Equity and efficiency in health status and health services utilization: a household perspective *.
Sirageldin, Ismail ; Diop, Francois
I. INTRODUCTION TO THE ISSUES
The objective of this paper could be phrased as follows: What are
the health consequences of changes in public fiscal and income policies?
This is an important question, especially in times where programmes of
macroeconomic structural adjustments are being implemented in many
developing countries. The health consequences of these policies continue
to be debated. Some argue that the main victims are mainly the poor and
the vulnerable [cf. Cornia et al. (1987) and (1988)]. Others maintain
that the longer term benefits will more than compensate for short-term
losses and that the real test is to compare with the consequences of not
making the adjustments. The conceptual and empirical foundation of the
debate seems to be less than satisfactory, however.
It is our view that to understand the health consequences of such
policies a careful examination of three issues are required: (a) the
existing pattern of disease; (b) the initial distributional structure
(equity pattern) of public policies; and (c) the behavioural response of
households in allocating resources towards health-promoting activities
given (a) and (b).
Our approach is necessarily context specific. It is in line with
Streeten's (1988) conclusion that "... the most important
general lesson that emerged was that there are no general lessons, and
that each case has to be treated separately and on its merits". Our
purpose is to provide an overall general framework that serves as a
guide to examine specific cases. For more detailed theoretical analysis,
see Diop (1990), and for an empirical application, see Diop and
Sirageldin (1990).
The Evolution of the Epidemiological Transition
Historical epidemiological transitions were mainly controlled by
changes of age structure in the population which were conditioned by the
environmental setting, including rural-urban differences, and by the
rate and type of social and economic development. The relative
importance of types of diseases and its causes followed more or less a
time sequence closely associated with the phases of the demographic
transition, where the rate of population growth and its age structure
were largely determined by the magnitude and rapidity of the mortality
declines and by the delay in responsiveness of birth rates [cf. Gray
(1988)].
As the demographic transition takes place with a large and
sustained decline in fertility, in association with changes in
socio-economic circumstances, and with wide adoption of new habits,
e.g., smoking, consumption of high fat diets, stress and sedentary life
styles, a post-epidemiological transition of disease takes hold, in
which society moves towards an age of degenerative and man-made disease.
As illustrated in Table 1, the absolute level and the relative
importance of a new set of disease, labelled as the disease of the
affluent, such as circulatory, cancers, vascular of CNS and mental
disorder increases [cf. Omran (1971, 1982); Jamison and Mosley (1990),
Tables 1.4, 1.5, and references cited therein]. This change in the
pattern of disease, perceived as sequential in nature, provided the
health profession with a blueprint for health planning, identifying
priorities and allocating resources over time which could be mobilized
to deal with major health problems in succession. The international
public health community, during the past two decades, for example, has
focused its attention primarily on the communicable childhood diseases
in less developed countries [cf. Jamison and Mosley (1990), p. 1]; also
Sirageldin et al. (1989), is an illustrative example of such emphasis.
Emerging New Patterns
The present experience of developing countries, however, has seemed
to produce more complex and diverse patterns than that anticipated by
the stylistic epidemiological transition. The complexity of this
emerging pattern is a reflection of (a) diversity in the causes of
diseases, (b) its associated risk factors, and (c) the style and
sustainability of the public and private intervention strategies.
Furthermore, the disease pattern is confounded by its interaction with
significant changes in population dynamics [cf. Sirageldin and Mosley
(1988)]. This emerging pattern has four main characteristics:
(a) Both pre- and post-epidemiological types of disease coexist. As
[Foege and Henderson (1986), p. 321], quoted in [Jamison and Mosley
(1990), p. 14] have observed, developing countries "... will not
have the luxury of dealing with two kinds of problems sequentially. For
the remainder of this century they will be dealing with both
simultaneously;"
(b) Many types of diseases in these new patterns imply different
risk factors and different target groups which accordingly require
separate sets of inputs, expertise, technologies and strategies. Thus, a
non-selective intervention becomes more costly. In addition, financial
constraints and reduced economic policy options, due to the economic
recession of the 1980s and the adoption of "structural
adjustment" policies have resulted in a reduced government budget
for health and other related social sectors. Hence priorities for
disease control and health objectives in general need to be reconsidered
and innovative cost-saving strategies need to be developed. One such
avenue has been through cost recovery schemes to shift away from public
subsidies to health services;
(c) Priorities for disease control strategies are difficult to
develop because of a lack of adequate criterion for ranking. In a
comprehensive review of the types of diseases, related diseases, policy
instruments and the cost-effectiveness (CE) of interventions (based on
discounted healthy life years (DHLY), Jamison and Mosley (1990)
attempted to develop a criteria for disease control priorities. What is
evident from their comprehensive review, aside from a lack of adequate
data, is a remarkable diversity in the range of estimates and
complexities of relating cost to effects within a consistent framework
across diseases and environments of any given intervention process.
