Have agricultural economists neglected poverty issues?
Thiesenhusen, William C.
1. INTRODUCTION
In the short term one can be pessimistic about the collective
progress of the Third World and its interactions with industrial
countries. There is plenty of bad news. With one-quarter of the
world's population, industrialized countries consume about 80
percent of the world's goods. With three-quarters of the
world's population, developing countries command less than
one-quarter of the world's resources. And the imbalance is growing
worse. (1) Of the 2.7 billion people in the tropical and subtropical regions outside of China, 40 percent live in poverty; more than 14
million of their children under 5 years of age starve to death or die of
disease each year. (2) Furthermore, at the same time as an increasing
proportion of the population of Africa is composed of young people (65
percent of its population is now under age 25), education budgets are
being cut--from $10.8 billion in 1980 to $5.8 billion in 1986. (3) In an
article assessing the globalization of economies, Richard J. Barnet
writes: "Poverty, population pressures, civil war, and repression
are turning Sub-Saharan Africa--black Africa minus South Africa and
Namibia--into a giant disaster zone, and in countries in South America,
such as Colombia and Peru, the civil society is dissolving. In the
Philippines more than seventy percent of the population is poor by any
human standard. With the end of the Cold War, the increasing
marginalization of the Third World appears likely." (4) The
predictions are ominous. Barnet concludes his article, written before
the crisis in Iraq, by speaking to an industrial-country audience:
"There is no real north-south dialogue, and politicians in the
industrial world feel little pressure to begin one. The end of the third
global conflict of the twentieth century offers a unique moment to
re-examine basic assumptions about the political organization of the
planet. Unless the people of Asia, Africa, and Latin America are part of
a new democratic order, we will all lose the chance for peace the world
has won." (5)
But taking a longer and more disaggregated view--looking at
progress since the Second World War--can engender a buoyant feeling that
the future does carry promise. Some countries which all but defined the
underdeveloped world forty years ago are Newly Industrial Countries
(NIC) today. And there has been forward movement even where progress was
less dramatic, in countries whose eventual NIC status is confidently
forecast. Agricultural productivity has taken quantum leaps. Some
diseases which were sapping industrial productivity years ago are now
eradicated and the productive life spans of populations have been
stretched. Despite the negative overall figures cited, education has
become more available to the masses of mankind, even rural dwellers. The
Inter-American Development Bank, after chronicling a disastrous
decade--one which saw Latin America in 1989 with the same per capita
income it had in 1977--and even though expenditures on health fell in
real terms by 5 percent in Costa Rica, 15 percent in Chile, 10 percent
in Brazil, 22 percent in Venezuela, and 30 percent in Uruguay, (6)
concluded that life expectancy, illiteracy rates, and infant mortality rates continued to improve in the 1980s. (7)
In a sense, these long-term positive indicators show a path for
laggard countries today and are especially inspiring since some of the
countries making the most progress toward NIC status were unlikely
candidates in the 1950s. It is safe to say that most of those who live
in the Third World are considerably better off today than they were
then. Indeed, with all the problems that still attend development in the
Third World, future historians may read these last four or five decades
as a time when there was the beginning of a true global concern for the
environment, for economic and social development, for the amelioration of societal inequities--an era marked by more security of expectations
than any in the past. (8) Although it is scant comfort to the hungry,
perhaps the most important progress has been made on attitudes. We may
be at the beginning of an era when poverty, ignorance, and disease are
not to be accepted as an inescapable lot but as conditions that can and
ought to be removed by policy and effort. Of course, we are a long way
from that goal in low-income countries, those at the bottom of the GNP per-capita list. And whether new awareness and concern will translate
into action is a matter for speculation.
Since so many of the root problems in Third World countries are
with the rural sectors, agricultural economists have a special
responsibility in development concerns: they are, by definition, applied
social scientists, and they investigate the empirical bases for real
world economic problems and devise suitable alternative policies, The
contributions of agriculture to economic development are: (1) to produce
a surplus and transfer it to nonagriculture, (2) to provide markets for
urban-based industry, (3) to maintain a labour reservoir, (4) to assist
in capital formation, and (5) to accumulate foreign exchange.
Agricultural economists exert much effort researching these matters.
Yet, as I read the economics journals and examine the career
trajectories of young agricultural economists, I have become concerned
that there is a diminished amount of intellectual activity devoted to
coping with rural poverty in the Third World. Frankly, I worry about a
recent disciplinary penchant of researching very narrow problems with
considerable rigour and often little data to the exclusion of empirical
examination of some of the more sweeping economic concerns confronting
oar societies.
In this paper, I deal with five questions:
(1) Why do agricultural economists neglect rural poverty?
(2) Why does the presence of large amounts of rural poverty imperil development?
(3) Should rural poverty be treated in situ?
(4) What is the shape of the current growth-equity debate as
concerns poverty reduction?
(5) Are there any new and promising methods for coping with rural
poverty?
My plea is for more research into neglected problems of Third World
poverty, particularly in the countryside. The World Bank estimates that
a billion or so contemporary people--a good one-fifth of mankind--can
still be considered to be in the grip of poverty. Poverty is
predominantly a rural problem, accounting for 60 percent of the
so-called hungry-poor in Latin America, 80 percent in Asia, and 90
percent in Africa. (9)
Suggesting poverty research in the Third World is not novel or even
original. And, happily, it does seem to be of renewed current concern,
mainly on the part of international organizations as the 1990s commence,
perhaps because structural adjustment has wrought harsh, though, it is
hoped, short-run difficulties to some categories of the poor. The Asian
Development Bank devoted a recent issue of the Asian Development Review
(10) to the matter; the World Bank featured it in its most recent World
Development Report. (11) The draft "State of Food and
Agriculture", to be published by FAO in 1991, contains a section on
rural poverty and structural adjustment. Daedalus, the journal of the
American Academy of Arts and Sciences, devoted much of its winter 1989
edition to the issue. A good bit of the 1990 report of the
Inter-American Development Bank, Economic and Social Progress in Latin
America, is devoted to poverty problems of women in Latin America's
work force, and you were addressed on it in your January meetings in
1989 and again last year. (12)
2. ADDRESSING RURAL POVERTY
FAO (13) sets out some characteristics of the Third World rural
poor, defined as those poor who either work on farms or do nonfarm work
that depends in part on agriculture:
(1) They are heterogeneous, including small-scale farmers, the
landless, nomads, pastoralists, and fisherfolk;
(2) The landless and the near-landless constitute the largest
single group of those afflicted by rural poverty: some 30 million
agricultural households are landless and 138 million are near landless;
landlessness is especially serious in South Asia, but numbers in this
category are growing in all of the Third World;
(3) Poverty affects an average of half the rural population in the
Third World, with Africa exhibiting the highest incidence (though the
situation is somewhat better in the Near East);
(4) Close correlates with extreme poverty are undernutrition, high
child mortality, and illiteracy;
(5) Resources to accommodate the poor are shrinking. In the 1975-80
period, absolute numbers in the agricultural population expanded by 103
million; the comparable 1980-85 figure was 96 million. At the same time,
expansion of arable land in the former period was 20.6 million hectares
as opposed to 11.4 million hectares in the latter period;
(6) The poor turn to nonfarm jobs when they can. There is an
inverse relationship between nonfarm employment of the rural labour
force and farm size, and nonfarm employment is especially utilized by
the rural poor during slack seasons in the countryside;
(7) Rural poverty stems from underemployment, which is rapidly
being translated into unemployment in urban areas. Between 1950 and
1980, the population of Africa's largest cities increased more than
sevenfold while those of major Asian and Latin American cities either
tripled or quadrupled;
(8) Poverty is closely correlated with high rates of sectoral
economic growth, and economic downturns affect countries with a higher
percentage of people in poverty more adversely than those with fewer
poor people; that is, economic slowdowns are more precipitous in
countries with larger groups in poverty. There is some tendency for low
or falling wages to be associated with low or falling rates of
agricultural growth;
(9) Rural poverty is associated with countries experiencing the
greatest fluctuation in the price index for food;
(10) The Inter-American Development Bank adds that rural women and
children are more severely affected by poverty than rural men, and it is
often the work of rural women that pulls families out of a
"poverty" category; (14) and
(11) A recent volume, Rural Poverty in South Asia, (15) points out
that international migration and the repatriation of remittances have
recently proved essential for rural poverty alleviation in some
countries.
