Testing for the onset of fertility decline: an illustration with the case of Egypt.
Zaky, Hassan ; Wong, Rebeca ; Sirageldin, Ismail 等
This paper describes and illustrates how the economic household
production model can be taken as a frame of reference to test the stage
of the fertility transition for a given society. Egypt during the 1970s
and early 1980s is taken as the setting to illustrate the test. Egyptian
fertility trends from the mid-1960s to the early 1980s puzzled
demographers and social scientists. It was not known if Egypt was at the
onset of a sustainable fertility decline by the early 1980s. The
illustration exercise shows that the Egyptian household fertility
behaviour during this period fits poorly with the model specification
corresponding to a post-transition society. We find that fertility by
the end of the 1970s was not endogenous to other household decisions,
and conclude that a sustained decline in fertility was unlikely without
this endogeneity. These results agree with previous literature on the
fertility transition in Egypt. The paper concludes with limitations of
the empirical test presented, laying emphasis on the lessons learned to
examine the stage of the fertility transition in any society. The
conclusions also highlight the importance of considering the stage of
the transition in order to specify fertility models appropriately.
INTRODUCTION
The economic household production model assumes that households
maximise utility under resource constraints-mostly time and income, and
given a set of preferences. In essence, the household production model
assumes that people behave rationally; that reproductive behaviour in
particular is economically rationale within biological, psychological,
and normative bounds. Individuals and households respond to price
signals and allocate their activities and resources within these set
bounds. The premise is the ability of the household to assign its
life-cycle time resource among three ends: activities that increase the
household members' market wage (that is, human capital), market
production, and non-market production including leisure. Accordingly,
the model implies simultaneous decisions on fertility and other
demographic and economic factors such as contraceptive use and female
labour force participation.
Applications of the model include those in developed- as well as
developing-country settings [DeTray (1974); Khan (1979); Michael
(1974)]. As [Easterlin (1975), p. 55] writes, "economics has
clarified causal inter-relations, for example, few economists would
speak of lower fertility 'causing' higher female labour force
participation, or vice versa, but would view both magnitudes as
simultaneously determined by other factors". It is argued, however,
that one of the shortcomings of the household production model is that
the outcome decisions modelled--such as fertility, contraceptive use,
and female labour force participation--may not be a matter of choice for
households in some societies. (1) Specially in pre-transition societies,
many of these decisions present limited choices. The trade-off between
fertility and other alternatives for time allocation by household
members may be highly limited. Hence, in this context, the predictions
of the household production model may not apply to all settings.
In the present paper, we argue that essentially three types of
societies exist. One is of stable high fertility where households do not
perceive a trade-off among the. various fertility-related household
outcomes. The second society implies a post-transitional stage, where
the household calculus of interdependent choices covers a wide range of
economic and demographic behaviour. The third is a transitional society.
It is our thesis that we could use the household production model as a
frame of reference to test the stage of the fertility transition for a
given society. If fertility as well as other decisions on the allocation
of resources are simultaneous, then the society is in a post-transition
stage. Alternatively, if the society is at the pre-transition stage,
fertility decisions are made mainly in the perceived context of
mortality restrictions and their biological consequences. The third type
is context-specific, where some, but not all, household decisions are
perceived under allocative control. In this sense, the weakness of the
household production model mentioned above can yield useful statements
on modelling fertility decisions for a given society: the
conceptualisation of fertility models is different if the particular
society under study is either in pre- or post-transition stage.
Egypt during the 1970s and early 1980s can be taken as the setting
to perform the test. Egyptian fertility trends from the mid-1960s to the
early 1980s have puzzled demographers and social scientists. The main
puzzle is the steady decline in the crude birth rate between 1964 and
1972, followed by a steady rise through the early 1980s. Several factors
can account for this reversal of trend. These include the presence of
difficult economic and social factors, such as the absence of husbands
and reduced incomes during the inter-war period, from 1967 to 1973. Such
explanations, although fitting conceptually with the general prediction
of the household production framework, lack an adequate explanation for
the full phenomenon. Bucht and El-Badry (1986) illustrated that the bulk
of change in the crude birth rate could be due to the change in the age
structure resulting from historical mortality and fertility experiences.