Their recommendation for setting national priorities is guarded:
"National health priorities can only evolve from a critical
analysis of the local epidemiological, administrative, economic, and
political context" (p. 35); and
(d) Another important characteristic is the emergence of
significant diversity in health outcomes and within socio-economic
groups, regions and countries. Table 2 illustrates the degree of
variation in infant mortality rates (IMR), low birth weight and maternal
mortality among countries of the Arab region. Although all countries
experienced significant declines in infant mortality, differentials
increased. For example, IMR varied from less than 30 to over 100 in
1988. More details are provided in UNICEF (1989). Within a country,
differentials are equally large [cf. DHS results presented in Studies in
Family Planning Vol. 19 (1987) and Vol. 20 (1988)]. National and
international policy-makers may have to allocate resources not only
according to "efficiency", as implied above, but also stress
on the issue of "equity".
Purpose
It is this last issue of differentials in health service
utilization and health outcomes that is the focus of the present paper.
The purpose is to examine the equity criteria which could guide health
policy-makers to minimize such differentials. Our primary focus is on
the household; how are household decisions for health maintenance
influenced by household status or status of various individuals in the
household, its immediate environment and by elements of public policy?
How are such decisions translated into health outcomes for various
members of the household?
We start introducing the paper by assuming the presence of a
household demand for health services utilization. We then examine the
social and political forces that influence the relative level of such
demand, and attempt to differentiate those related to efficiency and
those implying equity considerations in health production. As will be
apparent from the discussion below, issues of equity and efficiency in
health service utilization are interrelated and this may cause confusing
policy interpretations. Indeed, the question of equity could be
misleading if defined in terms of the household's access to health
services. Thus, the question that arises from this discussion is: As
governments withdraw or change the pattern of their social support and
commitments, how can the support for health care finance be replaced,
and who are the losers?
II. ON THE DETERMINANTS OF THE DEMAND FOR HEALTH SERVICES
UTILIZATION
The Demand for Health Services and the Demand for Health
We start with the basic notion that an individual's health is
limited to the individual's capacity to combat disease. We further
assume that this capacity can be maintained by health-promoting
activities, such as the utilization of health services, and other
health-influencing behaviour. These activities are valued for their
effect on health rather than for themselves. Abstracting for the moment
from intra-household allocative dynamics we assume that the stock of
each household member's health has a value in itself for it
augments her/his family welfare. This assumption will be relaxed later.
Meanwhile, the household demand for health services, and other
behaviours affecting health, are typically derived from the demand for
health. As, with other commodities produced within the family, the level
of child health that the family can attain is constrained by the
financial as well as nonfinancial resources of the family and its
economic environment. This treatment follows a growing tradition in
economics [Cropper (1977); Grossman (1972, 1972a); Muurinen (1982);
Muurinen et al. (1985); DaVanzo and Gertler (1990); Diop (1990); Diop
and Sirageldin (1990) and Diop et al. (1990)].
A household member is assumed to be innately endowed with an
initial stock of health at birth, which is partially determined by
inherited biological characteristics. Given the random distribution of
biological characteristics in a cohort of births, it is assumed that the
level of this initial stock of health bears little on the variability of
health status between socio-economic groups and their changes over time.
The initial stock of health of the individual member in the
household is positively affected by involvement in health-promoting
activities. Simultaneously, due to poor environmental conditions and
exposure to diseases prevalent in their community, the individual's
capacity to combat disease deteriorates.
In the case of children, health-promoting activities in addition to
others, include prenatal, perinatal and post-natal care, immunization,
modern and traditional medical goods and services for curative purposes,
and feeding practices. Typically, a family combines market and/or
nonmarket goods and services with its members' time in these
activities to promote and maintain the health of its children. The
combination of inputs used in this production process will depend not
only on relative prices of health-related goods and services including
family members' time, but also on the information that these
members have regarding the efficacy of these inputs. Knowledge of
health-related technologies is assumed to be acquired cumulatively
through direct experiences with these technologies and/or exposure to
health education programmes. But, most of all, it will take the form of
stocks of habits which result from past behaviours, or traditional
practices transmitted between generations within families or larger
networks (village or ethnic group for instance). Thus, health-promoting
activities may not only respond to current price configurations and
family income, but expectations regarding the quality of health-related
inputs based on outcomes of past behaviours, may be locked into patterns
of health-promoting activities, for some period of time, among specific
socio-economic groups.
In summary, the change of a child, a mother or other household
member's health status, over some period of time, can be viewed as
the outcome of two opposite effects:
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Inequalities in Health Services Utilization Depends on the Supply
of Other Health-related Goods
Changes over time of a household member's health in a given
socio-economic group will depend on the household's interaction
with health-promoting behaviour, changes in the supply of health-related
goods, and the servicing of its residential area. At a given point in
time, inequalities in household members' health, i.e.,
socio-economic differentials in household health, are a result of the
cumulative effects of health-promoting activities and the deterioration
of household members' health Which varies due to their
socio-economic environment.