Why Do Economists Avoid Rural Poverty?
The first reason why agricultural economists shun studies of rural
poverty comes from the complexities which these characteristics
introduce to any analysis of the rural poor:
(1) Since the poverty-stricken combine rural and urban as well as
domestic and international strategies to raise their incomes, the
sectoral and national limitation of any analysis is difficult, if not
impossible. To do their jobs, agricultural economists find themselves
working out of their sector and in situations which transcend national
territories. We continually are being made aware of how interconnected
all of our countries have become--through our factor and product
markets, through our common environment, through technology, through
improved communications. The worldwide trend to free trade areas, which
will have a profound effect on rural labour and rural poverty, merits
more careful thought and attention. How rural poverty will be affected
by the global economy is scarcely mentioned except to assume that
"a rising tide raises all ships";
(2) Since poverty impact on gender and on age groups is
differential, analyzing family income without these considerations is
fraught with problems;
(3) Since some aspects creating poverty are transitory, such as
structural adjustment, short- and long-term analyses and projections are
required;
(4) Since some aspects of poverty may be solvable only with
allocation of new resources, economics is entangled with more broadly
social issues which also must be addressed. By definition, coping with
rural poverty implies that growth and equity issues be addressed, and
this means a square confrontation with politics. In sum, problems
introduced by rural poverty tend not to obey the boundaries imposed upon
them by academic disciplines; and
(5) Since the rural poor are such a heterogeneous lot, a government
policy favourable to one group may wreak havoc on another. Raising
producer prices, for instance, may help the land-poor but worsen the
situation of the landless.
In sum, the "simple model" is not readily adaptable to
problems which are this encompassing, though models will be absolutely
essential to analyzing component parts of the issue.
The second reason that causes agricultural economists to avoid the
issue of rural poverty has philosophical roots: Can we address poverty
objectively? Some think not and stay away from the problem because of
ideological convictions. However, for the Third World, one of the
refreshing by-products of the recent liberating events in the USSR and
Eastern Europe and the passing of the Reagan era in U. S. politics is
that discussions on such issues can now be less polarized. The debate on
where within the spectrum from free markets to Marxist countries the
Third World ought to be has the promise of being more open and pragmatic
now than in the recent past. There is scope for both private
action--where private initiative needs to be unleashed, entrepreneurship
increased, and investment rewarded-and, when needed, governmental
redress.
On privatization and laissez faire, John Kenneth Galbraith warns
that it is not true that there is an essential therapy that comes from
human deprivation and unemployment and that "out of unemployment
and hunger will come a new and revitalized work ethic" (16) and
enhanced economic growth. Thus, even in an economy that is
"privatizing" and in other ways making a transition to freer
markets, there is a place for social expenditures on matters such as
poverty alleviation. Galbraith reminds us of the blinded vision that
free-marketeers sometimes exhibit when poverty is the subject:
"Nothing over the centuries has more often been urged than the
social reward of hardship by those who will not have to suffer it".
(17) Galbraith concludes, "In a very real sense, both East and
West, our task is the same: it is to seek and find the system that
combines the best in market motivation and socially motivated
action". (18)
A third reason for agricultural economists to avoid rural poverty
issues is that some of the reforms required for poverty alleviation,
such as land reform, result in lower labour productivity on specific
pieces of reformed property in the short run, even though there is
higher production per unit of land almost immediately. Then again, some
agricultural economists have become satisfied over the years with
"policies" that raise labour productivity in agriculture at
the expense of enormous waves of urban migration.
Fourth, agricultural economists are often committed to policies
that benefit commercial farming at the expense of farm labour and
small-scale agriculture.
And fifth, agricultural economists frequently undervalue the
contributions to development made by the rural poor. It is sometimes
assumed that land-poor rural people make only a marginal contribution to
production and that when compared to large producers who are ordinarily
favoured with more than their share of good land, technology, market
facilities, and credit, small farmers are insignificant contributors to
overall growth. In Brazil, as suggested by a strong inverse relationship
between farm size and production per hectare, this is not true. The
contributions of small farmers to production in Brazil are substantial.
(19) With Melmed-Sanjak, I examined the 1980 agricultural census, the
latest available in 1990, to determine the contributions to agricultural
production of farms under 50 hectares, which occupy only 12 percent of
the agricultural land in that vast country. These small farms utilize 28
percent of agricultural capital (in value terms) but employ 71 percent
of agricultural labour and occupy 39 percent of the country's
cropland. This cohort of small farms produces half of the income of the
agricultural sector and 40 percent of gross income. Around 80 percent of
this product is marketed, mostly for domestic consumption (see Table 1).
A U. N.-sponsored study of the 1970s corroborates our work, showing that
41 percent of Latin America's domestically consumed agricultural
products were produced by small farmers and that this sector also
accounted for 32 percent of the region's exportable agricultural
products. Indications are that the percentages were similar in the
1980s, even though 62 percent of these farm families were below the
poverty line. (20) In other words, the commodity contribution of the
land-poor is substantial; they contribute more than proportionally to
agricultural output, the vast bulk of which is transferred via the
market as agricultural surplus. Furthermore, the production process of
small-scale farmers is factor-rational. In a worker-plentiful,
capital-scarce economy, small farms utilize more than their share of
labour and save on capital.
Why Does the Presence of Large Amounts of Rural Poverty Imperil
Development?
There are economic as well as moral penalties to be paid by
countries that do not work to alleviate their rural poverty problems. If
these issues are not addressed, growing poverty hobbles the chances of
reaping rewards from globalization. Can a country like Brazil, for
example, reach her potential on the world stage with fully one-third of
her population--the rural landless; the urban homeless and marginals;
and many of the tertiary, informal sector of the economy--participating
only marginally in the market economy? If the number taking part in the
growth process is substantially below the potential, will not growth
itself be jeopardized?
At another level, the Bretton Woods institutions emphasize that
countries with an outward-oriented growth pattern have fared much better
than those which, behind high tariff walls, produce primarily for
internal markets. For the past several decades, in fact, the progress of
exporters has been teaching this lesson, one only recently learned in
Latin America, where, led first by Chile and joined now by Mexico, there
appears to be a shift toward freer trade.
