Unilateral international transfers and their effects on the welfare of the recipient and donor countries.
Burney, Nadeem A.
This paper analyses impacts of unilateral income and capital
transfers on welfare and terms of trade of the recipient and donor countries within a two-country framework. Introduction of the external
economies of scale, helps in explicitly incorporating the differences in
factor endowment between developed and developing economies in the
analysis. The paper discusses the conditions under which unilateral
capital transfer from a developed country may yield paradoxical result,
i.e. immiserize the developing country, despite market stability. The
analysis reinforces Brecher and Choudhri's analytical support to
Singer-Prebisch thesis from a new angle.
I. INTRODUCTION
The impact of unilateral international transfers on the welfare
levels and terms of trade of the countries concerned has been analysed
extensively. In general, the interest had been in the conditions under
which such transfers could harm a recipient country. In the context of
developing economies, these findings have special relevance for
countries like Pakistan, whose development process, to a large extent,
depends on grants from developed economies. The results, in fact, cast
serious doubts on the effectiveness of an aid-receiving policy. The
transfer can be in the form of income (purchasing power) or capital (a
productive resource). The focus, however, has been on the effect of
income transfer. This paper highlights the difference in the impacts of
these two type of transfers under different conditions.
According to the well-known Singer-Prebisch thesis (Singer, 1950,
and Prebisch, 1959), less developed countries in the growing world
economy suffer a welfare loss because of a secular decline in their
international terms of trade for primary-product exports. This had been
criticized on both theoretical and empirical grounds. Brecher and
Choudhri (1982) supported the Singer-Prebisch thesis but cited the
process of foreign investment as an additional factor responsible for
the welfare loss of the less developed countries. In this paper, we
suggest yet another cause of welfare loss--external economies of scale
in production within the context of a unilateral capital-transfer.
Earlier economists believed that the donor country suffered a net
burden from unilateral income-transfer while the recipient country
benefited from it, but were not agreed on the direction of the effect of
terms of trade. Leontief (1936)demonstrated that an international
transfer of purchasing power can paradoxically immiserize the recipient
country and enrich the donor country, through an improvement in the
terms of trade (a secondary effect) for the donor. Samuelson (1947, p.
29), however, showed that Leontief's paradoxes were related to the
existence of multiple and unstable equilibria. (1) Balasko (1978) has
redefined Samuelson's argument within the framework of regular
economies and draws a distinction between local and global versions of
the paradox. He has demonstrated that in a regular and smooth exchange
economy with two agents and two commodities, it is necessary and
sufficient (i) for the local transfer paradox to occur that the
Walrasian equilibrium be locally unstable, and (ii) for the global
transfer paradox to occur at a locally Walrasian stable equilibrium that
there be multiple Walrasian equilibria. (2)
Brecher and Bhagwati (1982) have shown that market instability is
not required for the immiserizing transfer from abroad when the transfer
itself induces distortions, (3) Johnson (1960) has shown that within a
two-country framework, with one country disaggregated into groups, a
transfer may yield paradoxical results. Komiya and Shizuki (1967) were
the first to show that Johnson's result holds despite market
stability. Gale (1974), using a restrictive three-agent Walras-stable
model with given endowments of goods and fixed coefficients in
consumption, has shown that both donor and the recipient can benefit
from the transfer, harming the third agent. (4) Bhagwati, Brecher, and
Hatta (1983a) have shown that the transfer paradoxes cannot arise even
in the three-country framework if the recipient and donor countries
uniformly and jointly impose an optimal tariff policy against the third
country, thus showing that the failure to eliminate a (foreign)
distortion in the sense of Bhagwati (1971) is the source of Leontief
transfer-paradoxes in the three-country case.
When capital (a productive resource) is involved in the transfer,
the world supply as well as the demand curve may shift as observed by
Caves and Jones (1977, p. 57). It is thus possible that both countries,
together, may gain from the unilateral capital transfer. Lin (1983) has
shown this to be a possibility when the countries involved in the
transfer have different but linear homogeneous production functions,
referred to as the Neo-Hecksher-Ohlin (N-H-O) framework. This, however,
is not true in the context of Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson (H-O-S)
framework where the countries are assumed to have identical and linear
homogeneous production functions.
Using duality framework, first introduced into the welfare analysis
of international trade theory by Hatta (1973, 1977), Takayama (1974),
Chipman (1979), and most comprehensively by Dixit and Norman (1980) and
Woodland (1982), this paper highlights the difference in the impacts Of
income and capital transfers under different conditions. This will be
accomplished, first, by examining the effects of income transfer on
terms of trade and welfare. The analysis shows that the qualitative
impacts of an income transfer are independent of the underlying
production structures in the countries. In the second stage, the effects
of unilateral capital transfer will be analysed. It will be shown that,
within the H-O-S framework, the qualitative impacts of unilateral income
and capital transfers are identical. (5) Within the N-H-O framework,
however, the impacts of the two types of transfers are different and a
unilateral capital transfer will yield paradoxical result under certain
conditions, i.e. it will immiserize the recipient country and enrich the
donor country through changes in terms of trade. (6) Finally, extending
the H-O-S framework, we will analyse the effects of a capital transfer
from a developed country on the welfare of a developing country.
The paper establishes the conditions under which a capital transfer
from a developed country may immiserize a developing country. The
analysis explicitly takes account of the difference in factor endowment
between countries, something that had not been done in any previous
studies. The adoption of the dual approach helps in dealing with the
issue in a general-equilibrium framework and enables us to analyse the
effects of transfers on terms of trade and welfare levels
simultaneously, thus permitting a unified and clear exposition of the
theory.
The paper is organized as follows. In Section II, we outline a
model of the world economy without specifying the underlying production
structures of the countries. In Section III, we discuss the stability of
the model. Section IV contains an analysis of unilateral
income-transfer. In Section V, the effects of unilateral
capital-transfer are analysed. In Section VI, we extend the analysis of
Section V to study the effects of capital transfer from a developed
country on the welfare and terms of trade of a less developed recipient
country. Section VII summarizes the results.
II. THE MODEL
The world is assumed to, consist of two countries, country a and
country [beta]. Each produces and consumes two goods, which are produced
with the help of capital a[beta] labour.
The following notations will be used in our model.
q = the relative price of good 1 (non-numeraire good);
[u.sub.i] = the welfare level of country i (i = [alpha], [beta]);
T = the value of income transfer in terms of good 1 (the
non-numeraire good);
[k.sup.i] = the amount of capital stock in country i (i = [alpha],
[beta]);
[k.sup.0i] = the initial amount of capital stock in country i (i =
[alpha],[beta]);
I = the amount of capital transfer;
[e.sup.i] (q, [u.sup.i]) = the expenditure function of country i (i
= [alpha], [beta]);
[g.sup.i] (q, [k.sup.i]) = the GNP function of country i (i =
[alpha],[beta]);
[z.sup.i] (q, [u.sup.i] , [k.sup.i]) = the compensated import
demand function for good 1 (the non-numeraire good) for country i (i =
[alpha], [beta]). It is positive (negative) as country i imports
(exports) goods 1;
[x.sup.i] (q, [u.sup.i]) = the compensated demand function for good
1 (the non-numeraire good) for country i (i = [alpha],[beta]);
[y.sup.i] (q, [k.sup.i]) = the output supply function for good 1
(the non-numeraire good) for country i (i = [alpha], [beta]); and
[c.sup.i](q, [u.sup.i], [k.sup.i]) = [e.sup.i](q, [u.sup.i]) -
[g.sup.i](q, [k.sup.i]) the overspending function (7) for country i(i =
[alpha], [beta]).
