Stability, wage contracts, rational expectations, and devaluations *.
Ali, Syed Zahid
I. INTRODUCTION
The effects of devaluations on economies have caused a great deal
of concern in recent years. Conventional economists such as Robinson
(1947) and Meade (1951) hold the view that due to high unemployment and
the absence of any supply-side effects of the exchange rates,
devaluation will increase employment if it increases the demand for home
goods. A number of papers have been written which seriously challenge
this result on a number of grounds. For example, Turnovsky (1981) has
derived the result that if agents under-predict changes in the exchange
rate then output will increase with devaluation. On the other hand, if
agents over predict changes in the exchange rate then output will reduce
with devaluation. However, economists such as Calvo (1983) and Larrian
and Sachs (1986) have supported the standard result by arguing that the
stability of the system is sufficient to rule out perverse outcomes of
devaluation. Buffie (1986), on the other hand, has derived the result
that for stable economies, devaluation may or may not increase Output.
However, Buffie shows that if the production function is separable between primary factors and the imported input then devaluation will
increase employment. Lai and Chang (1989) have derived the result that
currency devaluation has a negative impact on output if workers are free
from money illusion. Gylfason and Schmid (1983), report a similar
result: if the real wage is assumed to be constant then devaluation
contracts the real income.
The perverse effect of devaluation follows from the fact that the
aggregate supply function of goods shifts up in response to changes in
the exchange rate. In recent papers, economists have attempted to
develop a more realistic supply-side of the economy. In doing so,
however, they have enriched their models to the point that ambiguous
results are obtained. In this paper we have attempted to study the
short-run and long-run effects of devaluation of the domestic currency,
numerically, in a stochastic model with variable employment, output, and
prices. We have developed a model which involves both demand-side and
supply-side effects of the exchange rate. Contrary to the studies cited
above we have paid special attention to the nature of wage contracts. In
our model, labour has a two-period wage contract. In this circumstance
we have direct supply-side effects of the exchange rate in two periods.
The findings of our study reveal that in stable economies, for plausible
sets of parameter values, devaluation exerts a positive effect upon
output both in the short and medium run. Devaluation is neutral in the
long run.
II. THE MODEL
The model is defined by the following equations:
[m.sub.t] - [p.sub.t] = [a.sub.2] [Y.sub.t] - [a.sub.1][i.sub.t] +
[u.sub.it] ... ... (1)
[Y.sub.t] = -[c.sub.1][r.sub.t] + [c.sub.2]([e.sub.t] -
[p.sub.t.sup.d] + [p.sup.-m]) + [u.sub.2t] ... (2)
[i.sub.t] = [bar.[??]] + [u.sub.3t] ... ... ... (3)
[p.sub.t] = [gamma][p.sub.t.sup.d] + (1 - [gamma]) ([e.sub.t] +
[P.sup.-m]) ... ... (4)
[i.sub.r] = [r.sub.t] + [E.sub.t][p.sub.t+1] - [p.sub.t] ... ...
... (5)
Assuming that production of goods depends on labour and the fixed
stock of capital, and that the marginal productivity of labour is
constant, the supply-side of the model follows from this wage setting
rule:
[X.sub.t] = 0.5[[E.sub.t-1] [p.sub.t] + [E.sub.t-1][p.sub.t+1] + f
(h[E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t] + (1 - h) [E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t+1])] + [u.sub.4t]
... ... (6)
where
[m.sub.t] = ln of money stock;
[p.sub.t] = ln of consumer price index (CPI);
[p.sup.d.sub.t] = ln of domestic price of good [Y.sub.t];
[X.sub.t] = ln of nominal wage rate;
[Y.sub.t] = ln of domestic output;
[e.sub.t] = ln of nominal exchange rate;
[E.sub.t-j][p.sub.t-j] = mathematical expectation of [p.sub.t-j];
[u.sub.jt] = disturbance term;
[E.sub.t-j][Y.sub.t-j] = mathematical expectation of [Y.sub.t-j];
[r.sub.t] = real interest rate;
[i.sub.t] = nominal domestic interest rate;
[bar.[??]] = foreign interest rate; and
[p.sup.-m] = ln of foreign price of imported good.
