Investing in All the People.
Summers, Lawrence H.
I am honoured to have the privilege of addressing this
distinguished conference. I have read about Pakistan's
accomplishments and problems for many years and since coming to the
World Bank I have followed your government's bold reform efforts
closely. I feel fortunate to finally have the opportunity to visit your
country.
I decided to speak today on "Investing in All the People"
because an extensive body of recent research has convinced me that once
all the benefits are recognised, investment in the education of girls
may well be the highest return investment available in the developing
world. And, as I will make clear, increasing the education of girls is
an especially high priority for Pakistan.
Women's education may seem an odd topic for an economist to
address. But enhancing women's contribution to development is as
much an economic as a social issue. Economics, with its emphasis on
incentives, provides a useful way to understand why so many girls are
deprived of education and employment opportunities. And concrete
calculations demonstrate that there are enormous economic benefits to
investing in women.
In examining the links between women's education and
development, I will make five main points that, taken together, provide
a compelling case for action.
First, comparisons of the female fraction of the population in
different countries suggest that as many as 100 million women are
missing worldwide primarily due to higher death rates for young girls
than boys. Higher death rates are symptomatic of a much more general
pattern of female deprivation in the developing world, especially in
South Asia.
Second, underinvestment in girls is not an ineluctable consequence
of poverty, nor is it made necessary by any religious or cultural
tradition. It is an economic problem that results from a vicious cycle caused by distorted incentives. The expectation that girls will grow to
do little other than serve their husbands reduces parent's
incentive to invest in their daughter's human capital. Uneducated
women then have few alternatives and so the expectation becomes self
fulfilling, trapping women in a continuous circle of neglect.
Third, increasing educational opportunities for girls offers the
best prospect for cutting into this vicious cycle. As an economic
investment, increased outlays directed at educating girls may well yield
the highest return of all investments available in developing countries
considering both private benefits and returns to other family members.
Fourth, experience suggests that female education programmes are
relatively inexpensive compared to other development investments and
could quickly increase female enrollment rates.
Fifth, major initiatives to increase female education have the
potential to transform society over time. If a larger fraction of girls
had gone to school a generation ago millions of infant deaths each year
could have been averted and tens of millions of families could have been
healthier and happier.
THE PROBLEM OF EXCESS FEMALE MORTALITY
The experience of different countries as reflected in the
statistical record provides a natural starting point for any discussion
of development policy. I want to start with one of the most basic of all
national statistics--the demographic composition of the population. In
examining these statistics, many observers have been struck by the
differences between countries in what one might have expected to be a
biologically determined constant--the share of the population that is
female. My Harvard colleague Amartya Sen has recently highlighted how
large these differences are by calculating that worldwide more than 100
million women (1) are missing and labelling the fate of these women,
"one of the more momentuous problems facing the contemporary
world". (2) This problem is symptomatic of an even larger problem
of hidden underinvestment in the human development of the women who
survive and are counted.
In the industrialised world females comprise over 51 percent of the
population. In Sub-Saharan Africa the percent of the population that is
female is a little bit lower, ranging from 50.9 to 49.2 percent (Table
1). Likewise, the percentage of females in Latin America ranges from
50.7 to 49.5 percent. But, as seen in Figure 1, Asia in general and
Pakistan in particular stand out in any examination of sex ratios. The
female share of the population is 48.5 percent in China, 48.1 percent in
India, and 47.6 percent in Pakistan--the lowest measured share in the
developing world.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Why are there such large differences in sex ratios across
countries? As a matter of logic there are four
possibilities--differences between men and women in migration patterns,
differences in the share of female babies born, differences in male and
female population shares counted by census data, or differences in
female survival rates. There is no evidence that differing patterns of
migration between women and men can explain such large differences in
national sex ratios, nor are there noticeable differences across
countries in the share of female births: Claims that women are
undercounted in certain societies are largely unsubstantiated and fail
to explain differences in population ratios in nations of similar
culture. It follows that discrepancies in the share of women in the
population must be primarily a matter of differences in survival
probabilities.
Direct analysis of mortality rates supports the proposition that
discrepancies in female population ratios are caused by gender
differences in survival probabilities (Table 2). These differences are
most pronounced for girls and boys between the ages of 1 and 4.
Moreover, these current mortality rates and examination of cohort data
(4) demonstrate that the present low female population ratios do not
reflect excess female mortality that took place in the past but indicate
an ongoing problem. The precise mechanisms which cause these
discrepancies in mortality rates between boys and girls are not fully
understood. But studies have found evidence of differential feeding,
additional work burden inside and outside the home, and less attention
during illness for girls than for boys. Women also suffer excess
mortality due to the risks of childbearing. One third of all deaths
among Pakistani women aged 15 to 49 are due to complications of
pregnancy. (5)
Given that women get less than their share of the goods necessary
for survival, it is hardly surprising that their treatment falls short
in other respects (Table 1). There is a considerable tendency for
various indicators of the relative treatment of women to be correlated across countries. I am afraid that Pakistan clearly illustrates this
point. It lags badly on almost every indicator. As I have said, Pakistan
has the lowest ratio of women to men, and among low income countries,
the fifth lowest ratio of female to male primary enrollment, and the
seventh lowest female/male ratio in secondary enrollment.
THE VICIOUS CYCLE OF DEPRIVATION?
Why are girls deprived in so much of the world and what explains
the large variations across countries? These questions defy any simple
answer. But even a cursory examination of the available information
suffices to reject some explanations and to support others. It is a
misconception that low female population ratios are an inevitable
consequence of poverty. Africa has a far higher fraction of women than
South Asia despite the fact that it fares equally poorly on measures of
percapita income and much worse on most other social indicators.
Comparisons between populations also allow us to rule out the
notion that low female population ratios are unavoidable due to cultural
tradition. It would be foolish to deny that culture has a role in
explaining differences in sex ratios; any explanation of differing
survival rates for children must consider parents' aspirations for
their sons and daughters, which obviously cannot be divorced from
culture. Yet large differences in the treatment of girls exist between
nations with important cultural similarities. To take just one example,
the share of the female population in Indonesia is much closer to the
African share than to the Pakistani share. Even within a single country
large discrepancies in the ratio of females can exist. The state of
Kerala in India, for example, has a proportion of females which is far
higher than the nation as a whole. (6)
Whatever its original roots, the problem of excess female mortality
today is a consequence of a vicious cycle (depicted in Figure 2) whereby
parents fail to invest in their daughters because they do not expect
their daughters to be able to make an economic contribution to the
family, and the prophecy turns out to be self fulfilling. The nature of
this cycle is illustrated by two stories.
Situation A
A poor family has 6 children. The mother never attended school and
was married at age 15. She is completely illiterate and cannot do
arithmetic well enough to count out change. She stays home, does
household chores with her daughters, and works in the fields even though
she is 7 months pregnant. Her husband earns most of the family's
meager income and decides how it is spent. As he, not his sisters, is
expected to support his parents, he recognises that his economic
security depends on his sons' ability to support him in his old
age. He insists that the boys go to school while the girls stay home to
do chores and take care of the young babies. When his daughter becomes
mysteriously ill, he feels he cannot afford to go with her for two days
to the medical clinic in the city. His wife pleads with him but he will
not change his mind, repeating the words "we have to think about
our future". The wife finally relents, realising that he is right.