We adopt the notational convention that small letters with
superscripts a and [beta] denote variables of country a and country
[beta], respectively. If country [alpha] gives part of its income (T)
and capital (k) to country [beta], then the international equilibrium
under the two types of transfers is characterized by the following
equations:
[c.sup.[alpha]] (q, [u.sup.[alpha]], [k.sup.[alpha]] + T = 0 ...
... ... ... (2.1)
[c.sup.[beta](q, [u.sup.[beta]], [k.sup.[beta]]) - T = 0 ... ....
... ... (2.2)
[z.sup.[alpha]](q, [u.sup.[alpha]], [k.sup.[alpha]]) + z(q,
[u.sup.[beta]], [k.sup.[beta]]) = 0 ... ... ... (2.3)
[k.sup.[alpha]] = [k.sup.0[alpha]] - I ... ... ... ... ... ...
(2.4)
[k.sup.[beta]] = [k.sup.0[beta]] + I ... ... ... ... ... ... (2.5)
Equations (2.1) and (2.2) are the budget constraints for country
[alpha] and country [beta], respectively. Equation (2.3) is the market
equilibrium condition for the non-numeraire good. In the absence of
taxes, both countries face an identical relative commodity price, q, of
the non-numeraire good. The capital stock in country [alpha] and [beta]
is determined by Equations (2.4) and (2.5), respectively. Equations
(2.1) to (2.3), with I = 0, represent the model of the world economy
with unilateral income-transfer. It will be referred to as the
Income-Transfer Model of the World Economy. Similarly, the model
described by Equations (2.1) to (2.5), with T = 0, represents the model
of the world economy with a unilateral capital-transfer. It will be
referred to as the Capital Transfer Model of the World Economy. The
derivation of the model is based on the work of 'Dixit and Norman
(1980, pp. 128-136) and Woodland (1982, pp. 296-298), and also of Lin
(1983) who used an extended version of Dixit's Model.
Throughout the paper, subscripts refer to the derivative of the
function with respect to the particular variable. The own-price
derivative of the world's compensated excess import demand function
will be defined as [z.sub.q] = [z.sup.[alpha].sub.q.] +
[z.sup.[beta].sub.q]. It will be further assumed that (i)
[e.sup.[alpha].sub.u] [e.sup.[beta].sub.u] = 1, without loss of
generality, (ii) the non numeraire good is capital-intensive in both
countries, and (iii) factor-intensity reversal does not occur.
III. THE STABILITY ANALYSIS
In this section, we discuss what Walrasian stability means in our
model and prove that assumption of stability implies a negative Jacobian
of Equations (2.1)-(2.5) with respect to the variables [u.sub.[alpha]],
[u.sup.[beta]] and q.
In the model described by Equations (2.1) to (2.5), the
world-market equilibrium condition, i.e. Equation (2.3), is expressed in
terms of the compensated import-demand functions. The Walrasian
stability conditions, however, is defined for the ordinary (or
uncompensated) demand functions. Therefore, we define [??] the
uncompensated import-demand function, as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.1)
where [[??].sup.i](q) is the uncompensated demand function for the
non-numeraire good and i = [alpha], [beta]. If the indirect function is
substituted for [u.sup.i] in [z.sup.i](*), it can be readily seen that
[[??].sup.i](*) and [z.sup.i](*) are equivalent.
In the world market, commodity prices adjust in response to the
excess demand until an equilibrium is reached. Let [??] denote the
derivative of q with respect to time, and let
[??](q) [equivalent to] [[??].sup.[alpha]] + [[??].sup.[beta]](q)
... ... ... ... (3.2)
be the world's uncompensated excess import demand function for
the non-numeraire good. In the Equation (3.2), [k.sup.[alpha]] and
[k.sup.[beta]] are suppressed because they are kept constant in this
section. The adjustment process for the non-numeraire good can then
formally be written as
[??] = f(z) ... ... ... ... ... (3.3)
where z = [??](q) and f is a differentiable sign-preserving
function of z satisfying f(0) = 0. Under this adjustment process,
whenever there is excess import demand for the non-numeraire good its
relative price, q, increases. Thus Equations (2.1), (2.2), (2.4), (2.5),
and (3.3) represent the model of the world economy when it is out of
equilibrium. The equilibrium of this economy has to be the equilibrium
of Equation (3.3) since z = 0 follows from Equation (2.3). For given I
and T the adjustment process, Equation (3.3), gives rise to the
following differential equation.
[??] = h(q) ... ... ... ... ... (3.4)
Definition: An equilibrium of the world economy is Walras-stable if
it is a locally stable equilibrium of Equation (3.4) and if the
first-order derivative of h(q) does not vanish.
Local stability of Equation (3.4), together with the condition that
the first-order derivative of h(q) does not vanish, implies that
dh(q)/dq is negative. Thus stability condition for the world economy is
written as
d[??]/dq < 0 ... ... ... ... ... (3.5)
Theorem 1: If an equilibrium of the world economy is Walras-stable,
then
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Proof: See Appendix I
Note that the Jacobian [DELTA] is the determinant of the system of
Equations (2.1)-(2.5) with respect to the variables [u.sup.[alpha]],
[u.sup.[beta]] and q. Determining that at a stable equilibrium of the
world economy [DELTA] is negative is nothing but the Marshall-Lerner
condition.
IV. THE EFFECTS OF A UNILATERAL INCOME-TRANSFER
We now examine the impact of an exogenous increase in T upon the
variables [u.sup.[alpha]], [u.sup.[beta]] and q. To facilitate
exposition, the total effect of an exogenous increase in T on the
welfare levels of the countries will be decomposed into two components,
namely the primary effect and the terms-of-trade effect. The presence of
the terms-of-trade effect either reinforces or weakens the primary
effect of a change in T at a Walrasian-stable equilibrium of the world
economy.
Consider the income-transfer model of the world economy described
by Equations (2.1) - (2.3) with 1 = 0. It has three equations to
determine three variables, [u.sup.[alpha]], [u.sup.[beta]] and q, and
one parameter, T. We write the solution function as
[u.sup.i] = [v.sup.i](T) i = [alpha],[beta] ... ... ... ... (4.1)
q = [q.sup.*](T) ... ... ... ... ... (4.2)
where [k.sup.[alpha]] and [k.sup.[beta] are suppressed because they
remain constant throughout this section.
Lemma 1: The following relations hold in the income-transfer model
of the world economy.
[DELTA]. [du.sup.[alpha]]/dT = [-z.sub.q] ... ... ... ... ... (4.3)
[DELTA]. [du.sup.[beta]/dT = [z.sub.q] ... ... ... ... ... (4.4)
[DELTA]. [dq - dT] = [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] - [x.sup.[beta].sub.m]
... ... ... ... (4.5)
Proof: Taking the total differential of Equations (2.1) to (2.3),
from which Equations (4.1) and (4.2) are derived, and using the
properties of the expenditure and the GNP functions, we get the
following matrix form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Applying Cramer's rule and using the fact that [z.sup.[beta]]
= -[z.sup.[alpha]], we get relations (4.3) to (4.5). Q.E.D.
The term [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] - [x.sup.[beta].sub.m] represents
the gap in marginal propensity to spend on the non-numeraire good
between country [alpha] and country [beta]. This is also referred to as
the "consumption effect" of income transfer on international
terms of trade. Similarly', as [z.sub.q] is the own-price
derivative of the world's compensated imported-demand function, it
is termed the "consumption effect" of income transfer on
welfare levels. If country [beta] imports the non-numeraire good, i.e.
