Macroeconomic policy and private investment in Pakistan.
Khan, Ashfaque H.
This paper demonstrates that a theoretically consistent investment
function for a developing country like Pakistan can be specified and
estimated. A variant of the flexible accelerator model was modified to
incorporate the special features of developing countries. Within the
framework of the model thus derived, the impact of fiscal and monetary
policies on private investment has been examined.
I. INTRODUCTION
Ever since the publication of Jorgenson's (1967, 1971) seminal contributions, the neoclassical model of investment has served as a
theoretical foundation for estimating investment function in
industrialized countries. In the case of developing countries, however,
there exists a large gap between the modern theory of investment and the
investment functions that have been estimated. (1)
The purpose of this paper is as follows: First, to specify and
estimate a theoretically consistent private investment function for
Pakistan. As the Jorgenson type neoclassical model of investment cannot
be applied as such to Pakistan, (2) a variant of flexible accelerator
model will serve as theoretical foundation for our empirical investment
function. Second, we extend the work of earlier authors (3) by
specifying and estimating private investment in disaggregated form.
Third, within the framework of the model derived, the impact of monetary
and fiscal policies on private investment will be examined. Since
monetary policy in Pakistan has been implemented through the use of
credit rationing, bank credit to the private sector will serve as an
instrument of monetary policy. Public sector investment, on the other
hand, will serve as an instrument of fiscal policy. This will also
enable us to shed light on the issue of substitution and complementary
roles of public investment in Pakistan. (4, 5)
The plan of the paper is as follows: In Section II we discuss the
theoretical foundation of the model relevant to developing countries.
Data and its sources are also discussed briefly in the same section. The
results corresponding to the derived model are presented in Section III.
The last section deals with concluding remarks and the policy
implications of the research.
II. MODEL SPECIFICATION
The standard neoclassical optimizing investment model cannot be
applied as such to Pakistan because of the various institutional and
structural difficulties listed above. The model of private capital
formation which we intend to develop here is, therefore, a variant of
the flexible accelerator type. The roles of fiscal and monetary
authorities are explicitly introduced within the framework of the
derived model.
The production technology for our model is assumed to have fixed
proportions among factor inputs. The choice of technique is simply based
on its relative simplicity because factor prices do not enter into the
specification and is not subject to arguments against its use in an
underutilization situation. (6) The long-run version of the accelerator
principle can be derived from the underlying technology by assuming that
desired capital stock ([K.sup.*.sub.t]) is proportional to expected
output ([y.sup.e.sub.t]),
[K.sup.*.sub.t] = [alpha][y.sup.e.sub.t] ... ... ... ... (1)
The adjustment of capital stock to its desired level is assumed to
occur with a lag. Thus, we specify an adjustment mechanism as
[DELTA][K.sub.t] = [beta]([K.sup.*.sub.t] - [K.sub.t-1]) ... ...
... ... (2)
or
[K.sub.t] = [beta]([K.sup.*.sub.t] + (1 - [beta])[K.sub.t-1]) ...
... ... (3)
where [K.sub.t] is the actual capital stock; therefore,
[DELTA][K.sub.t] is net private investment, and [beta] is the adjustment
parameter such that 0 [less than or equal to] [beta] [less than or equal
to] 1. Gross private investment is defined as
[I.sup.p.sub.t] = [DELTA][K.sub.t] + [delta][K.sub.t-1] ... ... ...
