Fiscal imbalances as an obstacle to privatization effort.
Kemal, A.R.
I. INTRODUCTION
Pakistan has been pursuing privatization policies including market
liberalization and divestiture of public corporations for the last ten
years with a view to raising levels of investment and improving
efficiency levels. However, privatization efforts so far have not been
very successful in increasing the level of investment in the country.
The failure of privatization to boost investment in general, and private
investment in particular, is generally attributed to an ambivalent attitude of the government towards privatization. It is argued that even
though import and export policies have been liberalized, investment
sanctioning requirements have been by and large waived and price
controls have been lifted, yet the trade regime continues to be
restrictive, the establishment of large industrial projects remain
subject to investment sanctions and price controls can be invoked on one
pretext or another. Moreover, despite the government's
pronouncements no public sector corporation could be divested during the
last few years. These cast serious doubts on the efficacy of the
government's privatization policy.
Privatization, defined broadly, may not be restricted to just
divestiture; it encompasses all such measures which aim at the
enhancement of efficiency levels in the economy by restricting the size
of government economic activities and indirect public intervention in
the economy. It, therefore, is significant to examine the privatization
policies of the government with a view to determining whether the
private investment was in fact encouraged by the privatization policies
or not. It is argued that even if liberalization and divestiture
policies are pursued vigorously, the government's other policies,
particularly the huge fiscal deficit, would nullify the positive impact
of such policies on private investment. Accordingly, it is explored in
this paper to what extent efforts to enhance private investment through
privatization policies have been successful in Pakistan and to what
extent growing fiscal deficits have been responsible for the failure of
such policies.
The paper is divided into five sections. Section II examines
privatization policies pursued in the Eighties. Trends in fiscal
deficits, private investment and the transfer of private savings to the
public sector are explored in Section III. The effect of fiscal deficits
both directly and through credit rationing indirectly on private
investment is analyzed in Section IV. The Main conclusions of the study
are summarized in the final section.
II. PRIVATIZATION POLICIES IN PAKISTAN
Privatization policies pursued by the government of Pakistan may be
classified into two broad groups. The first includes policies such as
liberalizing trade regimes, easing investment licensing and extending
lavish incentives to the private investors. The second relates to
complete or partial divestiture of public investment. All these measures
aim at enhancing the profitability of private enterprises and opening up
of new areas for the private sector. In this section, privatization
policies are examined with a veiw to ascertaining whether they have
raised the profitability and/or opened new vistas for private investment
or not. It also includes discussion of various measure taken by the
government. For a detailed review, [see Heald (1989); Kemal (1989) and
UNDP (1989)].
Trade regimes have always been restrictive in Pakistan. While
import substitution industries grew at a rapid rate in their initial
stages, the high growth rates could not be sustained because of limited
domestic demand and slow growth of exports mainly due to low efficiency
levels. Besides, imports of a number of intermediate goods were not
allowed and as such the industries based on such inputs could simply not
be established in the country. Restrictions on the import of capital
goods had similar results. However, over the last five years, the
negative list of import policy has been reduced by 50 percent and
restrictions on imports of other goods have been removed. It is,
therefore, obvious that the easing of trade regimes must have helped
investments into a large number of industries.
Besides trade liberalization four other privatization measures may
have boosted private investment. Firstly, exempting all but three types
of industries and all projects not exceeding Rs 1000 million from
investment licensing. Second, simplification of investment sanctioning
procedures; the government has set up a Board of Industrial Investment
under the chairpersonship of the prime minister which meets regularly
every month and promises the decision on the approval of a project
within three months. Third, opening new areas of investment to the
private sector; for example, chemicals, light and heavy engineering,
automobiles, petrochemicals, petroleum refining, vegetable ghee and
cement not allowed to private sector since 1972 when they were
nationalized, have been opened to the private sector. Moreover, private
investment has also been encouraged in the other sectors including
energy and transport. Fourth, extremely liberal tax incentives in the
form of tax holidays, tax credits and depreciation allowances have been
provided to raise post-tax profits. Moreover, the tariff structure has
been rationalized and institutional reforms have been effected for
prompt removal of fiscal anomalies.