[z.sup.[beta]] > 0, an income transfer will improve its terms of
trade if its initial imports are cheaper at the new prices, i.e.
[z.sup.[beta]], dq/dT < 0.
Theorem 2 (Samuelson-Mundell): At a Walras-stable equilibrium of
the world economy, an exogenous increase in unilateral income-transfer
(i) improves (deteriorates) the terms of trade for the recipient country
if that country imports the non-numeraire good and, compared with the
donor country, has smaller (higher) marginal propensity to spend on the
non-numeraire good, and (ii) immiserizes the donor country and enriches
the recipient country.
Proof: We know that [z.sub.q], the own-price derivative of the
world's compensated import-demand function for the non-numeraire
good, is always negative. Also, [DELTA] < 0 at a Walrasian-stable
equilibrium of the world economy. Therefore, from Lemma 1 we have
(i) dq/dT </> 0 according as [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] >/<
[x.sup.[beta].sub.m]
(ii) [du.sup.[alpha]]/dT < 0
(iii) [du.sup.[beta]]/dT > 0 Q.E.D.
As the impacts of an income transfer on terms of trade and welfare
do not involve changes in the world supply of the non-numeraire good, it
suggests that the qualitative impacts of an income transfer are
independent of the underlying production structure in the two countries.
If the change in world's potential welfare (8) is defined as
[e.sup.[alpha].sub.u] [du.sup.[alpha]] + [e.sup.[beta].sub.u]
[du.sup.[beta]], then by adding Equations (4.3) and (4.4) it can be
easily demonstrated that a unilateral income-transfer leaves the
world's welfare, i.e. the aggregate Gross National Product (GNP)
measured in initial prices, unaltered.
A change in the unilateral income-transfer affects the welfare
levels of country [alpha] and country [beta] both directly through T,
referred to as the Primary (Pr) effect, and indirectly through q,
referred to as the Terms of Trade (TOT) effect, the secondary effect.
For an economic interpretation of Equations (4.3) and (4.4) in terms of
the Pr effect and the TOT effect, we divide the income-transfer model of
the world economy into two sub-models. From Equations (2.1)and (2.2),
which describe our first sub-model, the solution for [u.sup.[alpha]] and
[u.sup.[beta]] can be expressed as functions of (T, q). In particular,
we write the solution function as
[u.sup.i] = [v.sup.i] (T, q) i = [alpha], [beta] ... ... ... ...
(4.6)
where [k.sup.[alpha]] and [k.sup.[beta]] are suppressed as they are
kept constant in this section. If we substitute the value of q from
Equation (4.2) in Equation (4.6), the [v.sup.i](*) obtained must be
identical to [v.sup.i](*) in Equation (4.1), i.e.
[v.sup.i] = [v.sup.i](T, [q.sup.*](T)) i = [alpha], [beta] ... ...
... (4.7)
Differentiating Equation (4.7) with respect to T, we get the
following decomposition.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.8)
The first term on the right-hand side of Equation (4.8), i.e.
[partial derivative][v.sup.i]/[partial derivative]T, the Pr effect,
represents the change in the level of welfare due to a change in the
income transfer, at constant terms of trade. Its sign can be determined
by differentiating Equations (2.1) and (2.2) with respect to T while
holding dq = 0. As the Pr effect involves nothing but the transfer of
income from one country to another, it is always positive (negative) for
the recipient (donor) country, i.e.
[partial derivative][v.sup.[alpha]]/[partial derivative]T < 0
and [partial derivative][v.sup.[beta]] [partial derivative]T > 0 ...
... ... ... (4.9)
The Pr effect is nothing but an outward (inward) shift of the
budget constraint in the recipient (donor) country. Since the
market-clearing equation has not been taken into account, the Pr effect
does not depend on whether the market for the non-numeraire good is in
or out of the equilibrium.
The second term on the right-hand side of the decomposition, i.e.
the TOT effect, contains [partial derivative][v.sup.i]/[partial to
derivative]q. This corresponds to a change in the welfare induced by an
exogenous change in the price of the non-numeraire good. Its sign can be
determined by differentiating Equations (2.1) and (2.2) with respect to
q while keeping dT = 0. If country [beta] imports the non-numeraire
good, i.e. [z.sup.[beta]] > 0, then the following is true:
[partial derivative][v.sup.[alpha]]/[partial derivative]q < 0
and [partial derivative][v.sup.[beta]]/[partial derivative]q > 0 ...
... ... ... (4.10)
i.e. an exogenous increase in the price of the non-numeraire good
increases (decreases) the welfare of the country exporting (importing)
the non-numeraire good.
We know from Theorem 2 that the impact of a change in T on the
welfare of country [beta] (country [alpha]) is always positive
(negative). This indicates that, at a stable equilibrium of the world
economy, the Pr effect of an income transfer always dominates the TOT
effect. We know further that at a stable equilibrium of the world
economy [dq.sup.*]/dT is negative (positive) as [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m]
> [x.sup.[beta].sub.m] ([x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] <
[x.sup.[beta].sub.m]). Note that [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] <
[x.sup.[beta].sub.m] implies [dq.sup.*]/dT 3> 0, i.e. the
non-numeraire good becomes dearer. Thus when country [beta] imports the
non-numeraire good, i.e. [z.sup.[beta]], > 0, the TOT effect works
against it by decreasing the benefits from the transfer, and in favour
of country [alpha] by decreasing the burden of an income transfer. In
other words, the TOT effect weakens the Pr effect. In case
[x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] > [x.sup.[beta].sub.m], the Pr effect is
reinforced by the TOT effect. In the special case when
[x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] = [x.sup.[beta].sub.m] or when the recipient
country is small and it cannot influence the international commodity
prices, the TOT effect does not matter, i.e. dq/dT = 0.
V. THE EFFECTS OF A UNILATERAL CAPITAL-TRANSFER
This section examines the effects of a change in I on the variables
[u.sup.[alpha]], [u.sup.[beta]] and q. Throughout the section, all the
results will be stated under the assumption that the recipient country
imports the non-numeraire capital-intensive good. Consider the
capital-transfer model of the world economy described by Equations (2.1)
to (2.5) with T = 0. It determines three variables [u.sup.[alpha]],
[u.sup.[beta]] and q. Each variable can be solved in terms of the
parameter I. In particular, we write the solution functions as
[u.sup.i] = [v.sup.i] (I) i' = [alpha], [beta] ... ... ... ...
(5.1)
q = [q.sup.*](I) ... ... ... ... ... (5.2)
Lemma 2: The following relations hold in the capital-transfer model
of the world economy:
[DELTA]. dq / dI = ([x.sup.[alpha].sub.m . [x.sup.[alpha]] -
[r.sup.[beta].sub.m] . [r.sup.[beta]]) + ([y.sup.[beta].sub.k] -
[y.sup.[alpha].sub.k]) ... ... (5.3)
[DELTA]. [du.sup.[alpha]] / dI = (-[r.sup.[alpha] . [z.sup.q] +
[z.sup.[beta] {[x.sup.[beta].sub.m] . ([r.sup.[alpha]] - [r.sup.[beta])
+ ([y.sup.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k])} ... (5.4)
[DELTA] x [du.sup.[beta]] / dI = -[-[r.sup.[beta] x [z.sup.q] +
[z.sup.[beta] {[x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] x ([r.sup.[alpha]] - [r.sup.[beta])
+ ([y.sup.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k])}] ... (5.5)
Proof: Taking the total differential of Equations (2.1) to (2.5)
from which equations (5.1) and (5.2) are derived and using properties of
the expenditure and the GNP functions, we get the following matrix form
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Applying Cramer's rule and using the fact that [z.sub.[beta]]
= -[z.sub.[alpha]], we get relations (5.3) to (5.5). Q.E.D.