The analysis of Bucht and El-Badry questioned significant changes
in the fertility behaviour during the three decades following World War
II. Based on the 1980 Egyptian Fertility Survey, recent attempts to
examine demographic responses to modernisation did not give a clear
picture of the Egyptian demographic transition [Hallouda, Farid and
Cochrane (1988)]. For example, husband's and wife's education
were non-significant in models of the determinants of demand for
children [Cochrane, Khan and Osheba (1988)]. However, in the analysis of
the determinants of contraceptive use, female education opportunities
were significant while the analysis ".. demonstrated convincingly
that measures of female employment show [ed] no net effects on use"
[El-Deeb and Casterline (1988), p. 569]. Easterlin, Crimmins and Osheba
(1988) illustrated the importance of motivation in determining fertility
regulation, while income "added surprisingly little" to the
analysis of the impact of modernisation on the motivation for fertility
control [Easterlin, Crimmins, Ahmed and Soliman (1988), p. 671].
Analyses of age at marriage and age difference among spouses found
contradictions, leading [Sokona and Casterline (1988), p. 129] to
conclude that "our understanding of the determinants of the age
difference is poorly developed". In their analysis of the
determinants of birth interval length, [Trussell, Vaughan and Farid
(1988), p. 152] emphasised the importance of the biological determinants
in Egypt. Their analysis "... found that female education [was] not
a significant determinant of the risk of pregnancy; this (lack of
significance) is almost surely due to the effects of biological
factors." Other findings on infant and child mortality illustrate
the lack of consistent behavioural patterns [for example, Callum and
Cleland (1988); Eid and Casterline (1988)].
It is evident from this brief survey that whether Egypt had been at
the onset of a sustainable fertility decline by the early 1980s was
unknown. The purpose of the present paper is to illustrate that it is
possible to test if this was the case, using the approach described.
First, the paper will present the specification of alternative models
according to the stage of fertility transition (post-transition and
pre-transition). Next, we describe the data set available to perform the
test. We present the estimation techniques in the following section,
followed by the empirical findings. At the end, we provide the
discussion and conclusions.
It is worth mentioning that the main purpose of this paper is not
to add new knowledge to the subject of fertility transition in Egypt.
Rather, the purpose is to illustrate, with the case of Egypt, how the
predictions of the household production model can be used to test
empirically the stage of the fertility transition in a given society.
MODEL SPECIFICATION
Our approach is to examine fertility as a long-term decision,
instead of using a sequential decision-making approach. We condense a
couple's life cycle to one period; changes occurring during the
life cycle are ignored for the present investigation. Accordingly, our
focus is on couples who completed their desired family size by the end
of the 1970s. Hence, we study fertility from a completed-family-size
perspective, and we associate this variable with lifetime variables as
well, such as indicators of wealth and lifetime income, attained
education, ever-use of contraception, cumulative deaths, and
ever-employment of the woman. We use the household production model as
our frame of reference, and model a series of household-demand
functions. We present below the empirical specifications of the two
models, post- and pre-transition. Other specifications are presented in
Zaky (1989).
Post-Transition: Model I
For the transition from high to low fertility to become
sustainable, the relationship among a significant set of family size
decisions becomes integrated, re-enforcing, and simultaneously
determined in a behavioural context. These family size decisions include
fertility, contraceptive use, child mortality, female labour force, and
income. Families are assumed to control their resource allocation decisions, subject to basic resource constraints. Under such household
production regime, it is assumed that family size variables are choice
variables, fertility being one of them. This approach has long been
recognised in the economic demography literature [Cochrane, Khan and
Osheba (1988); Khan and Sirageldin (1975); Sirageldin et al. (1976);
Schultz (1978)]. Studies have concluded that fertility determination
should be estimated within a system of simultaneous equations. Hence,
the post-transition specification considers that a group of family
decisions are endogenous to the fertility decision. In our analysis,
these family decisions are: contraceptive use, child mortality, female
labour force, and income. The exogenous variables in our models include
variables both at the household and community levels, capturing aspects
of the opportunity cost of time, relative prices, social norms, and
household preferences. A brief elaboration of the choice variables
follows.
The decisions on income are assume as endogenous to the fertility
decision [Mueller and Short (1983)], since husbands may work longer
hours and increase their earnings as a response to more children. Also
at the post-transition stage, decisions on fertility are made
simultaneously with those on the allocation of time towards market
activities by women. Hence, female labour force is endogenous to
fertility decisions [Lee and Bulatao (1983); Schultz (1978)]. Child
mortality is an important determinant of the supply of children
[Bongaarts and Menken (1983)]. And it has been recognised as
simultaneously related to fertility, where the effect of fertility on
mortality is mainly biological, while the effect of mortality on
fertility is assumed as behavioural. Decisions on the use of
contraception are assumed to be made in the context of fertility
decisions as well [DeGraff (1991); Easterlin and Crimmins (1982)]. An
excess of number of children in relation to the desired number would
motivate the use of contraception.