The poverty rate is presently low in those East Asian countries
which serve as models for would-be export promotions, those which
attained NIC status in the 1980s. Unemployment in these countries is
low, literacy is high, and health conditions are much improved, even for
those at the very bottom of the income distribution spectrum. Why this
occurred has escaped many analysts: while great progress in poverty
reduction has taken place because of the NICs' export orientation,
chroniclers of their histories often fail to give adequate attention to
how their internal markets were built, their institutions reshaped, and
their land tenure patterns reformed so that the formerly excluded poor
enjoyed at least some immediate growth benefits. In the NICs (especially
Taiwan but also South Korea--and now Thailand and Malaysia), most of the
peasantry seem to benefit, though, of course, not to the same extent as
the rich.
These countries teach that growth, distribution, and amelioration
of poverty are importantly linked. Reforming institutions early in the
development process, perhaps through land reforms or other
distributional policies [like the New Economic Policy (NEP) in
Malaysia], is a measure to be ardently sought. Central America in the
1970s illustrates the perils of economies which grow rapidly but are
institutionally biased in such a manner that the poorer groups are
excluded.
A second major economic reason for alleviating rural poverty is its
link to environmental degradation, clearly made by the World
(Brundtland) Commission on Environment and Development: "Those who
are poor and hungry will often destroy their immediate environment in
order to survive: they will cut down forests; their livestock will
overgraze grasslands; they will overuse marginal land; and in growing
numbers they will crowd into congested cities". (21) The solution
lies in the intermediate (but, as yet, not very operational) concept of
"sustainable development", which the report defines as
"development that meets the needs of the present without
compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own
needs"." The report concludes, "[This] is not a
prediction of ever increasing environmental decay, poverty and hardship
in an ever more polluted world among ever decreasing resources. We see
instead the possibility for a new era of economic growth ... absolutely
essential to relieve the greater poverty that is deepening in much of
the developing world". (23)
In support of this idea, Martinez-Alier documents several ways in
which poverty is a cause of environmental degradation: it promotes
overuse of firewood and the eventual use of dung for heat instead of
fertilizer; it results in land overuse and eventual deterioration; it
necessitates off-farm work such that semi-proletarians do not have time
for conservation practices. (24)
There is an unfortunate side effect to linking the poor with
environmental damage where there is great inequity in resource
distribution, for it seemingly results in blaming the victim for
environmental degradation. (25) Keyfitz provides a recent example:
"In Brazil peasants from overpopulated regions have destroyed
millions of acres of rain forests in an attempt to eke out a living from
soil that is essentially unsuitable for farming". (26) Even
Martinez-Alier notes, "The social differentiation of a peasantry
creates marginal cultivation, which in turn leads to soil erosion since
they are concerned with immediate survival". (27) And again,
"In some poor countries, sheer population pressure has made soil
erosion worse by driving the landless onto marginal lands such as
hillsides and forests. The growing shortage of firewood often means an
ugly cycle of denuded hillsides, flash floods, silted rivers". (28)
In fact, the peasant is only the most immediately responsible party
for environmental damage; if blame must be apportioned, it is equally,
if not more, appropriate to charge the rural land-tenure system, which
allows rich landlords to monopolize the best resources in the region and
often, as reported in literature on the inverse relationship between
productivity and farm size, use them wastefully. Illustrating by
reference to peasants who have moved to the Brazilian frontier, Mahar
reasons, "It would be wrong to place all of the blame on the
settlers. Pushed by poverty and skewed land distributions in their
region of origin, the settlers have merely responded to incentives
created by the government". (29)
The threat to natural resources from inequalities has frequently
been asserted. Martinez-Alier notes that "environmental degradation
and poverty become tied together ... because of inequality of
distribution". (30) Hecht has concluded: "It is ludicrous to
describe environmental degradation as only a function of demographics.
Rather the situation is due to the extraordinary maldistribution of land
...". (31) Mahar writes that "the real causes [of tropical
deforestation] are poverty, unequal land distribution, and low
agricultural productivity combined with rapid population growth".
(32) The World Resources Institute claims: "The real causes of
deforestation are poverty, skewed land distribution (due to historical
patterns of land settlement and commercial agricultural development),
and low agricultural productivity". (33)
Painter claims that "the critical issue underlying
environmental destruction is the gross inequity in access to
resources". (34) The Brundtland Commission also draws attention to
the importance of greater equity in land distribution to improving
environmental conservation. (35) Foy and Daly elaborate, arguing that
environmental problems are caused primarily by maldistribution of
resources and total human resource use relative to the carrying capacity of the environment and only secondarily by misallocation of resources
due to government policy or market failure. (36) Haiti, El Salvador, and
Costa Rica, they say, "stand as warnings to large countries"
like Brazil. Foy and Daly report that in the three countries,
environmental degradation is not a relatively simple technical matter of
"getting the prices right"; rather, it relates to more complex
issues involving the political structure itself. (37)
Examining the relation of unequal resource distribution to the
environment involves a recognition that groups of users place
differential demands on resources; the poor have a proximate, direct
effect on them, while the impact of those who own ample land and water
is indirect but just as decisive, if not more so, in determining
resource destruction. Indeed, it appears that if the environmental
problem is ever to be alleviated, the lock which large landlords have on
most of the productive resources in some Third World areas must be
substantially modified or broken through land reform. Problems of
deforestation, for example, probably need to be solved in the major
farming regions of the countries involved, far from the site of actual
resource damage.
Should Rural Poverty Be Treated in Situ?
Urban poverty focuses more attention on itself than rural poverty;
hence, it is more quickly transformed into a political problem, thus
becoming a target for government policy. As poverty is transplanted to
urban areas when rural areas modernize, those concerned with development
are presented with a dilemma: Should they recommend institutional change
and more appropriate technology that will be labour absorbing and will
enable more intensive use of the available resources in rural areas,
thus treating the poverty problem in situ, or should they permit labour
productivity to rise in farming and allow poverty to become an explosive
urban issue when workers move en masse to cities?
The issue of the locus where poverty will be addressed comes up in
the Brazilian case, and whether economic policy is addressed to rural or
urban problems shapes its cost. In the last several decades, Brazil has
seen an unprecedented migration to towns in advance of economic
opportunity, often resulting in increased unemployment and homelessness
in the urban areas. Because much of the land in the country is tied up
in large estates and plantations, successive waves of agricultural
commercialization and mechanization have pushed labour off the land,
with resident farm labour and even sharecropping becoming outmoded
institutions because of the infrequency of their occurrence. Yet there
remain about 10 million landless farm labourers who depend mainly on
agriculture pursuits. Remarkably, there are some 35 million hectares of
idle agricultural land tied up in private estates, the census reveals,
enough to give each landless peasant 3.5 hectares--a king's ransom
in Asian terms, and an event about as politically likely as
Brazil's granting its Amazon rain forest to Bolivia.
In fact, if land transfers to needy peasants were possible, some $
3,500 (in U. S. dollars) per rural job created would be needed. That
amount would pay for the land at current prices and provide a modest
number of inputs to new owners. In contrast, to accommodate the 10
million labourers in town would involve a cost per job established that
is severalfold that amount. (38)
The lesson here is that it is possible to alleviate poverty in the
countryside by utilizing idle capacity and the production process.
However, linking poverty to production is virtually impossible in the
urban setting, especially where internal migration has been substantial.