... (4)
where [delta] is the rate of depreciation. Equation (4) can also be
written as
[I.sup.p.sub.t] = [1 - (1 - [delta])L][K.sub.t] ... ... ... ... (5)
where L is a lag operator i.e. [LK.sub.t] = [K.sub.t-1]. Writing
Equation (5) in terms of [K.sub.t] we have
[K.sub.t] = [I.sup.p.sub.t] / [1 - (1 - [delta])L] and [K.sub.t-1]
= [I.sup.p.sub.t-1] / [1-(1 - [delta])L] ... ... (6)
Substituting Equation (6) into Equation (3) we have
[I.sup.p.sub.t] / [1 - (1 - [delta])L = [beta] [K.sup.*.sub.t] +
(1-[beta]) [I.sup.p.sub.t-1] / [1 - (1 - [delta])L] ... ... (7)
Solving Equation (7) we get
[I.sup.p.sub.t] = [beta] [1 - (1 - [delta])L] [K.sup.*.sub.t] + (1
- [beta]) [I.sup.p.sub.t-1] ... ... (8)
An alternative way to derive Equation (8) is to specify a partial
adjustment mechanism directly for private investment, i.e.,
[DELTA] [I.sup.p.sub.t] = [beta] [[[??].sup.p.sub.t] -
[I.sup.p.sub.t-1]] ... ... ... ... (9)
where [[??].sup.p.sub.t]; is the desired level of private
investment. In the steady state desired private investment is given as
[[??].sup.p.sub.t] = [1 - (1 - [delta])L][K.sup.*.sub.t] ... ...
... ... (10)
If we combine Equations (9) and (10) and solve for [I.sup.p.sub.t]
we get Equation (8).
We now depart from the traditional optimizing model of the
neoclassical tradition and follow the approach suggested by Coen (1971),
where it is argued that in order to achieve the desired level of
investment, private investors react to the gap between desired and
actual investment, as measured by the [beta] coefficient. We argue that
the reaction of private investors depends upon three main factors: (1)
general market conditions; (2) the availability of bank credit to the
private sector; and (3) the level of public sector investment. Thus, the
coefficient of adjustment, [beta], is specified as a function of these
three factors in relation to the discrepancy between the desired and
actual investment.
[beta] = [[PSI].sub.0] + 1 / [[??].sup.p.sub.t] - [I.sup.p.sub.t-1]
[[[PSI].sub.1][G.sub.y] + [[PSI].sub.2][DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] +
[[PSI].sub.3] [I.sub.go] ... (11)
The choice of general market condition ([G.sub.y]) as an argument
in Equation (11) is made on the assumption that the private investor
would respond quickly to changes in desired investment if market
conditions are favourable. Assuming the trend level of gross domestic
product (GDP) as an indicator of full capacity, if actual GDP exceeds
capacity output the private investor's reaction to the gap between
the desired and actual investment would be slower. On the other hand, if
actual GDP falls short of the full capacity level, the private investor
would react sharply to the discrepancy between the desired and actual
investment. Hence, the effect of general market conditions on private
investment is at best ambiguous.
The choice of bank credit to the private sector
([DELTA][C.sup.r.sub.p]t) as an argument in Equation (11) is made on the
basis of a vast body of literature on "financial repression".
McKinnon (1973); Shaw (1973); Fry (1980, 1982) and Galbis (1979) have
argued that low nominal interest rates, interest rate ceilings combined
with high and variable rates of inflation have retarded the process of
financial deepening in many developing countries. In the case of
Pakistan, financial repression has been prevalent since its inception.
The government for a variety of reasons, always keeps the real interest
rate low which impedes financial deepening, capital formation and
growth. The money or capital market remains relatively less developed
and the interest rate is not determined by the free play of market
forces rather it is administered by the monetary authorities, therefore,
it does not reflect the true cost of financing investment. (7)
Second, in the traditional Keynesian model the link between the
real and monetary sectors are provided by the rate of interest via its
effect on investment. This has been the standard approach in the model
for developed countries because of the very nature of the well-organized
capital market. This link seems to be inapplicable in the model for
developing economies. Thus, bank credit in the investment function
actually provides a link between the real and monetary sectors. In doing
so it is also clear that monetary policy can have a direct influence on
the rate of private investment.
The choice of public investment ([I.sub.go]) as an argument in
Equation (11) is made on the following grounds. It is a well-accepted
proposition that in developing countries both private and public sector
investment play important roles in the country's economic
development. Pakistan, being a mixed economy, is a typical example of
the above proposition. However, there exists a disagreement as to
whether on balance, public sector investment raises or discourages
private investment. Ahluwalia (1982) and Srinivasan and Narayana (1977),
on the one hand, argue that public investment not only provides supply
of crucial inputs such as irrigation, power, transport and
communication, thereby encouraging private investment, but also augments
aggregate demand. Hence, their views project complementarity between
public and private investment.