The daughter dies.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Situation B
A poor family has 3 children. The mother went to school for five
years and is able to read and do arithmetic well enough to teach school
in the village. As her last birth was extremely difficult, she and her
husband adopted family planning. This allows her more time and resources
to spend on her family; she visits her ill mother often and buys her
medicine. She insists that all of her children go to school and practice
their reading each night, hoping to expand their horizons. She is
especially determined that her middle daughter, who has a remarkable
ability to make up stories, continue in school and develop her talent.
When the daughter gets sick and does not seem to be getting better, she
takes her to the medical clinic. The doctor gives them some ampicillin tablets and instructs the mother to give them to any of the children who
fall ill. The daughter's strep infection is cured, as is the
infection of the son who was running a high fever by the time the mother
returned home.
Some of the differences between these two situations are obvious
enough. An uneducated mother without skills that are valued outside the
home has less ability to influence choices within the family. Her
daughters are uneducated as well and a vicious cycle is
perpetuated--girls grow up only to marry into somebody else's
family and bear children. Girls are thus less valuable than boys and are
kept at home to do chores while their brothers are sent to school. They
remain uneducated and unskilled and the conditions necessary for them to
contribute to the economy are not created. The economy suffers and young
girls die of neglect.
By contrast, an educated mother faces a higher opportunity cost of
time spent caring for children. She has a greater value outside the home
and thus has an entirely different set of choices than she would without
education. She is married at a later age (Figure 3) and is able to
better influence family decisions. She has fewer, healthier children and
can insist on the development of all of them, ensuring that her
daughters are given a fair chance. And the education of her daughters
makes it much more likely that the next generation of girls, as well as
of boys, will be educated and healthy as well. The vicious cycle is thus
transformed into a virtuous circle.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
THE NEED FOR EDUCATION
What is the best way to convert what is too often a vicious cycle
into a virtuous circle? There is no one answer to this question. But I
believe that the available evidence suggests that programmes to raise
the education of girls offer the best hope. When one takes into account
all of its benefits, educating girls quite possibly yields a higher rate
of return than any other investment available in the developing world.
Consider its benefits.
Most obviously, there is the direct effect of increased female
education on the wages of female workers. The evidence is that the
returns in the form of higher wages are fairly similar for men and
women. As a rough approximation, wages increase by more than 10 to 20
percent for each additional year of schooling. In parts of the world
like South Asia and Africa, where literacy and school enrollment rates
are low, the returns to education are particularly high.
Returns of this magnitude are impressive by the standard of other
available investments, but they are just the beginning of the benefits
from increasing female education. In part because of what women do with
the extra income they earn, in part because of the extra leverage it
affords them within the family, and in part because of the direct
effects of being more knowledgeable and aware, female education has an
enormous impact on health practices including adoption of family
planning--an impact that as Table 3 demonstrates, is large enough to
justify increased educational outlays even if there were no direct
pecuniary benefits. While the evidence is that increased schooling of
boys and girls is similar in its wage impact, it is clear that educating
girls is much more effective in generating social benefits.
Educating women yields high returns in terms of healthier children
by cutting through the vicious cycle I just described. There is
overwhelming evidence that mothers channel much more of their income to
expenditures on children than their husbands do. But this is only one of
the channels through which education improves health. It also increases
the willingness to seek medical care and improves sanitation practices.
Educating an extra 1000 girls an additional year in 1990 would have cost
approximately $ 30,000. (7) The best available estimates suggest that
each year of schooling reduces under five mortality by up to 10 percent.
Similar estimates are obtained both from studies of cross sections in
individual countries and for studies of cross country variations in
infant and child mortality rates. With an average woman in Pakistan
having 6.6 children, it follows that providing an additional 1000 women
one extra year of schooling would prevent roughly 60 infant deaths.
What would it cost to achieve similar results through investments
in health care? Obviously the answer differs across health care
investments. For example, cost effectiveness estimates suggest that
programmes of supplementary antenatal feeding cost in the neighbourhood
of $ 700 per life saved. Other commonly recommended health interventions
are more expensive; measles immunisation programmes outside of high risk
environments, for example, cost $ 1000 per life saved. (8) Taking $ 800
as the cost of saving a life with health care interventions, the cost of
achieving the same reduction in mortality that would accrue from
devoting $ 30,000 to educating another 1000 girls is $ 48,000. As this
calculation ignores any other benefits of reduced child morbidity, it
underestimates the returns to female education as a health care
investment.
Educated women also choose to have fewer children. Econometric studies within individual countries looking at the effects of education
on fertility find that an extra year of female schooling reduces female
fertility by approximately 5 to 10 percent, or in the case of Pakistan
by about .7. (9) Thus a $ 30,000 investment in educating 1000 women
would avert 500 births. I will avoid the metaphysical question of trying
to value an averted birth and simply ask how much typical family
planning programmes spend per birth that they avert. A typical family
planning evaluation concludes that costs run approximately $ 65 per
birth averted. Averting 660 births would cost about $ 33,000, enough to
justify education on family planning grounds alone. (10)
There is a final group of beneficiaries of investments in female
education--the women themselves. Maternal mortality rates are ten times
as high in South Asia as in East Asia. By increasing knowledge about
health care practices and reducing the average pregnancies of these
women, female education significantly reduces the risk of maternal
mortality (Figure 4). Based only on the impact on the number of births,
and not including what are surely significant impacts on the risks
associated with any given birth, one can calculate that an additional
year of schooling for 1000 women will prevent three maternal deaths.
Achieving similar gains in adult mortality through medical interventions
of average cost effectiveness would cost close to $ 7,500. (11)
These estimates of the social benefits are of course crude. On one
hand, I have failed to discount benefits to reflect the fact that female
education operates with a lag. On the other hand, I have neglected the
add-on benefits as healthier better educated mothers not only have
healthier better educated children but healthier better educated
grandchildren. When the average mother has nearly 40 grandchildren as in
Pakistan, this is no small thing.
Even discounting the social benefits of education to reflect the
lags and taking no account of add-on benefits, the social benefits of
increased female education are sufficient to more than cover its costs.
Given that increases in female education also yield large wage
increases, it seems reasonable to conclude that the return to getting
more girls into school is in excess of 20 percent and may well be
considerably greater. Turning the vicious cycle I have described into a
virtuous circle has other benefits as well. It provides more women the
means to escape the exploitation and neglect that remains all too common
in many parts of the world and it helps them to become dignified members
of their family, their society, and their nation. I will come later to
the comparison of the return to educating girls with other developmental
expenditures. But let me just note for now that the calculations I have
just presented imply that educating girls looks quite attractive
compared with educating boys and quite likely has higher return than
health or family planning interventions.
INCREASING THE EDUCATION OF GIRLS
There is then an overwhelming case for increased investments in the
education of girls. How can this best be done? The first component of
any effort to raise female enrollment rates must be policies that
promote economic growth and poverty alleviation. Comparisons of both
countries and families demonstrate a strong impact of poverty
alleviation on enrollment rates. Because parents are more reluctant to
send girls than boys to school, poverty alleviation is especially
important for raising female enrollment rates.
But female enrollments do not always rise as incomes grow. It takes
the right policies to alter perverse incentives and provide the needed
encouragement to let girls learn.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Ultimately, whatever laws legislatures enact, it is parents who
decide whether or not to send their daughters to school. And although
the social returns to educating girls far exceed the returns to
educating boys, parents capture a larger fraction of the benefits of
educating their sons. In a survey done some years ago, by far the
largest single reason given by parents (over 45 percent) for not
educating daughters was lack of financial gain to the family (Table 4).
