The relationship between income and consumption in life cycle models.
Ahmad, Eatzaz
I. INTRODUCTION
The traditional life-cycle theory of consumption has been extended
in various directions. A major contribution to this subject is due to
Heckman (1974). He showed that under an endogenous work-leisure
decision, labour income unambiguously increases in response to
anticipated increase in the wage rate over the life cycle. Further, if
consumption and leisure are substitutes for each other, consumption also
increases over the life cycle. This explains a positive relationship
between consumption and current income in a life-cycle model. Browning,
Deaton and Irish (1985) and MaCurdy (1981, 1983, 1985) further
elaborated this theory and tested its empirical validity.
In this paper we provide an alternative interpretation to
Heckman's 0974) result. Using the class of utility functions
defined over consumption and leisure characterized by constant
elasticities of intertemporal and intratemporal substitution, we show
that the necessary and sufficient condition to have a positive
relationship between consumption and current labour income is that the
elasticity of substitution between consumption and leisure at a given
age is greater than the elasticity of substitution between consumption
(or leisure) at different ages. In addition, it is shown that the
planned savings and anticipated labour income are positively correlated over the life cycle under quite general conditions.
II. THE MODEL
Consider an individual who is to live through a certain life of
length T At each age t he has to allocate a fixed endowment of time E on
work H(t) and leisure E-H(t). We employ the class of utility functions
used by Auerbach, Kotlikoff and Skinner (1983):
U(C(t), E-H(t)) = 1/1 - 1/[sigma][[{ C(t)}.sup.1-1/[theta]] +
[alpha] [{E-H(t)}.sup.1 - 1/[sigma]].sup.1 - 1/[sigma]/1 - 1/[theta]]
... ... ... (1)
where, [sigma], [theta], [alpha] > 0. The parameter [theta] is
the (intratemporal) elasticity of substitution between consumption and
leisure at a given age, [sigma] is the (intertemporal) substitution
elasticity of consumption (or leisure) across two different ages and
[alpha] measures the intensity of preference for leisure over
consumption.
For simplicity and to avoid repetition we assume that the rate of
interest and the subjective discount rate are zero. The individual does
not receive or pay any transfers. The entireage path of the wage rate,
W(t) is known with certainty. The individual's life-cycle problem
is to maximize the lifetime utility function:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... ... ... (2)
with respect to consumption, C(t) and leisure, E-H(t) subject to
the lifetime budget constraint:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... ... ... (3)
and the boundary conditions: C(t) [greater than or equal to] 0, 0
[less than or equal to] H(t) [less than or equal to] E.
III. THE OPTIMAL SOLUTION
We solve our problem in two stages. We define the rate of
expenditure at age t in the units of consumption good, M(t)as
M(t) = C(t) + W(t) {E -H(t)} ... ... ... (4)
The lower-stage problem is to maximize utility at each age t by
choosing the rates of consumption and leisure assuming a given rate of
expenditure M(t). The resulting consumption and leisure demand functions
are substituted into the age-related utility function to obtain the
indirect utility function. In turn, the indirect utility function is
used at the upper stage to determine the optimal rates of expenditure
for different ages.
At the lower stage we have to choose C(t) and H(t) which maximize
the following Lagrange function such that [lambda](t) [greater than or
equal to] 0.
1/1 - 1/[sigma]] [[{ C(t)}.sup.1 - 1/[theta]] + [alpha] [{
E-H(t)}.sup.1 - 1/[theta]]].sup.1 - 1/[sigma]/1 - 1/[theta]] +
[lambda](t) [ M(t) - C(t) - W(t) { E-H(t)}] ... ... (5)
The parametrization of the utility function guarantees that the
constraints C(t) [greater than or equal to] 0, H(t) [less than or equal
to] E and (t) [greater than or equal to] 0 are not binding. For
simplicity we assume that H(t)
[greater than or equal to] 0 is also non-binding, that is, the
individual never retires from work. In appendix A it is shown that the
conditional consumption and leisure demand functions are
C(t) = M(t)/1 + {[W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]] [[alpha].sup.[theta]] ...