Divestiture policies have been pursued in Pakistan to realize
different objectives including increases in the efficiency of
operations, the alleviation of fiscal deficits and the broad-basing of
equity capital. The post-tax rate of return on equity in the public
sector during the Eighties has averaged around only 5 percent--well
below both the interest rate government offers on its financial
instruments and the average return on equity in the private sector. Such
low rates of return despite heavy protection indicate gross inefficiency
in the public sector operations. Therefore, the government decided to
divest a number of firms in the mid-Eighties. With a view to expediting
this the government also established a National Disinvestment Authority
in 1988. The authority did identify 14 loss-making industrial units with
assets of Rs 1464 million for disinvestment but these units could not be
divested due to a number of actions (or inactions) on the part of both
the private investors and the government. The investors in Pakistan seem
to have a short horizon, and as such are interested in buying only those
units which are already making profits. They do not seem to be
interested in buying loss-making units at lower prices and making
profits later through improvements in productivity. Besides the private
sector is scared away by the employment of excessive labour in the units
which they find difficult to get rid of after the take-over. Moreover,
public corporations have incurred huge debts which need to be settled.
Furthermore, the sale prices of these industrial units fixed by the
government exceeds substantially their replacement costs. It is,
therefore, no wonder that government's efforts to denationalize loss-making units have failed.
Besides complete divesture of loss-making units, the government has
also announced sale of public shares amounting to Rs 2 billion in 1985,
but has failed to divest any equity so far. Government has recently
announced the divesture of minority shares of six profit-making units.
It also intends to broad-base equity shares through divestiture. A
divestiture policy which aims at providing only minority shares has
failed to excite the private businessmen, see UNDP (1989). Similarly,
effective broad-basing of equity capital in a country with low per
capita incomes may turn out to be wishful thinking.
Despite the fact that the trade regime continues to be restrictive
and big industrial projects still require approval, there has been a
considerable liberalization of the market and the options of the private
investors have been considerably widened. The present environment is
definitely more conducive to private investment than that prevailing a
decade ago. Therefore, demand for private investment must have gone up
considerably. However, higher desired levels of investment has not led
to higher levels of investment in Pakistan.
III. TRENDS IN PRIVATE INVESTMENT AND FISCAL DEFICIT
Private investment as a percentage of both the GDP and total
investment fell in the first half of the Seventies when the government
nationalized a large number of the manufacturing industries. However,
the adoption of privatization policies in 1977-78, led to a substantial
increase in the share of the private sector by the early Eighties.
However, private investment as a percentage of GDP failed to increase
during the Eighties.
Table 1 shows that share of private investment which had declined
rather sharply from 54.8 percent in 1970-71 to 32.1 in 1974-75 rose to
39.3 percent by 1979-80. Even though it did slip down in the early
Eighties, it shows a rising trend since 1981-82. On the other hand,
after a sharp increase in the ratio of private investment to GDP from
4.6 to 6.3 percent in the second half of the Seventies, the share of the
private sector in GDP has stagnated around that level throughout the
Eighties. The somewhat constant ratio of private investment to GDP
contrasts sharply with the expected sharp increase in private investment
due to privatization policies recounted in the preceding section.
While the government pursued privatization policies in the
Eighties, budgetary deficits continued to grow rather sharply. To some
extent, the growing budgetary deficits are a reflection of tax
exemptions granted to encourage private investors. The slow growth of
public revenues and sharp increase in non-development expenditures
despite a fall in public investment resulted in sharp increases in the
overall fiscal deficit.
Table 2 shows that fiscal deficits have assumed alarming
proportions during the Eighties. These growing deficits have
necessitated the resource flow from private sector to public sector
especially because of the limited availability of external resources for
financing the budgetary deficits. That there has been a huge net
transfer of resources--equalling to one-half of private savings from the
private sector to the public sector--is quite obvious from Table 3. The
enhancing of profit rates on private investment and matching it with
higher return on its own financial assets only resulted in a higher cost
of debt servicing without any positive impact on private investment.