To continue our illustration of how inequalities in child health
develop between socio-economic groups, we examine the changes societies
undergo during economic crises and structural adjustments. We will
borrow some concepts from investment theory. It must be noted that the
analysis is similar conceptually for other household members as we
describe for children. First, when we consider children as durable
goods, the relevant price concept in the demand for child health is the
user-cost of health. In any period, the user-cost of child health, i.e.,
the shadow price of health, results from the interaction of the
effective costs of health-promoting activities and the deterioration of
child health. Secondly, as long as the marginal benefits (MB) of
increasing the stock of child health outweigh the effective marginal
costs (MC) of increasing that stock, parents will engage in activities
to promote child health. In addition, as the costs of health-promoting
activities increase (such as food price increases) and/or child health
further deteriorates, the level of child health that families can
achieve falls. These notions are illustrated in Figure 1.
The MB curve indicates the results of investing in child health.
The slope of the MB curve is based on the assumption that as the child
gets healthier, the marginal benefit received from increasing her/his
level of health gets smaller. The constant slope of the MC curve is
based on the simplifying assumption that increases in the costs of child
health-promoting activities are independent of the level of child health
stock. Increases in health-related inputs' prices, or declines in
the quality of these inputs, or the worsening of the child's
community environmental conditions shift the MC curve upward; whereas,
changes in the opposite directions shift it downwards. Increases in
family wealth, for example, shift the MB curve upward, and vice versa.
The relative position of the MB and MC curves summarizes the environment
of the family. [H.sup.*] indicates the level of child health the
household can achieve given this environment.
Let us assume we have two types of families, Type I and Type II,
both of which have similar characteristics except that Type I families
reside in an adequately serviced area while Type II families do not. For
children of Type II families, exposure to environmental contamination is
higher, i.e., the price of child health that these families face is
higher than prices faced by Type I families: P x [D.sup.II] > P x
[D.sup.I] (see Figure 2). The implication derived is that Type II
families will thus achieve a lower level of child health than families
of Type I other things being equal. Hence, if both these families are
being taxed at similar rates, whereas the publicly provided
environmental conditions of the Type I family is better off, then
society is implicitly subsidizing the promotion of Type I families'
child health and not the health of Type II families.
The same results hold when families face variable private prices
for using modern medical services. Given the direct effects of exposure
to diseases on the deterioration of child health, the shifts in the MC
curve are more responsive to cross-sectional or dynamic variation in
environmental conditions than to changes in the prices of health-related
goods. Furthermore, as a result of the synergistic effects of multiple
infections on child health [Mosley and Chen (1984)], exposure to poorer
environmental conditions inflate the effective marginal costs for using
modern medical services, therefore generating disproportionately larger
(upward) shifts in the MC curve. Within the urban setting, variable
densities and servicing of residential areas may result in large child
health differentials even in a context of relatively equal access to
medical services.
Urban food and housing subsidies operate similarly toward
generating inequalities in child health. In the case of food subsidies,
the shifts in the MC curve, however, will vary typically from one
socio-economic group to the other, depending on the share of food
purchased in the market and the proportion of total family expenditure
allotted towards food. For a more detailed analysis and empirical
testing of these propositions, including the effects of family wealth on
child health, [see Diop (1990) and Diop and Sirageldin (1990)].
Determinants of Differentials in Health Service Utilization
The previous discussion implies that the household demand for
health services is derived from its demand for health. The demand for
health services will depend on its productivity (marginal product) in
health production, the quality and price of such services and the prices
and availability of other complements and substitutes in the input of
health services. For example, Habicht et al. (1988) found that
mother's milk has a greater effect in promoting child survival in
areas where water and sewage facilities are poor. Figure 3 illustrates
these propositions. For a given level of other inputs and price
[P.sub.1] of health services, the household utilization of health
services will be [H.sub.1]. Two examples below illustrate the movement
of the health productivity curves. In the case where other inputs are
not available or are unequally subsidized between households, for
example, lack of adequate water and sanitation facilities would cause a
downward shift from MP1 to MP2 in health services resulting in a fall in
the household's utilization of health services to level
([H.sup.*.sub.2]). In the case where a cost-recovery scheme is imposed,
the effective price of health services would shift from [P.sub.1] to
[P.sub.2], and thus the health service utilization for this household
would further reduce to an underprivileged level ([H.sub.*.sub.4]).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The above analyses thus indicate that determinants of differentials
in health status and in health service utilization can be examined on
three interrelated levels:
(a) Community and regional differentials;
(b) Inter-household differentials; and
(c) Intra-household differentials.
In each of these cases differences in utilization could be the
result of inefficiency or inequity, both of which have inter- and
intra-household implications. Lack of efficiency implies that a
reallocation of resources will produce better health outcomes within the
same household budget constraints. Inequity implies that effective
prices of health inputs and of health-related factors faced by the
household are benefiting some households more than others, mainly a
result of basic environmental characteristics and/or unequal patterns of
public health facilities and social subsidies. A change in such patterns
should have uncompensated change in the distribution of health benefits
to society.
III. EQUITY VERSUS EFFICIENCY IN HEALTH SERVICES UTILIZATION
Community and Household Levels
The previous discussion implies that inequalities in health and
differences in health services utilization are related to efficiency and
equity considerations.