What can be done to make educating girls more attractive to
parents? While the evidence is far from clear and there is a need for
controlled experiments, current knowledge suggests enactment of an
agenda which will recognise the external benefits of female education in
determining financing policies and would seek to make educating girls
more attractive given both cultural traditions and the many competing
needs of poor families. As there are greater social benefits to
educating girls than boys, it is appropriate for females' education
to cost less than male education. Scholarship funds should be
established and more free books and other supplies provided for girls.
Because parents are more reluctant to educate their daughters, this is
particularly important. One study in Peru found that rules requiring
students to pay for textbooks had a large negative effect on female
enrollment but almost no effect on males. Whatever the general merits of
cost recovery in the case of basic education may be, the argument is
much weaker where there are large external benefits, as there are with
the education of females.
Providing schooling that responds to cultural and practical
concerns is also essential. Female enrollment is heavily dependent upon
schools not being too far away, upon the provision of appropriate
sanitation facilities, and upon the hiring of female teachers. This, of
course, is facilitated by raising female enrollment rates. Flexible
hours and the provision of care for younger siblings can also be helpful
in some cases.
These two measures--reducing costs for girls and making special
efforts to accommodate parents' practical needs--will make a big
difference in raising families' demand for female education. In the
survey cited above, the largest single reason given by girls for their
lack of enrollment was "there is no school for girls" (Table
5). A recent survey of households in four Pakistani districts shows that
enrollment rates for girls with a school in their village is equivalent
to male enrollment (Table 6). The enrollment rate of girls with a school
nearby, instead of in their village, is ninety percent of that of males.
This indicates that increasing the supply of educational facilities for
girls has tremendous potential for expanding enrollment.
Increasing female enrollment in school is dependent upon providing
resources for increased schooling. As education is a labour intensive
business, it is relatively inexpensive to provide in low income
countries. The available statistics indicate that in low income
economies, the average annual recurrent costs of primary schooling
(which comprise the vast majority of the costs) run slightly over $ 36
per student. Secondary education is somewhat more expensive per student,
reflecting in part lower enrollment rates. Since satisfactory estimates
of the average cost of secondary school are not available, I simply
assume that they are twice primary costs. (12)
* Raising the female primary school enrollment rate of girls to
equal the male primary school enrollment rate in the world's low
income countries would involve educating an additional 25 million girls
each year at a total cost of approximately $ 938 million (Table 7).
Raising the secondary school enrollment of girls to equal the secondary
school enrollment rate of boys would involve educating an additional 21
million girls at a total cost of $ 1.4 billion. Eliminating educational
discrimination in the low income parts of the world would thus cost a
total of $ 2.4 billion. This represents less than one-quarter of one
percent of their GDP, less than two percent of their government
consumption spending, less than one percent of their investment in new
capital goods, and less than l/10 of their defense spending.
* Similar calculations can be made for Pakistan. The recurrent
costs of raising female primary enrollment to equal the current primary
enrollment of males would be about $ 36 million or 625 million rupees.
This represents only 0.12 percent of GNP. Achieving the more ambitious
objective of equalising male and female enrollment rates in both primary
and secondary school would cost $ 64 million, 1.1 billion rupees or .22
percent of GDP. Of course these low costs will not meet all of
Pakistan's educational goals. Maintaining and raising the current
low overall enrollment rates with existing population growth will not be
cheap and will require major investments.
Considering the very low cost both in Pakistan and in low income
countries in general of equalising educational opportunities for men and
women, it is easier to wonder whether the world can afford not to make
the necessary outlays than it is to wonder if they are affordable. I
have already suggested that education looks very attractive relative to
other social sector investments. When compared to development
investments outside the social sector, education looks even more
attractive. Taking investments in power generation as an example,
current projections suggest that developing countries will spend
approximately $1 trillion on power plants over the next ten years. In
many of these nations, existing power plant capacity utilisation is less
than 50 percent due to poor maintenance and pricing problems. The
overall return on power plant physical assets in a sample of 57
developing countries has been estimated at an average of less than 4
percent over the last 3 years and less than 6 percent over the last
decade, returns which cannot even compare with those of providing
education for females.
No doubt efficiency in the power sectors of developing countries
can
and will be improved. And I have probably understated somewhat the
difficulty of raising enrollment rates by neglecting capital costs and
not taking explicit account of the special costs that must be incurred
in targeting girls. Nonetheless, it is hard to believe that building 19
out of every 20 planned power plants and using the savings to finance
world equal educational opportunity for girls would not be desirable.
WHAT COULD BE ACCOMPLISHED
Letting girls go to school, learn to read, and experience more of
the world beyond their homes makes them better off immediately and
enriches their families. Over time, getting girls into school can
transform societies as their sons and daughters and grandsons and
granddaughters reap the benefits. Contemplate a very crude estimate of
how much better off the world would be today if major investments in
increasing female education had been made a generation ago.
There are a number of different strategies to approaching this
counter factual. One method would be to simply extrapolate the
calculations based on microeconometric estimates based on surveys of
women within individual countries. Instead, as a kind of check on those
calculations, I examine the relationship between national rates of
infant mortality and female education a generation ago (Table 8 and
Figures 5 and 6), holding constant a variety of country characteristics.
The estimates are derived from a sample of the 45 developing countries
for which all the needed data are available. As the evidence I have
presented so far might lead one to expect, the relationship is both
statistically significant and implies large effects of education on
health and fertility. Female education rates are the most potent
variable in these equations, dwarfing the effects of male education or
the availability of medical care.
These relationships can be used to simulate the impact of an
increase in the female secondary school enrollment rate from its average
in 1965 to 30 percent (Table 9). For comparison, the male secondary
enrollment rate in this sample of countries averaged 22 percent in 1965.
The results are striking. In Pakistan alone raising the female secondary
enrollment rate from 6 to 30 percent in 1965 would have averted 1.2
million births per year and 297 thousand infant deaths. For a sample of
45 countries that includes about 71 percent of the low income
world's population (excluding China), the result would be 9.1
million births per year averted and 3.0 million fewer infant deaths.
CONCLUSION
My emphasis this afternoon is on the need for increasing
expenditures on female education. Those who advocate such policies also
argue for programmes directed at enhancing family planning and
women's health services as well as measures to combat
discrimination in labour and credit markets. I have little doubt that
such actions would also be constructive, but I believe that they are
less important than improvements in female education. Hard statistical
evaluations fairly consistently find that female education is the
variable most highly correlated with improvements in social indicators.
And the benefits of education have multiplier effects because they
empower women to bring about other necessary changes. The greatest
emphasis, therefore, should be put on closing the education gaps that I
have described.
Lectures and papers that plead the importance of a particular type
of investment in developing countries are hardly uncommon. Reflecting
the biases of an economist, I have tried to concentrate on the concrete
benefits of female education and explicitly contrast it with other
proposed investments. Expenditures on increasing the education of girls
do not just meet the seemingly easy test of being more socially
productive than military outlays. They appear to be far more productive
than other social sector outlays and than the vastly larger physical
capital outlays that are projected over the next decade.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
In making an economic argument for investing in the education of
women, I have tried to steer clear of the moral and cultural aspects
unavoidably implicated in any gender related question. Partially this
reflects my comparative advantage as an economist. But it also reflects
a conviction that one's viewpoint on feminism should not affect
one's evaluation of the arguments for educating girls. Helping
women be better mothers to their children is desirable on any view of
the proper role of women in society.