We start by explaining the model's supply-side. It is assumed
that workers, who are free of any money illusion, make a contract with
firms for two periods. For example, at time t-1 a group of workers,
whose contract is expiring at time t-1, makes a contract with the firm
for periods t and t + 1. Equation (6) indicates that to make the
contract, workers use their expectations regarding the consumer price
index [p.sub.t], [p.sub.t+1] and output [Y.sub.t], [Y.sub.t+1], which
are expected to prevail in period t and t + 1. The parameters (1-h) and
h are the weight associated to the output expected to prevail in period
t and t + 1 respectively. Whereas f represents the weight given to the
weighted average of the output expected in the period t and t + 1. An
important point to note is that due to the inclusion of the consumer
price index in Equation (6) we have allowed for the supply-side effects
of the exchange rate. For instance, if at time t the central bank
devalues the currency, then the group of workers who are negotiating
their wages for period t + 1 and t + 2 will take into account this
increase in the price of the foreign currency. This will increase the
average wage paid by the firms in the subsequent periods. Which in turn
increases the cost of production. The disturbance term, [u.sub.4t],
captures the stochastic shift in the wage rate. One final thing to note
here is that the exchange rate is an exogenous variable and devaluation
of the domestic currency is always an unanticipated event. (1)
Since we assume that the marginal productivity of labour is
constant and equal to 1 then firms must set the price of goods at
[p.sup.d.sub.t] = 0.5 ([X.sub.t] + [X.sub.t-1]) ... ... ... (7)
This completes the basic structure of the supply-side of the model.
Now we briefly describe the demand-side of the model. Equation (1)
defines the equilibrium in the money market. It is assumed that demand
for real money balances M/p is positively related to output and
negatively related to the nominal interest rate. Equation (2) shows that
the demand for goods is negatively related to the real interest rate but
positively related to the terms of trade [e.sub.t]
[p.sup.-m]/[p.sup.d.sub.t]. The disturbance terms, [u.sub.1t], and
[u.sub.2t], capture random shocks in the money and goods markets
respectively. Equation (3) defines perfect capital mobility. The stock
of money M always makes a discrete jump to keep the domestic nominal
interest rate, [i.sub.t], equal to the foreign interest rate,
[bar.[??]], plus the stochastic fluctuation in the foreign interest
rate, [u.sub.3t]. Equation (4) defines the consumer price index; it is
the price of the basket of goods which contains both domestically
produced goods and imported final goods. Equation (5) explains the
difference between the nominal and the real interest rate. The real
interest rate, [r.sub.t] is equal to the nominal interest rate,
[i.sub.t], minus the expected inflation, [E.sub.t][p.sub.t+1] -
[p.sub.t],. This completes the explanation of the basic structure of the
model In the short--run we have seven endogenous variables: [Y.sub.t],
[p.sub.t], [p.sup.d.sub.t], [r.sub.t], [m.sub.t], and [X.sub.t] which
give values by solving Equations (1) to (7) simultaneously.
We assume throughout that the disturbance terms [u.sub.1t], ...,
[u.sub.4t], have zero means, constant variances, and are independently
distributed.
III. PRELIMINARY MANIPULATIONS
By solving Equations (1) to (7), we can express the model in more
compact form as:
[X.sub.t] + 0.5 [ 0.5[gamma]([E.sub.t+1]+[X.sub.t-1] +
2[E.sub.t-1][X.sub.t]+[X.sub.t-1]) + 2(1-[gamma])([e.sub.t-1] +
[p.sup.-m])] + f * (h[E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t] + (1-h)
[E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t+1])] + [u.sub.4t] ... (8)
[Y.sub.t] = -[c.sub.1] [bar.i] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [E.sub.t]
[X.sub.t+1] + [c.sub.2][e.sub.t] + [c.sub.2] [p.sup.- m] - 0.5 [c.sub.2]
[X.sub.t] - 0.5 ([c.sub.1][gamma] + [c.sub.2]) [X.sub.t-1] + [u.sub.2t]
- [c.sub.1][u.sub.3t] ... ... (9)
Equation (8) could be considered a reduced form of the aggregate
supply function of good [Y.sub.t] if we substitute out the expression
for [E.sub.t-1] [X.sub.t+1], [E.sub.t-1] [X.sub.t], [E.sub.t-
1][Y.sub.t] and [E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t+1]. Equation (9), on the other hand,
can be interpreted as the aggregate demand function for good [Y.sub.t].