Three major reasons usually account for the relevance of these
considerations in the developing countries. Firstly, modern medical
goods and services are relatively recent in many parts of the less
developed countries. Even though mostly provided as collective goods,
their uneven spatial distribution within and between countries implies
variable private costs to families engaging in health-promoting
activities. Furthermore, the availability of traditional alternatives,
which can be viewed as substitutes to modern inputs in. health
investment, implies that utilization patterns will be determined not
only by relative prices, but also by the expectations that families have
about the relative efficacy of these alternative inputs. Secondly, the
subsidization of health-related goods, other than medical services, are
common policy in the context of most developing countries. Staple foods,
which constitute a large share of the food basket of urban families,
have been subsidized for a long time. Thirdly, infectious diseases are
highly prevalent, such that the environmental conditions of respective
communities become an important proximate determinant of child health.
The general pattern is that unequal access to modern medical services is
paralleled by unequal access to adequately serviced residential areas.
In the framework presented herein, and in the present context of
economic turmoil that prevailed during the 1980s, it is possible to
examine more critically the implications of macroeconomic adjustment on
household health. Such policies influence household health through four
mechanisms, namely, impact on (1) family income, (2) prices, primarily
of health-related goods, (3) quantity and quality of modern medical
goods and services, and (4) community environmental conditions. The
impact of adjustment policies on household's health status will
depend on the household's access to public services and the level
of subsidies they receive prior to and during the adjustment process.
Although it is not possible to discuss the impact of the whole
array of adjustment policies on household health, we will focus on
specific policy elements including (i) instruments aimed at restricting
real-income, and (ii) components curtailing public health expenditures.
Policy packages aimed at restricting real income may affect child,
maternal and other family members' health through family income and
prices. The magnitude of this impact will depend on the elasticity of
the demand for health-related goods. Typically, it will vary from one
socio-economic group to another.
These policies include wage control and curtailing consumer
subsidies to reduce domestic absorption. At the outset, let us note that
the effects of these policies on the capacity of families to maintain or
improve the health of their members during an adjustment period will
depend on family engagement in the market economy and on the extent of
family borrowing constraints. The mechanism is complex, however. In
essence, the health consequences of structural adjustment could be
examined through its, direct effect on income and prices and its
indirect effect on the structure of the health delivery system.
First, an example of the direct effect is the case of curtailing
food and housing subsidies and controlling wages. In such a case the
outcome of health-promoting activities will eventually be affected
through not only the quantity but also the quality of food available to
the household. In the context where families are engaged in the modern
labour market and a large share of food consumed by them is purchased
from the market, the health of children among poor families will be
disproportionately adversely affected by such a policy. However, in
settings where large proportions of families are entirely or partially
self-employed in subsistence agriculture, food price and wage changes
may not affect the health of children among the poorest sectors of
society, that is the rural poor, since their purchase of food is
minimal. Therefore, the effect of such a policy will be felt greatly by
the poor and middle income urban families. The argument here implies
that families with a large share of their consumption expenditures
composed of subsidized health-related goods are more likely to be
seriously affected than other groups of families.
Policy packages that significantly reduce public health
expenditures, however, will affect child health through either the
quantity and quality of medical goods or of environmental sanitation.
Reduction of public health expenditures at the central or local levels
may affect both the sanitation of residential areas, and the quantity
and quality of modern medical goods and services. Reductions and
irregularities of environmental sanitation in communities and
non-extensions and/or lack of maintenance of water supply systems are
likely to result in environmental contamination. The likely consequences
are an increase in the incidence of childhood infectious diseases. This
may occur mostly within nonstructured urban residential areas. Indeed,
villages which were not serviced prior to the adjustment period, will
not find a change in the intensity of environmental contamination. Their
conditions were poor even prior to adjustments.
Secondly, in the case of indirect effects, public health
expenditures are biased towards curative services. Thus, curtailing
public expenditures on health essentially delays the extension of
preventive programmes. Furthermore, in the context of declining public
expenditures on health, drugs and supplies are likely to be affected
more than the wages of medical personnel; therefore, impairing the
quantity and quality of medical services provided by the public sector.
Hence, curtailing public health expenditures may result in an increasing
demand for medical services which cannot be met by a health system
locked into a drug-intensive medical technology. Accordingly, among
socio-economic groups interacting in modern medical services, a
significant cut in government health outlay will be expected to
dramatically affect child and maternal health.
In a typical low income agricultural-based country, macroeconomic
adjustment policies will primarily affect, in the short run, the health
of children and women in the urban areas, especially those with real
income dependent on income and fiscal policies. In the long run,
however, such policies will delay child health improvements in the rural
areas as well. Many rural communities which had mildly benefited from
public subsidies, will have no effect on child or maternal health during
adjustment periods. Maternal health could be adversely affected if
intra-household resources were not favourably reallocated towards women.
