Wheat price policies in Pakistan: should there be a subsidy? *.
Ender, Gary ; Wasay, Abdul ; Mahmood, Akhtar 等
1. INTRODUCTION
In the 1980s, Pakistan's wheat policies taxed its producers
and subsidised its consumers. Moreover, the post-rationing, open-ended
system of releases has increased the burden on the government budget.
The Government now faces severe shortages of resources at a time when
human capital and physical infrastructure must be developed and
maintained. This paper reviews wheat price policies in Pakistan and,
patterns of wheat consumption over time, and makes recommendations for
policy changes.
Wheat is the dominant rabi, or winter, crop. However, about half
the wheat is grown after cotton. Most of this wheat is planted late and
yields substantially less than it could if planted earlier because the
producer price and profitability of wheat are depressed by government
policies. While cotton prices are also depressed by the Government,
cotton, and in particular a fourth picking, remains highly profitable,
even with new, earlier varieties. CIMMYT studies have shown that
wheat-cotton farmers are rational in planting wheat late, given the
prices they receive. (1) The average wheat yield has risen since the
Green Revolution, due to the adoption of HYVs. However, the yields of
HYVs have not risen.
After they harvest their wheat, farmers can sell it to the
Government (namely to the Pakistan Agricultural Storage and Services
Corporation (PASSCO) or the provincial food departments) at the
procurement price, or to a private trader at the market price. Thus two
prices prevail in the market at any given time. Wheat moves through both
channels primarily because of differences in quality. (In practice
farmers sell almost all marketed wheat to traders, and traders then sell
about half the marketed wheat to the Government.) Both the Federal and
Provincial Governments have at times resorted to movement restrictions
that tend to bottle up surpluses in certain districts. Clearly this
contributes to farmers' receiving lower prices in many areas.
Wheat production in Pakistan has trended upward. Despite increases
in yield and production, however, Pakistan has not achieved
self-sufficiency in wheat. Generally, wheat imported in years in which
there was less than 1 million tons imported was for the Afghan refugees,
not for Pakistan. Nevertheless, in five of the last ten and five of the
last seven years, Pakistan has imported significant amounts of wheat for
its own account.
Wheat is Pakistan's staple food, but urban consumers generally
do not purchase it as wheat. They buy flour or in many cases freshly
baked roti. (2) Wheat moves from traders to millers, and the ground
wheat eventually moves to consumers. Wheat also moves through the
government channel to reach consumers in the form of flour. Until 1987,
the Government maintained a ration system that distributed wheat to
millers for grinding at a fixed charge and distributed flour to
privately-owned, licensed ration shops. Ration card holders could
purchase flour at subsidised prices at ration shops. The Government
abolished this system because it was not fulfilling its objective of
helping low-income consumers.
While there are no longer ration shops, the Government maintains a
substantial presence in wheat marketing. Theoretically, it stands
prepared to sell any amount of wheat to anyone at the fixed release
price.3 In practice, there have been some informal restrictions on the
amounts released, keyed to numbers of hours of milling operation per
day. The current system does not attempt to target any recipient group.
Rather, its role is holding down and stabilising the price of wheat.
Because of the relationships between procurement and release
prices, a major role of the Government in wheat marketing has been
storage. Table 1 shows that the release price was sometimes below the
procurement price, and never higher by the Rs 400-600 that would fully
cover marketing costs. Thus the private sector has not had the incentive
to store wheat for most of the marketing year, since it could not earn a
sufficient return on its investment in storage facilities. Rather,
millers have come to depend on the Government to supply a substantial
part of their requirement of wheat during the latter part of the year.
This can be seen from seasonal release data in Table 2.
The inadequate gap between release and procurement prices has
resulted in a subsidy. The burden to the Government of this subsidy on
domestic wheat has been reduced, however, by the depressed producer
price. That is, if the Government had to procure domestic wheat at a
price comparable to world wheat prices, the subsidy would have been
more. While producers have borne part of the subsidy burden on domestic
wheat, the burden of importing wheat, when necessary, and releasing it
at the subsidised price falls entirely on the government budget. When
world prices rise quickly and domestic prices have been raised slowly,
the subsidy on imports can be quite large.