Pre-Transition: Model II
In traditional societies with relatively high fertility rates,
fertility is only partly controlled, and dominated by factors external
to the family decision process. These factors can be norms, culture, and
biological constraints. In such regimes, the family decisions on
fertility (family size, contraception, child mortality, female
employment, and income) have not reached the stage of being family
choice variables. They can be considered as ascribed decisions, and
hence knowledge on fertility can be gained by a simple approach where
only fertility and mortality are outcome variables. Hence, for the
pre-transition stage, the empirical specification would be a system of
two equations, one for fertility and one for mortality. As mentioned
earlier, fertility decisions are made mainly in the perceived context of
mortality restrictions and the biological consequences. In this stage,
fertility and mortality are closely inter-related through biological
factors.
DATA SET
We use the Egyptian Fertility Survey (EFS), conducted in 1980 by
CAPMAS [CAPMAS (1983)]. Questionnaires were completed for 8,788
ever-married women. A second phase of the EFS included a sub-sample of
about one-third of the households interviewed in the first phase,
covering a sample of 2,532 households. This second phase of the survey
included an economic, a husband's, and community (for rural areas
only) questionnaires. The data we use includes information from both
phases. We also note that our data set is cross-sectional, failing to
provide any time-sequence of events, especially among the endogenous
variables. Hence, we are confined to a study of association rather than
causation.
Our sub-sample of analysis includes ever-married women between 35
and 49 years of age. We use this age group to get women with completed
family size. We restrict the analysis to those couples who, by virtue of
the wife's age, will have a low probability of having any more
children. This group of couples, however, may include women who want
more children. Accordingly, we further limit the analysis to those women
who are fecund, in union, exposed to the risk of conception, and do not
desire additional children. This definition of our sample may imply a
possible selection bias in our estimates. Our sub-sample includes 518
ever-married women who satisfy the previous conditions. In this group of
women, as is shown in Table A1 in the Appendix, women have an average of
6.7 children ever-born, and have experienced 1.5 child deaths per woman.
Ever-use of contraception is 71 percent, while only 18 percent of the
women had ever-worked since marriage. Forty-seven percent of the women
live in rural areas, they have an average of 2 years of education, and
82 percent have never been employed while in union. Their average age is
40 years and 48 years for the husbands. Appendix I presents a list of
the variables used in our analysis.
METHODS OF ESTIMATION
Model I
The specification of the model for fertility decisions under the
post-transition regime represents a system of simultaneous equations.
The specification corresponds to the one discussed in Khan and
Sirageldin (1975). The model considers five variables as endogenous and
includes 17 exogenous variables, as follows:
(1) Fertility Equation
CEB = f1 (EUSE, CHDD, WEMP, FAMC, AGR, RES, PNRM, MACH, PRES, AGEW,
YSIN, WBML, HEMP, YWUC, YHUC).
(2) Contraceptive Equation
EUSE = f2 (CEB, CHDD, WEMP, FAMC, AGR, WATE, ELEC, TRAN, PRES,
AGEW, AGEH, WBML, HEMP, YWUC, YHUC).
(3) Mortality Equation
CHDD = f2 (CEB, WEMP, FAMC, AGR, PNRM, WATE, ELEC, MACH, TRAN,
PRES, YSIN, HMIG, HEMP, YWUC, YHUC).
(4) Female Labour Force Participation Equation
WEMP = f4 (CEB, CHDD, FAMC, AGR, MACH, TRAN, PRES, AGEW, AGEH,
HMIG, WBML, HEMP, YWUC, YHUC).
(5) Income Equation
FAMC = f5 (CEB, WEMP, AGR, RES, PNRM, WATE, ELEC, MACH, TRAN, PRES,
AGEH, HMIG, HEMP, YWUC, YHUC).
The definition of variables is given in Appendix I.
The five endogenous variables include two count variables, children
ever born and child deaths; two dichotomous variables, ever use of
contraception and female ever employment; and a continuous variable, the
lifetime income proxy.
Model II
The specification of the model for fertility decisions under the
pre-transition regime is given by a system of two equations as follows:
(6) Fertility Equation
CEB = f1 (CHDD, AGR, RES, PNRM, MACH, PRES, AGEW, YSIN, WBML, HEMP,
YWUC, YHUC, EUSE, WEMP, FAMC).