In summary, the patterns of public expenditures in many developing
countries reflect unequal spatial distribution of medical facilities,
environmental sanitation, housing and food subsidies, and are important
determinants of health inequalities in the developing countries. Family
financial as well as nonfinancial resources should explain an additional
component of child health variability. The third source of inequality
and inefficiency is reflected in the intra-household allocation of
resources.
Individual Intra-household Level
Intra-household allocation of resources is an underdeveloped part
of household analysis, especially in analyzing the demand for health.
There is, however, a growing literature which seems to lake two extreme
positions. In one position, families or households are assumed to have a
common utility enforced by an arbitrary decision-maker where the welfare
status of each individual within the household is determined by an
arbitrary rule. Some empirical studies attempted to examine whether the
allocation rule is based on efficiency criteria [cf. Rosenzweig and
Schultz (1982)]. On the other extreme, the household is seen to be
composed of individuals with different preferences, interests and power.
Household members, such as husband, wife or other adults, are in a
continuous "bargaining process", each attempting to gain
ground. [The literature is growing. A representative contribution
includes Folbre (1984); Rosenzweig and Schultz (1982); McElroy and Homey
(1981); Senauer et al. (1988); Lloyd et al. (1979); Zhao (1991) and
references cited therein.]
The focus of this new development is mainly on the determinants of
women's status within and outside the household. The role of women
in enhancing their own as well as their children's health status is
seen as a consequence of improved women's socio-economic status. It
seems, however, that in many instances the status of women is not well
defined. It is often defined as women's ability to improve their
children's health. This is unfortunate since improving women's
status should be considered as a basic human right, whose achievement
should not be conditional on statistical verification of women's
role in household production of health! [For a review of the concept of
women's status, see Zhao (1991).]
On the other hand, when focusing on the health status of households
in the context of structural adjustments, it is essential to understand
how intra-household allocation of resources are related to the effect of
the adjustment process on the inter-household distribution of income and
the demand for health. The latter effects set limits on any
intra-household allocative mechanism whether or not based on a
bargaining process.
It is intriguing, however, to observe how the various branches of
the social sciences have moved in recent years towards an
"individualistic" market-oriented approach to provide
solutions to a broad range of social issues, even where social values,
including that of the last citadel, the family unit, were important
determinants of behaviour. Further research is required to understand
the role of family values in the dynamics of family decisions and
especially their role in the enhancement of women's status within
and outside the household. For example, in a Nash-type bargaining model,
the threat point may be equally based on social factors and not only on
women's market wages as usually modelled [cf. Zhao (1991), for an
empirical application of an expanded bargaining framework].
CONCLUSIONS
In this paper we attempted to conceptualize some issues related to
equity and efficiency in health status and health service utilization.
Using the household production of health as a general framework, both
the demand for health and the demand for health services depend on the
structure of government fiscal and distribution policies. The demand for
health services will depend not only on its own price but also on the
prices of other complementary inputs available to the household, such as
nutrition and environmental sanitation. These related inputs are mainly
subsidized and in most instances largely, if not exclusively, provided
by the government. Such subsidies, however, are not equally distributed.
The health benefit (the marginal value product) from the use of health
services for those with lower subsidy on other health-related inputs
should be lower. Accordingly, a low demand for health (income effect)
and a low utilization of health services by such households may simply
imply a rational decision reflecting a perceived low productivity of
these inputs.
It is evident that in order to examine the effect of public
policies on health status, e.g., structural adjustment or cost recovery
schemes, the measure of household income should incorporate the effect
of public subsidies. The traditional income groups may not be sufficient
to examine household response to change in the economic environment. In
an empirical test for the case of the Ivory Coast, Diop (1990)
illustrated that the rural poor and the urban poor were not affected by
structural adjustments. It was the middle class urban families who were
hurt the most.
Comments on "Equity and Efficiency in Health Status and Health
Services Utilization: A Household Perspective".
This lecture provides a valuable perspective by including the
effect on the distribution among households and within households of
improvements in health arising from programmes and policy that affect
health, including the provision of health services, but also policies
affecting education, nutrition, supplies, and sanitary facilities.
I must confess that although my Ph.D. is in economics, and I once
taught several courses in economics, my work in demography has led me
away from economic theory, and to some degree alienated me from
applications of the theory of economic choice to demographic behaviour.
I remember when Becker's theory of fertility decision, based on the
quality as well the quantity of children, was first presented at an NBER conference in about 1960. His discussant, Duesenberry, said "no-one
is in this room, including Becker, feels that he has a choice between
two children who go to college, and three who do not".
I am uneasy with the model showing the level of health chosen by
equating marginal benefits of health with the marginal cost. I do not
understand the units along with the axis. How is one more unit of health
defined? It seems to me that even an ordinal rating of health is hard to
achieve. It is not easy to decide whether Professor Sirageldin is
healthier than Professor Diop.
Much of the improvement in health that has been achieved is the
result of new medical and public health technology. Preston illustrates
this point by showing that the difference in life expectancy from 1930
to 1960 at the same per capita income is much greater than the
difference at either date at two different per capita incomes.