We already know that (i) [DELTA], the Jacobian of Equations (2.1)
to (2.5) with respect to the variables [u.sup.[alpha]], [u.sup.[beta]]
and q, is negative at a Walras-stable equilibrium of the world economy,
(ii) [z.sub.q] the own-price derivative of the world's compensated
import-demand function, is always negative, (iii) [z.sup.[beta]] is
positive (negative) as a country [beta] imports (exports) the
non-numeraire good, and (iv) [x.sup.i.sub.m] (i = [alpha], [beta]), the
marginal propensity to spend on the non-numeraire good, is always
positive in both countries as long as it is normal. Thus the impact of a
unilateral capital-transfer on the terms of trade and welfare levels of
the countries involved in the transfer depends on the signs of
[r.sub.[alpha]] - [r.sub.[beta]] and [y.sub.[beta].sub.k] -
[y.sub.[alpha].sub.k].
The term [r.sub.[alpha]] - [r.sub.[beta]] is the gap in the return
on capital between country [alpha] and country [beta]. The term
[y.sub.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sub.[alpha].sub.k], on the other hand,
corresponds to a change in the world supply of the non-numeraire good
induced by a unilateral capital-transfer, at hypothetically constant
terms of trade. This is the "production effect" of capital
transfer. Taken individually, [y.sub.[alpha].sub.k] and
[y.sub.[beta].sub.k] are the Rybczynski effects in country [alpha] and
country [beta] respectively. As [y.sub.i.sub.k] [equivalent to]
[g.sub.i.sub.kq] [equivalent to] [partial derivative][r.sup.i] /
[partial derivative]q, [y.sup.i.sub.k] also represents the
Stopler-Samuelson effect on the price of capital of a change in the
price of the non-numeraire good in country i. Consequently,
[y.sub.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sub.[alpha].sub.k] = [partial
derivative]([r.sup.[beta]] - [r.sup.[alpha]]) / [partial derivative]q is
also the change in the gap between the prices of capital in country
[alpha] and country [beta] induced by a change in the price of the
non-numeraire good.
A. The Effect of Capital Transfer on Terms of Trade
A unilateral transfer of capital from country [alpha] to country
[beta] improves the latter country's terms of trade if its initial
imports are cheaper at the new price, i.e. [z.sup.[beta]] dq/dI < 0.
If country [beta] imports the non-numeraire good, i.e. [z.sup.[beta]]
> 0, the necessary and sufficient condition for a capital transfer to
improve its terms of trade is
([x.sup.[alpha].m] [x.sup.[alpha]] - [x.sup.[beta].k]
[r.sup.[beta]]) + ([y.sup.[beta].k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k]) > 0
The term [x.sup.[alpha].m] [r.sup.[alpha]] is the unit change in
demand in country [alpha] induced by the capital transfer. Similarly,
[x.sup.[beta].m] [r.sup.[beta]] is the unit change in demand in country
[beta]. Thus [x.sup.[alpha].m] [r.sup.[alpha]] - [x.sup.[beta].m]
[x.sup.[beta]] is the net change in aggregate demand induced by one
dollar's worth of capital transferred from country [alpha] to
country [beta]. We will refer to this as the consumption (or demand)
effect on the terms of trade. When production functions are linear
homogeneous and identical between countries, as in the standard H-O-S
framework, and factor prices are equalized, Equation (5.3) reduces to
[DELTA]. dq / dI = [r.sup.[alpha] . ([x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] -
[x.sup.[beta].sub.m]) ... ... ... ... (5.6)
since [y.sub.[alpha].sub.k] = [y.sub.[beta].sub.k] and
[r.sup.[alpha]] = [r.sup.[beta]]. Comparing Equation (4.3) with Equation
(5.6), it is obvious that the qualitative impact of income and capital
transfers on the terms of trade are identical in the standard H-O-S
framework.
In general, the signs of [y.sup.[beta].sub.k] -
[y.sup.[alpha].sub.k] and [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] [r.sup.[alpha]] -
[x.sup.[beta].sub.m] [r.sup.[beta]] can not be determined without the
knowledge of the underlying production structures in the two countries.
Thus we have the following theorem.
Theorem 3: At the Walras-stable equilibrium of the world economy, a
set of sufficient conditions for a capital transfer to improve the terms
of trade of country [beta] is (i) [z.sup.[beta]] > 0, i.e. country
[beta] imports the non-numeraire good; (ii) [y.sup.[beta].sub.k] -
[y.sup.[alpha].sub.k] [greater than or equal to] 0, i.e. the capital
transfer increases the world supply of the non-numeraire good; (iii)
[x.sup.i.sub.m] [greater than or equal to] 0 (i = [alpha], [beta]), i.e.
the non-numeraire good is normal in both countries;
(iv)[x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] [greater than or equal to]
[x.sup.[beta].sub.m], i.e. country [beta] has a lower marginal
propensity to spend on the non-numeraire good than country [alpha]; and
(v) [r.sup.[alpha]] [greater than or equal to] [r.sup.[beta]], i.e.
country [alpha] has a higher return on capital than country [beta].
Proof: The proof follows from Equation (5.3).
If any of the inequalities in conditions (i) through (v) of Theorem
3 is reversed, then it is possible that the unilateral capital-transfer
may improve the terms of trade of country [alpha] (the donor country).
This has been shown by Brecher and Choudhri (1982) and Lin (1983) within
the N-H-O framework. Throughout it is implicitly assumed that both
countries have identical factor intensities, i.e. the non-numeraire good
is capital- or labour-intensive in both countries. In the event of a
factor-intensity reversal, if [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k] < 0 and
[y.sup.[beta].sub.k] > 0, condition (ii) is always satisfied.
B. The Effect of Capital Transfers on Welfare
1. The Case o/Reinforcing Terms of Trade Effect
A change in the unilateral capital-transfer affects the welfare
levels of country a and country [beta] both directly through L referred
to as the Pr effect, and indirectly through q, referred to as the TOT
effect. For an economic interpretation of Equations (5.4) and (5.5) in
terms of the Pr effect and the TOT effect, we divide the
capital-transfer model of the world economy into two sub-models exactly
as was done for income transfer. From Equations (2.1) and (2.2) with T =
0, which describe our first sub-model, the solution for [u.sup.[alpha]]
and [u.sup.[beta]] and can be expressed as a function of (I, q). In
particular, we write the solution functions as
[u.sup.i] = [v.sup.i] (I, q) i = [alpha], [beta] ... ... ... ...
(5.7)
If we substitute the value of q from Equation (5.2) in Equation
(5.7), the [v.sup.i](*) obtained must be identical to [v.sup.i](*) in
Equation (5.1), i.e.
[v.sup.i](I) = [v.sup.i](I, [q.sup.*](I)) ... ... ... ... ... (5.8)
Differentiating Equation (5.8) with respect to I, we get the
following decomposition.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... (5.9)
The first term on the right-hand side, i.e. [partial
derivative][v.sup.i]/[partial derivative]I the Pr effect, represents the
change in the level of welfare strictly due to a unilateral
capital-transfer at constant terms of trade. Its sign can be determined
by differentiating Equations (2.1) and (2.2) with respect to I. As the
Pr effect involves nothing but the transfer of capital from one country
to another, it is always negative (positive) for country [alpha]
(country [beta]), i.e.