IV. OVERALL BUDGETARY DEFICIT, CREDIT EXPANSION AND PRIVATE
INVESTMENT
That the overall budgetary deficit has assumed grave proportions
and that it has led to huge capital transfer from private to the public
sector are evident from Tables 2 and 3. The transfer has been effected
both directly through the sale of government financial instruments and
indirectly through the advances of the banking sector to finance the
budgetary deficits.
Table 4 clearly brings out the fact that not only the public sector
has been instrumental in pre-empting large amounts of private savings,
but also relied rather heavily on bank financing. Given the
government's preference to contain the money supply for price
stability, it has had serious implications for credit availability to
the private sector.
Money supply and credit are controlled by the State Bank through a
credit plan rather than by resorting to changes in bank rate, reserve
requirements or open-market operations. Credit expansion is controlled
by setting targets of credit expansion by each financial institution and
implementing it through administrative controls. Since the main
consideration of the government has been to contain the expansion of
money supply within safe limits, the increase in credit to finance
budgetary deficit implies a reduction in the availability of credit to
the private sector. Trends in money supply, budgetary support and
private credit presented in Table 5 show that the increase in credit for
budgetary support slowed down the increase in credit to the private
sector.
In order to assess the impact of fiscal deficits on private
investment it has been postulated that the budgetary deficit affects
credit availability to the private sector which in turn is a major
factor in determining the level of private investment. In order to
analyze the impact of the budgetary deficit it has alternatively been
proxied by overall budgetary deficit, bank financing of the budgetary
deficit and total domestic financing of the deficit. Accordingly, a
two-equation recursive system has been set up as follows:
CR = F(OD, [D.sub.78) ... ... ... ... (1)
Ip = F (Y, Ig, CR, [D.sub.78]) ... ... ... ... (2)
where
Ip = Private Investment;
Ig = Public Investment;
Y = Change inGDP;
CR = Growth rate of credit; and [D.sub.78] = Dummy variable taking
value equal to one for years from 1977-78 to 1987-88.
In Equation (1), OD is alternately defined as the budgetary deficit
financed by the banking sector (BD) and the budgetary deficit financed
domestically (TD). The impact of the budgetary deficit on private
investment in the manufacturing sector (IMp) has also been analyzed.
The results show that the model fits the data quite well. A very
high proportion of variations both in the change in credit and private
investment has been explained by the variables postulated earlier. The
relationship between credit and budgetary deficit turns out to be
negative and significant irrespective of the definition of the budgetary
deficit employed.
Change in income, credit to private sector and public investment
are positive and significant variables in explaining variations in
private investment. Moreover, public investment is complementary to the
private investment but in the manufacturing sector, the two are
negatively related. It, therefore, follows that constraining aggregate
public investment instead of raising the level of private investment in
fact, may lower the aggregate private investment. Therefore, the focus
should be on restricting public investment in the manufacturing sector
only rather than restricting aggregate public investment.
Credit is positively related to aggregate private investment and to
private investment in the manufacturing sector. Since the deficit in the
budget is negatively related to credit availability to the private
sector, it implies that budgetary deficits have a negative impact on
private investment.
The most surprising result of the study is that the dummy variable
has a negative sign and is significant in case of aggregate private
investment. However, the coefficient is insignificant in case of private
investment in the manufacturing sector though the sign remains negative.
The preceding discussions lead us to an unmistakable conclusion
that the budgetary deficits have had a significant negative impact on
private investment. It is a pity that while the privatization
initiatives resulted in higher profitability, they did not lead to
higher private investment because of credit constraints necessitated by
the huge budgetary deficits. It brings out basic inconsistencies in
public policy. Moreover, higher desired investment levels generated
higher demand for credit but because of the restraints on credit it had
to be rationed. Consequently, privatization has become a source of
patronage and corruption rather than an instrument of promoting private
investment.