In towns, poverty alleviation is usually attempted with rudimentary
welfare systems and spending programmes, which quickly run aground for
lack of funds and political will. Since no urban safety net is adequate
for the job, city services are strained, income polarization increases,
urban homelessness proliferates, and repression mounts.
Most development technicians would opt for policies that would
alleviate poverty on the farm not only because they are cheaper but also
because acute concern for the polluted urban environment has arisen
during the last decade. But the political barriers which mitigate
against a countryside solution are formidable. As rural-to-urban
migration reaches some sort of balance point, however, and the
challenged middle classes of the city gain some political ascendancy
over the elite rural classes, policy-makers should recognize that the
alleviation of poverty through rural redistribution and reform may well
become possible.
Also, rural poor people in Third World countries are obtaining a
more articulate political voice. Complaints from those in rural poverty
are increasingly enunciated with the works of rural area religious
groups and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), better methods of
communications, political parties anxious for the rural vote, rural
unionization, and the cooperative movement.
If rural poverty problems should be increasingly addressed in situ,
how should they be treated? There are five major ways to ameliorate
rural conditions in the Third World; specific poor-group targeting is
possible with all of them: (1) increase productivity of those with some
land; (2) couple more peasants with land in settlements or in agrarian
reforms; (3) increase the health and skill levels of those in poverty;
(4) pull rural poverty groups into more farm, nonfarm, agroindustrial,
urban, or international employment; (5) channel government spending to
the poor. The last is, in general, not a viable option in the Third
World; Pakistan is known for some degree of success in the first and the
last of these; (39) and currently, agrarian reform is an obvious but
politically difficult option. (40) On the fourth method, Adelman
cautions, "Great Britain, Belgium, France, Switzerland, Germany,
Denmark, Sweden, Norway and the U. S. all experienced declines in the
shares of income accruing to the poor and increases in absolute and
relative poverty during early phases of their Industrial
Revolutions". (41) She notes that those periods of maldistribution
were long lasting--that is, from two to six or seven decades--but
estimates that they would probably be confined to one generation in the
contemporary Third World. Yet industry and agriculture are quite
different in this respect. Adelman argues that agricultural development
utilizes precisely the factors that the farm sector has in
abundance--unskilled labour. For example, "planting of HYVs
[high-yield varieties] on irrigated land can produce an increase in the
demand for unskilled labour by a factor of 7.5". (42) In Pakistan,
one can argue "agriculture first" in the course of economic
development primarily because of the sector's efficient use of
labour and its production of food. The latter, if imported, can be a
lavish user of foreign exchange. Hard currency, however, is best
directed elsewhere, bringing in technology and key industrial inputs.
What is the Shape of the Current Growth-equity Debate as Concerns
Poverty Reduction?
Poverty has two roots: one is lack of economic growth; the other,
inequitable income, wealth, and resource distribution. Major components
of the latter are concentration of assets in the hands of a few,
inadequate schooling, lack of social services and infrastructure, high
fertility, and employment problems.
These days there is little debate on the point that agricultural
growth is the indispensable component to rural poverty alleviation. John
Mellor has noted that "the problem of decreasing poverty and
improving the nutritional status of the poor must be seen as one of
bringing about broad-based development with agriculture as the leading
edge". (43) To accomplish this, he calls for (1) well-operating
markets, (2) an indigenous agricultural research system, and (3) massive
investment in rural infrastructure.
The World Bank, in its analysis of a dozen or so countries in which
data have been relatively good over a fairly long contemporary period,
argues that changes in the incomes of the poor can be explained by
decomposing them into that part attributable to overall economic growth
and that part ascribed to differences in the inequality of income
distribution. (44)
In this analysis, unfortunately, rural and urban poor were not
disaggregated, a task which must be accomplished some day. The World
Bank displays the change in poverty as measured by a head-count index
and compares it with a simulated change in poverty, or the change that
would have occurred if inequality had either remained constant or moved
in a favourable direction; if, that is, everyone received the same
percentage increase in income which growth had generated or the
percentage gain was somehow "progressively" distributed. This
implies that if the actual decrease in poverty is less than the
simulated decrease, then growth increases inequality: the poor gain less
than the nonpoor. If the actual decrease in poverty is bigger than the
simulated decrease, the opposite is true. The Bank's data show that
in India, the actual and the simulated changes in poverty were almost
exactly the same--that is, the poor enjoyed about the same percentage
increase as everyone else over the 1972-83 period--and that, therefore,
income attributable to growth was distributed in about the same way as
initial income.
There is no case in the World Bank data where the effect of growth
was exactly offset by increasing inequality, but there were many cases
in which inequality worsened the poverty problem.
Brazil, for example, was enjoying a very high rate of growth during
the study period, but concomitantly inequality was becoming a more
severe problem. Given the growth it had experienced between 1960 and
1980, a drop of poverty incidence of 34 percent was forecast by the
World Bank model. But since inequality increased, there was a drop of
only 29 percent in poverty incidence. And if distribution in Brazil had
proceeded to the same progressive extent as Malaysia, given
Brazil's growth rate, poverty reduction would have been in the
order of 43 percentage points. So the pattern of growth and the way the
income effects of growth are distributed as well as its rate are
important determinants of changes in the incidence of poverty. In
Malaysia, growth was not as rapid as in Brazil, but income effects from
it were distributed more equitably, and while a 19 percent reduction in
poverty was forecast, actual reduction was 23 percentage points. High
growth does not indicate progress in solving social problems. Pakistan
is a high-growth, least-developed country, and Brazil, a high-growth,
middle-income country. Yet Brazil has one of the highest mortality rates
for children under 5 years of age among the LDCs and Pakistan has one of
the lowest primary school enrollment rates for children. In the latter
case, failure to improve the skills of the labour force limits the
extent to which the poor can benefit from growth, the World Bank
concludes. (45)
Levels and rates of growth of GNP do not always limit the progress
of social indicators. One peculiar characteristic of development over
the last several decades is the fact that social indicators have tended
to run ahead of economic ones. And in some low-income countries, like
China, Sri Lanka, and the Indian state of Kerala, per-capita income
levels are very low, but other indicators--such as infant mortality,
life expectancy, literacy, and nutrition--exhibit surprising progress,
though the sustainability of that progress is in question, especially
when growth rates slow and expenditures for nonsocial programmes rise. A
country's solution to problems attendant upon poverty, in other
words, depends on its GNP (a rough indication of its capacity to act)
but also on its distribution of wealth (a sign of its public will). [One
important limitation to poverty alleviation is that the Third World
spends half of its total annual expenditures for maintenance of military
establishments and servicing the national debt.] (46)
Focusing on absolute and dire poverty, that is, the poorest tenth
of the population (which is most likely to be rural), all countries in
the World Bank sample enjoyed larger-than-average percentage increases
to this group except Brazil and Costa Rica, where relative inequality
worsened over the period studied. Even at that, the poorest tenth
enjoyed an absolute gain in Brazil but not in Costa Rica.
No simple pattern for poverty reduction emerges from the World Bank
analysis. In low-growth Colombia, a country which also demonstrated some
reduction in income inequality during the study period, the poorest
tenth of the population did worse than the population at large, for mean
income growth dropped by 11 percent in the decade ending with 1988 while
income for the poorest tenth of the population fell by 20 percent. The
opposite was true for Malaysia, a relatively high-growth country which
also showed some improvement in income distribution in the period
examined.