[partial derivative][v.sup.[alpha]]/[partial derivative]I < 0
[partial derivative][v.sup.[beta]]/[partial derivative]I > 0 ... ...
... ... (5.10)
The Pr effect can also be regarded as the effect of growth in the
ith country on its welfare when international prices do not change. In
other words, it is the outward (inward) shift of the
production-possibility frontier in country [beta] (country [alpha]).
Note that since Equation (2.3) has not been taken into account, the Pr
effect does not depend on whether the market for the non-numeraire good
is in or out of equilibrium.
The second term on the right-hand side of the decomposition, i.e.
the TOT effect, contains [partial derivative][v.sup.i]/[partial
derivative]q. This corresponds to the change in welfare induced by an
exogenous change in the price of non-numeraire good. We know from
Equation (4.10) that if country [beta] imports the non-numeraire good,
[partial derivative][v.sup.[alpha]]/[partial derivative]q < 0
[partial derivative][v.sup.[beta]]/[partial derivative]q > 0
Thus from the decomposition (5.9) and Equations (4.10) and (5.10)
it can be shown that the impact of a capital transfer on welfare levels
depends on (i) the direction of the change in international terms of
trade induced by capital transfer, and (ii) the relative magnitude of
the Pr effect and the TOT effects. Note that when country [beta] imports
the non-numeraire good, an improvement in its terms of trade, i.e. dq/dI
< 0, reinforces the positive (negative) impact of the Pr effect on
the welfare level of country [beta] (country [alpha]). In other words,
an improvement induced by capital transfer in the terms of trade of
country [beta] (the recipient country) ensures that a capital transfer
will always benefit the recipient country and harm the donor country.
2. The Case of Countervailing Terms-of-Trade Effect
In the event that country [beta] experiences a deterioration in its
terms of trade, i.e. dq/dI > 0, the transfer-induced gain and/or loss
is/are not so Straightforward. The following theorem shows, however,
that the improvement in the welfare of country [beta] can be consistent
with its terms-of-trade deterioration.
Theorem 4: At the Walras-stable equilibrium of the world economy, a
set of sufficient conditions for a capital transfer to enrich country
[beta] and immiserize country [alpha] is (i) [z.sup.[beta]] >
[y.sup.[beta].sub.k] [greater than or equal to] (ii)
[y.sup.[alpha].sub.k], (iii) [x.sup.i.sub.m] [greater than or equal to]
0, and (iv) [r.sup.[alpha]] [greater than or equal to] [r.sup.[beta]].
Proof: The proof follows from Equations (5.4) and (5.5).
If any of the above conditions fails to hold, there is a
possibility that a capital transfer may give paradoxical results, i.e.
country [alpha] may get enriched and country [beta] may become
immiserized. Note that conditions (i) through (iv) of Theorem 4 are
identical to conditions (i) through (iii) and (v) of Theorem 3. This
shows that (a) an improvement in the terms of trade of country [beta]
always implies an improvement in its welfare and (b) an improvement in
welfare is consistent with the terms-of-trade deterioration. This can
alternatively be seen from the following equations obtained by
substituting Equation (5.3) in Equations (5.4) and (5.5).
[du.sup.[alpha]]/dI = -[r.sup.[alpha]] - [z.sup.[alpha]] x dq/dI
[du.sup.[beta]]/dI = -[r.sup.[beta]] + [z.sup.[beta]] x dq/dI
A transfer-induced improvement in the terms of trade of the
recipient country, i.e. [z.sup.[beta]] x dq/dI < 0 and
[z.sup.[alpha]] x dq/dI > 0, implies unambiguous increase (decrease)
in the welfare of the recipient (donor) country. In case the transfer
deteriorates the terms of trade of the recipient country, i.e.
[z.sup.[beta]] x dq/dI > 0 and [z.sup.[alpha]] x dq/dI < 0, the
welfare of the recipient (donor) country may still increase (decrease)
as long as the rental earned (forgone) on the transferred capital is
enough to compensate for the loss (gain) due to the terms of trade.
When factor prices are equalized in the standard H-O-S framework,
Equations (5.4) and (5.5) reduce to
[DELTA]. [du.sup.[alpha]]/dI = [r.sup.[alpha]] . [z.sub.q] ... ...
... ... (5.11)
[DELTA]. [du.sup.[beta]]/dI = [r.sup.[alpha]] . [q.sub.a] ... ...
... ... (5.12)
Since [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k] = [y.sup.[beta].sub.k] and
[r.sup.[alpha]] = [r.sub.[beta]], comparing Equations (5.11) and (5.12)
with Equations (4.3) and (4.4) respectively, we find that the
qualitative impacts of a unilateral income and capital transfer on the
welfare levels of each country are identical in the standard H-O-S
framework.
So far it has been assumed that the non-numeraire good is
capital-intensive in both countries. When factor intensities are
different, condition (ii) may not hold. If, however, the non-numeraire
good is labour-intensive in country [alpha], i.e. [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k]
[less than or equal to] 0, and capital-intensive in country [beta], i.e.
[y.sup.[beta].sub.k] > 0, condition (ii) always holds. Theorem 4 is
essentially an extension of Lin's analysis to the case in which
production functions are not necessarily linear homogeneous or
identical.
As mentioned earlier, a capital transfer can change the
world's aggregate GNP measured in the initial prices. This can be
determined by adding Equations (5.4) and (5.5).
([du.sup.[alpha]] + [du.sup.[beta]]) = -([r.sup.[alpha]] -
[r.sup.[beta]]) dI ... ... ... ... (5.13)
The term within the parentheses on the left-hand side is the change
in the world's potential welfare, as already defined. A capital
transfer from country a to country [beta] will increase, leave
unchanged, or decrease the world's potential welfare according as
the rental rate in country [beta] is greater than, equal to, or less
than that in country [alpha].
VI. CAPITAL TRANSFER AND IMMISERIZATION OF A DEVELOPING COUNTRY
The analysis presented in the preceding section is based on a
rather general framework. The relevance of the results to specific
situations is thus not clear. For example, the debate over the impact of
capital transfer is more relevant and interesting in the context of a
developed country transferring part of its' capital to a developing
country. There is nothing in the framework that clearly distinguishes a
developed country from a developing country. The majority of the
developing countries can be characterized as exporting mostly primary
products and having smaller capital-labour ratio than those obtaining in
developed countries.
Within the N-H-O framework, Brecher and Choudhri (1982) have
analysed the impact of foreign investment, which includes a unilateral
capital-transfer, on the welfare of a developing country. (9) They have
demonstrated that if the primary-product exports of the developing
countries are capital-intensive, then the process of foreign investment
can immiserize the developing country through a deterioration of their
terms of trade. (10) While their analysis does take into account some
features of the developing countries' structure by considering
nature of their exports, the results depend critically on the factor
intensity of the developing countries' exports, which is
unobservable. Also, the evidence suggesting that the primary-product
exports of the developing countries are capital-intensive is not very
convincing. In this section, by extending the familiar H-O-S framework,
an attempt is made to incorporate explicitly the differences in factor
endowment, an observable phenomenon, between the two countries. This
makes the framework more realistic, especially in the context of
developing versus developed countries. Later we will analyse the effects
of capital transfer from a developed country on the welfare of a
developing recipient country.