This fact, raises a dilemma in health policy when an innovation,
such as oral dehydration therapy (or ORT) occurs. ORT involves giving a
victim of diarrhea a substantial amount of a special liquid that is well
absorbed by a diarrheal patient. The intermediate cause of death from
diarrhea is dehydration; an effective treatment is intravenous injection of fluid; in ORT the fluid is supplied to the body orally, using a
solution of salts that will ensure absorption even in a diarrheal
patient. ORT prevents death by treating symptoms of dehydration, without
curing the disease, unless the patient is treated repeatedly after each
episode of diarrhea. However, death is postponed rather than prevented.
Thus it requires understanding and persistence on the part of the
parents of an affected child to make effective use of ORT. As a
consequence ORT is especially beneficial to the educated family, and
increases the inter-family differential in health. In my view, this fact
is not an argument against introducing ORT; within reasonable cost
limits it is worthwhile saving many infants, even though health
differentials are increased. The inequality inherent in this feature of
ORT does argue, however, for the design of a programme that teaches even
the uneducated how to administer OPT.
Ansley J. Coale
Princeton University, USA.
Comments on "Equity and Efficiency in Health Status and Health
Services Utilization: A Household Perspective"
It is a pleasure to be a discussant of a paper by Professor Ismail
Sirageldin, particularly so because it deals with the extremely
important and topical issue of equity and efficacy in household
utilization of health facilities. Professor Sirageldin's and his
co-author Francois Diop's motivation for writing this paper arises
from data presented in Table 2 where infant mortality rates for several
Arab Countries are compared for the 1960s and the 1980s and they find
that despite falls in mortality considerable divergence across countries
persists in the latter period.
Though I greatly enjoyed reading the paper which brings up some
very interesting points, it does not (in my opinion) do full justice to
the very complex issues of Equity and Efficacy of Health Services
Utilization nor does it provide us with an answer to the question of why
regional, residential, socio-economic differentials persist even after
health transitions have been achieved (as is the case of most of the
Arab States).
One reason for this shortcoming may be due to the complexity of the
issues being discussed. But here I am concerned because I find that the
paper is trying to forcibly fit a simple static model to processes that
the authors themselves describe as dynamic and interrelated with many
other factors which are then completely omitted from the model.
My comments are in no way meant to minimize the usefulness of
introducing some structure and for drawing on economic tools to explain
inequities in health and health care utilization but are just an attempt
to point out ways in which the paper could better incorporate some of
the complexities present in this issue.
The paper is based on the concept of "health status" of a
household and the model used to explain differences in health status is
based on the concepts of 'marginal' betterment and
'prices' of health-related goods. But is the health status of
a household a measurable variable? At a time when we are made
increasingly aware that even the health of a single individual is hard
to measure (definitions vary from "no illness episode in the last
week" to a very broad concept of total well-being), should we be
trying to measure the health of a household assuming it to be a sum of
the health "stock" of all its household members? In my opinion
a more concrete measure of household health status in the form of
morbidity, mortality rates or anthropometic measures of individuals may
be more desirable.
It would be very useful if the paper were to qualify the concept of
price of health-related goods. Is price of such goods just a measure of
the cost of consultation of a doctor, hospitalization, medicines, or
also the costs of transport which in the case of many rural communities
is a major component of health costs? Should it, in fact, even involve
the costs of preventive care such as a good and nutritious diet,
exercise, etc.?
Similarly, when utilizing the concept of marginal productivity of
health, which depicts the increment in health status to be accrued with
additional health inputs, a range of factors are covered each one as
Important a Determinant of Health (for example, the availability of
potable water, sanitation services, sewerage or individual factors such
as maternal education, better spacing etc. etc.). Whereas the model
focuses on how society may be implicitly subsidizing health care of
certain families it should also incorporate the fact that societies also
tend to subsidize services closely related to health such as Education,
Communication Links, Energy, Water very usually for the same set of
people (such as urban elites). So the model should allow for a whole
package of factors which lead to better health for a particular
community instead of assuming quite unrealistically that a single factor
such as health services will be subsidized in isolation. The whole
process is quite synergistic: it is easier to set up schools and health
centres where there is water available and where there are good roads
and telephone links etc.
I would like to throw up a question for discussion which Professor
Sirageldin and a co-author raised in their book on Research in Human
Capital and Development. It is the question of what is the role of
Development in Improving Health? Since public expenditures vary greatly
across countries--for example in 1977 Tanzania spent 38 percent more
while Pakistan spent 77 percent Less than Might be Expected Based on
Norm Expenditures, it is critical to ask to what extent is human capital
created and how is the health status of a community influenced by the
level of public expenditure on health.
Answers to this question and to related ones like why
Pakistan's IMR remains so high when per capita incomes have risen
significantly? Does development necessarily lead to declines in
mortality and to a diminution of differentials in mortality? Are
increased public health expenditure and enhanced public subsidies to
health a necessary precondition for improvement in the health of the
community?