On the other hand, Sundararajan and Thakur (1980) argue that public
investment exerts a negative influence on private investment. Their
argument is based on the fact that both private and public sectors
compete for a limited amount of physical and financial resources and
because of its dominating role in developing countries, the public
sector siphons resources for its use through licensing and other
controls. Their views suggest a substitutability between the public and
private sectors.
It is clear that the issue is an empirical one, and private
investment must be studied at a disaggregated level. A distinction must
be drawn between agriculture and manufacturing sectors to obtain a
proper perspective of the dominance of complimentarity and
substitutability. Therefore, the purpose of including public investment
in the private investment function is to analyse the above issue for
Pakistan.
On the basis of the above arguments, we now complete the
specification of the private investment function. Substitute Equation
(11) into Equation (9) to get
[DELTA][I.sup.p.sub.t] = {[[PSI].sub.0] + 1 / [[??].sup.p.sub.t] -
[I.sup.p.sub.t-1] ([[PSI].sub.1][G.sub.y] +
[[PSI].sub.2][DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] + [[PSI].sub.3][I.sub.go])}
([[??].sup.p.sub.t] - [I.sup.p.sub.t-1]) ... ... ... ... (12)
Simplifying Equation (12), we get
[I.sup.p.sub.t] = [[PSI].sub.0] [[??].sup.p.sub.t] +
[[PSI].sub.1][G.sub.y] + [[PSI].sub.2][DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] +
[[PSI].sub.3][I.sub.go] + (1 - [[PSI].sub.0]) [I.sup.p.sub.t-1] ... (13)
Substitute Equation (10) into Equation. (13) to get
[I.sup.p.sub.t] = [[PSI].sub.0][1 - (1 - [delta])L][K.sup.*.sub.t]
+ [[PSI].sub.1][G.sub.y] + [[PSI].sub.2][DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] +
[[PSI].sub.3][I.sub.go] + (1 - [[PSI].sub.0]) [I.sup.p.sub.t-1] ... ...
... ... (14)
If we substitute the desired demand for capital stock given in
Equation (1) into Equation (14), we get a basic dynamic accelerator
model for private investment fully consistent with theory.
[I.sup.p.sub.t] = [alpha][[PSI].sub.0] [1 - (1 -
[delta])L][y.sup.e.sub.t] + [[PSI].sub.1][G.sub.y] + [[PSI].sub.2]
[DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] + [[PSI].sub.3][I.sub.go] + (1 -
[[PSI].sub.0])[I.sup.p.sub.t-1] ... ... ... ... (15)
Since the issue of complementary and substitution roles of public
sector investment is central to our discussion, following Blejer and
Khan (1984), we also use both the level ([I.sub.go]) and changes in
public, investment ([DELTA][I.sub.go]) to influence the coefficient of
adjustment [beta] in Equation (11). By doing so, our private investment
function is extended to
[I.sup.p.sub.t] = [alpha][[PSI].sub.0][1 - (1 -
[delta])L][y.sup.e.sub.t] + [[PSI].sub.1][G.sub.y] + [[PSI].sub.2]
[DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] + [[PSI].sub.3][I.sub.go] +
[[PSI].sub.4][DELTA][I.sub.go] + (1 - [[PSI].sub.0]) [I.sup.p.sub.t-1]
... ... ... ... (16)
A priori, we expect the following signs for the coefficients
[alpha][[PSI].sub.0] > 0; [alpha][approximately equal to] 1;
[[PSI].sub.1] [??] 0; [[PSI].sub.2] > 0; [[PSI].sub.3] [??] 0;
[[PSI].sub.4] [??] 0
To make our specification straight, the unobservable expected
output ([y.sup.e.sub.t]) has to be transformed into observable one.