... ... ... (6)
E-H(t) = {[W(t)}.sup.-[theta]] [[alpha].sup.[theta]] M(t)/1 +
{[W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]] [[alpha].sup.[theta]] ... ... ... (7)
We can find the age-related indirect utility function by
substituting these demand functions into the utility function. The
result (derived in Appendix B) is
V(W(t), M(t)) = [ 1 + [{ W(t)}.sup.1 - [theta]]
[[alpha].sup.[theta]]].sup.1 - [sigma]/[sigma](1 - [theta])] [{
M(t)}.sup.1 - 1/[sigma]/1 - 1/[sigma] ... (8)
Notice here that the parameter o can also be interpreted as the
intertemporal substitution elasticity for expenditure.
Next, the lifetime utility function can be expressed as a function
of expenditure rates by substituting the indirect utility function into
Equation (2). Using Equation (4), we can also express the budget
constraint Equation (3) as a function of expenditure rates. The upper
stage problem is to maximize the following Lagrange function with
respect to M(t) for all t such that [lambda] [greater than or equal to]
0.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... ... (9)
Where, V(W(t), M(t)) is given by Equation (8). As before, the
boundary conditions: M(t) [greater than or equal to] 0, [lambda]
[greater than or equal to] 0 are not binding. The maximization
conditions other than the budget constraint are
[[1 + {[W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]]
[[alpha].sup.[theta]]].sup.1-[sigma]/[sigma](1-[theta])]
{[M(t)}.sup.-1/[sigma]] = [lambda] ... ... (10)
We can find a solution for M(t) conditional upon [lambda], the
marginal utility of wealth, from Equation (10) as follows:
M(t) = Z [1 + [{W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]]
[[alpha.sup.[theta]]],.sup.1-[sigma]/1-[theta]] ... ... (11)
where Z = [[lambda].sup.-[sigma]] > 0. The anticipated changes
in the wage rate over the life cycle are already incorporated into the
maximization problem and do not induce any reallocation of expenditure.
As a result [lambda], the marginal utility of wealth remains constant
[See Ahmad (1988) and MaCurdy (1981, 1983)]. Thus the
"[lambda]-constant" demand function for expenditure given by
Equation (11) contains sufficient information to study the anticipated
changes in wage rate. (1)
Finally, substituting the upper stage solution given by Equation
(11) into the lower stage solution given by Equations (6) and (7) gives
the [lambda]-constant demand functions for consumption and leisure:
C(t) = Z [1 + [{W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]]].sup.[theta]-[sigma]/1-[theta]] ... ... ... (12)
E-H(t) = Z [{W(t)}.sup.-[theta][[alpha].sup.[theta]] [1 +
[{W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]].sup.[theta]-
[sigma]/1-[theta] ... (13)
These demand functions are used to find the relationship between
the anticipated changes in income and consumption in the next section.
IV. CHANGES IN INCOME AND CONSUMPTION OVER TIME
According to Equation (13) work hours vary over the life cycle only
due to anticipated changes in the wage rate. Therefore, if the age path
of the wage rate is fully anticipated, the age path of income Y(t) =
W(t) H(t) is also known at the beginning of the horizon. The anticipated
changes in income over the life cycle are given by the following age
derivative, derived in Appendix C.
[??](t) = [H(t) + Z [{W(t)}.sup.-[theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]]
{[theta] + [sigma] [{W(t)}.sup.1- [theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]]} B(t)]
W(t) ... ... ... ... (14)
where,
B(t) = [! + [{W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]]].sup.[theta]-[sigma]/1-[theta] - 1] > 0 ... ... (15)
Equation (14) shows that income varies over the life cycle in the
same direction as the anticipated wage rate.
Next, the planned changes in consumption can be found by taking the
age derivative of Equation (12). The result is obvious:
[??](t) = ([theta]-[sigma]) Z [{ W(t)}.sup.-[theta]]
[[alpha].sup.[theta]] B(t) W(t) ... ... (16)
To find the marginal consumption rate out of anticipated income, we
divide the rate of change in planned consumption by the rate of change
in anticipated income. The result is:
dC/dt / dY/dt = ([theta] - [sigma]) Z [{
W(t)}.sup.-[theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]] B(t)/H(t) + Z [{ W(t)}.sup.-
[theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]] [[theta] + [sigma] [{
W(t)}.sup.1-[theta]][[alpha].sup.[theta]] B(t) ... (17)
From this Equation we can derive two important results.