The amounts of recent wheat subsidies are shown in Table 3. Data
relating to the federal subsidy are from federal budget documents. The
provincial subsidies have been taken from annual Economic Surveys.
Initially the subsidy arising out of imports was borne by the federal
government, while the subsidies paid on domestic operations were carried
by provincial budgets. Eventually, however, because of block grants from
the Federal Government to the Provinces, the entire cost of wheat
operations was shouldered by the federal government.
These amounts are quite substantial in comparison to
Pakistan's economy and government expenditures. The largest
subsidy, in 1988-89, is about 1 percent of GDP and about 6 percent of
total government revenue (or about 13 percent of the difference between
total revenue and total expenditures). Pakistan is currently under a
combination World Bank structural adjustment loan and IMF standby
arrangement, under which various fiscal targets, including reduction of
the fiscal deficit, have been set.
In the latter half of the 1980s, the Government has been removing
subsidies on fertilizer. In the last two years (1989-90 and 1990-91),
the Government has recognised the "squeeze" this put on
farmers, and it has also significantly raised the procurement price of
wheat. However, it remains below the adjusted world price. The increases
in procurement price have made it harder for the Government to increase
the gap between the release and procurement prices, for to do so, the
release price would have to rise even faster than the procurement price.
Thus the ratio rose to its historical high of 1.08, but no further. The
Government has also improved cost recovery in its marketing operations
by charging more for the bags in which it distributes wheat.
Nevertheless, the basic price structure has not changed with the
abolition of rationing.
Two aspects of the post-rationing system (i.e., since 1987) are
disturbing. One is the higher levels of releases, shown in Table 4,
which result in high subsidy volumes. To achieve these releases, the
Government seeks to procure large amounts and supplements these with
imports. Although the new price regime would logically lead to lower
procurement, the Government has apparently not reduced its targets.
Second, while the domestic per unit subsidy has been gradually reduced,
the previous Government was willing to undertake very expensive,
subsidised imports. Under the new government, also, imports seem likely
to be substantial.
2. RESULTS OF HOUSEHOLD INCOME AND EXPENDITURE SURVEYS
Given these government policies, what has been the pattern of
change of per capita income, the real price of wheat flour, and wheat
consumption since the early 1970s? According to official Household
Income and Expenditure Surveys (HIES), per capital consumption of wheat
has declined in all groups, despite increases in per capita income and
decreases in the real price of wheat. Thus, according to time-series
evidence, wheat may have become an inferior good. Consumption of other
valued foods like meat, milk, and ghee has increased; calorie
consumption has not changed significantly. This is true for the average
Pakistani and for the lowest income quartile as well.
Changes in Per Capita Real Income
Pakistan's real GNP expanded by 5 percent or more every year
but four in the 1970s and 1980s. With population growing at about 3.1
percent, per capita real income has also increased significantly during
this period. At these rates of growth, per capita real income over the
18-years period (1968-69--1986-87) showed a cumulative increase of over
60 percent.
Changes in the Real Price of Flour
In the 1970s and 1980s, the nominal price of wheat flour increased
less rapidly than the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and the CPI for food.
During 1969-70 1971-72, an index of the real price of flour (deflated by
the CPI) had the value .97; it dropped to .91 during 1984-85--1986-87.
Changes in Consumption
The most comprehensive, ongoing measurement of expenditures in
Pakistan is the Household Income and Expenditure Survey (HIES), which is
conducted by the Federal Bureau of Statistics. The survey gathers many
types of information, including quantities of food consumed and the
expenditures made on food items, among other goods and services. The
survey has not been conducted every year, but results are available for
1968-69, 1%9-70, 1970-71, 1971-72, 1979, 1984-85, 1985-86, and 1986-87.