There are various methods of transformation that have been used in the
literature. (8) The most widely used method is the adaptive expectations model given by Cagan (1956) in which the expected output depends upon
its previous expected value and upon the fractional difference between
the actual output and its previous expected output, i.e.,
[DELTA][y.sup.e.sub.t] = [lambda][[y.sub.t] - [y.sup.e.sub.t-1]]
... ... ... ... (17)
where [lambda] is the coefficient of expectations which is always
positive and less than unity, i.e. 0 [less than or equal to] [lambda]
[less than or equal to] 1. Using lag-operator notation we can write
Equation (17) as
[y.sup.e.sub.t] = [lambda][y.sub.t[??]] + [(1-[lambda])L]
[y.sup.e.sub.t] ... ... ... (18)
Further manipulation of Equation (18) yields
[y.sup.e.sub.t] = [lambda][y.sub.t] / [1 - (1 - [lambda])L] ... ...
... ... (19)
We substitute Equation (19) in Equations (15) and (16) to get
Equations (21) and (22). (9)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)
After some tedious calculation we arrive at Equation (21)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)
By substituting Equation (19) in Equation (16) and going through
tedious calculation we arrive at Equation (22).
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (22)
Although Equations (21) and (22) represent the specification of
aggregate private investment function we use the same specification for
private investment in manufacturing and agricultural sectors. By doing
so, we implicitly assume the same technology for agriculture,
manufacturing and for the private sector economy as a whole. As
mentioned earlier, the choice of technology is made on the basis of its
simplicity because no matter what technology we use, it will only be an
approximation [see Klein (1974)].
Data
The quality of empirical research depends on the quality of the
data base. In a developing country like Pakistan one would expect
serious deficiencies in the basic quality of economic data. In recent
years, however, the data base of Pakistan has considerably improved. For
our purposes, the data regarding all the variables for the period
1959-60 to 1985-86 are taken from Pakistan Economic Survey, 1986-87 and
are restated in constant prices of 1959-60. Since the consistent
time-series data for investment (both private and its various components
and public investment) are published by government sources only from the
period 1963-64 onward, therefore, for the period 1959-60 to 1962-63,
these are taken from Naqvi et al. (1983).
As regards public sector investment, a clear distinction is made
between the public sector investment in infra-structural development and
in the manufacturing sector. For our purpose, we use the former one
because this is more akin to government's fiscal duty. Furthermore,
public sector investment in manufacturing is the postnationalization
(1972 onward) phenomenon and the series have fluctuated irratically.
As regards the variable to represent general market condition we
use the difference between actual and trend GDP. The trend level of GDP
is calculated as [y.sub.T] = [y.sub.o][e.sup.gt] where [y.sub.T] is the
trend GDP, [y.sub.o] is the initial value of GDP (in our case the GDP in
the year 1959-60), g is the average growth rate of GDP and t is the
linear time trend. The general market condition ([G.sub.y]), therefore,
is calculated as [G.sub.y] = t - [y.sub.T] where y is actual GDP. For
the rate of depreciation ([delta]) that appears in Equations (21) and
(22) we use an arbitrary value of 5 percent per year because no such
rate is available from government sources. (10) The first term in
Equations (21) and (22) is calculated as follows.
[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [y.sub.t] - (1 - 0.05) [y.sub.t-1] ... ... ...
(23)
If we use Equation 17(a) as an adaptive expectations model then
Equation (23) would be written as
[DELTA][y.sub.t-1] = [y.sub.t-1] - (1-0.05) [y.sub.t-2] ... ... ...
(24)
III. RESULTS
Aggregate private investment function as well as private investment
in manufacturing and agriculture given in Equations (21) and (22) are
estimated by using annual time-series data for the period 1959-60 to
1985-86 with the help of Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) technique. (11)
The results corresponding to aggregate private investment are reported
in Table 1. It can be seen from the result that the coefficient of
changes in output, though possess an expected positive sign, failed to
reach the 5 percent level of significance in both the specification. The
short-run accelerator coefficient is similar in both the specification.