Result 1: The marginal consumption response to anticipated income
changes is positive (negative) if and only if the intratemporal
substitution elasticity [theta] is greater (less) than the intertemporal
substitution elasticity [sigma]. If the two parameters are equal, the
marginal consumption rate would be zero.
This result is explained as follows. An anticipated increase in the
wage rate at age t affects consumption on two accounts. First, it makes
consumption cheaper relative to leisure at age t. As a result the
individual would consume more at age t. The magnitude of this effect
depends on the size of the intratemporal elasticity of substitution
between consumption and leisure, [theta]. Second, the anticipated
increase in the wage rate at age t makes expenditure (on consumption and
leisure) relatively more expensive at that age in comparison to other
ages. Therefore, the individual plans to consume less at age t. The
magnitude of this effect depends on the size of the intertemporal
substitution elasticity of expenditure (or consumption) at different
ages, [sigma]. Since income varies directly with the wage rate, the sign
of the marginal consumption response to in anticipated income follows
the pattern described above.
Result 2: The marginal consumption rate out of anticipated income
is less than one irrespective of the size of the two substitution
elasticities.
Thus, while the individual may increase consumption in response to
an anticipated increase in the wage rate under certain conditions on the
substitution elasticities, he will increase savings under more general
conditions.
V. CONCLUSIONS
A life-cycle model of consumption and work hours is studied. Using
the class of utility functions with constant intertemporal and
intratemporal elasticities of substitution, changes in labour income and
consumption over the life cycle are derived. It is shown that the
marginal propensity to consume out of anticipated labour income is
positive if and only if the (intratemporal) elasticity of substitution
between consumption and leisure at a given age is greater than the
(intertemporal) elasticity of substitution between expenditure on
consumption and leisure across two different ages. In addition, it is
shown that the marginal propensity to save out of anticipated labour
income is positive under quite general conditions. This supports the
idea that the Keynesian Absolute Income Hypothesis of the consumption
function can be supported even in the life-cycle context.
Comments on "The relationship between income and consumption
in life cycle models"
Let me start by saying that the paper by Dr Ahmad is an interesting
and useful contribution to the debate on the relationship between income
and consumption. The recent interest over this relationship is partly
due to the paper by Lester Thurow in an 1969 issue of the American
Economic Review in which he presented empirical evidence supporting a
positive relationship between income and consumption. Thus,
contradicting the life-cycle consumption theory which predicts no
necessary relationship between consumption and income at any age. Lester
Thurow explained this positive relationship in terms of credit market
restrictions by arguing that credict market restrictions prevent
consumers from borrowing as much against their future income as they
desire at the going interest rate. Since income tends to increase with
age and discounted future income cannot be fully transferred at the
borrowing rate, this leads to an increase in the consumer's net
worth which causes consumption to increase with age. Nagatani (1972) has
explained the same phenomenon in terms of uncertainty of future income
by arguing that a typical consumer buys less than he would in a riskless
environment with the same expected income. However, consumption plans
are successfully revised once expected income is realized. Subsequently,
Heckman (1974) presented an alternative neo-classical model to explain
Thurow's result. Rather than resorting to credit market
restrictions or uncertainty, Heckman treats earnings as resulting from a
life-cycle labour supply decision, where individuals are free to set
their hour of work and wage rate change systematically over the life
cycle. Heckman demonstrates that in such an environment the consumption
path of market goods depend on the wage rate at each age. Heckman in his
paper considered a very general form of the utility function to show the
positive relation between income and consumption. Dr Ahmad in his paper
has considered a very specific form, namely the constant elasticity of
substitution, to derive the necessary and sufficient condition for a
positive relation between income and consumption. I would imagine that
it should be possible to obtain similar conditions by considering
different forms of the utility function.
Let me now turn to some specific comments on the paper.