It seems to me that these are important issues for research before
we embark on any serious study of equity and efficiency in health care
utilization in less developed countries. An important underlying
assumption of the arguments presented in the paper is that health
subsidies do contribute to differentials in mortality. In Pakistan it
cannot be denied that the urban sector is better subsidized in health
care and there is a concentration of health services in the cities
(Professor Sirageldin presents this in the form of a shift downwards on
the curve whereby marginal cost of health care in urban areas are lower
than in rural areas). However, there are many other confounding issues
in the calculus of health choices, for instance, data from the National
Health Survey of 1982 show that even where there is a government
facility within a mile's radius, the level of utilization is only
30-40 percent. Quality of public services available are very important
and the strong psychological value attached to one form of health care
over another is critical. Many poor persons prefer to pay a higher fee
and consult a private doctor or, more likely a quack, even when a
government facility (which would be cheaper) is located nearby. Also,
many persons resort to fakirs and hakims in which they have faith rather
than experimenting with modern medicine even if it is heavily
subsidized. Here the authors mention the importance of past experiences
of the household/community and that I feel is yet another dimension
which ought to be incorporated in their model.
One of the major aims of the paper was to investigate reasons for
socioeconomic and regional differentials in mortality in the PAPCHILD
countries and, in particular, to see whether the impact of recent
structural adjustment policies exacerbate these differences. If
structural adjustment does lead to a reduction in the government budget
on health and social sectors (as it seems to be the case in many
societies) then there will be a reduction in public subsidies in health
and an increase in user costs etc. The health of the community will
suffer. But if urban areas (which are already oversubsidized) suffer
more (as it is argued in the paper because of greater self-sufficiency
in food items in rural areas) then the effect may lead to greater
equity.
However, the case of countries like Pakistan is perhaps more grave
as public expenditure on the social sectors is already extremely low and
a further decrease in public subsidies will erode even further the very
modest advances made in the health sector--leave alone the question of
whether differentials in health care utilization will rise! It is not a
question here of who will fill the gap of withdrawing health care
financing but a case of even greater dependence on private care in the
cities and a bigger deficiency in the services available in rural areas
where No Health Care may be the option.
Last but not least, is the question of intra-household allocations
and inequities in health care. Though the authors do tackle this issue
in the end of their paper I would just like to add that it has become
increasingly apparent that the health needs of particular groups such as
children under five, women in reproductive ages and the elderly are
particularly marked. Historically noted trends in differential
allocations in health care and nutrition (as also in related
'goods' such as education and information) have been used to
explain the higher female mortality found in South Asia and some North
African countries. Recent research may be pointing towards the Voter
importance of social factors over economic factors in the study of
determinants of individual mortality. It may be useful to study whether
differences in the mortality of individuals within groups may not be
greater than across the groups to which they belong. The results of such
studies might radically change the conclusion derived in this paper
which is that patterns of public expenditures in the PAPCHILD region
mainly reflect the unequal spatial distribution of medical and other
facilities.
Zeba A. Sathar
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
REFERENCES
Cornia, Giovanni Andrea, Richard Jolly and Frances Stewart (eds)
(1987) Adjustment with a Human Face. (Volume I) Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Cornia, Giovanni Andrea, Richard Jolly and Frances Stewart (eds)
(1988) Adjustment with a Human Face. (Volume II) Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
Cropper, M. L. (1977) Health, Investment in Health, and
Occupational Choice. Journal of Political Economy 85 : 1273-1294.
DaVanzo, Julie, and Paul Gertler (1990) Household Production of
Health: A Microeconomic Perspective on Health Transitions. A Rand Note
N-3014-RC, Santa Monica, California.
Diop, Francois Pathe (1990) Economic Determinants of Child Health
and the Utilization of ftealth Services in Sub-Sahara Africa: The Case
of Ivory Coast. Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins
University.
Diop, Francois P., and Ismail Sirageldin (1990) Economic Crisis and
Child Survival: Who Benefits from Adjustment with a Human Face.
Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University. (Mimeographed.)
Diop, Francois, Kenneth Hill and Ismail Sirageldin (1990) Economic
Crisis, Structural Adjustment and Health in Africa. Washington, D. C.:
The World Bank. (World Bank Report.)
Foege, W. H., and D. A. Henderson (1986) Management Priorities in
Primary Health Care. In J. A. Walsh and K. S. Warren (eds) Strategies
for Primary Health Care. Chicago and London: University of Chicago
Press. 313-321.
Folbre, Nancy R. (1984) Market Opportunities, Genetic Endowments,
and Intrafamily Resource Distribution. American Economic Review 75 :
518-520.
Gray, Ronald H. (1988) Fundamentals of the Epidemiologic and
Demographic Transitions. In Ismail Sirageldin and Alan Sorkin (eds)
Research in Human Capital and Development (Vol. 5). Public Health and
Development. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, Inc. 25-42.
Grossman, Michael (1972) On the Concept of Health Capital and the
Demand for Health. Journal of Political Economy 80 : 223-255.
Grossman, Michael (1972a) The Demand for Health: A Theoretical and
Empirical Investigation. New York: Columbia University Press. (NBER
Occasional Paper No. 119.)