There are those who say that educating girls is a strategy that
pays off only in the long run. I am reminded of a story that John F.
Kennedy used to tell of a man asking his gardner how long it would take
for a certain seed to grow into a tree. The gardner said it would take
100 years, to which the man replied, "Then plant the seed this
morning. There is no time to lose".
Comments on "Investing in All the People" (1)
In his Quaid-i-Azam Lecture, Professor Summers lends the prestige
of his office of the Vice Presidency of the World Bank "to make a
point: educating women is the best investment the developing world can
make." (2) Professor Summers puts his point across through a
five-fold argument which involves (i) mortality, (ii) economic
incentives, (iii) portfolio choice, (iv) costs and (v) societal transformation. I take each in turn.
The importance of gender for questions of mortality, particularly
child mortality, is well-known and well-understood. In their 1976
examination of Bangladeshi data, Ben-Porath and Welch wrote that
girls born into families where girls are in the majority are
significantly more likely to die before age five than girls born
into families with more boys than girls. (3)
Since then Amartya Sen has highlighted the importance of low female
survival rates in the LDCs as "one of the more momentous problems
facing the contemporary world" and an important problem for
development economics. (4)
Second, Professor Summers draws attention to what has now come to
be known as the Chicago-Columbia approach to the economics of the
household, and one associated particularly with the names of G. Becker
and T. W. Schultz. The basic insight is to regard children, boys and
girls, with differing levels of education as different commodities, each
with its own shadow prices and its own demand and supply. Summers writes
Economics, with its emphasis on incentives, provides a useful way
to understand why so many girls are deprived of education and
employment opportunities. Underinvestment is not an ineluctable
consequence of poverty, nor is it made necessary by any religious
or cultural tradition. It is an economic problem that results from
a vicious cycle caused by distorted incentives. In making an
economic argument for investing in the education of women, I have
tried to steer clear of the moral and cultural aspects unavoidably
implicated in any gender related question. Partially, this reflects
my comparative advantage as an economist.
Summers contrasts a vicious cycle involving, at the macroeconomic level, ignorance, poverty, high mortality and high fertility, with that
of virtuous circle where education leads to economic progress and low
mortality and fertility rates; see his parables labelled Situation A and
Situation B as well as his Figure 2.
I have already referred to issues of mortality. In the context of
fertility decisions, Ismail Sirageldin and I attempted in our work in
the seventies, to apply the insights of this approach to 1968 Pakistani
data. In particular, we constructed the variable EC about which we wrote
This variable can be better described if we mention the
corresponding questions that were asked. It was first inquired
whether the wife thought it "necessary nowadays to educate
children." Those who answered yes were then asked how much
education was necessary for girls. Out of these answers, we
constructed the dummy variable as follows: zero if the answer to
the first question was no or the answer to the second question was
less than three grades, one otherwise. (5)
However, we were very conscious of our data base not allowing us to
study the question with any depth and we emphasised
the inadequacy of the variable EC as measuring the differential
shadow prices of boys and girls. It is only our presumption that
EC, in measuring a couples commitment to the education of their
children, measure the parents' willingness to absorb a higher cost
of their sons' education as opposed to that of their daughters'. It
must also be borne in mind that in the context of Pakistani society
the costs of a son's education have to be balanced by the dowry
provisions a parent has to furnish for his daughter at her
marriage. Of course, these would be just one of the considerations
that make up the total shadow prices of boys and girls. (6)
Despite all of this, we were unambiguously clear about the
importance of our principal findings.
The negative inducement of the number of living sons on wanting
additional children is about three times that due to the number of
living daughters. Thus, for example, a family with no children has
a probability of 78.2 percent [of wanting additional children,] and
with seven sons only a probability of 1.6 percent. Both figures are
reasonable. The surprise [lies in that] for a family with seven
daughters only, this probability is around 40 percent. Indeed, if
we turn the question round to ask how long a string of girls would
be needed so that the probability falls to 1.6 percent, the answer
comes out to be more than twenty. (7)
The interesting questions pertain to the incentives and
institutions that make a Punjabi farmer's choice of seven sons as
opposed to seven daughters, rational, whatever meaning one may choose to
give to the term. The question is the nature of the equilibrium that is
responsible for the imbalance between education and opportunities. One
has to be particularly wary here, it seems to me, of a partial
equilibrium approach, whereby equilibrium embraces both the economic and
the socio-cultural. Institutions of any complex society are not only
linked to each other, but any one of them typically serves more than one
end and its unilateral abolition without corresponding modifications of
others, however desirable from the point of view of one objective, may
be disastrous from the point of view of another. (8)
Of course, the interesting point in Professor Summers' Lecture
is not the advocacy of education for girls - hardly anybody would object
to that--but that, dollar for dollar, it is the best investment for
Pakistan. This is a question of portfolio choice and he writes
It is hard to believe that building 19 out of every 20 planned
power plants and using the savings to finance world educational
opportunity for girls would not be desirable. (9) Concrete
calculations demonstrate that there are enormous economic benefits
to investing in women. And, as I will make clear, increasing the
education of girls is an especially high priority for Pakistan.
Expenditures on increasing the education of girls do not just meet
the seemingly easy test of being more socially productive than
military outlays. They appear to be far more productive than other
social sector outlays and than the vastly larger physical capital
outlays that are projected over the next decade.
The point that is being made here is not that education, be it of
girls or of boys, is a public good and hence there is a tendency for
free-market outcomes to undersupply it, but that it is more
undersupplied, and hence has a higher social return, than any other
public good. This is a most interesting point and I shall make two
observations in relation to it.
It is a triviality that to term an element of a set as a best
element implies not only that one has a clear idea of what is in the
set, but also what one's objective function is. Thus, Professor
Summers's claim opens the ground for a host of interesting
questions as regards both the nature of commodity that is being invested
in as well as the methodology of welfare economics. The former leads, in
particular, to concrete thinking as regards educational policy in
Pakistan. When we say more education of girls, do we mean the action of
devoting more resources within the existing curriculum or do we also
allow for changes in the curriculum itself?. Should we continue the
emphasis on memorisation and the current mix between the sciences and
the humanities, and between vocational and non-vocational instruction?
What goes into the humanities? How much should cultural and religious
studies be emphasised? Which culture? How about history? Should it be
World history or European history or Pakistani history? What should be
the medium of instruction? What about the education of the educators?
How should the curriculum differ between the provinces? Should it differ
across gender? In sum, once we raise the question of the best
investment, we are naturally led towards the specification of the
precise nature of the commodity involved? (10) Again, how precise is
precise? I do not have answers to these questions but it is clear that
research resources devoted to them also have a high social return. (11)
The question of objectives and what this implies for the
methodology of welfare economics can best be taken up in the context of
the last two points of Professor Summers. The fourth leg of his argument
involves figures on the costs of equalising male/female enrollment
ratios and to consider the speed with which female enrollment rates can
be increased. He concludes with the statement that
Major initiatives to increase female education have the potential
to transform society over time.