An analysis of the quality of these surveys is given in the Appendix.
Survey Results (1970s and 1980)
The simplest way to compare the results of the various surveys is
to match them up by income groups. A potential problem with this
approach is that, because of inflation, the rupee bounds of the income
groups changed from the 1970s to the 1980s. That is, individuals'
incomes changed, and the HIES income groups were adjusted in an attempt
to give a comparable representation of expenditure patterns. In this
situation, one can graph wheat consumption by income level and compare
the results of the different surveys. If one observes no crossing of
graphs or other anomalies, one may conclude that the results, as
compared, are a reasonable reflection of the actual trend of
consumption. This is the case for wheat flour consumption in Pakistan in
the 1970s and 1980s.
A more sophisticated way to look at the pattern of wheat and flour
consumption is by constructing income quartiles. This ensures that
consumers in the same part of the income spectrum are being compared.
HIES publications provide the data necessary to construct quartiles;
limited interpolation was necessary, as the cumulative incomes of these
groupings did not always come out equal to exactly 25 percent, 50
percent, 75 percent and 100 percent.
Such quartile analysis reveals a pattern of declining wheat
consumption over time (see Table 5). When combined with increasing real
per capita income and a decreasing real price, this pattern is most
consistent with a zero or negative income elasticity. [Goldman (1989),
p. 24] says that a negative income elasticity for wheat is
"plausible". Even if there is some inaccuracy in the survey
results, the consistent decline in consumption shown by the results
should be interpreted to mean at least that there was not the increase
in consumption that one would normally expect with an increase in income
and a decrease in price.
With a substantial increase in income and a small decline in the
price of flour, consumers in the 1980s were able to devote a much
smaller part of their total expenditures to wheat (see Table 6).
Consumers in the first three quartiles reduced significantly the share
of their expenditures that went to wheat, while the highest
quartile's consumers spent the same share to purchase less wheat,
presumably of a higher quality. Finally, the increase in income also led
to declines in the share of food in all expenditures. In the 1980s, food
was a smaller share of expenditures for all quartiles, and less than 50
percent for the upper two quartiles.
These data are consistent with the notion that, over time,
Pakistani consumers have chosen to eat less wheat and more of other
foods. That is, there was no general decline in nutrition. Further
evidence includes their maintenance of calorie intake and increases in
the consumption of other foods. Moreover, it is normal in countries
where a high percentage of calories come from one staple food for staple
consumption to eventually decline.
One can examine the total calorie intakes of all income groups
'and the lowest income groups over time, as calculated from the
HIESs. (5) Because recent surveys have added some foods to those
counted, the results are calculated both on an as-reported basis and
with the new foods omitted. One observes little change in the average
total calorie intake (see Table 7). Calorie intake in the low-income
group also varies little, but fluctuates with wheat production: 1971-72
and 1984-85 were years of low output.
Milk, rice, ghee and oil, pulses, beef, and citrus are the most
important calorie sources in the Pakistani diet besides wheat and sugar
products. Calorie intake for all income groups and for the lowest income
group increases or does not decrease over time for all of these foods.
The lack of response of wheat intake in Pakistan to increases in
income is not unusual. Schiff and Valdes (1990) cite studies which have
also found this phenomenon, even at very low income levels. They mention
the desire for diversity in the diet as well as for freshness, taste,
and convenience as factors that explain the lack of increase in the
quantity consumed.
Recent Survey Results
The analysis above can be broadened and further verified with the
addition of the results of the 1987-88 HIES. This is a particularly
interesting exercise because of the changes in the wheat marketing
system that took place in 1987.
The Government operated a ration system for wheat until April,
1987. When the Government abolished the ration system, it took care to
have a very large stock of wheat on hand. This would ensure that the end
of rationing did not turn into a political calamity. Indeed, the
Government then released much more wheat than it ever had (see Table 4).