Countries in the World Bank sample which experienced the fastest
reduction in poverty showed relatively rapid economic growth. In more
egalitarian countries, a somewhat lower rate of economic growth served
to reduce poverty, but more egalitarianism coupled with rapid economic
growth was the surest recipe for poverty reduction.
Growth without a fairly equitable distribution is a very blunt
instrument for poverty alleviation. Even so, one researcher has recently
concluded that "in terms of satisfying basic needs, average real
income growth is much more decisive than changes in income shares".
(47) But growth can be honed with institutional change and public policy
so that improvements in distribution channel income gains to lower
strata of society, perhaps the most enduring manner of
"targeting" a solution for groups in poverty. On the other
hand, redistribution without growth is equally suspect: in the absence
of growth, it is a once-and-for-all event. Fortunately, since Hollis
Chenery's classic monograph (48) and the real life experiences of
the four East Asian tigers, we know that in due time both equity and
distribution can be achieved with some positive relation with one
another and not as a tradeoff.
Are there any New and Promising Methods for Coping with Rural
Poverty?
The trend to privatization over the 1980s and the resultant gaps in
government services have introduced a new feature which is potentially
important in alleviating rural poverty in many Third World countries.
This novel element amounts to a virtual proliferation of
nongovernmental organizations, which have appeared to act in concert
with an array of grass-roots organizations and are now serving to
organize and focus the efforts of the rural poor on solving their own
problems in certain communities. They also may serve to counteract local
elites and the tendency toward centralization of resource management
(characteristic of many Third World countries); to petition the
government or private banks for resources; and to divide, use, and
monitor inputs that are forthcoming. The function of NGOs in providing
some surveillance over factor and technology use may prove an invaluable
supplement to government extension services; for these organizations may
provide an esprit de corps for economic activity which local groups of
farmers often find missing in programmes managed by government
technicians.
While often short on capital and nontraditional in style, these
innovative organizations may stretch existing capital to more recipients
or over projects of increasingly varied risk. At the same time, NGOs can
make that expenditure more efficient by focusing it on specific poverty
groups, expanding it to new and perhaps controversial areas, and
possibly even adding a catalytic feature to the investment package.
These NGO/grass-roots organizations may indeed function as
quasi-capital, to use a term of Simon Kuznets, or even quasi-technology.
They may make it easier to mobilize and even to maximize local economic
activity because of their democratic, grass-roots, egalitarian, and
self-help characteristics.
These NGOs/grass-roots organizations tend to work on some fairly
welled-fined areas of rural development, usually among those farmers
with some resources: peasants with some land, fisherfolk with some
crafts, artisans with some skills and talent. Their efforts tend to
concern increasing farm production, adding commonly managed community
projects, augmenting women's income, enhancing environmental
protection, serving to disburse productive resources like credit, and so
on. The existing asset endowment of the poor is taken as a given, but
the participants often receive rural credit, technology, basic
information on how to access other resource pools, and so forth. Credits
rather than grants are emphasized. These programmes, projects, and
organizations frequently are sponsored by church groups, foundations,
political parties, activist assemblies of one type or another, and even
private enterprise itself.
Omissions of some groups in rural poverty in this network--the
landless peasant, especially--are also noteworthy; these latter tend to
be covered more by their inclusion in advocacy rather than
resource-enhancing areas of NGO endeavour (for example, the landless
pressing for agrarian reforms or higher wages and benefits; the
underprivileged pressing for human rights considerations, rights for
indigenous peoples, benefits for women and children, and the like). The
very fact that they are left out of these programmes re-emphasizes the
need to operate in a way that raises the incomes of those who lack basic
resources, those who, in other words, constitute the very poorest of the
rural poor.
Some elements of these programmes are appropriate for economic
analysis and, in the main, their potential for alleviation of rural
poverty has been neglected by scholars and policy-makers, though it is
significant that an article in the World Bank journal, Finance and
Development, for December 1990, called for a more serious consideration
of the issue. This report concluded, "In 1983, NGOs from developed
countries provided grants of some $ 3.6 billion (equal to 13 percent of
official development assistance), mostly raised by themselves, to
developing countries. By 1987, such NGOs were providing about $ 5.5
billion--nearly $1 billion more than credits from the International
Development Association in 1988". (49) Kenya reports 130 NGOs
interacting with 26,000 grass-roots organizations in 1988; Bangladesh
has some 10,000 NGOs, 230 of which receive foreign funds. NGOs also were
cooperating with 50 World Bank projects in 1990, and bilateral aid
programmes also use them as convenient vehicles of assistance. Of all
aid to developing countries, 64 percent is bilateral, 22 percent is
multilateral, and 14 percent is nongovernmental. Growth of the activity
of these organizations has been fairly rapid, but until lately the bulk
of their activity was so small that they could be easily neglected by
analysts.
An interest in the NGOs and in corresponding grass-roots
organizations in the alleviation of rural poverty comes not only from
the mounting size of these groups in terms of their contributions to
foreign assistance but also from their unconventional manner of
operating, from the flexibility they exhibit, from the charisma their
employees often demonstrate, and from their success in arranging the
institutional patterns necessary for small-scale development (for
example, providing an integrated package of inputs or services, from
health care to adult education and agricultural technology). The
important questions: Are there some aspects of the work which NGOs do
through their constant experimentation that are worthy of translation
into larger nationally sponsored or international efforts? Or is this
work so unique, so small, and so circumscribed that NGOs have a distinct
sphere of influence which cannot transcend local effort? Do these
organizations contain the seeds of their own destruction? Are they, in
other words, by virtue of the democratic principles which characterize
their essence, doomed to consume their scarce capital or to be riven by
internal dissension? How can these eventualities be prevented?
I contend that the NGO/grass-roots-organization programmes--which
illustrate varying, and possibly replicable, approaches to rural poverty
and which do indeed link growth with distribution and social
progress--are not sufficiently researched.
Such programmes often include the following, which deserve
attention:
1. Successful mutual-liability group efforts at lending, where the
groups themselves are the collateral;
2. Revolving credit funds which are community managed;
3. Attempts to reach the poor with education and agricultural
technology but without asset redistribution;
4. Government "service vouchers", which the public sector
distributes to target groups for technical assistance (this allows
"consumers" who are unhappy with the extension help they are
presently receiving to recur to other private groups which offer the
same service); and
5. Efforts to move higher-value crops, technology, inputs, and
credit, once open only to the richer farmers, to the poorer peasants.
To offer an example of the last-mentioned programme: traditionally,
export crops have been the domain of elite, land-rich farmers in Central
America. Recently these higher-value exportables have been moving, via
micro-programmes on private company initiative, to peasant farms, where
their cultivation raises with the following questions: (1) Are they
environmentally sound, that is, do they promote too lavish use of
chemical inputs? (2) Is contract farming, which sometimes is necessary
for the incorporation of high-value exportables into peasant farming, so
geared to the profits of large farms and/or private corporations that
the small farmers are invariably shortchanged? (3) Does high-profit
farming by small farmers so raise land prices that the gains of the few
are swamped by the losses of the poorer nonparticipants? (4) Once the
production of exportables has broken the nexus between peasants and
subsistence, are the small farmers left on such unfamiliar territory
that they end up more poorly than before?