Unlike Blejer and Khan (1984) the response of private investment to
the general market condition appears to be strong as the coefficient for
this variable ([G.sub.y]) is statistically significant at the 5 percent
level across specifications. The coefficients are more or less same
across specifications and possess a positive sign. This is an important
finding as it suggests that the economy has been operating below the
capacity level and as such private investors tend to react quickly in a
situation of excess capacity.
As regards the effects of changes in bank credit to the private
sector on private investment it can be seen from the results that the
coefficient for this variable is statistically significant at the 5
percent level and bears a positive sign. This result implies a direct
role of monetary policy in influencing private investment behaviour.
Since monetary policy in Pakistan has been implemented through the use
of credit rationing, for such type of policies to work financial markets
must be kept segmented and restricted [see Fry (1982)]. This finding, in
a way confirms the existence of financial repression in Pakistan.
Furthermore, given the limited amount of financial resources available
if government attempts to siphon the resources by dint of its dominant
role it will adversely affect private investment and most likely would
lead to a fall in total investment as well.
In order to determine whether public investment ([I.sub.go]) is a
complement or substitute for private investment, this variable was
introduced in the investment function. It can be seen that the
coefficient for the variable ([I.sub.go]) turned out to be statistically
significant with a positive sign, hence confirming its complementary
role in the case of Pakistan. This finding supports the argument of
Ahluwalia (1982) and Srinivasan and Narayana (1977) while it differs
with Sundararajan and Thakur (1980) and Blejer and Khan (1984). The
coefficient for public sector investment is large and establishes a
relatively important role for this sector in the process of private
sector capital formation. This finding is true across the various
specifications. However, on the other hand, the coefficient for changes
in public sector investment ([delta][I.sub.go]) turned out to be
statistically significant with a negative sign implying a substitution
role in Equation (22). This finding is consistent with Blejer and Khan
(1984) and suggests that if government diverges from the established
investment pattern on infrastructure this would crowd out private
investment.
Private Investment in Disaggregated Form
The results corresponding to private investment in manufacturing
and agriculture for the general form of Equations (21) and (22) are also
reported in Table 1. It can be seen from the results that like total
private investment the accelerator coefficients of manufacturing and
agriculture though bear a positive sign are statistically insignificant
across the different specifications. The response of private investment
in manufacturing to the general market condition appears to be strong as
the coefficient for this variable ([G.sub.y]) is statistically
significant at the 5 percent level only in the extended specification
i.e. Equation (22). Like total private investment the coefficient of
[G.sub.y] bears a positive sign and suggests that our manufacturing
sector has been operating below the full capacity level. The private
investor tend to react quickly in a situation of excess capacity. The
situation is, however, quite different in the case of private investment
in agriculture where the coefficient of [G.sub.y] is statistically
significant with the negative sign only in the extended specification.
The negative sign implies that our agricultural sector has been
operating above capacity and investment in this sector was constrained by resource availability. (12)
As regards the availability of funds to the private investor in
these two sectors it can be seen that the coefficients of changes in
bank credit to the private sector bear a positive sign and are
statistically significant at the 5 percent level across specification
only in the manufacturing sector. In the case of the agricultural sector
the coefficient is statistically significant at the 10 percent level
only in the extended specification. (13) These results indicate that the
monetary authority can influence private investment in the manufacturing
sector by the use of bank credit (monetary policy). However, the effect
of monetary policy on private investment in the agricultural sector
appears to be weak.
Fiscal policy on the other hand, appears to have a strong influence
on private investment in the manufacturing and agriculture sectors. The
coefficients of public sector investment ([I.sub.go]) are statistically
significant at the 5 percent level across specifications and sectors. It
is important to note that the coefficients of [I.sub.go] have positive
signs and hence, confirm the complementary role of public sector
investment even at the disaggregated level. This finding suggests a
relatively important role for fiscal policy in the process of private
sector capital formation. Unlike total private investment, the
substitution role of changes in public sector investment
([delta][I.sub.go]) could not be confirmed in the disaggregated level.
