首页    期刊浏览 2024年10月05日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Stability, wage contracts, rational expectations, and devaluations *.
  • 作者:Ali, Syed Zahid
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:1993
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:The effects of devaluations on economies have caused a great deal of concern in recent years. Conventional economists such as Robinson (1947) and Meade (1951) hold the view that due to high unemployment and the absence of any supply-side effects of the exchange rates, devaluation will increase employment if it increases the demand for home goods. A number of papers have been written which seriously challenge this result on a number of grounds. For example, Turnovsky (1981) has derived the result that if agents under-predict changes in the exchange rate then output will increase with devaluation. On the other hand, if agents over predict changes in the exchange rate then output will reduce with devaluation. However, economists such as Calvo (1983) and Larrian and Sachs (1986) have supported the standard result by arguing that the stability of the system is sufficient to rule out perverse outcomes of devaluation. Buffie (1986), on the other hand, has derived the result that for stable economies, devaluation may or may not increase Output. However, Buffie shows that if the production function is separable between primary factors and the imported input then devaluation will increase employment. Lai and Chang (1989) have derived the result that currency devaluation has a negative impact on output if workers are free from money illusion. Gylfason and Schmid (1983), report a similar result: if the real wage is assumed to be constant then devaluation contracts the real income.
  • 关键词:Currency devaluation;Devaluation (Currency);Econometric models;Wages;Wages and salaries

Stability, wage contracts, rational expectations, and devaluations *.


Ali, Syed Zahid


I. INTRODUCTION

The effects of devaluations on economies have caused a great deal of concern in recent years. Conventional economists such as Robinson (1947) and Meade (1951) hold the view that due to high unemployment and the absence of any supply-side effects of the exchange rates, devaluation will increase employment if it increases the demand for home goods. A number of papers have been written which seriously challenge this result on a number of grounds. For example, Turnovsky (1981) has derived the result that if agents under-predict changes in the exchange rate then output will increase with devaluation. On the other hand, if agents over predict changes in the exchange rate then output will reduce with devaluation. However, economists such as Calvo (1983) and Larrian and Sachs (1986) have supported the standard result by arguing that the stability of the system is sufficient to rule out perverse outcomes of devaluation. Buffie (1986), on the other hand, has derived the result that for stable economies, devaluation may or may not increase Output. However, Buffie shows that if the production function is separable between primary factors and the imported input then devaluation will increase employment. Lai and Chang (1989) have derived the result that currency devaluation has a negative impact on output if workers are free from money illusion. Gylfason and Schmid (1983), report a similar result: if the real wage is assumed to be constant then devaluation contracts the real income.

The perverse effect of devaluation follows from the fact that the aggregate supply function of goods shifts up in response to changes in the exchange rate. In recent papers, economists have attempted to develop a more realistic supply-side of the economy. In doing so, however, they have enriched their models to the point that ambiguous results are obtained. In this paper we have attempted to study the short-run and long-run effects of devaluation of the domestic currency, numerically, in a stochastic model with variable employment, output, and prices. We have developed a model which involves both demand-side and supply-side effects of the exchange rate. Contrary to the studies cited above we have paid special attention to the nature of wage contracts. In our model, labour has a two-period wage contract. In this circumstance we have direct supply-side effects of the exchange rate in two periods. The findings of our study reveal that in stable economies, for plausible sets of parameter values, devaluation exerts a positive effect upon output both in the short and medium run. Devaluation is neutral in the long run.

II. THE MODEL

The model is defined by the following equations:

[m.sub.t] - [p.sub.t] = [a.sub.2] [Y.sub.t] - [a.sub.1][i.sub.t] + [u.sub.it] ... ... (1)

[Y.sub.t] = -[c.sub.1][r.sub.t] + [c.sub.2]([e.sub.t] - [p.sub.t.sup.d] + [p.sup.-m]) + [u.sub.2t] ... (2)

[i.sub.t] = [bar.[??]] + [u.sub.3t] ... ... ... (3)

[p.sub.t] = [gamma][p.sub.t.sup.d] + (1 - [gamma]) ([e.sub.t] + [P.sup.-m]) ... ... (4)

[i.sub.r] = [r.sub.t] + [E.sub.t][p.sub.t+1] - [p.sub.t] ... ... ... (5)

Assuming that production of goods depends on labour and the fixed stock of capital, and that the marginal productivity of labour is constant, the supply-side of the model follows from this wage setting rule:

[X.sub.t] = 0.5[[E.sub.t-1] [p.sub.t] + [E.sub.t-1][p.sub.t+1] + f (h[E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t] + (1 - h) [E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t+1])] + [u.sub.4t] ... ... (6)

where

[m.sub.t] = ln of money stock;

[p.sub.t] = ln of consumer price index (CPI);

[p.sup.d.sub.t] = ln of domestic price of good [Y.sub.t];

[X.sub.t] = ln of nominal wage rate;

[Y.sub.t] = ln of domestic output;

[e.sub.t] = ln of nominal exchange rate;

[E.sub.t-j][p.sub.t-j] = mathematical expectation of [p.sub.t-j];

[u.sub.jt] = disturbance term;

[E.sub.t-j][Y.sub.t-j] = mathematical expectation of [Y.sub.t-j];

[r.sub.t] = real interest rate;

[i.sub.t] = nominal domestic interest rate;

[bar.[??]] = foreign interest rate; and

[p.sup.-m] = ln of foreign price of imported good.

We start by explaining the model's supply-side. It is assumed that workers, who are free of any money illusion, make a contract with firms for two periods. For example, at time t-1 a group of workers, whose contract is expiring at time t-1, makes a contract with the firm for periods t and t + 1. Equation (6) indicates that to make the contract, workers use their expectations regarding the consumer price index [p.sub.t], [p.sub.t+1] and output [Y.sub.t], [Y.sub.t+1], which are expected to prevail in period t and t + 1. The parameters (1-h) and h are the weight associated to the output expected to prevail in period t and t + 1 respectively. Whereas f represents the weight given to the weighted average of the output expected in the period t and t + 1. An important point to note is that due to the inclusion of the consumer price index in Equation (6) we have allowed for the supply-side effects of the exchange rate. For instance, if at time t the central bank devalues the currency, then the group of workers who are negotiating their wages for period t + 1 and t + 2 will take into account this increase in the price of the foreign currency. This will increase the average wage paid by the firms in the subsequent periods. Which in turn increases the cost of production. The disturbance term, [u.sub.4t], captures the stochastic shift in the wage rate. One final thing to note here is that the exchange rate is an exogenous variable and devaluation of the domestic currency is always an unanticipated event. (1)

Since we assume that the marginal productivity of labour is constant and equal to 1 then firms must set the price of goods at

[p.sup.d.sub.t] = 0.5 ([X.sub.t] + [X.sub.t-1]) ... ... ... (7)

This completes the basic structure of the supply-side of the model. Now we briefly describe the demand-side of the model. Equation (1) defines the equilibrium in the money market. It is assumed that demand for real money balances M/p is positively related to output and negatively related to the nominal interest rate. Equation (2) shows that the demand for goods is negatively related to the real interest rate but positively related to the terms of trade [e.sub.t] [p.sup.-m]/[p.sup.d.sub.t]. The disturbance terms, [u.sub.1t], and [u.sub.2t], capture random shocks in the money and goods markets respectively. Equation (3) defines perfect capital mobility. The stock of money M always makes a discrete jump to keep the domestic nominal interest rate, [i.sub.t], equal to the foreign interest rate, [bar.[??]], plus the stochastic fluctuation in the foreign interest rate, [u.sub.3t]. Equation (4) defines the consumer price index; it is the price of the basket of goods which contains both domestically produced goods and imported final goods. Equation (5) explains the difference between the nominal and the real interest rate. The real interest rate, [r.sub.t] is equal to the nominal interest rate, [i.sub.t], minus the expected inflation, [E.sub.t][p.sub.t+1] - [p.sub.t],. This completes the explanation of the basic structure of the model In the short--run we have seven endogenous variables: [Y.sub.t], [p.sub.t], [p.sup.d.sub.t], [r.sub.t], [m.sub.t], and [X.sub.t] which give values by solving Equations (1) to (7) simultaneously.

We assume throughout that the disturbance terms [u.sub.1t], ..., [u.sub.4t], have zero means, constant variances, and are independently distributed.