In the subsequent discussion we assume the following:
(i) The production of the first commodity in both countries
generates external economies of scale, and the industrial production
function is homothetic; and
(ii) The second commodity is produced by linear homogeneous
production function.
These assumptions directly affect the terms [r.sup.[alpha]] -
[r.sup.[beta]], i.e. the gap in the return on capital between country a
and country [beta], and [y.sup.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k],
i.e. change in the world supply induced by the capital transfer, in
Equations (5.3) through (5.5). Taken individually, [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k]
and [y.sup.[beta].sub.k] represent the change in the output of y, the
non-numeraire good, in country [alpha] and country [beta], respectively,
at hypothetically constant terms of trade induced by a change in capital
stock. When industrial production functions are linear homogeneous, the
sign of [y.sup.i.sub.k] (i = [alpha], [beta]) follows directly from the
Rybczynski theorem, i.e. [y.sup.i.sub.k] (i = [alpha], [beta]) is
positive (negative) as y, the non-numeraire good, is capital
(labour)-intensive relative to the other good.
In the standard H-O-S trade theory, which assumes a
constant-return-to-scale (CRS) technology, factor prices depend only on
commodity prices which are determined in the international market. In
other words, there exists a one-to-one relationship between factor and
commodity prices. Thus, when free commodity-trade equalizes factor
prices, i.e. [r.sup.a] - [r.sup.[beta]] = 0, capital transfer does not
alter the world supply. This, however, is not true under non-CRS
technology. The presence of external economies of scale, which imply
industrial production functions exhibiting increasing returns to scale
(IRS), complicates the analysis, firstly because the relationship
between factor and commodity prices is no longer one-to-one and secondly
because the output-factor endowment relationship, i.e. the Rybczynski
theorem, is not so straightforward.
In the presence of production externalities, the production
structure of a dosed economy producing two goods, using two factors of
productions, has been analysed by Jones (1968), Kemp (1969), Panagariya
(1980), and Burney (1985), assuming perfect competition and full
employment. The analyses show that, in the presence of production
externalities, factor prices also depend on factor endowments and
degrees of production externalities in addition to the commodity prices.
For a closed economy producing two goods, when the production of the
first commodity generates external economies of scale and the second is
produced by CRS production function, Burney (1985) has examined the
relationship between factor prices and factor endowments. (11) It has
been shown that at a Marshall-stable equilibrium of such an economy,
(12)
D. dr/dk = -[([l.sup.2]).sup.2] [c.sup.1.sub.y] > 0 ... ... ...
... (6.5)
where D is the Jacobian of Equations (1') through (4')
given in the Appendix, with respect to the variables [Y.sup.1],
[Y.sup.2], w and r. It is positive at a Marshall-stable equilibrium of
the economy. For proof, the readers are referred to Burney (1985). The
term [c.sup.1.sub.y] represents change in the unit cost of producing
first commodity induced by a change in the industrial output. It is
negative when production of [Y.sup.1] generates external economies of
scale.
As already indicated, in the presence of production externalities,
the Rybczynski theorem is not so straightforward. Thus it is not clear
whether [y.sup.i.sub.k] (i = [alpha], [beta]) is positive or negative
even when factor intensity is known. Hence, it is difficult to give any
sign to the term [y.sup.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k]. Burney
(1985), however, has shown that if the equilibrium of the closed economy
is Marshall-stable, the Rybczynski theorem continues to hold even in the
presence of production externalities, i.e. in an economy producing
goods-generating production externalities, [y.sub.k] is positive
(negative) as good y is capital (labour)-intensive relative to the other
good, provided the equilibrium of such an economy is Marshall-stable.
Following the H-O-S framework, we assume that for each industry the
production function is identical between country [alpha] and country
[beta]. Thus both countries have identical and homothetic production
functions which are not necessarily linear homogeneous. This assumption
will be referred to as the Similarity Condition or Condition S. Since
production functions are assumed to be homothetic instead of being
linear homogeneous, as in the H-O-S framework, the model of the world
economy satisfying condition S is an extension of the H-O-S framework.
Let [kappa] = k/L be the capital-labour ratio, then dr/dk > 0
implies that dr/d[kappa] > 0, i.e. there exists a positive
relationship between return on capital and capital-labour ratio in an
economy where the production of one commodity generates external
economies of scale and the other exhibits CRS technology. (13) This
suggests that under a free commodity-trade, a country with higher
capital-labour ratio will have higher return on capital. In the
subsequent discussion we assume that, in the model of the world economy
satisfying condition S, country [alpha] is capital-abundant compared
with country [beta] which is labour-abundant. This assumption may be
expressed by [[kappa].sup.[alpha]] > [[kappa].sup.[beta]]. We will
further assume that each country exports the commodity which uses its
abundant factor more intensively and imports the commodity which uses
its scarce factor more intensively, i.e. country [alpha] imports
labour-intensive good and country [beta] imports capital-intensive good.
We label country [alpha], which is capital-abundant and exports
capital-intensive goods, a developed country and country [beta], which
is labour-abundant and imports capital-intensive goods a developing
country. It follows that in the model of the world economy satisfying
condition S, the developed country will have a higher return on capital
than the developing country under free trade, i.e.
[r.sup.[alpha]] - [r.sup.[beta]]>0,
provided equilibria of the developed and the developing countries
are Marshall-stable.
We now analyse the impact of a unilateral capital-transfer from a
developed country on the welfare of a developing country. Unless
otherwise stated, it will be assumed throughout that the non-numeraire
good y is capital-intensive. It has been shown in the previous section
that a unilateral transfer can immiserize the recipient country only
through a deterioration of her terms of trade. From Theorem 3 we know
that at a Walras-stable equilibrium of the world economy a set of
sufficient conditions for capital transfer to improve the terms of trade
of the recipient country is (i) [z.sup.[beta]] > 0, (ii)
[y.sup.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k] [greater than or equal to]
0 (i = [alpha], [beta], (iv) [x.sup.[alpha].sup.m] [greater than or
equal to] [x.sup.[beta].sub.m], and (v) [r.sup.[alpha]] [greater than or
equal to] [r.sup.[beta]] As each term has already been explained in the
previous section, the explanation is not being repeated.
In the model of the world economy satisfying condition S, as the
developing country imports capital-intensive goods and has a lower
return on capital than is obtained by the developed country, conditions
(i) and (v) of Theorem 3 are automatically satisfied. However, in order
to establish a meaningful factor-reward-endowment relationship and to
rule out perversity in output-factor-endowment relationship, in the
presence of production externalities, Marshallian stability has to be
introduced into the framework. Assuming (i) normality in consumption in
both countries and (ii) a taste bias in the developed country in favour
of capital-intensive good or [x.sup.[alpha]].sub.m] [greater than or
equal to] [x.sup.[beta].su.b.m], i.e. a higher marginal propensity to
spend on the capital-intensive non-numeraire good in the developed
country than in the developing country, we arrive at the following
theorem.
Theorem 5: At the Walras-stable equilibrium of the world economy
satisfying condition S, if the equilibrium of each country is
Marshall-stable, then a capital transfer from the developed country will
improve the terms of trade of the developing country provided the
transfer increases the world supply of the non-numeraire good, i.e.
[y.sup.[beta].sup.k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k] [greater than or equal to]
0.