Leaving aside the obvious point of the difficulty of using market
prices for internationally non-traded commodities in an LDC, especially
in the case of a "large" project, there is a fine line here
between an economist's "scientific" evaluation of a
particular project and his or her advocacy of it as a citizen of a
relevant community, be it of Pakistan, or of the LDCs as a whole, or of
the world or of any other grouping that is relevant. To put the matter
another way, best obviously implies a criterion which is being
maximised, and as I understand the new welfare economics, an economist
simply spells out to those in charge of policy the various trade-offs
involved. It is then left to the executive, elected or appointed or
whatever, to take the necessary decisions. (12) But maybe, here I am
being influenced too much by old-fashioned constructs such as
Arrow's impossibility theorem.
In the context of the last point, I would also like to raise two
cautionary flags. It is clear that there are obvious impediments,
economic and social, towards the endogenous realisation of outcomes that
we consider desirable and would like to see realised. As such, this
argues--and Professor Summers is doing precisely this--for policy
interference, and in particular for a transition from one Nash
equilibrium to another. It may very well be that LDCs, and Pakistan in
particular, have in-built buffers resulting from their rich historical
heritage, that facilitates these transitions and makes their costs
negligible, but I would like to make the point that it would be
reckless, especially if the policy interventions are to be major
initiatives, to disregard this aspect.
My second point simply underscores what Professor Summers says
himself.
It would be foolish to deny that culture has a role in explaining
differences in sex ratios; any explanation of differing survival
rates for children must consider parent's aspirations for their
sons and daughters, which obviously cannot be divorced from
culture. Yet large differences in the treatment of girls exist
between nations with important cultural similarities. To take just
one example, the share of female population in Indonesia is much
closer to the African share than the Pakistani share.
As Geertz's fascinating study shows, cultural similarity is an
elusive thing and sometimes efficacy obtains where one would least
expect it. (13)
In conclusion, I refer to Business Week which quotes Professor
Summers as follows:
Some people thought I was the greatest thing ever to come to
Pakistan; others thought America has 20 million latchkey kids
because of the sort of ideas I was pushing. (14)
In thanking Professor Summers for his Quaid-i-Azam Lecture, I would
take a somewhat intermediate position--he raises an important and
challenging topic, both from the point of view of economics and others
so-called "human sciences" and one on which scholars,
including those from Pakistan, have been working for some time.
M. Ali Khan
The Johns Hopkins University, USA.
Comments on "Investing in All the People"
This comment represents a watershed in my professional life. One
that I did not expect to reach till rather later in my career. I was
prepared to be harsh if necessary in my comments because of the position
in which Prof. Summers has placed me. I however find that harshness is
not necessary because I agree with so much of what he has said. In my
lecture I describe the gender gap in cognitive skills in rural Pakistan,
analysed its sources and suggested how best to eliminate them. In
essence, I was recommending substantial increases in government spending on the education of girls. How very nice of the organisers of this
conference to arrange for the Chief Economist of the World Bank to
forcefully second my argument. The only situation I might have preferred
would be for the Minister of Finance to be present along with the
Minister of Defence and Minister of Water and Power, and announce that
they have agreed to have a reallocation of public expenditure from the
military for future investment in power plants and primary and secondary
education systems, enabling Pakistan, to eliminate in short order, the
enormous gender gap in education that currently prevails. In my comments
I wish to raise a few queries and provide a few additional arguments to
support Larry Summers contention that the returns to investment in
girls' education are high. There is however a difference in our
understanding of the situation. At least in the situation in Pakistan,
Prof. Summers and I agree on the prescription of the problem of a large
gender gap in schooling. There are adjustments which need to be made,
largely by the government on the supply side of the market for
education. But we disagree on the origin of the problems. He places
emphasis on inadequate household demand for the schooling of girls. Why
emphasise inadequate supply? Moreover, there is, I think a fundamental
inconsistency in arguing, as Prof. Summers does, that the solution to
the problem of inadequate demand is an increase in supply. What is the
point of providing schools to girls, when their parents would not send
them. The evidence I believe is strong that at least in Pakistan, demand
is adequate and supply is the problem. Prof. Summers set the stage for
his discussion of education by talking about other manifestations of
gender bias. Given normal sex ratios, there are, worldwide, more than
one hundred million women missing, presumably because of higher
mortality among girls and women than among boys and men. This gender gap
in mortality rates is to be found in Pakistan. Indeed he notes that at
47 percent Pakistan has the lowest measured share by women in the
population of the developing world. I do not dispute these stylised facts but one aspect puzzles me. The one hundred million missing women
and the proportion of women refer to the entire population stock and not
to the flow. Not to what is happening at the margin. It is conceivable for example that the stock has the gender composition it does because of
the biases in infant feeding practices, health care and other reasons
that were prevalent 20-30-40 or more years ago, but are no longer
prevalent today. In his Table 1, Prof. Summers anticipates such a query
and as an indicator of what is happening today, presents data on females
as a percentage of the population from 0-4 years of age. The data only
increase my puzzlement. In Pakistan that proportion is a full percentage
point higher than the percentage of females in the total population,
suggesting that at least in Pakistan the gender bias and the mortality
rate can, may be, substantially reduced. Turning now to the core of his
argument which pertains to the investment in schooling of girls, which
he sees as the most effective way of breaking the vicious circle of
higher fertility, little or no education, low productivity and higher
mortality which face women in developing countries. Educating girls
will, he argues, convert this vicious circle to a virtuous one by
contributing to reduction in fertility, an increase in the productivity
of women, both in the labour market and in the household, and to reduce
the mortality of women and their daughters. He goes on to present
stylised facts pertaining to the economic benefits in investing in the
education of girls. He notes, first of all, that the returns to
education in the wage labour market are at least as high for women as
for men. He could further note that education increases the probability
of attaining a wage job and that this effect can be larger for women
than for men. He still places a greater emphasis on the returns to
education that changes household behaviour. Educated women have
healthier children. Similarly, he shows that investment in the education
of girls is a more cost-effective means of reducing female fertility
than directly investing in family planning programmes. I would add
another similar example. It is possible to improve the cognitive outputs
per year of schooling by expending resources on improving the quality of
schooling or by increasing the education of women. Given two children
with the same ability, the same number of years of schooling, and the
same quality of schooling, the child with the educated mother will learn
more. I would not be surprised if ensuring that the mothers are
educated, is not a more cost-effective means of increasing the cognitive
skills of children than investing in the improvement of the quality of
schools. Of course, the investment choices are not mutually exclusive.
Indeed, I expect that there is a positive interaction between these two
types of human capital investment. Returns to investment in quality
enhancement are likely to be higher if mothers are educated. This point,
I believe generalises returns to investment in health care or in family
planning are also likely to be higher if women are educated. This only
reinforces Prof. Summers argument that the returns to education are
higher. I now turn to the issue of just how high. He suggests that there
may be excess of 20 percent per year--A couple of comments on
this--First a few words of caution. A rate of return of 20 percent imply
a doubling of resources invested roughly in 3 1/2 years. If such
investment opportunities were abundant in sectors as large as education
then poor countries would be transformed to rich ones at a much more
rapid rate. Why might returns be much lower? First, if the quality of
schooling is too low then the various benefits noted by Prof. Summers
will not be reaped. Sitting in a class room will not be sufficient to
achieve these benefits. It is necessary to acquire the cognitive and
other skills that schools are trying to teach. Second, in countries such
as Egypt, the government is so compelled by political pressure to hire
second school university graduates for jobs that have low or even
negative marginal productivity. If the response to increase the
education for girls is increased, much of the potential productivity
benefit of education will be squandered. Third, Prof. Summers notes that
many of the benefits of education are inter-generational. They will be
reaped by the children of the current generation of girls. Though they
have the power to transform society, when such benefits are discounted
in the conventional way they may appear to be low. There is a risk that
expectations of such higher rates of return are not fulfilled in the
short run. The political will to stay the course may be undermined. But
these are only qualifications on the margin. I agree that the returns,
both private and social, to investment in primary and secondary
schooling are likely to be higher. Higher at the margins are returns to
investment in the schooling of boys and higher than planned investment
in physical capital. This brings me to the basic point of disagreement
with Prof. Summers. If private returns are so high, why is the parental
demand for girls schooling so low? Are parents ignorant of the returns?