(7) Mortality Equation
CHDD = f2 (CEB, AGR, PNRM, WATE, ELEC, MACH, TRAN, PRES, YSIN,
HMIG, HEMP, YWUC, YHUC, WEMP, FAMC).
The specification of the system of equations for both models
implies identification; the number of exogenous variables excluded from
each equation in the model is at least as great as the number of
endogenous variables included minus one. For both Models I and II, we
estimate the structural forms of the equations in a simultaneous system.
We use tobit regression techniques for the fertility and mortality
equations, probit for the contraceptive-use and employment equations,
(2) and least squares for the income equation using a two-stage
estimation procedure. (3) After presenting the two-stage estimates of
the structural forms for Models I and II, we also present the
single-equation estimates for the fertility equation in Model II. The
latter, a single-equation specification, assumes that all explanatory
variables are exogenous to fertility in the pre-transition stage.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Model I
Table 1 shows the parameter estimates of the structural form of the
five-equation system. Column 1 presents the estimates for the fertility
equation, which included all the other endogenous variables (fertility,
mortality, female labour force, and income). The results show no
evidence of a significant relationship between the endogenous variables
included in this equation and fertility. However, longer duration of
marriage, ownership of residence, and higher crowdedness are associated
with more children ever born. We note that women who are older and with
more education have lower fertility.
Column 2 of Table 1 shows the results for ever-use of
contraception, with a specification including four endogenous factors as
explanatory variables (fertility, mortality, female labour force, and
income). The estimates reflect that the availability of water and
electricity increase the probability of ever-using a contraceptive
method. Among the endogenous variables included in this equation,
children ever born, woman's employment, and income are not
significant, whereas child mortality is positively related to
contraceptive use.
The results for the mortality equation are given in Column 3 of
Table 1. This equation includes three endogenous variables (fertility,
female employment, and income). The results show that the availability
of a machine in the household and higher crowdedness are negatively
related to child mortality, while longer duration of marriage leads to
more child deaths, as expected. Surprisingly, no endogenous variables
are significant.
For the labour force participation equation, the results are given
in Column 4 of Table 1. Explanatory variables in this equation include
three endogenous variables (fertility, mortality, and income). The
results suggest that wife's education and employment before
marriage are significant determinants of female employment among these
women. No significant endogenous variables are found, except for child
mortality. More child deaths decrease the likelihood of women to
ever-work, agreeing with a priori expectations.
Column 5 of Table 1 shows the results for the income equation. This
equation includes the endogenous variables corresponding to fertility
and labour force participation. Higher income is associated with higher
husband's age, more education of both spouses, residence in urban
areas, availability of a means of transport, and ownership of
agricultural land. A higher number of children ever born is associated
with lower income.
Model II
The model includes a system of two equation: one for fertility and
one for mortality, and each is contained in the other equation. In
Egypt, a traditional society with relatively high fertility rates, we
would expect the effect of fertility on mortality, which is mainly
biological in nature, to be positive. The effect of mortality on
fertility, which is mainly behavioural in nature, is expected to be
positive. The estimation results shown in the first two columns of Table
2 reflect no significant effects from mortality on fertility, or vice
versa.
The third column of Table 2 shows the results of the
single-equation estimation procedure for the fertility equation. This
single-equation approach considers all explanatory variables as
exogenous to fertility. The results show that ever-use of contraception,
family income, and child mortality are positively related to completed
fertility. This is in line with other empirical work [Schultz (1976)].
The relationship between fertility and female employment (WEMP)
appears as non-significant in the results of Model I and Model II. To a
certain extent, this result is expected as female employment in its
"formal" definition in rural Egypt is rare. Female labour
participation is mainly confined to the family's farm and this
participation is unrelated to fertility behaviour. The positive
association between ever-use of contraception and completed fertility
supports the idea that contraception in Egypt is mainly used to stop
having more children rather than to space births.
The positive association between income and fertility supports the
hypothesis that more children may pressure families to work more and
earn more [Mueller and Short (1983)].
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS
We examine the correlates of family size decisions in Egypt, using
data on women who completed their desired family size by the end of the
1970s. We find that family size decisions had not yet reached the stage
of being fully controlled within the family's allocative decisions.