III. PRELIMINARY MANIPULATIONS

By solving Equations (1) to (7), we can express the model in more compact form as:

[X.sub.t] + 0.5 [ 0.5[gamma]([E.sub.t+1]+[X.sub.t-1] + 2[E.sub.t-1][X.sub.t]+[X.sub.t-1]) + 2(1-[gamma])([e.sub.t-1] + [p.sup.-m])] + f * (h[E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t] + (1-h) [E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t+1])] + [u.sub.4t] ... (8)

[Y.sub.t] = -[c.sub.1] [bar.i] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [E.sub.t] [X.sub.t+1] + [c.sub.2][e.sub.t] + [c.sub.2] [p.sup.- m] - 0.5 [c.sub.2] [X.sub.t] - 0.5 ([c.sub.1][gamma] + [c.sub.2]) [X.sub.t-1] + [u.sub.2t] - [c.sub.1][u.sub.3t] ... ... (9)

Equation (8) could be considered a reduced form of the aggregate supply function of good [Y.sub.t] if we substitute out the expression for [E.sub.t-1] [X.sub.t+1], [E.sub.t-1] [X.sub.t], [E.sub.t- 1][Y.sub.t] and [E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t+1]. Equation (9), on the other hand, can be interpreted as the aggregate demand function for good [Y.sub.t]. Once we obtain the expression for [E.sub.t-1] [X.sub.t+1], [E.sub.t-1] [X.sub.t], [E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t], [E.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t+1], [E.sub.t][X.sub.t+1] and [X.sub.t] we can solve Equations (8) and (9) simultaneously to get the equilibrium value of output [Y.sub.t] and the wage rate [X.sub.t]. The method we will use in deriving the expression for [E.sub.t] [X.sub.t+1], [E.sub.t-1] [Y.sub.t+1] etc., is called the undetermined coefficient method. According to this method, by inspecting the model carefully, we assume a trail solution of the endogenous variables. Then using the trail solution we eliminate the expression for current and future expectations of the variables. By inspecting Equations (8) and (9) we assume the following trail solution of [X.sub.t] and [Y.sub.t]:

[Y.sub.t] = [[psi].sub.1][bar.i] + [[psi].sub.2][e.sub.t] + [[psi].sub.3][e.sub.t-1] + [[psi].sub.4][p.sup.-m] + [[psi].sub.5] [X.sub.t-1] + [[psi].sub.6][u.sub.2t] + [[psi].sub.7][u.sub.3t] + [[psi].sub.8][u.sub.4t] (10)

[X.sub.t] = [[delta].sub.1][bar.i] + [[delta].sub.2][e.sub.t-1] + [[delta].sub.3][p.sup.-m] + [[delta].sub.4][X.sub.t- 1] + [[delta].sub.5][u.sub.2t] + [[delta].sub.6][u.sub.3t] + [[delta].sub.7][u.sub.4t] ... (11)

A point to note hero is that following McCallum (1983), in order to avoid the non-uniqueness problem, we exclude the additional lags of the variables [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t] in the trial solution of [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t]. Using Equations (7) to (10) the reader can readily derive the following reduced forms for [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t] :

[Y.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.1] [bar.i] + [[alpha].sub.2][e.sub.t] + [[alpha].sub.3][e.sub.t-1] [[alpha].sub.4][p.sup.-m] + [[alpha].sub.5] [X.sub.t-1] [[alpha].sub.6][u.sub.2t] + [[alpha].sub.7][u.sub.3t] + [[alpha].sub.8][u.sub.4t] (12)

[X.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.1] [bar.i] + [[beta].sub.2][e.sub.t-1] + [[beta].sub.3][p.sup.-m] + [p.sub.4][X.sub.t-1] - [[beta].sub.5][u.sub.4t] ... ... (13)

where

[[alpha].sub.1] = -[c.sub.1] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] ([[delta].sub.1] + [[delta].sub.4][[delta].sub.1]) - 0.5[c.sub.2][[delta].sub.1]

[[alpha].sub.2] = [c.sub.2] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [[delta].sub.2]

[[alpha].sub.3] = 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [[delta].4] [[delta].sub.2] - 0.5 [c.sub.2][[delta].sub.2]

[[alpha].sub.4] = [c.sub.2] + 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1]([[delta].sub.3] + [[delta].sub.4][[delta].sub.3]) - 0.5[c.sub.2][[delta].sub.3]

[[alpha].sub.5] = 0.5 [gamma] [c.sub.1] [[delta].sup.2.sub.4] - 0.5 [c.sub.2] [[delta].sub.4] - 0.5 ([c.sub.1] [gamma] + [c.sub.2])

[[alpha].sub.6] = 1 - 0.5 [c.sub.2] [[delta].sub.5]

[[alpha].sub.7] = -([c.sub.1] + 0.5 [c.sub.2][[delta].sub.6])

[[alpha].sub.8] = -0.5 [c.sub.2][[delta].sub.7]

[[beta].sub.1] = 0.25[gamma](3 [[delta].sub.1] + [[delta].sub.4] [[delta].sub.1]) + 0.5f[A.sub.1]