What I have urged in this paper is something pretty homely: more
study of rural poverty issues and empirical study of programmes aimed at
helping the rural poor increase their incomes and the application of
those lessons to national development.
Comments on "Have Agricultural Economists Neglected Poverty
Issues?"
Professor Thiesenhusen has presented a radical paper. It is radical
for two reasons. One, he links poverty to the concentrated land
distribution in developing countries. And suggests we do something about
it. Two, structural adjustment, women's development, and
environmental degradation, all very pressing concerns on their own, are
here linked to poverty very significantly.
I have two comments on the paper. One, to alleviate poverty there
is a need to examine the causal mechanisms that generate poverty. So
there is need for more detail here. Two, I disagree on the potential of
NGOs in alleviating poverty in the long run. Let me take the points of
agreement and disagreement in turn.
Inequal Land Distributions
The argument for land reforms is simple and compelling. 60 to 90
percent of the hungry poor live in rural areas of less developed
countries, (LDCs). The landless and near landless are the single largest
group of the rural poor. Their underemployment and unemployment leads to
poverty. So land reforms have two arguments. Land for the land hungry
will generate a permanent income stream for them, rather than leaving
them as permanent basket welfare cases which in any case no LDC can
afford.
Land redistribution will increase the number of small farms and
reduce the number of large farms. Small farms absorb more labour per
acre. This will increase employment. And Professor Thiesenhusen shows
through the case study of Brazil, that this employment generation in the
rural areas is more cost effective than a similar effort in the urban
areas.
We do have a common worry that small farms have a higher output per
acre but a lower output per labour compared to large farms. So land
reforms will increase output per acre but reduce output per labour. But
I suggest that there are two plus points here and only one minus. Total
output will increase. And output per scarce resource, which is
productive land will increase. Labour is not a scarce resource, so if
output per labour drops this is a secondary problem to be dealt with
through technical change in the long run.
I will add that lack of credit is critical for poverty alleviation.
Imperfect credit markets bias income gains against the poor.
Structural Adjustment, Women, and Conservation Link to Poverty
Professor Thiesenhusen's survey of surveys highlights a number
of interesting findings. He emphasises that growth is not necessarily
linked to poverty alleviation. A redistribution policy is needed as in
Malaysia. He argues that poverty affects rural women and children more
than men. And that rural women's work pulls families out of
poverty.
His most radical stand is that a survey of studies shows that
poverty causes environmental degradation in a variety of ways. The
argument is that a skewed distribution of productive assets drives the
poor to strip productive assets with future potential for present
consumption, e.g., forests, uplands erosion etc.
Causal Mechanisms of Poverty
For poverty alleviation we need as detailed scenarios of poverty
generation as possible, otherwise poverty alleviation programmes will
merely treat the symptoms rather than the root causes. Taking the
example of Pakistan, I would like to emphasize one major causal
mechanism that has been at work.
In canal colonies and irrigated areas, the green revolution
technology has enhanced profitability. But landlords sharecropping out
land have only had half the increase in profitability compared to
self-cultivators. This has created a powerful incentive to evict
sharecroppers, where share rents could not be increased. This eviction has been facilitated by large horsepower tractorization. So the landless
population has increased significantly over time in the canal colonies.
In the more concentrated South and West of the country, land market
imperfections have led to an inability to evict tenants. This has led
large landlords to change the traditional sharecropping contract beyond
all recognition. This has reduced the share, income and security of the
sharecropper significantly.
NGOs
There is a Clint Eastwood film called 'The Good, the Bad and
the Ugly'. Appraisal of Pakistan's poverty alleviation NGOs
shows a few good ones, many inefficient bad ones, and mostly corrupt and
ugly ones.
The strong points of the good ones are: one, that they target
groups, and not individuals. Two, they deliver an integrated package of
inputs, rather than meeting single needs like health, or education or
food, because single needs all constrain one another.
The weak points are, one, ideological welfare motivation on the
behalf of individuals cannot be a long-run factor in eliminating
poverty. And two, corruption is a simple proportion of the size of the
budget. Presently public programmes are large, so public corruption is
high. When NGOs become large, their corruption will become high as well.
So I favour institutional structural change like redistributive
land reforms and improvement of factor markets, credit and labour.
Moazam Mahmood
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Comments on "Have Agricultural Economists Neglected Poverty
Issues?"
I find myself in broad agreement with what Professor Thiesenhusen
has stated despite our somewhat different backgrounds and experiences.
We are both structuralists in the sense that any development economist
must be a structuralist. But the structural elements that we emphasize
are very different. That is because we come from different backgrounds
of geographic emphasis. His emphasis and experience has been much more
in Latin America whereas mine has been much more in Asia and Africa.
Given my general agreement I would like to make three brief
complementary statements about the paper. One has to do with a
philosophical issue. The second has to do with the nature of the growth
processes that reduce poverty. The third concerns the circumstances in
which the poverty reducing growth may not be possible without the kind
of structural change that Professor Thiesenhusen emphasizes.
We have an immense moral problem in the world with something like a
billion people falling quite clearly under an absolute poverty line that
leaves them, in the Rawlsian sense, in an unjust, an unfair, and morally
unacceptable circumstance. This is a moral problem of such immensity that its removal must be a basic objective of the development process.
However, there is a very troubling aspect to this moral problem. It is
here that surface some of the differences in approach, derived from
differences in background, between Professor Thiesenhusen and myself.
If we face a moral problem that is to be dealt with primarily by
redistribution of assets and income within developing countries then it
is not particularly a problem of moral concern to people in the higher
income countries. However, if it must be dealt with substantially
through growth and through the broad processes of growth which require a
very substantial set of incremental resources, such that the capability
of providing those resources determines the time path over which they
are provided, then it becomes a moral problem of the rich developed
countries in which 95 to 100 percent of the population is above that
poverty line. I maintain that such growth is essential. Thus, it is very
much a moral problem of the rich countries of the world and one that
they do not face up to particularly.
Why do the developed countries, the rich countries, not face up to
this moral problem? I would assert that the vast bulk of the people in
the rich countries of the world do recognize this moral problem and
would like to deal with it. Thus, I largely dismiss the first possible
explanation. That is that people in rich countries of the world have a
nationalistic view of the world, such that poverty in other countries or
within other cultural groups, is of less consequence to them than
poverty in their own country. Since the rich countries have very little
absolute poverty by the kind of definitions that are used in this paper
they really do not see much of problem. I think that this is not true.
The polls in the United States suggest this not to be the case. For
example, 60 percent or more of the public support foreign aid in order
to reduce poverty, although much less than a majority support foreign
aid per se.
The reason for this discrepancy is the serious problem in the
developed countries of a sense of hopelessness about measures to reduce
poverty that is akin to the Malthusian view. The Malthusian view is a
hopeless view about poverty in the world. It concludes that poverty
cannot be eliminated because of processes, in the Malthusian case, of
population growth. One sees that represented in the early years of the
industrial revolution. We now have a sense of hopelessness about
developing countries ever eliminating poverty. That sense of
hopelessness is promulgated by the way the poverty issue is presented to
the developed country audience. We are constantly told that the number
of poor are expanding despite the substantial efforts and substantial
foreign assistance in the past. We are constantly having it driven home
to us that the poverty problem is a redistribution problem, not a growth
problem, and, therefore it is a problem to be solved within the
developing countries. So if one is going to have a recognition of
absolute poverty in its massive occurrence in poor countries of the
world, i.e. the one billion people, and if we are going to have a more
rapid dealing with the problem and the elimination of it through major
resource transfers in the world, one has to see it not as a hopeless
problem but one which eventually will have to be dealt with by
self-sustaining growth; a self-sustaining growth which is reached more
rapidly by resource transfers.