The perception of the household as utility maximiser may be correct, but
many of the essential parameters in household production decisions are
exogenous to fertility behaviour. Income, female work, and ever-use of
contraception are not perceived as under the control of the household
decision-maker(s), especially as part of their family size behaviour.
The Egyptian household fertility behaviour during this period
cannot be represented adequately by a simultaneous system of equations.
A single-equation model performs better in representing our expectations
and in identifying the determinants of fertility.
Often, conceptual differences between Model I (post-transition) and
Model II (pre-transition) are detected. All endogenous variables
included in the fertility equation in Model I are insignificant, while
the same ones are significant (except for female employment) with the
expected signs in the single-equation approach of Model II.
To the extent that the coverage of the EFS data is sufficient for
our purposes, that we can capture the main factors by proxy variables,
and that we restrict the analysis to women with completed fertility, we
can draw guarded conclusions from the analyses.
In conclusion, we have argued that it is possible to test the stage
of the transition for a given society, and have illustrated this point
for Egypt. We find that in Egypt, given the data set used and the time
frame the data represents, fertility by the end of the 1970s was not
endogenous to other household decisions. Accordingly, we do not expect a
dramatic decline in fertility without this endogeneity. The findings
support the general conclusions of Bucht and El-Badry (1986) and
Trussell et al. 0988) about the importance of the biological
determinants of fertility. The predictions of the economic model of
household production to model fertility do not apply to Egypt during the
period of our analysis. This is probably because there were limitations
to the choices offered to households: the economic costs of fertility
were not perceived fully by the households as under their allocative
control.
It seems that traditional roles within and between generations
continued to be deeply rooted in the Egyptian society through the 1970s
[Tuma (1988)]. But this conclusion requires another test to assess if
the events of the late 1970s and the 1980s would lead to change.
Given the limitations of the data set we used, and the possible
questions on the adequacy of some of the measures to capture the
concepts stipulated by the theoretical models, we interpret our results
with extreme caution. We repeat, however, that the main purpose of the
empirical exercise in this paper was not to add new knowledge on
fertility in Egypt, but rather to illustrate the use of empirical tests
to identify the stage of the transition for a given society.
We also conclude that the specification of fertility models,
specially for developing countries, should focus on more details of
other outcome variables. As has been previously argued in the
literature, the specification should vary according to the stage of the
fertility transition in the given society. Also, the exogeneity of
outcomes (such as contraceptive use and female labour force
participation) can be better specified, as can the role of the
determinants of these outcomes in the fertility model. If for example,
contraceptive use is exogenous to fertility, then the price of
contraception would not be an effective constraint for the household
fertility decisions.
Appendix I
DEFINITION OF VARIABLES
CEB : Total number of live births.
EUSE : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the wife has ever used a
contraception method and zero otherwise.
CHDD : Total number of child deaths under five years of age.
WEMP: Dummy variable with a value 1 if the wife has ever worked
while in union and zero otherwise.
FAMC : Current monthly family expenditure in Egyptian Pound (L.
E.).
CUSE : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the wife is currently using
a contraception method and zero otherwise.
AGR : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the family owns an
agricultural land and zero otherwise.
RES : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the family owns their
current residence and zero otherwise.
PNRM : Number of persons per room in the residence.
WATE : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the source of drinking
water is a faucet located in the residence or outside the residence but
inside structure and zero otherwise.
ELEC : Dummy variable with a value 1 if there is electricity in the
residence and zero otherwise.
MACH: Dummy variable with a value 1 if there is a radio set, or
television, or gas stove, or water heater, or telephone, or sewing
machine, or refrigerator in the residence and zero otherwise.
TRAN : Dummy variable with a value 1 if there is a bicycle, or a
motorcycle, or a car in the residence and zero otherwise.
PRES : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the current place of
residence is urban and zero otherwise.
AGEW: Wife's age in completed years.
AGWG: Wife's age at first marriage.
YSIN : Years in union.
AGEH : Husband's age in completed years.
HMIG : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the place of birth of
husband is different from PRES or whether the husband is working abroad
and zero otherwise.
WBML: Dummy variable with a value 1 if the wife was working before
marriage and zero otherwise.
HEMP : Dummy variable with a value 1 if the occupation of husband
is professional, or clerical, or sales, or skilled labour and zero
otherwise.
YWUC: Education of wife in years.
YHUC : Education of husband in years.