The nominal price of flour actually fell in 1987-88, the only year this
happened in all of the 1970s and 1980s. (6)
The fall in the nominal price and the corresponding larger decline
in the real price induced some lower-income consumers to increase their
per capita consumption of wheat flour modestly in 1987-88. The average
increase in the quantity of flour consumed by these groups was about 3
percent, from 11.4 to 11.8 kilograms per person per month. Consumption
by income groups other than the lowest three was indistinguishable from
that in 1986-87. Other data in the HIES revel that the three lowest
income groups in 1987-88 constituted about 4 percent of the total
population.
One can also compare consumption in 1987-88 to the average for the
other surveys of the 1980s. (When comparing 1987-88 to the average of
the other three surveys in the 1980s, one should bear in mind that in
1984-85, wheat consumption among the poor declined substantially due to
low wheat production). Here it is apparent that the tendency for wheat
consumption to decline among the higher-income groups was continuing.
The lower nominal price in 1987-88 was able to induce additional
consumption only among the very poor, and then only very slightly.
3. NET EFFECT OF POLICIES
The Government of Pakistan has been providing a subsidy on the sale
of wheat. Through this subsidy, the Government seems to have given all
consumers who purchase wheat, which is the large majority, an income
transfer in the form of cheaper wheat. Consumers benefit from the low
release price through its dampening effect on the level of wholesale
prices.
Millers may also benefit from low and constant release prices.
During a given year, the retail price of wheat flour has generally moved
along with the wholesale wheat price, while the release price remains
constant throughout the year. Millers' margins at the end of the
year are higher than at the beginning; at that time they are buying
mostly from the Government, at the release price, and they are capturing
some of the subsidy. The millers' ability to jointly set flour
prices helps them capture some of the subsidy at this time. On the other
hand, there has been excess capacity and geographical maldistribution in
the industry since the rationing period, so the overall return on
investment may not be abnormally high.
Over the past twenty years, real prices to consumers have declined,
whether due to the subsidy or not, and individuals have not increased
their consumption. Even when the nominal price of wheat fell, in
1987-88, the poor who increased their consumption represented only about
4 percent of the population; their increase in consumption was only
about 3 percent. Consumption by better-off groups continued to decline.
Price stabilisation was also a government objective, but presumably this
could have been accomplished without depressing the price.
Nutrition may have improved marginally, but average calorie
consumption did not change substantially. Nor has severe malnutrition been eliminated. The National Nutrition Survey (1985-87) found that:
Protein-energy malnutrition and anaemia continues as a serious,
widespread problem throughout the country.... According to WHO
criteria of weight-for-age,... 10 percent [of young children] are
severely [malnourished]. (7)
Even if severe malnutrition were half this much, it would still be
disturbing.
During the 1970s and early 1980s, both the commercial poultry
industry and the volume of wheat handled by the Government grew
steadily. Cheap wheat became an economical source of calories for the
poultry industry. Along with the Government's large-scale wheat
marketing operations came the likelihood of increased losses to insects
and shrinkage during storage, as well as spillage and spoilage. Finally,
because wheat in Pakistan has been cheaper than in neighbouring
countries, unrecorded exports were also stimulated.
Thus, besides the direct fiscal cost of the wheat subsidy, there
was considerable waste, use of wheat for feed, and smuggling to other
countries; per capita consumption of wheat as food did not increase.
Expenditures on health, education, and other social programmes were
lower than they might have been. (8) More foreign exchange was also
expended on wheat imports.
The interaction of the subsidy and wheat demand can be thought of
as follows. Per capita consumption of wheat (as food) can be taken as
constant, although the case can be made that it has declined. Over time,
the per capita demand curve for food use has shifted back. At the same
time there has been a decreasing real price, which is the result of the
subsidy and other factor. The declining price stimulates demand for
other "uses", namely feed, smuggling, and additional losses.
Thus, total per capita use (disappearance) continues to increase.