Although the type of model employed in the paper has been widely
used in many other studies, the specific form adopted in this paper is
highly simplistic. For instance, both the interest rate and the rate of
time preference are assumed to be zero. Similarly, initial wealth has
been excluded from the analysis. However, because of the model being
simplistic the results holds under some very special circumstances. For
instance, within the life-cycle framework, the positive relationship
between income and consumption holds only if the interest rate equals
the rate of time preference, i.e., as long as the consumers are at a
steady state equilibria. It has been shown elsewhere that if the
interest rate and the rate of time preference differ, the association
between income and consumption is not precise. Since the author has used
a specific form of the utility function it would be interesting to know
whether in a more general case the positive relation between income and
consumption is possible over certain ranges of values of the parameters.
While the condition for positive relation between income and
consumption, derived in this paper is important in its own right, it
would be interesting to know under what sort of circumstances this is
likely to hold and what policy implications are likely to emerge.
Finally, it has also been shown in the paper that under quite
general circumstances, planned savings and anticipated labour income are
positively correlated. With both interest rate and the rate of time
preference assumed to be zero, it is not clear that in the model what
motivates the consumers to save.
Nadeem A. Burney
Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad.
Appendix
A. THE DEMAND FUNCTIONS AT THE LOWER STAGE
The maximizing conditions for the Lagrange problem Equation (5)
are:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... ... (A1)
We can eliminate k(t) by taking ratio on the two sides of the first
two equations. The result after simplification is:
C(t) = (W(t)/[[alpha]}.sup.[theta]] {E-H(t)} ... ... ... (A2)
Solving Equations (A1) and (A2) simultaneously gives the lower
stage solution in terms of the conditional demand functions for
consumption and leisure given by Equations (6) and (7) respectively.
B. THE INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTION
To find the indirect utility function we substitute the consumption
and leisure demand functions ((6) and (7)) into the utility function (1)
as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Simplifying further, we obtain the indirect utility function (8).
C. THE AGE PATHS OF WORK HOURS AND INCOME
Differentiate Equation (13) with respect to t, we find the age path
of work hours:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Collecting the common terms on the right hand side, we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A4)
where, B(t) is given by Equation (15).
Next, the age derivative of income Y(t) = W(t)H(t)is [??](t) =
H(t)[??](t)+W(t)[??](t) which can be inferred from (A4). The result is
given by Equation (14).
REFERENCES
Ahmad, E. (1988) Consumption and Work Hours in Life Cycle Models
under Uncertain Lifetimes: An Individual Analysis and an Equilibrium
Analysis with Overlapping Generations. Unpublished Ph D. Dissertation,
Department of Economics, McMaster University.
Auerbach, A. J., L. J. Kotlikoff and J. Skinner (1983) The
Efficiency Gains from Dynamic Tax Reform. International Economic Review
24 : 1 81-100.
Browning, M. J., A. Deaton and M. Irish (1985) A Profitable
Approach to Labour Supply and Commodity Demands over the Life-cycle.
Econometrica 53 : 3 503-543.
Fisher, I. (1930) The Theory of Interest. New York: The Macmillan
Company.
Friedman, M. (1957)A Theory of Consumption Function. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Heckman, J. J. (1974) Life Cycle Consumption and Labour Supply: An
Explanation of the Relationship between Income and Consumption over the
Life Cycle. American Economic Review 64 : 1 188-194.
MaCurdy, T. E. (1981) An Empirical Model of Labour Supply in a
Life-cycle Setting. Journal of Political Economy 89 : 6 1059-1085.
MaCurdy, T. E. (1983) A Simple Scheme For Estimating an
Intertemporal Model of Labour Supply and Consumption in the Presence of
Taxes and Uncertainty. International Economic Review 24 : 2 265-289,
MaCurdy, T. E. (1985) Interpreting Empirical Models of Labour
Supply in an Intertemporal Framework with Uncertainty. In J. J. Heckman
and B. Singer (eds) Longitudinal Analysis of Labour Market Data.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Modigliani, F., and R. Brumberg (1954) Utility Analysis and the
Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross-section Data. In K. K.
Kurihara (ed) Post-Keynesian Economics, 1954. New Brunswick, New York:
Rutgers University Press.
(1) The term "[lambda]-constant" is due to MaCurdy
(1981). He derived the [lambda]-constant demand functions for
consumption and leisure to study the response of consumption and work
hours to anticipated changes in wage rate over the life-cycle.
EATZAZ AHMAD, The author is Assistant Professor at the Department
of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Ishmabad.