The coefficients of [delta][I.sub.go], though bearing a negative sign,
were statistically insignificant. The coefficients of the lagged private
investment in both the sectors are statistically significant at the 1
percent level and it takes approximately three years in the case of the
manufacturing sector and two years in the case of the agriculture sector
to adjust between the actual and desired level of investment due to
variation in output. (14)
IV. CONCLUDING REMARKS
While it has been demonstrated that a theoretically consistent
investment function for a developing country like Pakistan can be
specified and estimated, the major findings of this paper can be
summarized as follows:
(i) On the one hand, changes in output appear to have minor impact
on private investment while on the other hand, the general market
condition appears to have a strong influence on private capital
formation. It is also found that Pakistan's economy with the
exception of the agricultural sector has been operating below full
capacity levels and, thus the private investor tends to react quickly in
a situation of excess capacity.
(ii) Private investment in Pakistan is found to be constrained by
the availability of funds. Thus, the monetary authority can influence
private investment behaviour by changing bank credit to this sector.
Fiscal policy appears to have a relatively stronger effect on private
investment.
It is also found that public sector investment in providing
infrastructure clearly augments private capital formation in
Pakistan thereby confirming its complementary role.
As regards the policy implications of the analysis it is clear that
the proper use of bank credit as a policy instrument can influence the
level of private capital formation in Pakistan. Credit rationing which
is itself a component of financial repression is a major impediment to
financial deepening, hence to savings, investment and growth, the
interest rate should be left to find their equilibrium levels in a free
market environment. With respect to fiscal policy, public sector
investment is found to play an important role in augmenting private
capital formation. A reduction in investment on infrastructure by this
sector as a policy would discourage private investment and may retard
growth.
REFERENCES
Akluwalia, I. J. (1982). "Industrial Performance in India,
1959-60 to 1978-79: An Analysis of Deceleration in Growth since the
Mid-Sixties". New Delhi: Indian Council for Research on
Internations Economic Relations. (Mimeographed)
Bhattacharya, B. B. (1984). Public Expenditure, Inflation and
Growth: A Macroeconometric Analysis for India. Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Bischoff, C. W. (1971). "Business Investment in the 1970s: A
Comparison of Models". Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Vol.
1.
Blejer, M. I., and Mohsin S. Khan (1984). "Government Policy
and Private Investment in Developing Countries". IMF Staff Papers.
Vol. 31, No. 2.
Cagan, P. (1956). "The Monetary Dynamics of
Hyperinflation". In Milton Friedman (ed.), Studies in the Quantity
Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Coen, R. M. (1971). "The Effect of Cash Flow on the Speed of
Adjustment". In Gary Fromm (ed.), Tax Incentives and Capital
Spending. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Edwards, S., and Mohsin S. Khan (1985). "Interest Rate
Determination in Developing Countries: A Conceptual Framework". IMF
Staff Papers. Vol. 32, No. 3.
Fry, Maxwell J. (1980). "Saving, Investment, Growth and the
Cost of Financial Repression". World Development. Vol. 8, No. 4.
Fry, Maxwell J. (1982). "Models of Financially Repressed Developing Economies". World Development. Vol. 10, No. 9.
Galbis, Vic.ente (1979). "Money, Investment and Growth in
Latin America, 1961-1973". Economic Development and Cultural
Change. Vol. 27, No. 3.
Hall, R. E. (1977). "Investment, Interest Rates, and the
Effects of Stabilization Policies". Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity. Vol. 1.
Jorgenson, D. W. (1967). "The Theory of Investment
Behaviour". In R. Ferber (ed.), Determinants of Investment
Behaviour. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Jorgenson, D. W. (1971). "Econometric Studies of Investment
Behaviour: A Survey". Journal of Economic Literature. Vol. IX, No.
4.
Khan, Ashfaque H. (1987). "A Macroeconometric Study of the
Growth Prospects of Pakistan's Economy". Unpublished Ph.D.
Dissertation, The Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, U.S.A.
Khilji, Nasir M. (1982). "Growth Prospects of a Developing
Economy: A Macroeconometric Study of Pakistan". Unpublished Ph.D.
Dissertation, McMaster University, Canada.