Table A1
Descriptive Statistics of the Main Variables
Ever-married Women Ages, 35-49 (a)
Explanatory
Variables and Mean Standard
Expected Signs (a) Deviation
Children Ever Born 6.75 (2.51)
Ever Use of Contraception 0.71 (0.45)
Current Use of Contraception 0.48 (0.50)
Child Deaths 1.51 (1.63)
Female Employment 0.18 (0.38)
Monthly Family Expenditure 54.35 (41.70)
Ownership of Agricultural Land 0.23 (0.42)
Ownership of Current Residence 0.60 (0.49)
Number of Persons per Room 2.59 (1.41)
Availability of Water 0.49 (0.50)
Availability of Electricity 0.74 (0.44)
Availability of Durable Goods 0.82 (0.39)
Availability of Means of Transport 0.18 (0.34)
Place of Residence 0.53 (0.50)
Wife's Age in Years 39.88 (3.81)
Wife's Age at Marriage in Years 17.27 (4.02)
Years in Union 22.15 (5.15)
Husband's Age in Years 48.12 (7.27)
Husband's Migration History 0.24 (0.42)
Pre-marriage Wife's Employment 0.14 (0.35)
Husband's Employment 0.50 (0.50)
Wife's Education in Years 2.30 (3.74)
Husband's Education in Years 3.91 (5.20)
Sample Size N 518
(a) The sample includes women who are ever-married, aged 35-49
years, fecund, in union, exposed, and do not desire additional
children.
Authors' Note: We appreciate the comments made by the referees
and have addressed their concerns in preparing the final version of the
paper.
REFERENCES
Amemiya, T. (1974) Multivariate Regression and Simultaneous
Equation Models when the Dependent Variables are Truncated Normal.
Econometrica 42:6 999-1012.
Bongaarts, J., and J. Menken (1983) The Supply of Children: A
Critical Essay. In A. Bulatao and R. D. Lee (eds) Determinants of
Fertility in Developing Countries. (Volume 1.) New York: Academic Press
pp. 27-60.
Bucht, B., and M. A. El-Badry (1986) Reflections on Recent Levels
and Trends of Fertility and Mortality in Egypt. Population Studies
40:101-113.
Callum, C., and J. Cleland (1988) The Effect of Birthspacing on
Infant and Child Mortality. In A. M. Hallouda et al. (eds) Demographic
Responses to Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp. 215-238.
CAPMAS (1983) The Egyptian Fertility Survey 1980. Cairo: Central
Agency for Public Mobilisation and Statistics in Egypt.
Cochrane, S., M. A. Khan and I. Osheba (1988) The Determinants of
the Demand for Children among Husbands and Wives. In A. M. Hallouda et
al. (eds) Demographic Responses to Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp.
353-385.
DeTray, D. N. (1974) Child Quality and the Demand for Children. In
Theodore W. Schultz (ed) Economics of the Family. Chicago: The
University of Chicago Press.
DeGraff, D. S. (1991) Increasing Contraceptive Use in Bangladesh;
The Role of Demand and Supply Factors. Demography 28:1 February 65-81.
Duesenberry, J. S. (1969) Comment. In Demography of Economic Change
in Developed Countries. New York: NBER pp. 31.
Easterlin, R. A. (1975) An Economic Framework for Fertility
Analysis. Studies in Family Planning 6: 54--63.
Easterlin, R. A., and E. M. Crimmins (1982) An Exploratory Study of
the "Synthesis Framework" of Fertility Determination with
World Fertility Survey Data. The Hague, Netherlands: International
Statistical Institute.
Easterlin, R. A., E. M. Crimmins and I. T. Osheba (1988)
Determinants of Fertility Control. In A. M. Hallouda et al. (eds)
Demographic Responses to Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp. 609-644.
Easterlin, R. A., E. M. Crimmins, M. A. Ahmed and S. M. Soliman
(1988) The Impact of Modernization on the Motivation for Fertility
Control. In A. M. Hallouda et al. (eds) Demographic Responses to
Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp. 645-673.
Eid, I., and J. B. Casterline (1988) Differentials in Infant and
Child Mortality. In A. M. Hallouda et al. (eds) Demographic Responses to
Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp. 179-214.
El-Deeb, B., and J. B. Casterline (1988) Determinants of
Contraceptive Use. In A. M. Hallouda et al. (eds) Demographic Responses
to Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp. 527-573.
Hallouda, A. M., S. Farid and S. H. Cochrane (eds) (1988)
Demographic Responses to Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS.
Khan, A. (1979) Relevance of Human Capital Theory to Fertility
Research: Comparative Findings for Bangladesh and Pakistan. In I.