That brings me to the second set of comments which are about the
nature of the growth processes which can play a role in eliminating
poverty of an absolute nature over the long run. I constantly emphasize
that I am dealing with absolute poverty and not with distribution as
represented by the Gini Coefficient. The people concerned with poverty
in the foreign assistance community and even to a substantial extent
within developing countries themselves virtually never focus on this
issue of the details of the rural development strategy which would bring
about a rapid diminution in poverty. Till one focusses on that one is
dealing with rather a hopeless situation. I have tried to simplify these
down to three elements.
First is agricultural technology which requires an immense
institutional effort and institutional priorities which we do not often
see either in the multi-lateral financial institutions or even within
the bulk of the developing countries. Second is provision of rural
infrastructure, which requires massive investment, I have made a back of
the envelop estimate that in order to provide an acceptable level of
rural infrastructure for eliminating poverty will require on the order
of 300 billion dollars investment. That is obviously not an investment
that can be made in one or even in a few years. Spread over 15 years
that comes to $ 20 billion per year. Third, we have similar financial
requirements for investments of a similar magnitude to those for
infrastructure. Thus, there are very substantial investments to be made.
The flow of resources can greatly affect the time path by which one
moves along that route.
The third comment that I have to make about this paper deals with
the redistributive side, very much emphasized by Professor Thiesenhusen.
He is more on the redistributive side, and I somewhat more on the
production side. As an aside, when he mentions the views of agricultural
economists, I would not include myself. I am an economical
agriculturalist which I say only partly in jest. But I am very
production oriented. I do want to close on the note, however, that it is
perfectly clear that there are countries in which you cannot do the
sorts of productivity increasing things that an economical
agriculturalist wants done until you have a major redistribution of
assets. One of the critical issues to face up to is where is that line?
Which are the countries in which we must have a major redistribution of
assets to make growth progress. Frankly, I do not find it very helpful
to see Bangladesh, where there is hardly a holding of larger than 3-4
hectares, as a country that cannot make progress in rural development
until after a major redistribution of rural assets. I can understand
that position in an imperial period Ethiopia or in pre-Sandanista
Nicaragua. So we have a serious issue of where that line can be drawn so
we can talk about the countries where we can make a good deal of
progress with sustainable growth in eliminating poverty and the
countries where we cannot.
Thank you very much.
John W. Mellor
IFPRI, USA.
REFERENCES
Adelman, Irma (1989) Industrialization and Poverty. Address to the
Sri Lanka Economics Association, Colombo.
Barnet, Richard (1990) Defining the Moment. New Yorker 16 July.
Bautista, Germelino M. (1990) The Forestry Crisis in the
Philippines: Nature, Causes, and Issues. Developing Economies 28 :
67-94.
Bonilla, Elssy (1990) Working Women in Latin America. Economic and
Social Progress in Latin America. Washington, D. C.: Inter-American
Development Bank.
Brundtland Commission (World Commission on Environment and
Development) (1987) Our Common Future. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Burki, Shahid Javed (1988) Poverty in Pakistan. In T. N. Srinivasan and P. K. Bardhan (eds) Rural Poverty in South Asia. New York: Columbia
University Press. 69-88.
Chenery, Hollis et al. (1974) Redistribution with Growth. New York:
Oxford University Press.
de Janvry, Alain, and Elisabeth Sadoulet (1989) Investment
Strategies to Combat Rural Poverty: A Proposal for Latin American. World
Development 17 : 1203-1221.
de Tray, Dennis (1989) Reducing Poverty in Developing
Countries--Some Basic Principles for Policy Design. The Pakistan
Development Review 28 : 4 437-460.
Dixon, John A., and Louise A. Fallon (1989) The Concept of
Sustainability: Origins, Extensions, and Usefulness for Policy. Society
and Natural Resources 2 : 73-84.
Economist (1989) The Environment: A Survey. 2 September.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization) (1988) ACC Task Force on
Rural Development. Rural Development. Special Issue, February.
Foy, George and Herman Daly (1989) Allocation, Distribution and
Scale as Determinants of Environmental Degradation: Case Studies of
Haiti, El Salvador and Costa Rica. Environment Department Working Paper
No. 19. Washington, D. C.: World Bank, Policy Planning and Research
Staff.
Gaibraith, J. K. (1990) The Rush to Capitalism. New York Review of
Books 25 October 51-52.
Hecht, Susanna B. (1985) Environment, Development, and Politics:
Capital Accumulation and the Livestock Sector in Eastern Amazonia. World
Development 13 : 663-684.
Interpaks Interchange (1990) Fitting Green Revolution to Needs of
'Hungry Poor'. 7:5.
Inter-American Development Bank (1990) Economic and Social Progress
in Latin America. Washington, D. C.: IADB.
Keyfitz, Nathan (1989) The Growing Human Population. Scientific
American September 118-126.
MacNeill, Jim (1989) Strategies for Sustainable Development.
Scientific American September 154-165.
Mahar, Dennis J. (1989) Government Policies and Deforestation in
Brazil's Amazon Region. Washington, D. C.: World Bank.
(Mimeographed.)
Malik, Muhammad Hussain (1988) Some New Evidence on the Incidence
of Poverty in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 27 : 4 509-515.
Martinez-Alier, J. (1989) Poverty as a Cause of Environmental
Degradation. Draft. Washington, D. C.: (Mimeographed.)
Mellor, John (1988) Agricultural Development in the Third World:
The Food, Development, Foreign Trade Nexus. Paper prepared for the 1988
World Food Conference, 6-8 April.
N'Mi, Kebir (1990) Africa's Troubled Schools [Le Nouvel
Afrique Asie]. World Press Review December.
NRC (National Research Council) (1990) Working Group on Population
Growth and Economic Development Population Growth and Economic
Development. Washington, D. C.: National Research Council.
Painter, Michael (1988) Comanagement with Whom? Conservation and
Development in Latin America. Paper presented to symposium, Culture: The
Missing Component in Conservation and Development, held in Washington,
D. C.: 8-9 April.
Pearce, David (1989) An Economic Perspective on Sustainable
Development. Development: The Journal of the Society for International
Development 2/3
Pearce, David, Edward Barbier and Anil Markandya (1990) Sustainable
Development: Economics and Environment in the Third World. Hants, Eng.:
Edward Elgar Publishing.
Postel, Sandra (1984) Protecting Forests. In Lester R. Brown (ed)
State of the World 1984. New York: W. W. Norton for the Worldwatch
Institute.
Redclift, Michael (1987) Sustaining Development: Exploring the
Contradictions. London: Methuen.
Srinivasan, T. N., and Pranab K. Bardhan (eds) (1988) Rural Poverty
in South Asia. New York: Columbia University Press.
Stein, Leslie (1989) Third World Poverty, Economic Growth and
Income Distribution. Canadian Journal of Development Studies 10 :
225-240.
Sutton, Francis X. (1989) A World to Make: Development in
Perspective. Daedalus 118 : 11-17.
