1] 79261 92174 16.3%
In Presence of NFC Award[2] 82147 92912 13.1%
Actual
In Presence of NFC Award[3] 84420 95850 13.5%
Difference (%)
[1] and [2] 3.6% 0.8%
[2] and [3] 2.8% 3.2%
[1] and [3] 6.5% 4.0%
Table 6
Impact of 1991 NFC Award on the Budget Deficit
(Rs in Million)
1991-92 1992-93
Impact oN Federal Budget Deficit
[DELTA] G -12244 -15572
[DELTA] T 26240 29010
[DELTA] [BD.sub.F] 13996 13488
[DELTA] [BD.sub.F] as % of GDP 1.15% 0.99%
Impact on Provincial Budget Deficit
[DELTA] [E.sub.P] 2886 738
[DELTA] G -12244 -15572
[DELTA] T 26240 29010
[DELTA] [R.sub.P] -1788 -422
[DELTA] [BD.sub.P] -9322 -12278
[DELTA] [BD.sub.P] as % of GDP -0.77% -0.90%
Impact on National Budget Deficit
[DELTA] BD 4674 1210
[DELTA] A BD as % of GDP 0.38% 0.09%