Since in a two-country framework improvement in the terms of trade
for one country implies a simultaneous deterioration in those of the
other, if conditions in Theorem 5 are satisfied, the transfer will
deteriorate the terms of trade of the developed country. In case the
transfer decreases world supply, the sign of dq/dI in Equation (5.3) is
ambiguous even if [x.sup.[beta].sub.m] [greater than or equal to]
[x.sup.[alpha].sub.m]. This is because return on capital in the
developed country, i.e. country [alpha], is always higher than that in
the developing country, i.e. country [beta]. Thus if capital transfer
decreases world supply, it is likely that the terms of trade of the
developing country may deteriorate. In the standard H-O-S framework,
this is not possible as long as [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m] [greater than or
equal to] [x.sup.[beta].sub.m]. The transfer will definitely deteriorate
the terms of trade of the developing country if the "production
effect", i.e. [y.sup.[beta].sub.k] - [y.sup.[alpha].sub.k],
dominates the "consumption effect", [x.sup.[alpha].sub.m]
[r.sup.[alpha]] - [x.sup.[beta].sup.m] [r.sup.[beta]].
Within the N-H-O framework, Brecher and Choudhri (1982) have shown
that direct foreign investment will deteriorate the terms of trade of
the recipient country if (i) the recipient country exports
capital-intensive good, (ii) foreign investment decreases world supply,
and (iii) the recipient country has higher propensity to spend on the
non-numeraire good than the investing (donor) country. Note that Brecher
and Choudhri's condition (ii) is identical to our condition in
Theorem 5.
We know from our discussion in the previous section that a change
in the unilateral capital-transfer affects the welfare of the recipient
as well as donor country both directly through change in the capital
stock, the Pr effect, and indirectly through change in the terms of
trade, the TOT effect. While the Pr effect is always positive, the TOT
effect can take any sign. The immiserization of the recipient country
always implies a deterioration of its terms of trade induced by the
transfer. Also, the welfare improvement of the recipient country can be
consistent with its terms-of-trade deterioration. This can only be true
if the rental earned on the amount of transferred capital is enough to
compensate for the loss due to the deterioration of the terms of trade.
Similarly, the transfer-induced improvement in the terms of trade of the
donor country will not improve its welfare if the foregone rental on the
transferred capital outweighs the benefits from the terms-of-trade
improvement.
In the model of the world economy satisfying condition S, if the
return on capital is not high in the developing country, then it is
quite likely that the capital transfer from the developed country will
yield paradoxical result, i.e. the transfer may immiserize the
developing recipient country through a deterioration of its terms of
trade and enrich the developed donor country despite the world
equilibrium as well as the equilibrium of each country being stable. In
the standard H-O-S framework, this is not possible.
As in the model of the world economy satisfying condition S, the
return on capital is not equal in the developing and the developed
countries. Therefore, capital transfer from the latter to the former can
simultaneously immiserize both the countries and, hence, the world as a
whole.
VII. CONCLUSION
Within a 2x2x2 framework, this paper has examined the effects of
unilateral income and capital transfers on the terms of trade and
welfare levels of two countries. It has been shown that within the H-O-S
framework, qualitative effects of income and capital transfers on the
terms of trade and welfare are identical. If the world equilibrium is
Walras-stable, both types of transfers lead to an unambiguous increase
(decrease) in the welfare of the recipient (donor) country. Within the
N-H-O framework, however, effects of income and capital transfers are
different. Also, a unilateral capital-transfer can yield a paradoxical
result under certain conditions despite market stability, i.e. capital
transfer can immiserize the recipient country and enrich the donor
country. Finally, we have shown that in the extended H-O-S framework, a
unilateral capital-transfer from a developed country may immiserize a
developing country through a deterioration in her terms of trade.
Appendix I
Proof of Theorem 1
Proof: When the world economy is out of equilibrium, Equation (2.3)
does not hold. Replacing Equation (2.3) by (3.2), then differentiating
the entire model with respect of [??], using properties of the
expenditure and the GNP functions and writing in a matrix form, we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Applying Cramer's rule we get
[DELTA]. dq/d[??] = 1
Hence dq/d[??] < 0 iff [DELTA] < 0 Q.E.D.
Appendix II
Assuming perfect competition and full employment, the production
structure of such an economy is described by the following four
equations. For a detailed derivation of the model, interested readers
are referred to Burney (1985).
[l.sup.1]([y.sup.1], w, r) [y.sup.1] + [l.sup.2](w, r) [y.sup.2] =
L 1'
[[zeta].sup.1]([y.sup.1], w, r) [y.sup.1] + [[zeta].sup.2](w, r)
[y.sup.2] = k 2'
[c.sup.1] ([y.sup.1], w, r) = [q.sup.1] 3'
[c.sup.2](w, r) = [q.sup.2] 4'
where [l.sup.i] (*) and [[zeta].sup.i] (*) are respectively input
demand functions for labour and capital per unit of output,
corresponding to the ith good (i = 1,2); [y.sup.i] is the output of the
ith industry, w and r are returns to labour and capital, respectively; k
and L are respectively total amounts of capital and labour available in
the economy; [c.sup.i] (*) is unit cost function of a firm in the ith
industry; and [q.sup.i] is the price that each firm in the ith industry
faces in the absence of market distortions. The model differs from the
H-O-S models in that [y.sup.1] appears in [l.sup.i] (*). [[zeta].sup.i]
(*) and [c.sup.1] (*).
REFERENCES
Balasko, Y. 0983). "The Transfer Problem and the Theory of
Regular Economics". International Economic Review. Vol. 19, No; 3.
pp. 687-694.
Bhagwati, J. N. (1971). "The Generalized Theory of Distortions
and Welfare". In J. N. Bhagwati et al. (eds.), Trade, Balance of
Payment and Growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Bhagwati, J. N., R. A. Brecher and T. Hatta (1983a). "The
Generalized Theory of Transfer and Welfare: Bilateral Transfer in a
Multilateral World". American Economic Review. Vol. 73, No. 4. pp.
606-618.
Bhagwati, J. N., R. A. Brecher and T. Hatta (1983b). "The
Generalized Theory and Welfare: Exogenous (Policy-Imposed) and
Endogenous (Transfer-induced) Distortions". Quarterly Journal of
Economics. Vol. C, No. 3. pp. 697-714.
Bhagwati, J. N., R. A. Brecher and T. Hatta (1984). "The
Paradoxes of Immiserizing Growth and Donor-Enriching
'Recipient-Immiserizing' Transfer: A Table of Two
Literatures". Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. Vol. 120, No. 2. pp.
228-243.
Brecher, R. A., and J. N. Bhagwati (1982). "Immiserizing
Transfers from Abroad". Journal of International Economics. Vol.
13, No. 3/4. pp. 353-364.
Brecher, R. A., and E. U. Choudhri (1982). "Immiserizing
Investment from Abroad: The Singer-Prebisch Thesis Reconsidered".
Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 97, No. 1. pp. 181-190.
Burney, Nadeem A. (1985). "International Capital Movements and
Welfare in the Presence of External Economies of Scale".
Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation. The Johns Hopkins University.
Caves, R. E., and R. W. Jones (1977). World Trade and Payments. 4th
Edition. Boston: Little and Brown.
Chipman, J. S. 0979). "The Theory and Application of Trade
Utility Functions". In J. Green and J. A. Scheinkman (eds.),
General Equilibrium Growth and Trade. New York: Academic Press. pp.
277-296.