Or are they still biased against their daughters or so traditional in
their attitude that they are willing to sacrifice these benefits? Here
it is important to recall that in Pakistan, as in many other countries,
the main cost of education is borne by the Government leaving parents
only the opportunity costs. Is the opportunity cost that much higher for
girls than boys? Are households so resource constrained that they cannot
afford these opportunity costs even when the net result of investment
are so large? In Pakistan the answer to these four questions appear to
be No, No, No and No. Parents have come to recognise that investment in
girls education is a good thing. But the main reason more girls are not
in school is that very often a school for girls is not available. Nearly
one-half of the villages in our sample had primary schools for boys but
did not have primary schools for girls. Prof. Summers inconsistency in
recommending an increase in supply to solve the problem of inadequate
demand is I think, best resolved in the Pakistani case by recognising
the increase in the supply of schooling of girls. This is necessary to
satisfy the currently frustrated demand of parents. Policy need not
address biases which are deeply embedded, incentive systems or household
preferences: if the schools are provided the girls will attend.
Richard H. Sabot
Williams College, Williamstown, USA.
(1) This comment has benefitted from the response of Professor
Summers to my remarks in Islamabad, and from conversations with Saleha
Jilani and Leila Khan as well as with my Hopkins's colleagues. The
responsibility for any errors, including those of tone and emphasis, and
for the views expressed here is of course solely mine.
(2) See Business Week for a perception of Professor Summers's
presentation in the popular press.
(3) The italics are the authors'; [see Ben-Porath-Welch
(1976), p. 297].
(4) See Summers's article for detailed references.
(5) [See Khan-Sirageldin (1979), p. 533.1
(6) See Khan-Sirageldin (1977) in the Johns Hopkins working paper
version.
(7) [See Khan-Sirageldin (1977), p. 488.]
(8) I return to these issues in my discussion of Professor
Summers's last point.
(9) Also the last but one paragraph in Summers's essay titled
"The most influential investment" in Scientific American,
August 1992, p. 132.
(10) See Khan (1989) for the importance of the definition of a
commodity for the fundamental theorems of welfare economics.
(11) See especially Lecture 1 in Derrida (1984) for a fascinating
discussion of how the French language was imposed on what is now France
to build what is now the French nation.
(12) See Khan's (1992) discussion of Harberger's views on
this point.
(13) I would like to refer here to my work with Ismail Sirageldin,
see Khan-Sirageldin (1981, 1983), on interspousal communication and the
asymmetric importance of a husbands' opinions on those of his wife.
(14) See paragraph 2 in the Business Week article.
Author's Note: This paper was prepared for the Quaid-i-Azam
Lecture at the Eighth Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society of
Development Economists in Islamabad, Pakistan, in January 1992. I am
grateful to Dennis de Tray, Barbara Herz., Dale Hill, Lant Pritchett,
Laura Raney, Sheryl Sandberg and Kalanidhi Subbarao for valuable
discussions and assistance in the preparation of this paper. The views
expressed should be attributed only to me.
REFERENCES
Ben-Porath, Y., and F. Welch (1976) Do Sex Preferences Really
Matter. Quarterly Journal of Economics XC 285-318.
Business Week (1992) The In-Your-Face-Economist at the World Bank.
May 11, 76-78.
Derrida J. (1984) Languages and Institutions of Philosophy.
Recherches semiotiques/Semiotic Inquiry 4, 91-154.
Geertz, C. (1968) Islam Observed: Religious Development in Morocco
and Indonesia Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Khan, M. Ali (1989) In Praise of Development Economics. The
Pakistan Development Review 28: 337-378.
Khan, M. Ali (1992) On Measuring the Social Opportunity Cost of
Labour in the Presence of Tariffs and an Informal Sector. Invited
Presentation at the Eight Meeting of the Pakistan Society of Development
Economists, Islamabad, Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review.
(Forthcoming.)
Khan, M. Ali, and I. Sirageldin (1977) Son Preference and the
Demand for Additional Children in Pakistan. Demography 14 481-95.
Republished in B. Boulier (ed) Household Models of Economic Demographic
Decision Making. IUSSP, Belgium, 1979.
Khan, M. Ali, and I. Sirageldin (1979) Education, Income and
fertility in Pakistan. Economic Development and Cultural Change. 27
519-47. Abstract in Sociological Abstracts.
Khan, M. Ali, and I. Sirageldin (1981) Intrafamily interaction and
desired additional fertility in Pakistan: A Simultaneous Equation Model with Dichotomous
Dependent Variables. The Pakistan Development Review 20: 37-60.
Khan, M. Ali, and I. Sirageldin (1983) How Meaningful are
Statements about the Desired Number of Additional Children? An Analysis
of 1968 Pakistani Data. The Pakistan Development Review 22: 1-22.
(1) Ansley Coale (1991), using slightly different assumptions about
expected masculinity ratios, calculates that the total number of missing
females is approximately 60 million. As Coale says, even this lower
independent estimate "confirms the enormity of the social
problem".
(2) Amartya Sen. "Women's Survival as a Development
Problem". Comments prepared for the 1700th Stated meeting of the
American Academy of Arts and Sciences on March 8, 1989.
(3) There is some evidence that in higher income Asian countries
modern medical technologies have been used to selectively abort female
fetuses. Where selective abortion is not practiced, male births
generally slightly outnumber female births. The median ratio of the
number of male to female births in 24 countries in Europe from 1962 to
1980 was 1.059, with 71 percent falling between 1.055 and 1.064
(Chahnazarian, 1986).
(4) Examination of the female population ratios for cohorts in
1951, 1961, and 1972 show near equal increases as the cohort ages from
0-10 years to 10-20 years, indicating consistently higher female
mortality.
(5) Senior Minister Begum Nusrat Bhutto. Inaugural Address. Safe
Motherhood South Asia Conference. Lahore, Pakistan. March 1990.
(6) This difference may be partially due to migration. But this is
unlikely to be the whole story. It is noteworthy that Kerala's
health and primary education systems are very strong, both overall and
in their treatment of girls and women.
(7) The World Bank's best estimate of the average recurrent
cost of one year of secondary school in Pakistan is $ 28.7. On the one
hand, the marginal cost will be higher for girls. On the other hand,
primary school is cheaper than secondary school so our use of $ 30 as
the recurrent costs of one year of school is conservative.
(8) Jamison and Mosley's study, described in Chapter 1 of
Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries (1990), gives costs
for a wide variety of health interventions. The cost of supplementary
antenatal feeding per discounted healthy life year gained is $ 25. The
cost of measles immunisation per discounted healthy life year gained
outside of high risk environments is $ 40. The cost of immunisation for
tuberculosis and leprosy per discounted healthy life year gained is $
75. The cost of improved cholera immunisation per discounted healthy
life year gained is $ 200.