Klein, Lawrence R. (1974). "Issues in Econometric Studies of
Investment Behaviour". Journal of Economic Literature. Vol. XII,
No. 1.
Krishnamurty, K., and V. Pandit (1985). Macroeconometric Modelling
of the Indian Economy: Studies on Inflation and Growth. Delhi: Hindustan
Publishing Corporation.
Lanyi, A., and Rusdu Saracoglu (1983). "The Importance of
Interest Rates in Developing Economies". Finance and Development.
Vol. 20, No. 2.
McKinnon, Ronald I. (1973). Money and Capital in Economic
Development. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Mikhail, W. M. (1985). "A Standard Aggregative Model for the
Jordanian Economy". International Journal of Middle East Studies.
Vol. 17.
Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider, and Ather Maqsood Ahmed (1986).
Preliminary Revised P.I.D.E. Macro-econometric Model of Pakistan's
Economy. Islamabad. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider, Ather Maqsood Ahmed and Ashfaque H. Khan
(1984). "Possibilities of Regional Trade Expansion: A Link Model
for Pakistan, India, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka". Pakistan
Development Review. Vol. XXIII, No. 1.
Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider, Ashfaque H. Khan, N. M. Khilji, and A. M.
Ahmed (1983). The P.I.D.E. Macro-econometric Model of Pakistan's
Economy. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
Rashid, M. A. (1984). "Modelling the Developing Economy: The
Philippines". The Developing Economies. Vol. XXII, No. 3.
Shaw, Edward S. (1973). Financial Deepening in Economic
Development. New York: Oxford University Press.
Srinivasan, T. N., and N. S. S. Narayana (1977). "Economic
Performance since the Third Plan and its Implications for Policy".
Economic and Political Weekly. Annual Number.
Sundararajan, V., and S. Thakur (1980). "Public Investment,
Crowding out and Growth: A Dynamic Model Applied to India and
Korea". IMF Staff Papers. Vol. 27, No. 4.
Wai, U. Tun, and Churng-Huey Wong (1982). "Determinants of
Private Investment in Developing Countries". Journal of Development
Studies. Vol. 19, No. 1.
(1) For example, Naqvi et al. (1983), Naqvi et al. (1984), Naqvi
and Ahmed (1986), Khilji (1982), Krishnamurty and Pandit (1985), Mikhail
(1985), Rashid (1984) and Bhattacharya (1984) have all estimated
investment functions with no sound theoretical foundation.
(2) For more on this issue see Blejer and Khan (1984), Wai and Wong
(1982) and Sundararajan and Thakur (1980).
(3) See for example Sundararajan and Thakur (1980), Wai and Wong
(1982), Blejer and Khan (1984) and Khan (1987).
(4) We shall discuss this issue in detail in Section II.
(5) In the literature the substitution and complementary roles of
public investment are represented by 'crowding out' and
'crowding in' respectively. Since interest rates in developing
countries are not determined freely by market forces; rather, they are
administered by the monetary authority the use of the word
'crowding out' and 'crowding in' seems to be
inappropriate for a developing country like Pakistan
(6) Various authors have used different technology, for example,
Khan (1987) has used 'nested' C.E.S. production technology;
Blejer and Khan (1984) and Sundararajan and Thakur (1980) have used
fixed coefficient and Cobb-Douglas technology respectively. No matter
what production technology is ultimately used, it will be only an
approximation. See Klein (1974).
(7) For a more detailed discussion on the importance of interest
rates in developing countries, see Lanyi and Saracoglu (1983).
Furthermore in a recent paper Edwards and Khan (1985) analysed the
positive association between the degree of development of financial
sector (liberalization of domestic financial market) and the general
economic performance.
(8) On this issue see Hall (1977), Bischoff (1971) and Blejer and
Khan (1984).
(9) We also specified the adaptive expectations model in Equation
(17) as
[DELTA][y.sup.e.sub.t] = [lambda][[y.sub.t-1] - [y.sup.e.sub.t-1]
... ... ... (17a)
The only difference it would make in Equations (21) and (22) is
that the first term in these equations would now be written as
[lambda][alpha][[PSI].sub.0][[y.sub.t-1] (1 - [delta])[y.sub.t-2]]
(10) A 5 percent rate of depreciation is a standard one in
developing countries and has been used widely, for example, Khan (1987),
Blejer and Khan (1984).