Thiesenhusen, William C. (ed) (1989) Searching for Agrarian Reform
in Latin America. Boston: Unwin Hyman.
Thiesenhusen, William C., and Jolyne Melmed-Sanjak (1990)
Brazil's Agrarian Structure: Changes from 1970 through 1980. World
Development 18 : 393-415.
Tisdell, Clem (1988) Sustainable Development: Differing
Perspectives of Ecologists and Economics, and Relevance to LDCs. World
Development 16: 373-84.
UNICEF (United Nations Children's Fund) (1990) The State of
the World's Children. New York: Oxford University Press.
Williams, Aubrey (1990) A Growing Role for NGOs in Development.
Finance and Development 27 : 31-33.
World Bank (1990) Worm Development Report 1990. Washington, D. C.:
The World Bank.
World Resources Institute (1985) Tropical Forests: A Call for
Action, Part 1. Report of the International Task Force convened by the
World Resources Institute, the World Bank, and the United Nations
Development Programme. Washington, D.C.: WRI.
(1) [MacNeill (1989), p. 156.]
(2) Agenda 2000 (1988).
(3) N'Mi (1990).
(4) [Barnet (1990), p. 60.]
(5) Ibid.
(6) de Janvry and Sadoulet (1989).
(7) [Inter-American Development Bank (1990), p. 26.]
(8) Sutton (1989).
(9) [Interpaks Interchange (1990), p. 5.]
(10) Vol. 8, No. 1 (1990).
(11) World Bank (1990).
(12) [Malik (1988) and de Tray (1989).]
(13) FAO (1988).
(14) [Bonilla (1990), pp. 221-32.]
(15) Srinivasan and Bardhan (1988).
(16) [Galbraith (1990), p. 51.]
(17) Ibid.
(18) Ibid.
(19) Thiesenhusen and Melmed-Sanjak (1990).
(20) [Bonilla (1990), p. 225.]
(21) [Brundtland Commission (1987), p. 28.]
(22) [Ibid., p. 28.] Redclift seems to agree with this definition
and also quotes G. Conway's definition: "'Sustainability
refers to the system's ability to maintain productivity in the face
of a major disturbance, such as that caused by soil erosion, farmer
indebtedness, or unanticipated drought or a new pest. The loss of
sustainability is then expressed through declining productivity or a
sudden collapse in the system" [Redclift (1987), p. 191. The matter
is again considered by Clem Tisdell (1988).
Pearce at al. (1990) define sustainability as a vector of
development characteristics that is nondecreasing over time, where
elements included in the vector (Pearce et al. (1990) include as
"elements" increases in real income per capita, improvements
in health and nutritional status, educational achievement, access to
resources, a "fair distribution of income", increases in basic
freedoms) are open to ethical debate, and where "the relevant time
horizon for practical decision-making is similarly indeterminate outside
of agreement on intergenerational objectives" [Pearce et al.
(1990), p. 3]. A key necessary condition for achieving that definition
is "non-negative change in the stock of natural resources and
environmental quality" [Ibid., p. 4]. As Pearce says elsewhere,
"Sustainable development is about being fair to the future. It is
about leaving the next generation a similar, or better, resource
endowment than that which we inherited" [Pearce (1989), p. 7].
In some contrast, Dixon and Fallon (1989) note that tradeoffs are
essential to any definition. One such exchange is regional versus
national development such as may be illustrated with a logging programme
at Bacuit Bay in the Philippines, which would generate needed foreign
exchange but reduce the fish kill and hamper tourism. While claiming
that they prefer to protect the local industries because chances of
national-level leakages are great, they remind that the more
unsustainable alternative, logging, does finance development elsewhere
in the country. Other questions are pertinent: Which alternative leaves
most resources for the next generation? How far into the future does our
concern extend--to next month, the next generation, or the next hundred
years? Then there are matters of equity and of how much net social
welfare we are ready to sacrifice for, as an example, one species that
would be rendered extinct? Are there nonnegotiable alternatives? Dixon
and Fallon show that sustainability is not self-evident and that it
involves calculations and projections; this may even mean weighing of
short-term productivity gains (and survival) against long-term
conservation.
The National Academy of Sciences reminds that the rate at which a
stock of resources is depleted depends on the rate of population growth,
income levels, and, perhaps most important, the success of the
price-induced search for more efficient ways to extract and use the
resource. "The rate of population growth, in itself, bears no
necessary relationship to the rate of depletion. Indeed, the fact that
exhaustible resource consumption is highest in economies with high
income levels means that the trends in demand for resources in developed
countries may be much more important in determining the rate of global
resource use than the trends in developing countries" [NRC (1990),
p. 15].
(23) [Brundtland Commission (1987), p. 1.]
(24) Martinez-Alier (1989).
(25) [Mahar (1989), pp. 2-3.]
(26) [Keyfitz (1989), p. 120.] In the Philippines, peasants tend to
be forced into uplands where damage may ensue. [See Bautista (1990),
especially n. 24.] Postel quotes a study by the Indian Institute of
Science, which estimated that over half the forest losses in India
between 1951 and 1976 were from conversions to agricultural land, where
primarily the landless were "encroaching on good forest to bring
land under cultivation" [Postel (1984), p. 77]. Some countries,
notably Indonesia, clear forested land to encourage the population of
more populated islands to move to islands where pressure there is less
on resources.
(27) [Martinez-Alier (1989), p. 3.]
(28) [Economist (1989), p. 9.]
(29) [Mahar (1989), p. 46.]
(30) [Martinez-Alier (1989), p. 3.]
(31) [Hecht (1985), p. 679.]
(32) [Mahar (1989), p. 3.]
(33) [World Resources Institute (1985), p. 3.]
(34) Painter (1988).
(35) [Brundtland Commission (1987), p. 141.]
(36) Foy and Daly (1989).
(37) Ibid.
(38) Author's interview with T. Miguel Pressburger, 28
November 1990.
(39) Burki (1988).
(40) Thiesenhusen (1989).
(41) [Adelman (1989), p. 2.]
(42) [Ibid., p. 5.]
(43) [Mellor (1988), p. 2.]
(44) [World Bank (1990), pp. 46-55.]
(45) [World Bank (1990), p. 51.]
(46) [UNICEF (1990), p. 1.]
(47) [Stein (1989), p. 237.]
(48) Chenery et al. (1974).
(49) [Williams (1990), p. 31.]
William C. Thiesenhusen is Professor of Agricultural Economics,
University of Wisconsin-Madison, USA.
Table 1
Small Farms * in Brazil: Input and Output, as Percent of Total
1970 1980
I. Ipput Indicators
Farms 84 82
Agricultural Land 15 12
Cropland 52 39
Capital Equipment 42 28
Labour 76 71
II. Output Indicators
Agricultural Production that is Marketed ** 80
Farm Net Income 54 50
Farm Gross Income 46 40
Source : Adapted from William C. Thiesenhusen and Jolyne
Melmed-Sanjak, "Brazil's Agrarian Structure: Changes from 1970
through 1980", World Development 18 (1990), Table 3, p. 398, which
was calculated from Censo Agropecuario, 1970, Tables 9, 27, 31, 34;
Censo Agropecuario, 1980, Tables 18, 29, 32, 33, and 34, and Table
4, p. 399.
* Under 50 Hectares.
** No data.