(9) A study by Dennis de Tray (1972) finds the elasticity of
fertility with respect to female education is -0.3. At a level of three
years of schooling an additional year would reduce fertility by 10
percent Other more recent studies confirm this magnitude. In Kenya
(Schafgans, 1991) a woman with secondary education has one fewer child
than a woman with five to eight years of schooling. In Peru (Herz and
Khandker, 1991) an additional year of schooling reduced urban
women's number of offspring by roughly 0.26 (6.7 percent of the
country's mean fertility rate of 3.9). In Thailand (Schultz, 1991)
an additional year of schooling reduced fertility by 7 to 9 percent.
(10) Of course family planning is also useful in promoting
women's and children's health and preventing primitive
abortion with its high risks of morbidity and mortality.
(11) The cost of integrated antenatal and delivery care for
maternal mortality per discounted healthy life year gained is $150
(Jamison and Mosley, 1990).
(12) This assumption overstates the cost of secondary education
Pakistan and understates the cost in some other parts of the world,
particularly where foreigners are hired to teach secondary school. For
Pakistan, we have rough estimates and hence we use $ 30 as the recurrent
cost of one year of secondary school.
Lawrence H. Summers is Vice President and Chief Economist at the
World Bank, Washington, D.C., U.S.A.
Table 1
Selected Statistics on Women's Role
GNP Fem. Fem. as
per % of % of
Capita Total Population
Regions 1989 Population Age 0-4
Low-income 330 49.0% 48.5%
W/o China and
India 300 50.0% 49.2%
Low-and-middle
Income 800 49.2% 48.7%
High Income 1730 51.0% 48.7%
Low Income Countries
Asia
Bangladesh 180 48.5% 48.5%
China 350 48.5% 48.2%
India 340 48.2% 48.5%
Indonesia 500 50.2% 49.2%
LaoPDR 180 49.7% 49.5%
Nepal 180 48.7% 48.5%
Pakistan 370 47.6% 48.7%
Sri Lanka 430 49.5% 49.0%
Latin America
Haiti 360 51.0% 49.5%
SS Africa
Benin 380 51.0% 50.0%
Burkina Faso 320 50.5% 50.0%
Central Africa
Rep. 390 51.5% 50.0%
Chad 190 50.7% 50.0%
Ethiopia 120 50.2% 50.0%
Ghana 390 50.5% 49.7%
Kenya 360 50.0% 49.5%
Lesotho 470 51.9% 50.5%
Madagscar 230 50.5% 49.7%
Malawi 180 51.0% 49.5%
Mali 270 51.7% 50.0%
Mozambique 80 50.7% 50.0%
Niger 290 50.5% 50.0%
Nigeria 250 50.5% 49.7%
Sierra Leone 220 51.0% 50.0%
Somalia 170 52.4% 50.0%
Tanzania 130 ... ...
Togo 390 50.7% 49.7%
Ugenda 250 50.5% 49.7%
Zaire 260 50.7% 49.7%
Zambia 390 50.7% 49.5%
Life Expectancy
Ratio Maternal
Regions F F/M Mortality
Low-income 63 1.03
W/o China and
India 56 1.04
Low-and-middle
Income 65 1.05
High Income 79 1.08
Low Income Countries
Asia
Bangladesh 51 0.98 600
China 71 1.03 44
India 59 1.02 500
Indonesia 63 1.05 800
LaoPDR 51 1.06
Nepal 51 0.98
Pakistan 55 1.00 600
Sri Lanka 73 1.06 90
Latin America
Haiti 57 1.06 340
SS Africa
Benin 53 1.08 1680
Burkina Faso 49 1.07 600
Central Africa
Rep. 52 1.06 600
Chad 48 1.07 700
Ethiopia 49 1.07 2000
Ghana 56 1.06 1070
Kenya 61 1.07 510
Lesotho 58 1.07
Madagscar 52 1.04 300
Malawi 48 1.02 250
Mali 49 1.07
Mozambique 50 1.06 479
Niger 47 1.09 420
Nigeria 54 1.10 1500
Sierra Leone 44 1.10 450
Somalia 49 1.07 1100
Tanzania 51 1.09 370
Togo 55 1.06 476
Ugenda 50 1.06 300
Zaire 54 1.06 800
Zambia 56 1.08 110
Primary Enroll.
Ratio
Regions F F/M
Low-income 95
W/o China and
India 68
Low-and-middle
Income 97
High Income 102
Low Income Countries
Asia
Bangladesh 49 0.64
China 126 0.90
India 83 0.73
Indonesia 117 0.98
LaoPDR 98 0.96
Nepal 57 0.55
Pakistan 28 0.55
Sri Lanka 105 1.00
Latin America
Haiti 80 0.96
SS Africa
Benin 43 0.51
Burkina Faso 24 0.59
Central Africa
Rep. 51 0.62
Chad 29 0.40
Ethiopia 28 0.61
Ghana 66 0.85
Kenya 91 0.93
Lesotho 123 1.21
Madagscar 95 0.98
Malawi 65 0.89
Mali 17 0.59
Mozambique 59 0.78
Niger 21 0.57
Nigeria 48 0.67
Sierra Leone 40 0.59
Somalia 13
Tanzania 66 0.99
Togo 78 0.63
Ugenda 50 0.66
Zaire 65 0.76
Zambia 92 0.90
Secondary Enroll.
Ratio
Regions F F/M
Low-income 29
W/o China and
India 20
Low-and-middle
Income 36
High Income 94
Low Income Countries
Asia
Bangladesh 11 0.46
China 37 0.74
India 29 0.58
Indonesia 43 0.81
LaoPDR 22 0.96
Nepal 17 0.49
Pakistan 11 0.42
Sri Lanka 74 1.17
Latin America
Haiti 17 0.89
SS Africa
Benin 9 0.39
Burkina Faso 4 0.50
Central Africa
Rep. 6 0.35
Chad 2 0.20
Ethiopia 12 0.67
Ghana 30 0.61
Kenya 19 0.70
Lesotho 30 1.67
Madagscar 19 0.83
Malawi 3 0.60
Mali 4 0.44
Mozambique 4 0.57
Niger 4 0.44
Nigeria 7 0.24
Sierra Leone
Somalia
Tanzania 3 0.60
Togo 12 0.33
Ugenda 8 0.50
Zaire 14 0.44
Zambia
Age
Regions Fertility Marriage
Low-income 4
W/o China and
India 5.6
Low-and-middle
Income 4
High Income 1.8
Low Income Countries
Asia
Bangladesh 5.5 20.0
China 2.4 22.4
India 4.3 18.7
Indonesia 3.5 20.0
LaoPDR 5.7 16.7
Nepal 5.9 17.9
Pakistan 6.7 19.8
Sri Lanka 2.7 24.4
Latin America
Haiti 4.7 23.8
SS Africa
Benin 6.5 18.3
Burkina Faso 6.5 17.4
Central Africa
Rep. 5.8
Chad 5.9
Ethiopia 6.5 17.7
Ghana 6.4 19.3
Kenya 7.7 20.4
Lesotho 5.8 20.5
Madagscar 6.4 20.3
Malawi 7.6 17.8
Mali 7.0 18.1
Mozambique 6.3 17.6
Niger 7.0
Nigeria 6.5 18.7
Sierra Leone 6.5
Somalia 6.8 20.1
Tanzania
Togo 6.5
Ugenda 6.9
Zaire 6.1 20.1
Zambia 6.8 19.4
Table 2
Comparison of the Ratio of Female to Male Age-specific
Mortality Rates
Age 0-1 1-4
Pakistan 0.89 1.26
Bangladesh 0.93 1.12
Syria 0.95 1.04
Algeria 0.91 1.02
Malaysia 0.83 1.00
Mali 0.81 0.94
Columbia 0.80 0.91
Philippines 0.74 0.90
Bolivia 0.86 0.90
Malawi 0.85 0.89
Jordan 0.87 0.83
Singapore 0.74 0.80
Mauritius 0.66 0.58
Source: United Nations Demographic Yearbook 1988.