Sirageldin (ed) Research in Human Capital and Development. (Volume 1.)
Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press Inc. pp. 3-43.
Lee, L. F. (1981) Simultaneous Equations Models with Discrete and
Censored Dependent Variables. In C. F. Manski and D. McFadden (eds)
Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric Applications.
Cambridge: MIT Press pp. 346-364.
Lee, R. D., and R. A. Bulatao (1983) The Demand for Children: A
Critical Essay. In R. A. Bulatao and R. D. Lee (eds) Determinants of
Fertility in Developing Countries. (Volume 1.) New York: Academic Press
pp. 233-287.
Michael, R. T. (1974) Education and the Derived Demand for
Children. In Theodore W. Schultz (ed) Economics of the Family. Chicago:
The University of Chicago Press.
Mueller, E., and K. Short (1983) Effects of Income and Wealth on
the Demand for Children. In R. A. Bulatao and R. D. Lee (eds)
Determinants of Fertility in Developing Countries. (Volume 1.) New York:
Academic Press pp. 590-642.
Nelson, F., and F. Olson (1978) Specification and Estimation of a
Simultaneous Equation Model with Limited Dependent Variables.
International Economic Review 19:3 695-709.
Schultz, T. P. (1976) Determinants of Fertility: A Microeconomic Model of Choice. In A. J. Coale (ed) Economic Factors in Population
Growth. London: Macmillan.
Schultz, T. P. (1978) The Influence of Fertility on Labor Supply of
Married Women: Simultaneous Equation Estimates. Research in Labor
Economics 2: 273-351.
Sokona, O., and J. B. Casterline (1988) Socio-economic
Differentials in Age at Marriage. In A. M. Hallouda et al. (eds)
Demographic Responses to Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp. 101-132.
Trussell, J., B. Vaughan and S. Farid (1988) Determinants of Birth
Interval Length. In A. M. Hallouda et al. (eds) Demographic Responses to
Modernization. Cairo: CAPMAS pp. 133-158.
Tuma, E. H. (1988) Institutional Obstacles to Development: The Case
of Egypt. World Development 16:10 1185-1198.
(1) Duesenberry (1969) provided an early critique of the household
production model.
(2) In censored, truncated, and qualitative endogenous variables,
the assumption is that the non-observed variables are continuous and
with a normal distribution. For dichotomous observed variables, we use
probit estimation techniques, while for polychotomous observed
variables, we use tobit techniques.
(3) The procedure, when applied with tobit and probit techniques,
is analogous to the two-stage least squares, and yields consistent and
asymptotically normal parameter estimates. It has been suggested and
applied, for example, by Amemiya (1974); Lee (1981); Nelson and Olson
(1978).
Hassan Zaky is associated with the Department of Statistics,
Faculty of Economics and Political Science, Cairo University, Giza,
Egypt: Rebeca Wong is Assistant Professor and Ismail Sirageldin is
Professor in the Department of Population Dynamics, The Johns Hopkins
University, 615 N. Wolfe Street, Baltimore, MD 21205, USA.
Table 1
Estimates for Structural Form Parameters of Model 1
Ever-married Women Ages 35-49
Egyptian Fertility Survey, 1980
Dependent Variable
Explanatory
Variables and (1) (2)
Expected Fertility Contraception
Signs * (CEB) (EUSE)
Constant 3.466 *** -1.402 -0.548 -1.512
AGR + 0.319 -0.268 0.019 -0.494
RES + 0.949 *** -0.261
PNRM + 0.252 *** -0.083
WATE 0.750 ** -0.295
ELEC 0.611 *** -0.219
MACH ? -0.543 * -0.326
TRAN 0.164 -0.749
PRES - -0.324 -0.297 0.136 -0.311
AGEW ? -0.056 * -0.034 -0.019 -0.031
YSIN + 0.218 *** -0.035
AGEH ? -0.003 -0.022
HMIG ?