V. CONCLUSIONS
The main findings of the study are summarized below:
(i) Even though trade policies and investment sanctioning policies
are still restrictive they have been considerably liberalized over the
last ten years. The liberal policies along with lavish incentives to
private investment has enhanced the private profitability and hence the
demand for investment;
(ii) The divesture policies have not met with success due to
ambivalent attitude of the government;
(iii) The budgetary deficits have grown rather sharply
necessitating huge resource transfers from the private to the public
sector. The budgetary deficits have not only crowded out investible
funds from the private sector, but have also pre-empted large amounts of
bank credits;
(iv) The budgetary deficit has led to considerable slowing down of
the increase in credit to the private sector,
(v) Public investment is positively related to private investment.
However, public investment in the manufacturing sector leads to lower
private investment in manufacturing. Accordingly, rather than
restricting public investment focus should be on the changes in
composition of public investment;
(vi) The limited availability of credit to the private sector has
constrained the growth of private investment; and
(vii) The increase in demand for credit due to enhanced
profitability on private investment on the one hand and the limited
availability of credit on the other has led to credit rationing. This
leads to an unmistakable but rather unfortunate conclusion that
privatization instead of leading to higher level of investment and
efficiency has become an instrument of corruption and patronage.
Comments on "Fiscal Imbalances as an Obstacle to Privatization
Effort"
Dr Kemal's paper discusses a topical issue of relevance not
only to Pakistan but in a global context as well. The push for
privatization comes, although in different forms, from all parts of the
world--the industrial countries, the 'socialist and centrally
planned' economies and LDCs. The paper is a much needed
contribution at an appropriate time.
The paper argues that despite some liberalization of trade and
investment sanctioning policies and incentives to private investment
over the last ten years, as well as divestiture policies, the fiscal
deficits have constrained the growth of private investment by limiting
the availability of credit to the private sector. In other words, the
positive effect of privatization has been nullified by fiscal policy.
Although Dr Kemal recognizes that the trade regime continues to be
restrictive and big industrial projects subject to investment approvals,
he still concludes that the demand for private investment must have gone
up considerably. What he perhaps ignores is other factors in the
investment environment such as realities of labour laws and practices,
subsidized access to credit resources, wage and price controls, the
overall regulatory environment--all of which create special
problems--not to mention the law and order and political situation.
Accordingly, the positive effect on investment may be less than has been
claimed for these reasons.
Similarly, divestiture has been more difficult and less than was
expected. For example, 14 loss-incurring industrial units could not be
divested for various reasons. Successful divestiture releases pressures
on the budget. Its partial success, therefore, is a drain on budget and
credit resources on the one hand adding to fiscal imbalance, and on the
other dampening the increase in demand for investment. In fact, there is
a need for a case by case study of losers. Some may need to be
liquidated (those that will never succeed), some rehabilitated, some
partially privatized, some totally. If this distinction is not made,
private investment may not increase irrespective of fiscal imbalances.
This has not been discussed by the author. A related minor point is that
investors in Pakistan may not have a short horizon as claimed, but may
have the right perception that they will never make profits.
The final conclusion of the author that privatization has become an
instrument of corruption and patronage is not focussed. It is not
privatization per se but credit rationing which has led to this.
The conclusion of the author that public and private investment are
complementary on the whole but substitutes in manufacturing is an
important one but has not been substantiated. A greater disaggregation of data and a deeper analysis would be helpful.
A minor point is that the author has not highlighted why public
revenues have grown so slowly.
Yasmeen Mohiuddin
University of South Sewanee, Sewanee, Tennessee, USA.
REFERENCES
Heald, D. (1989) Privatization, Pakistan and the Global Experience.
Paper presented to Seminar sponsored by UNDP, Islamabad. March.
Kemal, A. R. (1989) Privatization--Experience of Pakistan. Paper
submitted to Seminar Organized by MARGA Institute, Colombo. June.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Ministry of Finance, Economic Adviser's Wing.
United Nations Development Programme (1989)National Seminar on
Privatization and Investment Islamabad. November.