The Government has recently made further progress in enlarging the
gap between the release and procurement prices: In April, 1991, it
announced a second increase (for 1991-92) in the procurement price. More
importantly, it effected the largest single increase in the release
price-over 19 percent. This raised the gap between the two prices to
about 11 percent, and raised the Government's recovery of its
marketing costs to about 90 percent. However, the Government is not yet
fully committed to removing the wheat subsidy. Moreover, as long as the
domestic price remains below the world price, imports, when they are
necessary, will remain subsidised.
The wheat subsidy remains, despite progress in reducing poverty.
According to the World Development Report [World Bank (1990), p. 40],
"Even countries that are often thought to have followed
inegalitarian paths of development, such as Brazil and Pakistan, have
succeeded in reducing the headcount index", a simple measure of the
number of persons in poverty. In addition, the average income
shortfall--the amount needed to get out of poverty--declined
substantially in Pakistan over the past 20 years.
A general thrust of the 1990 Development Report is that the poor
need health and skills, and the opportunity to use the skills, which
generally means labour-intensive growth. That is, governments should
spend scarce resources on health, nutrition, education, roads, etc. The
report states that Pakistan has among the lowest expenditures on health
and education as a percent of GNP in the world.
These facts lead us to paint a new picture of the existing
situation, which we hope will be considered by policy-makers. In this
view, poverty is less, although it is concentrated in some areas; there
is still malnutrition. Wheat consumption is not increasing. Appropriate
government measures, we feel, would be a decrease in direct intervention
in the economy and a return to its major role of providing
infrastructure and building human capital. A general wheat subsidy does
not belong in this scheme, but targeted programmes do.
4. RECOMMENDATIONS
The Government should eliminate the wheat subsidy. The
"domestic" subsidy can be eliminated immediately by raising
the release price. The subsidy on imported wheat should be eliminated as
soon as possible, especially when it is possible to take advantage of
lower international prices of wheat. When the subsidy has been removed,
the Government may wish to reconsider its massive involvement in wheat
marketing. Specifically, the Government should bring procurement prices
up to the world level, at least on a long-run average basis. Then it
would be possible to eliminate most of the Government's role in
storage.
We have shown that there is little need to keep subsidising wheat
flour to the general economy. Timmer has argued that subsidising an
inferior good is an efficient way to help the poor. However, this line
of reasoning usually relies on the use of a secondary staple to achieve
targeting. In this case the primary staple may have become inferior (so
there is no targeting), and the volume to be subsidised is too large
under the budgetary circumstances.
How do we help the malnourished? The Government should target
food-for-work or other programmes to specific groups. This might be done
through the zakat system. The zakat system achieves targeting by having
a social stigma attached to it: only the truly poor receive zakat.
Self-targeting programmes like food-for-work will have greater impacts
on the target groups and less leakage than the existing general subsidy
mechanism. Nutrition education would also help with preventable problems
of food choices and intra-family distribution.
If the Government follows these recommendations, there will be
significant impact on Pakistan's flour millers. No longer will the
Government be storing wheat for them at less than full cost. A
concomitant of this system has been a lack of credit in Pakistan for
agricultural marketing operations. We suggest that, since the Government
is also effecting a transition to commercialised banking, it should
remove all obstacles to the provision of credit to flour millers and
other agribusinesses.
Appendix
QUALITY OF HOUSEHOLD INCOME AND EXPENDITURE SURVEYS
Various scholars, including Ahmad et al., Alderman, and Goldman
have analysed and/or commented on the data in these surveys. [Ahmad and
Ludlow (1988), p. 2] point out that the surveys in the late 1960s and
early 1970s had small sample sizes. This is particularly true for two of
the twelve income groups, the highest and lowest; other groups,
including the second and third lowest, had more reasonable sample sizes.
Small sample sizes in some "cells" make detailed cross-section
analysis hazardous. However, these surveys are still recognised as valid
at the national level and for averages of all income groups.