(11) In a single equation model like this the problems of reverse
causation cannot be ruled out. However, it has been observed, for
example in Naqvi et al. (1983), Naqvi and Ahmed (1986) and Khan (1987)
that the reverse causation problems are not serious in the case of
Pakistan.
(12) See Blejer and Khan (1984).
(13) Instead of credit to the private sector we used credit
disbursed to the agricultural sector.
(14) The time lag in the adjustment of private investment is
calculated as (1-[[PSI].sub.o]) / [[PSI].sub.o].
ASHFAQUE H. KHAN, The author is Research Economist at the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. This paper is a modified
version of a part of his Ph.D. dissertation submitted to the Johns
Hopkins University. He is extremely grateful to his dissertation
advisors Professors Lawrence R. Klein, Bela Balassa and Carl Christ for
their advice, comments and guidance. The useful suggestions of Professor
Louis Maccini are gratefully acknowledged. He also wishes to thank
Nadeem A. Burney, Muhammad Hussain Malik and an anonymous referee for
their helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. Needless to
say, the author alone is responsible for any errors and ommissions.
Table 1
Results of Total Private Investment, Private Investment in
Manufacturing and Agriculture
Total Private Investment
Equation (21) Equation (22)
[DELTA][y.sub.g](1) 0.11 0.09
(1.40) (1.31)
[DELTA][y.sub.m](1)
[DELTA][y.sub.A](1)
[G.sub.y] 0.12 0.13
(2.17) * (2.38) *
[DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] 0.10 0.14
(2.09) * (2.07) *
[I.sub.go] 0.14 0.24
(2.32) * (2.94) *
[DELTA][I.sub.go] -0.16
(2.44) *
[I.sub.p](1) 0.72 0.66
(6.04) * (5.31) *
[I.sub.pm](1)
[I.sub.pa](1)
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.83 0.83
h 0 0.76
Private Investment in Manufacturing
Equation (21) Equation (22)
[DELTA][y.sub.g](1)
[DELTA][y.sub.m](1) 0.03 0.02
(1.46) (1.15)
[DELTA][y.sub.A](1)
[G.sub.y] 0.08 0.09
(1.58) ** (1.91) *
[DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] 0.05 0.05
(1.88) * (2.18) *
[I.sub.go] 0.04 0.04
(2.62) * (2.03) *
[DELTA][I.sub.go] -0.006
-0.13
[I.sub.p](1)
[I.sub.pm](1) 0.82 0.81
(9.75) * (8.17) *
[I.sub.pa](1)
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.81 0.81
h 1.63 0.29
Private Investment in Agriculture
Equation (21) Equation (22)
[DELTA][y.sub.g](1)
[DELTA][y.sub.m](1)
[DELTA][y.sub.A](1) 0.05 0.01
(0.83) (1.14)
[G.sub.y] -0.08 -0.09
(1.34) (1.73) *
[DELTA][C.sup.p.sub.r] 0.004 0.17
(0.01) (1.49) **
[I.sub.go] 0.04 0.07
(1.87) * (2.01) *
[DELTA][I.sub.go] -0.06
(1.02)
[I.sub.p](1)
[I.sub.pm](1)
[I.sub.pa](1) 0.76 0.63
(5.79) * (4.12) *
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.88 0.89
h 0 0.41
Notes: (i) The t-values are given in parentheses.
* The coefficients are statistically significant at 5-percent level
** The coefficients are statistically significant at 10-percent level.
(ii) h is the Durbin h-statistic defined as h = (1 - DW/2) [square
root of T / 1 -T [var([??])]]
where T is the number of observations and var ([??]) is estimated
as, the square pf the standard error of the coefficient of the
lagged dependent variable.
(iii) In the first column of the Table '(1)' appearing with the
variables indicate one period lag.