WBML ? -0.585 -0.821 -0.294 -0.825
HEMP ? 0.178 -0.241 0.088 -0.261
YWUC - -0.113 * -0.066 0.011 -0.097
YHUC - -0.061 -0.040 -0.019 -0.073
CEB (b) 2.550 -2.944
EUSE (b) + 0.829 -0.726
CHDD (b) + -0.603 -0.891 1.069 * -0.608
WEMP (b) ? 1.158 -1.461 0.084 -1.252
FAMC (b) + 0.002 -0.012 0.012 -0.029
PROCEDURE TOBIT PROBIT
LOG-LIKELIHOOD -1061.2 -225.59
DEGREES OF
FREEDOM 502 502
N 518 518
(3) (4)
Mortality Female Labour
(CHDD) (WEMP)
Constant -0.736 -0.664 -0.364 -1.560
AGR + 0.249 -0.508 0.553 -0.561
RES +
PNRM + -0.139 * -0.079
WATE -0.251 -0.373
ELEC -0.125 -0.303
MACH ? -0.594 ** -0.297 0.474 * -0.271
TRAN 0.019 -0.725 0.900 -0.865
PRES - 0.214 -0.379 0.396 -0.385
AGEW ? 0.024 -0.036
YSIN + 0.155 *** -0.043
AGEH ? -0.002 -0.025
HMIG ? 0.243 -0.260 0.328 -0.231
WBML ? 1.537 *** -0.275
HEMP ? 0.316 -0.301 -0.256 -0.269
YWUC - 0.010 -0.116 0.225 * -0.126
YHUC - -0.075 -0.076 0.129 -0.090
CEB (b) -3.488 -4.666 -0.499 -1.576
EUSE (b) +
CHDD (b) + -1.467 ** -0.713
WEMP (b) ? 0.544 -0.618
FAMC (b) + -0.016 -0.031 -0.052 -0.037
PROCEDURE TOBIT PROBIT
LOG-LIKELIHOOD -921.98 -119.90
DEGREES OF
FREEDOM 502 503
N 518 518
(5)
Income
(FAMC)
Constant -8.235 -11.26
AGR + 14.059 *** -3.642
RES + -1.894 -3.594
PNRM + -0.513 -1.103
WATE 3.010 -4.510
ELEC -4.614 -3.832
MACH ? 3.541 -4.160
TRAN 22.355 *** -4.242
PRES - 7.501 * -4.288
AGEW ?
YSIN +
AGEH ? 0.713 *** -0.189
HMIG ? 3.521 -3.227
WBML ?
HEMP ? 4.739 -3.493
YWUC - 3.758 *** -0.571
YHUC - 2.443 *** -0.390
CEB (b) -55.198 ** -22.64
EUSE (b) +
CHDD (b) +
WEMP (b) ? -3.337 -6.763
FAMC (b) +
LEAST-
PROCEDURE SQUARES
LOG-LIKELIHOOD -2493.0
DEGREES OF
FREEDOM 502
N 518
Standard errors are in parentheses.
* 0.05 < P value < = 0.10.
** 0.01 < P value < = 0.05.
*** P value < = 0.01.
(a) The expected signs refer to the direction
of the expected effects of endogenous and
exogenous variables on fertility.
(b) Endogenous variable.
Table 2
Estimates for Structural Form Parameters of Model II
Ever-married Women Ages 35-49
Egyptian Fertility Survey, 1980
Single-
equation
Two-equation Model Model
Explanatory
Variables and (1) (2) (3)
Expected Fertility Mortality Fertility
Signs (a) (CEB) (CHDD) (CEB)
Constant 3.948 *** -0.647 2.985 ***
AGR + 0.274 0.024 0.309 *
RES + 0.920 *** 0.878 ***
PNRM + 0.292 *** -0.116 0.328 ***
WATE -0.386
ELEC 0.007
MACH ? -0.412 -0.603 ** -0.138
TRAN -0.345
PRES - -0.349 0.071 -0.251
AGEW ? -0.066 ** -0.060 **
YSIN + 0.219 *** 0.137 *** 0.150 ***
AGEH ?
HMIG ? 0.188
WBML ? 0.178 -0.027
HEMP ? 0.095 0.202 0.014
YWUC - -0.095 *** -0.031 -0.084 ***
YHUC - -0.055 ** -0.107 *** -0.016
EUSE + 0.588 *** 0.714 ***
WEMP ? -0.191 0.006 -0.095
FAMC + 0.003 -0.002 0.004 **
CEB -3.144 (b)
CHDD + -0.737 (b) 0.789 ***
PROCEDURE TOBIT TOBIT TOBIT
LOG-LIKELIHOOD -1058 -923 -939
DEGREES OF
FREEDOM 502 502 502
N 518 518 518
* 0.05 < Pvalue < = 0.10.
** 0.01 < Pvalue < = 0.05.
*** P value < = 0.01.
(a) The expected signs refer to the direction of the
expected effects of endogenous and exogenous variables
on fertility.
(b) Endogenous variables.