Once we obtain the expression for [E.sub.t-1] [X.sub.t+1], [E.sub.t-1]
[X.sub.t], [E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t], [E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t+1],
[E.sub.t][X.sub.t+1] and [X.sub.t] we can solve Equations (8) and (9)
simultaneously to get the equilibrium value of output [Y.sub.t] and the
wage rate [X.sub.t]. The method we will use in deriving the expression
for [E.sub.t] [X.sub.t+1], [E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t+1] etc., is called the
undetermined coefficient method. According to this method, by inspecting
the model carefully, we assume a trail solution of the endogenous
variables. Then using the trail solution we eliminate the expression for
current and future expectations of the variables. By inspecting
Equations (8) and (9) we assume the following trail solution of
[X.sub.t] and [Y.sub.t]:
[Y.sub.t] = [[psi].sub.1][bar.i] + [[psi].sub.2][e.sub.t] +
[[psi].sub.3][e.sub.t-1] + [[psi].sub.4][p.sup.-m] + [[psi].sub.5]
[X.sub.t-1] + [[psi].sub.6][u.sub.2t] + [[psi].sub.7][u.sub.3t] +
[[psi].sub.8][u.sub.4t] (10)
[X.sub.t] = [[delta].sub.1][bar.i] + [[delta].sub.2][e.sub.t-1] +
[[delta].sub.3][p.sup.-m] + [[delta].sub.4][X.sub.t- 1] +
[[delta].sub.5][u.sub.2t] + [[delta].sub.6][u.sub.3t] +
[[delta].sub.7][u.sub.4t] ... (11)
A point to note hero is that following McCallum (1983), in order to
avoid the non-uniqueness problem, we exclude the additional lags of the
variables [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t] in the trial solution of [Y.sub.t] and
[X.sub.t]. Using Equations (7) to (10) the reader can readily derive the
following reduced forms for [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t] :
[Y.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.1] [bar.i] + [[alpha].sub.2][e.sub.t] +
[[alpha].sub.3][e.sub.t-1] [[alpha].sub.4][p.sup.-m] + [[alpha].sub.5]
[X.sub.t-1] [[alpha].sub.6][u.sub.2t] + [[alpha].sub.7][u.sub.3t] +
[[alpha].sub.8][u.sub.4t] (12)
[X.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.1] [bar.i] + [[beta].sub.2][e.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.3][p.sup.-m] + [p.sub.4][X.sub.t-1] -
[[beta].sub.5][u.sub.4t] ... ... (13)
where
[[alpha].sub.1] = -[c.sub.1] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1]
([[delta].sub.1] + [[delta].sub.4][[delta].sub.1]) -
0.5[c.sub.2][[delta].sub.1]
[[alpha].sub.2] = [c.sub.2] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [[delta].sub.2]
[[alpha].sub.3] = 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [[delta].4] [[delta].sub.2]
- 0.5 [c.sub.2][[delta].sub.2]
[[alpha].sub.4] = [c.sub.2] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1]([[delta].sub.3]
+ [[delta].sub.4][[delta].sub.3]) - 0.5[c.sub.2][[delta].sub.3]
[[alpha].sub.5] = 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [[delta].sup.2.sub.4] - 0.5
[c.sub.2] [[delta].sub.4] - 0.5 ([c.sub.1] [gamma] + [c.sub.2])
[[alpha].sub.6] = 1 - 0.5 [c.sub.2] [[delta].sub.5]
[[alpha].sub.7] = -([c.sub.1] + 0.5 [c.sub.2][[delta].sub.6])
[[alpha].sub.8] = -0.5 [c.sub.2][[delta].sub.7]
[[beta].sub.1] = 0.25[gamma](3 [[delta].sub.1] + [[delta].sub.4]
[[delta].sub.1]) + 0.5f[A.sub.1]
[[beta].sub.2] = 0.25[gamma](3 [[delta].sub.2] + [[delta].sub.4]
[[delta].sub.2]) + 0.5f[A.sub.2] + 1 - [gamma]
[[beta].sub.3] = 0.25[gamma](3 [[delta].sub.3] + [[delta].sub.4]