[[beta].sub.2] = 0.25[gamma](3 [[delta].sub.2] + [[delta].sub.4] [[delta].sub.2]) + 0.5f[A.sub.2] + 1 - [gamma]

[[beta].sub.3] = 0.25[gamma](3 [[delta].sub.3] + [[delta].sub.4] [[delta].sub.3]) + 0.5f[A.sub.3] + 1 - [gamma]

[[beta].sub.4] = 0.25[gamma]([[delta].sup.2.sub.4] + 2[[delta].sub.4] + 1) + 0.5f[A.sub.4]

[[beta].sub.5] = 1

[A.sub.1] = [[psi].sub.1] + [[psi].sub.5] [[delta].sub.1] (1 - h)

[A.sub.2] = [[psi].sub.2] + [[psi].sub.3] + [[psi].sub.5] [[delta].sub.2] (1 - h)

[A.sub.3] = [[psi].sub.4] + [[psi].sub.5] [[delta].sub.3] (1 - h)

[A.sub.4] = h[[psi].sub.5] + (1 - h) [[psi].sub.5] [[delta].sub.4]

We have now two reduced form of [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t]. Equations (10) and (12) are the reduced form of [Y.sub.t]. While, Equations (11) and (13) are the reduced form of [X.sub.t]. For rational expectation consistency we need:

[[psi].sub.1] = [[alpha].sub.1], [[psi].sub.2] = [[alpha].sub.2], [[psi].sub.3] = [[alpha].sub.3], [[psi].sub.4] = [[alpha].sub.4], [[psi].sub.5] = [[alpha].sub.5], [[psi].sub.6] = [[alpha].sub.6], = [[psi].sub.7] = [[alpha].sub.7], [[psi].sub.8] = [[alpha].sub.8]

[[delta].sub.1] = [[beta].sub.1], [[delta].sub.2] = [[beta].sub.2], [[delta].sub.3] = [[beta].sub.3], [[delta].sub.4] = [[beta].sub.4], [[delta].sub.5] = 0, [[delta].sub.6] = 0, [[delta].sub.7] = [[beta].sub.5] ... (14)

By solving the system of Equation (14) we will get the solution to the model.

IV. STABILITY ANALYSIS AND SHORT-RUN AND LONG-RUN EFFECTS OF DEVALUATION

Taking the first differences of Equations (12) and (13), while setting changes in all exogenous variables except the exchange rate to zero we get:

[DELTA][Y.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.2] [DELTA][e.sub.t] + [[alpha].sub.3][DELTA][e.sub.t-1] + [[alpha].sub.5][DELTA] [X.sub.t-1] ... ... ... (15)

[DELTA] [X.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.2] [DELTA][e.sub.t-1] + [[beta].sub.4][DELTA] [X.sub.t-1] ... ... ... ... (16)

Assuming that initially there is no change in the exchange rate, from Equation (16) we get:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (17)

Similarly, solving Equations (15) and (17) simultaneously we get:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (18)

Finally, using Equations (4), (9) and (16) we get:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)

Equation (18) gives the discounted sum of change in output in the event of devaluation. While Equations (17) and (19) gives the discounted sum of change in nominal wage rate and the CPI respectively. From (17), (18) and (19) it is evident that the discounted sum of output, prices, and nominal wage rate will be on stable path if and only if [absolute value of [[beta].sub.4]] < 1.

In order to derive the impact effect of devaluation upon-the endogenous variables, we first get the solution to the model. For this purpose we first need to solve the system of equation given in (14). Since it is cumbersome to obtain the mathematical solution, we solve this system for a plausible set of parameter values. Following Fischer (1988) we assume [c.sub.1] = 0.1, [c.sub.2] = 0.2, [gamma] = 0.8. We also assume that h = 0.5 and f = 0.65. When these values are substituted in (14) we get the following solution to the model:

[[alpha].sub.1] = -0.09593, [[alpha].sub.2 = 0.22778 = [[alpha].sub.3] = -0.06097, [[alpha].sub.4] = 0.16681 = - [[alpha].sub.5]

[[beta].sub.1] = -0.08518, [[beta].sub.2] = [[beta].sub.3] = 0.69454, [[beta].sub.4] = 0.30546