A. R. KEMAL, The author is Chief of Research at the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Trends in Investments
Share in Total
Investment Share in GDP
Years Private Public Private Public
1960-61 57.9 42.1 7.6 5.5
1965-66 54.8 45.2 9.7 8.0
1970-71 50.1 49.9 7.0 6.9
1974-75 32.1 67.9 4.6 9.8
1979-80 39.3 60.7 6.3 11.3
1980-81 39.3 60.7 6.1 9.4
1981-82 36.4 63.6 5.6 9.7
1982-83 38.4 61.6 6.0 9.6
1983-84 40.4 59.6 6.1 9.0
1984-85 41.4 58.6 6.2 8.7
1985-86 41.2 58.8 6.1 8.7
1986-87 40.7 59.3 6.3 9.2
1987-88 42.1 57.9 6.2 8.6
Source: Based on data obtained from Economic
Survey (Various Issues).
Table 2
Fiscal Deficits in Pakistan
Fiscal Deficit as Budgetary Support as
Years Percentage of GDP Percentage of GDP
1980-81 5.3 0.8
1981-82 5.3 1.7
1982-83 7.1 1.7
1983-84 6.0 1.9
1984-85 7.7 3.9
1985-86 7.6 1.2
1986-87 7.7 1.9
1987-88 8.6 2.0
Source: Economic Survey (Various Issues).
Table 3
Net Private Savings, Private Investment and
Transfers from Private Sector
In Million Rs
Net Out-flow
Private Private from Private
Years Savings Investment Sector
1980-81 33,083 24,608 8,475
1981-82 38,747 28,570 10,117
1982-83 58,423 31,225 27,198
1983-84 60,991 36,412 24,579
1984-85 64,192 41,573 22,619
1985-86 80,809 45,959 34,850
1986-87 104,932 50,682 54,250
1987-88 111,410 58,702 52,708
1988-89 127,797 70,179 57,618
As Percentage of GDP
Net Out-flow
Private Private from Private
Years Savings Investment Sector
1980-81 11.9 8.8 3.1
1981-82 12.0 8.8 3.4
1982-83 16.0 8.8 7.4
1983-84 14.5 8.7 5.8
1984-85 13.6 8.8 4.8
1985-86 15,7 8.9 6.8
1986-87 18.3 8.9 9.4
1987-88 16.6 8.8 7.8
1988-89 16.5 9.1 7.4
Table 4
Financing of Budgetary Deficit
Financing of Budgetary Deficit
(Million Rs)
Overall External Non-Bank Bank
Years Deficit Financing Financing Financing
1980-81 14,618 7,741 4522 2355
1981-82 17,175 5,645 6014 5516
1982-83 25,639 5,700 13810 6129
1983-84 25,153 4,894 12393 7866
1984-85 36,777 5,169 12873 18735
1985-86 41,644 10,971 24575 6098
1986-87 46,710 9,522 26273 10915
1987-88 57,563 13,272 30350 13941
1988-89 51,170 15,000 32424 3746
As Percentage of Overall
Budgetary Deficit
External Non-Bank Bank
Years Financing Financing Financing
1980-81 53.0 30.9 16.1
1981-82 32.9 35.0 32.1
1982-83 22.2 53.9 23.9
1983-84 19.5 49.3 31.3
1984-85 14.1 35.0 50.9
1985-86 26.3 59.0 14.6
1986-87 20.4 56.2 23.4
1987-88 23.1 52.7 24.2
1988-89 29.3 63.4 7.3
Source: Based on Economic Survey data
(Various Issues).
Table 5
Budgetary Support and Credit to Private Sector
Increase Credit to
in Money Budgetary Private
Years Supply Support Sector
1980-81 12197 5568 6635
1981-82 11889 6756 8986
1982-83 29515 9199 10923
1983-84 17242 7513 15176
1984-85 20638 18273 13919
1985-86 27206 8623 19355
1986-87 28912 10612 21252
1987-88 29321 18324 21799
1988-89 12681 8004 18183
Source: Economic Survey (Various Issues).