[[delta].sub.3]) + 0.5f[A.sub.3] + 1 - [gamma]
[[beta].sub.4] = 0.25[gamma]([[delta].sup.2.sub.4] +
2[[delta].sub.4] + 1) + 0.5f[A.sub.4]
[[beta].sub.5] = 1
[A.sub.1] = [[psi].sub.1] + [[psi].sub.5] [[delta].sub.1] (1 - h)
[A.sub.2] = [[psi].sub.2] + [[psi].sub.3] + [[psi].sub.5]
[[delta].sub.2] (1 - h)
[A.sub.3] = [[psi].sub.4] + [[psi].sub.5] [[delta].sub.3] (1 - h)
[A.sub.4] = h[[psi].sub.5] + (1 - h) [[psi].sub.5] [[delta].sub.4]
We have now two reduced form of [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t]. Equations
(10) and (12) are the reduced form of [Y.sub.t]. While, Equations (11)
and (13) are the reduced form of [X.sub.t]. For rational expectation
consistency we need:
[[psi].sub.1] = [[alpha].sub.1], [[psi].sub.2] = [[alpha].sub.2],
[[psi].sub.3] = [[alpha].sub.3], [[psi].sub.4] = [[alpha].sub.4],
[[psi].sub.5] = [[alpha].sub.5], [[psi].sub.6] = [[alpha].sub.6], =
[[psi].sub.7] = [[alpha].sub.7], [[psi].sub.8] = [[alpha].sub.8]
[[delta].sub.1] = [[beta].sub.1], [[delta].sub.2] = [[beta].sub.2],
[[delta].sub.3] = [[beta].sub.3], [[delta].sub.4] = [[beta].sub.4],
[[delta].sub.5] = 0, [[delta].sub.6] = 0, [[delta].sub.7] =
[[beta].sub.5] ... (14)
By solving the system of Equation (14) we will get the solution to
the model.
IV. STABILITY ANALYSIS AND SHORT-RUN AND LONG-RUN EFFECTS OF
DEVALUATION
Taking the first differences of Equations (12) and (13), while
setting changes in all exogenous variables except the exchange rate to
zero we get:
[DELTA][Y.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.2] [DELTA][e.sub.t] +
[[alpha].sub.3][DELTA][e.sub.t-1] + [[alpha].sub.5][DELTA] [X.sub.t-1]
... ... ... (15)
[DELTA] [X.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.2] [DELTA][e.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.4][DELTA] [X.sub.t-1] ... ... ... ... (16)
Assuming that initially there is no change in the exchange rate,
from Equation (16) we get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (17)
Similarly, solving Equations (15) and (17) simultaneously we get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (18)
Finally, using Equations (4), (9) and (16) we get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)
Equation (18) gives the discounted sum of change in output in the
event of devaluation. While Equations (17) and (19) gives the discounted
sum of change in nominal wage rate and the CPI respectively. From (17),
(18) and (19) it is evident that the discounted sum of output, prices,
and nominal wage rate will be on stable path if and only if [absolute
value of [[beta].sub.4]] < 1.
In order to derive the impact effect of devaluation upon-the
endogenous variables, we first get the solution to the model. For this
purpose we first need to solve the system of equation given in (14).
Since it is cumbersome to obtain the mathematical solution, we solve
this system for a plausible set of parameter values. Following Fischer
(1988) we assume [c.sub.1] = 0.1, [c.sub.2] = 0.2, [gamma] = 0.8. We
also assume that h = 0.5 and f = 0.65. When these values are substituted
in (14) we get the following solution to the model:
[[alpha].sub.1] = -0.09593, [[alpha].sub.2 = 0.22778 =
[[alpha].sub.3] = -0.06097, [[alpha].sub.4] = 0.16681 = -
[[alpha].sub.5]
[[beta].sub.1] = -0.08518, [[beta].sub.2] = [[beta].sub.3] =
0.69454, [[beta].sub.4] = 0.30546
Since this solution to the model meets the stability condition i.e.