Since this solution to the model meets the stability condition i.e. [absolute value of [[beta].sub.4]] < 1, we proceed to study the effect of devaluation on output and prices. For a more direct comparison we have plotted the variable [DELTA][Y.sub.t](= [Y.sub.t] - [Y.sub.t-1])/[Y.sub.t-1]), [DELTA][p.sub.t](= ([p.sub.t] - [p.sub.t-1])/[p.sub.t-1]) and [DELTA] [X.sub.t](=([X.sub.t] - [X.sub.t-1])/[X.sub.t-1]) against time, t, which we have generated for a ten-point devaluation of the domestic currency. From Figure 1 it is evident that devaluation is expansionary in the impact period. In the first period there is a 2.28 percent increase in the output. From Figure 2, on the other hand, it can be seen that this increase in output is achieved at the expense of higher inflation. The price level has increased by 2 percent. A point to note here is that the change in the inflation rate has not exceeded the change in the exchange rate. This implies that the nominal devaluation has resulted in real devaluation (fall in competitiveness). In the second period the change in output reduces from 2.28 percent to 1.67 percent while inflation has further increased. This happens as the group of workers whose contract expired in the second period, has demanded an increase in the wage rate for the next two periods in response to the increase in the CPI and output. This can be seen in Figure 3 where the nominal wage increases from 0 percent to 6.95 percent in the second period. After the sixth period, however, the change in output becomes zero while, both inflation and the nominal wage rate increases to the full amount of the nominal devaluation i.e., 10 percent. These results re-establish the conventional belief that devaluation is expansionary in the short and medium run, but neutral in the long run. The reader can confirm easily that in the long run

[DELTA][X.sub.t] = [DELTA][m.sub.t] = [DELTA][p.sup.d.sub.t] = [DELTA][p.sub.t] = [DELTA][e.sub.t].

The results which we have reported above although depend upon the choice of our parameter values but, do not change qualitatively when a different set of parameter values is used. More importantly, we do dot get contractionary effects of devaluation for any reasonable parameter values. It is seen that devaluation has more expansionary effects both in the short and the medium run for high values of [a.sub.2], [c.sub.2], [gamma], while devaluation is less expansionary for high values of [a.sub.1], [c.sub.1], f, and h.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS

In this paper we studied the effects of devaluation on output in a model in which partly sticky wages exist in the form of a two-period wage contract. Due to the nature of these wage contracts, half of the labour force cannot adjust their wage rate in response to a change in the CPI and output. The main finding of the paper is that for stable economies and for plausible sets of parameter values, devaluation exerts a positive impact upon output both in the short and the medium run. The scope of our study, however, is more of a theoretical nature. The model which we have developed in this paper could be considered as an approximation of a developed small open economy such as Canada. The results of our study, therefore, should not apply to less developed countries. For a less developed country we need a model which should allow a lesser degree of capital mobility. Furthermore, we should allow direct supply-side effects of the exchange rate through the inclusion of imported inputs in the model. Because in less developed countries a large fraction of the total output is produced with the combination of both domestic resources and the imported inputs. In this new model the elasticity of substitution between imported inputs and domestic inputs will play a crucial role in determining the net effect of devaluation upon the nominal and real variables of the economy.

Author's Note: I am grateful to Aynul Hasan, who was the discussant, and W. M. Scarth for useful comments and thoughtful insights. Nevertheless I am responsible for any remaining omissions, oversights, and errors in the paper.

REFERENCES

Buffie, E. P. (1986) Devaluation and Imported Inputs: The Large Economy Case. International Economic Review 27: 123-40.

Calvo, G. (1983) Staggered Contracts and Exchange Rate Policy. In J. A. Frankel (ed) Exchange Rates and International Macroeconomics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Fischer, S. (1989) Real Balances, the Exchange Rate, and Indexation: Real Variables in Disinflation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 103: 27-49.

Gylfason, T., and Schmid (1983) Does Devaluation Cause Stagflation? Canadian Journal of Economics 16: 641-654.

Lai, C. C., and W. Chang (1989) Income Taxes, Supply-Side Effects, and Currency Devaluation. Journal of Macroeconomics 11: 281-295.

Larrian, F., and J. Sachs (1986) Contractionary Devaluation and Dynamic Adjustment of Exports and Wages. NBER Working Paper No. 2078.

Meade, J. E. (1951) The Balance of Payments. London: Oxford University Press.

Robinson, J. (1947) Essays in the Theory of Employment. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Turnovsky, S. J. (1981) The Effects of Devaluation and Foreign Price Disturbances under Rational Expectations. Journal of International Economics 11: 33-60.

* Owing to unavoidable circumstances, the discussants comments on this paper have not been received.

(1) Sec Turnovsky (1981) for a model in which agents form expectations about possible changes in the exchange rate and the foreign price level.

Syed Zahid Ali is Assistant Professor in International Institute of Islamic Economics, International Islamic University, Islamabad.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有