Table 3
Net Social Benefits of One Additional Year Schooling for 1,000 Women
Recurrent Cost of One Year Education for 1000 Women $30,000
Child Mortality
Percentage Reduction in Child (< 5) Mortality 7.5
Total Fertility Rate in Pakistan 6.6
Total Averted Deaths per 1,000 Women 60
Alternative Costs per Averted Deaths $800
Value of Averted Deaths $48,000
Births Averted
Percentage of Reduction in Total Fertility Rate 7.5
Birth Averted 500
Alternative Cost per Birth Averted $65
Value of Averted Births $33,000
Maternal Mortality
Maternal Mortality per 100,000 Births 600
Mother's Death's Averted 3
Alternative Cost per Averted Maternal Deaths $2,500
Value of Averted Maternal Deaths $7,500
Total Discounted Social Benefits (15 Years, 5 Percent) $42,600
Table 4
Responses to the Question 'If Boys and Girls are Equal in the Eyes
of Parents, Why Do Most of the Parents Educate their Sons and not
the Daughters?'
Response No. Percent
1. There are no Financial Gains to
the Parents 716 45.2
2. It is not Customary to Educate Girls 256 16.2
3. There is no Proper Arrangement for
Girls Education 209 13.2
4. Since Boys and Girls are not Equal,
there is no Question of Educating Both 133 8.4
5. Poverty Prevents 'Parents from
Educating Daughters 74 4.7
6. Girls become too Independent after
Getting Educated 58 3.7
7. Ignorant Parents do not Value their
Children's Education 49 3.1
8. Purdah is the Reason for not
Educating Girls 44 2.8
9. Girls have to do Household Work 18 1.1
10. Girls are not Intellectually Capable
of Getting an Education 16 1.0
11. Education does not Help Girls in
their Future Life 12 .8
1,585 100.0
Source Nasra M. Shah Pakistani Women: A Socioeconomic and Demographic
Profile. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad 1986.
Table 5
Reasons Why the Girls Thought they were not in School
Reason No. Percent
1. There is no School for Girls 85 33.0
2. The Relatives are Against My Education 57 22.1
3. Poverty is the Reason for not Educating Me 47 18.2
4. I am not Good Enough for Study 26 10.1
5. They do not Send Me to School because
of Work at Home 22 8.4
6. There is no Teacher in School 12 4.7
7. The Teacher does not Treat Me Well 9 3.5
258 100.0
Source: Nasra M. Shah Pakistani Women: A Jocioeconomic and Demographic
Profile. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad 1986.
Table 6 Proportion of Respondents Attending School
School in-Village School Nearby
Age Cohort M F M F
10-14 93.1 97.8 71.8 66.1
20-24 100.0 * -- ** 67.2 43.2
30-44 43.8 -- ** 52.2 32.3
Source: Prepared from "The Gender Gap in Cognitive Skills in a Poor
Rural Economy" by Harold Alderman, Jere R. Behrman, David R. Ross,
and Richard Sabot.
* 12 respondents.
** All 7 respondents attended school.
*** Both respondents attended school.
Table 7
Cost of Raising Female Enrollment Sufficiently to:
A
Equalize
Female/Male Enrollment
Number Students Cost
(Millions) (Millions)
Primary
Low Income 25 938
Low Income
(w/o India, China) 6 230
Pakistan 1.8 36
Secondary
Low Income 21 1,201
(w/o India, China) 5 271
Pakistan 0.9 28
B
Raise Female Enrollment
to Level in High Income
Ratios Countries
Number Students Cost
(Millions) (Millions)
Primary
Low Income 9 328
Low Income
(w/o India, China) 14 560
Pakistan 5.8 115
Secondary
Low Income 98 5,329
(w/o India, China) 3.8 2,203
Pakistan 5.2 157
Table 8
Cross-country Regression Results for LDCs (N = 45)--Determinants of
TFR, IMR and Female Secondary Enrollment, 1987
Dependent Variables:
TFR IMR FEMSEC
Constant 7.09 125.417 -0.666
(9.83) *** (6.508)*** (-0.182)
Female Secondary -0.389 -5.967 1.786
Gross Enrol. Rate, 1965 (-3.592) *** (-2.414) ** (1.999) **
Female Secondary 0.016 0.139 -0.00607
Gross Enrol. Rate^2 (3.526) *** (1.293) (-0.155)
Female Secondary -0.0002 -0.00129 -0.0003
Gross Enrol. Rate^3 (-3.937) *** (-0.940) (-0.567)
Male Secondary 0.0837 -0.565 -0.739
Gross Enrol. Rate 1965 (0.720) (-0.235) (-0.891)
Male Secondary -0.006 0.0588 0.031
Gross Enrol. Rate^2 (-0.720) (0.630) (0.891)
Male Secondary 0.0001 -0.00074 -0.00027
Gross Enrol. Rate^3 (2.078) ** (-0.692) (-0.673)
% Population w/ -0.442
Access to Water (-1.866) *
Population per 0.00 0.00082
Physician (0.161) (1.924) *
Urban Population as 0.014 0.539 0.296
% of Total Pop. (1.120) (2.564) ** (2.791) ***
Gross National Income -0.00069 -0.012 0.0024
per Capita, 1987 (-2.428) ** (-2.407) ** (1.120)
Expend. on Education 1.769
as % of GNP, 1985 (2.976) ***
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.66 0.74 0.88
Source: K. Subbarao and L. Raney "Social Gains from Female Education,
PHRWD, forthcoming.
* Significant at the 10% level.
** Significant at the 5% level.
*** Significant at the 1 % level.
(standard errors corrected for heteroskedasticity).
Table 9
The Long Run Impact of Improved Female Education *
Births per Year, 1987 (Millions)
Actual Simulated Averted
45 Low and Middle 62.3 53.2 9.1
Income Countries (b) 15%
16 Low Income 41.7 34.3 7.4
Countries (c) 18%
Pakistan 4.1 2.9 1.2
30%
Deaths per Year, 1987 (Millions)
Actual Simulated Averted
45 Low and Middle 4.9 1.9 3.0
Income Countries (b) 61%
16 Low Income 3.8 1.5 2.3
Countries (c) 61%
Pakistan 0.4 0.1 0.3
75%
Source: K. Subbarao and L. Raney, "Social Gains from Female Education"
PHRWD, Forthcoming.
(a) Simulation depicts the scenerio if the female gross secondary
enrollment rate in 1965 were raised to 30 percent.
(b) These 45 countries represent 55 percent of the world population,
and 71 percent of the LDC population, excluding China.
(c) These 16 countries represent 35 percent of the world population,
and 70 percent of the low-income LDC population excluding China.