According to the Director-General of FBS, Mr S. M. Ishaque, all the
HIES surveys have sample frames, and raising factors were used in all
published results, except in 1979. The results of this survey should be
used with caution. In general, the rural frame varies little. The urban
frame was updated in the 1970s, but the raising factors were not applied
to the raw data for 1979. A new frame completed in 1983 has been applied
to the 1980s data.
[Goldman (1989), p. 20] claims the surveys of the early 1970s
"form a weak statistical base", and may not be comparable to
later ones; he calls the 1979 survey "particularly strong".
The surveys of 1980s include food consumed outside the home, but it
is not known to the authors whether the early surveys did or not. Thus a
comparison of the early and recent surveys might be biased toward
showing an increase in the consumption of some food items.
One check that can easily be performed on these survey data is to
calculate the prices implied by the quantity and expenditure data.
Results of such calculations show that the implied price of wheat
purchased by lower-income consumers tended to be lower than that
purchased by those with high incomes, and the implied prices increase
more or less monotonically. This is consistent with expectations, since
higher-income consumers can purchase higher-quality flour, and flour
products in more convenient forms.
From these comments and analysis, we derive the following
conclusions:
--With the exception of 1979, the HIES results are valid at the
national level;
--Comparisons of the results of the early surveys for the lowest
income group with those from the 1980s should be treated with caution;
and
--The existing surveys are the best information we have on which to
base policy.
This paper cites HIESs from the late 1960s/early 1970s, 1979, and
the 1980s, depending to little on the 1979 data. Conclusions regarding
the utility of a subsidy in increasing the consumption of flour by
low-income consumers depend on the quality of the consumption data for
this group. The quality of these data are diminished by the small sample
size in the early surveys in the survey's very lowest income group.
However, the sample size problem does not seem so serious that a rising
trend in consumption would be reflected in the survey results as a
failing trend. Moreover, flour and baked products consumed outside the
home are included in the surveys of the 1980s and may not be in the
earlier period, so the comparison of the two sets of surveys may
overstate the (relative) level of consumption in the recent period.
Authors' Note: Space limitations required the elimination of
many tables and figures; the complete version of this paper is available
from the authors.
REFERENCES
Ahmed, Ehtisham, and Stephen Ludlow (1988) On Changes in Inequality
in Pakistan: 1979-84. London: London School of Economics.
Akhtar, M. Ramzan, Derek Byerlee, Abdul Oayyum, Abdul Majid and
Peter R. Hobbs (1986) Wheat in the Cotton-Wheat Farming Systems of the
Punjab: Implications for Research and Extension. Islamabad: Pakistan
Agricultural Research Council. (PARC/CIMMYT Paper No. 86--8.)
Goldman, Richard H. (1989) Demand Management of Pakistan's
Food System, 1960-1986. Paper produced for the Agricultural Policy Analysis Project, Phase II. Harvard Institute for International
Development.
Pakistan, National Institute of Health, Nutrition Division (1988)
National Nutrition Survey, 1985-87, Report.
Sahibzada, Shamim A., and Mir Annice Mahmood (1989) Education in
Selected Islamic Countries, A Comparative Analysis. The Pakistan
Development Review 28:4 803-27.
Schiff, Maurice, and Alberto Valdes (1990) The Link between Poverty
and Malnutrition: A Household Theoretic Approach. The World Bank;
Country Economics Department. (PRE Working Paper WPS 536.)
World Bank (1990) Poverty. World Development Report. Oxford
University Press.
* Owing to unavoidable circumstances, the discussant's
comments on this paper have not been received.
(1) [Akhtar et al.. (1986), p. 24.]
(2) Roti is a generic term for several kinds of unleavened breads,
including naan and chappati, which are baked while stuck to the sides of
a brick oven.
(3) There is a minimum purchase of ten tons.
(4) Upper income consumers, who already had a much lower share, may
have purchased higher quality foods and diversified sufficiently that
their share did not decrease.
(5) Lack of time prevented analysis of all surveys and construction
of low-income quartiles. The years chosen are representative.