[absolute value of [[beta].sub.4]] < 1, we proceed to study the
effect of devaluation on output and prices. For a more direct comparison
we have plotted the variable [DELTA][Y.sub.t](= [Y.sub.t] -
[Y.sub.t-1])/[Y.sub.t-1]), [DELTA][p.sub.t](= ([p.sub.t] -
[p.sub.t-1])/[p.sub.t-1]) and [DELTA] [X.sub.t](=([X.sub.t] -
[X.sub.t-1])/[X.sub.t-1]) against time, t, which we have generated for a
ten-point devaluation of the domestic currency. From Figure 1 it is
evident that devaluation is expansionary in the impact period. In the
first period there is a 2.28 percent increase in the output. From Figure
2, on the other hand, it can be seen that this increase in output is
achieved at the expense of higher inflation. The price level has
increased by 2 percent. A point to note here is that the change in the
inflation rate has not exceeded the change in the exchange rate. This
implies that the nominal devaluation has resulted in real devaluation
(fall in competitiveness). In the second period the change in output
reduces from 2.28 percent to 1.67 percent while inflation has further
increased. This happens as the group of workers whose contract expired
in the second period, has demanded an increase in the wage rate for the
next two periods in response to the increase in the CPI and output. This
can be seen in Figure 3 where the nominal wage increases from 0 percent
to 6.95 percent in the second period. After the sixth period, however,
the change in output becomes zero while, both inflation and the nominal
wage rate increases to the full amount of the nominal devaluation i.e.,
10 percent. These results re-establish the conventional belief that
devaluation is expansionary in the short and medium run, but neutral in
the long run. The reader can confirm easily that in the long run
[DELTA][X.sub.t] = [DELTA][m.sub.t] = [DELTA][p.sup.d.sub.t] =
[DELTA][p.sub.t] = [DELTA][e.sub.t].
The results which we have reported above although depend upon the
choice of our parameter values but, do not change qualitatively when a
different set of parameter values is used. More importantly, we do dot
get contractionary effects of devaluation for any reasonable parameter
values. It is seen that devaluation has more expansionary effects both
in the short and the medium run for high values of [a.sub.2], [c.sub.2],
[gamma], while devaluation is less expansionary for high values of
[a.sub.1], [c.sub.1], f, and h.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS
In this paper we studied the effects of devaluation on output in a
model in which partly sticky wages exist in the form of a two-period
wage contract. Due to the nature of these wage contracts, half of the
labour force cannot adjust their wage rate in response to a change in
the CPI and output. The main finding of the paper is that for stable
economies and for plausible sets of parameter values, devaluation exerts
a positive impact upon output both in the short and the medium run. The
scope of our study, however, is more of a theoretical nature. The model
which we have developed in this paper could be considered as an
approximation of a developed small open economy such as Canada. The
results of our study, therefore, should not apply to less developed
countries. For a less developed country we need a model which should
allow a lesser degree of capital mobility. Furthermore, we should allow
direct supply-side effects of the exchange rate through the inclusion of
imported inputs in the model. Because in less developed countries a
large fraction of the total output is produced with the combination of
both domestic resources and the imported inputs. In this new model the
elasticity of substitution between imported inputs and domestic inputs
will play a crucial role in determining the net effect of devaluation
upon the nominal and real variables of the economy.
Author's Note: I am grateful to Aynul Hasan, who was the
discussant, and W. M. Scarth for useful comments and thoughtful
insights. Nevertheless I am responsible for any remaining omissions,
oversights, and errors in the paper.
REFERENCES
Buffie, E. P. (1986) Devaluation and Imported Inputs: The Large
Economy Case. International Economic Review 27: 123-40.
Calvo, G. (1983) Staggered Contracts and Exchange Rate Policy. In
J. A. Frankel (ed) Exchange Rates and International Macroeconomics.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Fischer, S. (1989) Real Balances, the Exchange Rate, and
Indexation: Real Variables in Disinflation. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 103: 27-49.
Gylfason, T., and Schmid (1983) Does Devaluation Cause Stagflation?
Canadian Journal of Economics 16: 641-654.
Lai, C. C., and W. Chang (1989) Income Taxes, Supply-Side Effects,
and Currency Devaluation. Journal of Macroeconomics 11: 281-295.
Larrian, F., and J. Sachs (1986) Contractionary Devaluation and
Dynamic Adjustment of Exports and Wages. NBER Working Paper No. 2078.
Meade, J. E. (1951) The Balance of Payments. London: Oxford
University Press.
Robinson, J. (1947) Essays in the Theory of Employment. Oxford:
Basil Blackwell.
Turnovsky, S. J. (1981) The Effects of Devaluation and Foreign
Price Disturbances under Rational Expectations. Journal of International
Economics 11: 33-60.
* Owing to unavoidable circumstances, the discussants comments on
this paper have not been received.
(1) Sec Turnovsky (1981) for a model in which agents form
expectations about possible changes in the exchange rate and the foreign
price level.
Syed Zahid Ali is Assistant Professor in International Institute of
Islamic Economics, International Islamic University, Islamabad.