Habicht, Jean-Pierre, Julie DaVanzo, and William P. Butz (1988)
Mother's Milk and Sewage: Their Interactive Effects on Infant
Mortality. Pediatrics 81:3 456-461.
Jamison, Dean T., and W. Henry Mosley (eds) (1990) Selecting
Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries. Washington, D. C.:
The World Bank.
Lloyd, Cynthia B., Emily S. Andrews, and Curtis L. Gilroy (eds)
(1979) Women in the Labour Market. New York: Columbia University Press.
McElroy, Marjorie, and Mary Jean Homey (1981) Nash-Bargained
Household Decisions: Toward a Generalization of the Theory of Demand.
International Economic Review 22 : 333-349.
Mosley, W. Henry, and Lincoln C. Chen (1984) An Analytical
Framework for the Study of Child Survival in Developing Countries.
Population and Development Review 10 (Supp): 25-45.
Muurinen, J. M. (1982) Demand for Health: A Generalised Grossman
Model. Journal of Health Economics 1 : 5-28.
Muurinen, J. M., and J. Le Grand (1985) The Economic Analysis of
Inequalities in Health. Social Science and Medicine 20 : 10 1029-1035.
Omran, A. R. (1971) The Epidemiological Transition: A Theory of the
Epidemiology of Population Change. Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly 49 :
509-538.
Omran, A. R. (1982) Epidemiologic Transition. In J. Ross (ed)
International Encyclopedia of Population (Vol. 1). New York: The Free
Press, MacMillan Publishing Company. 172-183.
Rosenzweig, Mark R., and T. Paul Schultz (1982) Market
Opportunities, Genetic Endowments and the Intrafamily Resource
Distribution: Child Survival in Rural India. American Economic Review 72
: 803-815.
Senauer, Benjamin, Marito Gareia, and Elizabeth Jacinto (1988)
Determinants of the Intrahousehold Allocation of Food in the Rural
Philippines. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 70 : 1 170-180.
Sirageldin, Ismail, and W. Henry Mosley (1988) Health Services and
Population Planning Programmes: A Review of Interrelations. In Ismail
Sirageldin and Alan
Sorkin (eds) Research in Human Capital and Development (Vol. 5).
Public Health and Development. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, Inc. 3-23.
Sirageldin, Ismail et al. (eds) (1989) Towards More Efficacy in
Child Survival Strategies: Understanding the Social Constraints and
Responsibilities. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University.
Streeten, Paul (1988) Beyond Adjustment: The Asian Experience.
Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.
UNICEF (1989) Middle East and North Africa Region, UNICEF Goals and
Strategies for the 1990s, Selected Indicators. Representatives Meeting,
Amman, Jordan, 4-5 September.
Zhao, Xiyan (1991) Demographic Change and Economic Status of Women
in Rural China. Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins
University.
* The Pakistan Society of Development Economists is grateful to the
Friedrich Ebert Stiftung. Germany for providing the funds for the
delivery of this Distinguished Lecture.
Ismail Sirageldin and Francois Diop are affiliated with The Johns
Hopkins University, USA.
Table 1
Percent of Deaths by Cause, Developed and Industrialized Countries,
Circa 1985
Developing Industrial
Cause of Death Countries Countries
1. Infectious and Parasitic Diseases 45. 4.6
2. Maternal Causes 1.3 0.05
3. Perinatal Causes 8.4 0.9
4. Cancers 6.6 20.8
5. Chronic Obstructive Pulmonary Disease 6.1 3.5
6. Circulatory (and Certain Degenerative) 17.1 53.7
7. External Causes 6.3 7.0
8. Other and Unknown 9.2 13.
Total Percentage 100 100
Total Cases 37,900,000 11,045,000
Source: Based on Jamison and Mosley (1990).
Table 2
Health Indicators for 16 Arab Countries and 6 Other Countries
Babies with Maternal
IMR Low Birth Weight Mortality
1965 1988 1985% per 100,000
33 Yemen DR 147 118 13 NA
36 Sudan 160 106 15 607
45 Yemen Arab Rep 197 128 9 NA
48 Egypt 172 83 7 500
52 Morocco 145 71 9 327
64 Tunisia 145 48 7 1000
(Rural Only)
67 Jordan 114 43 7 NA
69 Syria Arab Rep 114 46 9 280
78 Lebanon 56 NA NA NA
81 Algeria 154 72 9 129
92 Oman 194 38 14 NA
93 Libya 138 80 5 NA
95 Iraq 119 68 9 NA
97 Saudi Arabia 148 69 6 52
107 Kuwait 64 15 7 18
111 UAE 108 25 NA NA
21 China 90 31 6 44
23 Pakistan 149 107 25 600
34 Indonesia 128 68 14 800
89 Korea Rep of 62 24 9 34
117 Sweden 13 6 4 4
120 Japan 18 5 5 15
Source: World Bank (1990) World Development Report. Washington,
D. C.: Oxford University Press.
Note: Numbers in first column are rank by level of GNP in 1988.