(6) Economic Survey, 1989-90.
(7) Pakistan, National Institute of Health, Nutrition Division,
1988, National Nutrition Survey, 1985-87, pp. vi, vii.
(8) Sahibzada and Mahmood (1989) show that literacy in Pakistan and
government expenditures on education are quite low by the standard of
other comparable, Islamic countries.
Gary Ender is Senior Agricultural Economist, Abt Associates Inc. in
USAID's Agricultural Policy analysis Project; Abdul Wasay and
Akhtar Mahmood are Project Management Specialists (Policy) in the Office
of Agriculture and Rural Development, USAID/Islamabad.
Table 1
Pakistan: Official Wheat Prices
Crop Procurement Release Difference Ratio
Year Price (1) Price (2) (2-1) (2/1)
Rupees per Metric Ton
1984-85 1,750 1,703 (47.10) 0.97
1985-86 2,000 1,703 (297.10) 0.85
1986-87 2,000 2,000 0.00 1.00
1987-88 2,063 2,100 37.50 1.02
1988-89 2,125 2,300 175.00 1.08
1989-90 * 2,400 2,600 200.00 1.08
Source: Government of Pakistan.
* Release price was initially announced as Rs 2,500.
Table 2
Pakistan: Monthly Releases of Wheat
1987-88 1988-89 1989-90
Thousand Metric Tons
May 26223 198
June 308 318 168
July 296 328 259
August 278 424 362
September 325 440 367
October 384 547 483
November 453 562 486
December 578 609 530
January 667 665 596
February 566 590 513
March 640 585 522
April 449 439 461
Source: Government of Pakistan, Ministry of Food, Agriculture,
and Cooperatives.
Table 3
Pakistan: Wheat Subsidies
Fiscal Year Federal Provincial Total
Rs Million
1986-87 150 2,625 2,775
1987-88 368 3,549 3,917
1988-89 4,947 2,956 7,903
1989-90 4,492 2,667 7,159
Source: Government of Pakistan.
Table 4
Pakistan: Annual Releases of Wheat
Thousand Metric Tons
1984-85 3,695
1985-86 3,543
1986-87 3,793
1987-88 5,202
1988-89 5,717
1989-90 * 5,386
Source: Economic Survey, 1989-90.
* Estimate
Table 5
Pakistan: Per Capita Consumption of Wheat and Flour, 1970s and 1980s
Income Quartiles
All Lowest Second Third Highest
Kilograms/Person/Month
1968-69-1971-72 (A) 11.60 11.72 11.52 11.64 11.63
1979 (B) 11.20 11.39 11.15 11.16 11.05
1984-85-1986-87 (C) 10.79 11.03 10.95 10.70 10.27
Percentage Change,
(A) to (C) -7.0% -5.9% -5.0% -8.1% -11.7%
Source: Calculated from Household Income and Expenditure Surveys.
Table 6
Pakistan: Share of Wheat in All Expenditures, 1970s and 1980
Income Quartiles
All Lowest Second Third Highest
1968-69-1971-72 15% 20% 16% 14% 6%
1979 9% 14% 10% 10% 5%
1984-85-1986-87 9% 12% 9% 7% 5%
Source: Calculated from Household Income and Expenditure Surveys.
Table 7
Pakistan: Total Calorie Intake, 1970s and 1980s
All Income Groups Lowest Income Group
As Reported Adjusted As Reported Adjusted
Calories/Person/Day
1970-71 2061 2061 2060 2060
1971-72 2009 2009 1839 1839
1979 2172 2135 2044 2021
1984-85 2155 2104 1928 1899
1986-87 2182 2104 2122 2068
Source: Calculated from Household Income and Expenditure Surveys.
Note: The early surveys doe not include yoghurt, fruits, tomatoes,
and other vegetables. In the columns labeled "Adjusted", these
calories are subtracted from the totals in the later surveys to
make the totals comparable.