Dixit, A. K., and V. Norman (1980). Theory of International Trade:
A Dual, General Equilibrium Approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Dixit, A. K., and V. Norman (1983). "The Multi-Country
Transfer Problem". Economic Letters. Vol. 13, No. 1. pp. 49-53.
Gale, D. (1974). "Exchange Equilibrium and Coalitions: An
Example". Journal of Mathematical Economics. Vol. 1, No. 1. pp.
63-66.
Hatta, T. (1973). "A. Theory of Piecemeal Policy
Recommendations". Ph.D. Dissertation. The Johns Hopkins University.
Hatta, T. (1977). "A Recommendation for a Better Tariff
Structure". Econometrica. Vol. 45, No. 8. pp. 1859-1869.
Hatta, T. (1984). "Immiserizing Growth in a Many-Commodity
Setting". Journal of International Economics. Vol. 17, No. 3/4. pp.
335-345.
Johnson, H. G. (1955). "The Transfer Problem: A Note on
Criteria for Changes in the Terms of Trade". Economica. Vol. 22,
No. 86. pp. 113-131.
Johnson, H. G. (1956). "The Transfer Problem and Exchange
Stability". Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 64, No. 3. pp.
212-225.
Johnson, H. G. (1960). "Income Distribution, the Offer Curve,
and the Effects of Tariffs". Manchester School of Economics and
Social Studies. Vol. 28, No. 3. pp. 215-242.
Johnson, H. G. (1971). "The Theory of Trade and Growth: A
Diagrammatic Analysis". In J. N. Bhagwati, et al (eds.), Trade,
Balance of Payments and Growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Johnson, H. G. (1974). "Welfare Economics of Reversed
International Transfer". In Horwich and Samuelson (eds.), Trade,
Stability and Macroeconomics. New York: Academic Press.
Jones, R.W. (1968). "Variable Returns to Scale in General
Equilibrium Theory". International Economic Review. Vol. 9, No. 3.
pp. 261-272.
Jones, R. W. (1970). "The Transfer Problem Revisited".
Economica. Vol. 37, No. 146. pp. 178-184.
Jones, R.W. (1975). "Presumption and the Transfer
Problem". Journal of International Economics. Vol. 5, No. 3. pp.
267-274.
Jones, R. W. (1984). "Transfer Problem in a Three-Agent
Setting". Canadian Journal of Economics. Vol. 17, No. 1. pp. 1-14.
Kemp, M. C. (1969). The Pure Theory of International Trade and
Investment. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
Kemp, M. C., and S. Kojima (1985). "Tied Aid and the Paradoxes
of Donor-Enrichment and Recipient-Impoverishment". International
Economic Review. Vol. 26, No. 3. pp. 721-729.
Komiya, R., and T. Shizuki (1967). "Transfer Payments and
Income Distribution". Manchester School of Economics and Social
Studies. Vol. 35, No. 3. pp. 245-255.
Laing, N. F. (1961). "Factor Price Equalization in
International Trade and Returns to Scale". Economic Record. Vol.
37, No. 79. pp. 339-351.
Leontief, W. (1936). "Note on the Pure Theory of Capital
Transfer". Exploration in Economics: Notes and Essays contributed
in Honor of F. W. Taussing. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Lin, Po-Sheng (1983). "International Capital Movements and the
Theory of Trade and Welfare". Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation. The
Johns Hopkins University.
Mundell, R. A. (1960). "The Pure Theory of International
Trade". American Economic Review. Vol. 50, No. 1. pp. 67-110.
Mundell, R. A. (1968). International Economics. New York:
Macmillan.
Panagariya, A. (1980). "Variable Returns to Scale in General
Equilibrium Theory Once Again". Journal of International Economics.
Vol. 10, No. 4. pp. 499-526.
Panagariya, A. (1983). "Variable Returns to Scale and the
Heckscher-Ohlin and Factor-Price Equalization Theorems".
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. Vol. 119, No. 2. pp. 259-279.
Polemarchakis, H. M. (1983). "On the Transfer Paradox".
International Economic Review. Vol. 24, No. 3. pp. 749-760.
Postlewaite, A., and M. Webb (1980). "The Effect of
International Commodity Transfer". Unpublished Paper. University of
Kentucky.
Postlewaite, A., and M. Webb (1984). "The Possibility of
Recipient-Harming, Donor-Benefiting Transfers with More than Two
Countries". Journal of International Economics. Vol. 16, No. 3/4.
pp. 357-364.
Prebisch, Raul (1959). "Commercial Policy in the
Under-developed Countries". American Economic Review. Vol. XLIX,
Papers and Proceedings. pp. 251-273.
Samuelson, P. A. (1947). Foundations of Economic Analysis.
Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Samuelson, P. A. (1952). "The Transfer Problem and Transport
Costs: The Terms of Trade when Impediments are Absent". Economic
Journal. Vol. 62, No. 246. pp. 278-304.
Samuelson, P. A. (1954). "The Transfer Problem and Transport
Cost, II: Analysis of Effects of Trade Impediments". Economic
Journal. Vol. 64, No. 254. pp. 264-289.
Singer, H. W. (1950). "The Distribution of Gains between
Investing and Borrowing Countries". American Economic Review. Vol.
XL, Papers and Proceedings. pp. 473-485.
Srinivasan, T. N., and J. N. Bhagwati (1983). "On Transfer
Paradoxes and Immiserizing Growth". Journal of Development
Economics. Vol. 13, No. 1/2. pp. 217-222.
Takayama, A. (1974). "On the Analytical Framework of Tariffs
and Trade Policy". In G. Horwich and P. A. Samuelson (eds.), Trade
Stability and Macroeconomics. Essay in Honor of Lloyd A. Metzler. New
York: Academic Press. pp. 153-178.
Woodland, A. D. (1982). International Trade and Resource
Allocation. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Yano, M. (1983). "Welfare Aspects in Transfer Problem".
Journal of International Economics. Vol. 15, No. 3/4. pp. 277-289.
(1) See also Samuelson (1952, 1954), Johnson (1955, 1956, 1971,
1974), Mundell (1960, 1968 p. 17), Srinivasan and Bhagwati (1983), Jones
(1970, 1975) and Kemp (1969). Postlewaite and Webb (1980) have shown
that, if there is a transfer which simultaneously benefits the donor and
harms the recipient, then there must be multiple equilibria after the
transfer where the competitive equilibrium does not give the
counterintuitive result.
(2) Polemarchakis (1983) has extended Balasko's analysis to a
large number of goods and agents and show that the paradoxes are of
interest only either in its local version or when Walrasian equilibrium
is unique. Hatta (1984) has shown that in commodity framework conditions
normality in consumption and stability are substitutes.
(3) Recently Kemp and Kojima (1985) has shown that the donor
benefits and the recipient suffers despite market stability when the aid
is tied.
(4) Yano (1983) has extended Gale's analysis into a fully
general three country model allowing for substitutability in both
production and consumption. Bhagwati, Brecher and Hatta (1983b, 1984),
have also analysed the transfer problem in more than two country
framework.
(5) For quantitative impacts to be identical, the amount of capital
transfer must be such that it earns rental equal to the income transfer.
(6) Brecher and Choudhri (1982) first showed this. See also Lin
(1983).
(7) This term is due to Bhagwati, Brecher and Hatta (1983).
(8) Dixit and Norman (1980) refer to this as simply a change in
welfare.
(9) Lin (1983) has extended Brecher and Choudhri's analysis by
also examining the impact of the foreign investment on the welfare of
the investing (donor) country.
(10) As noted by Breeher and Choudhri, their analysis is an
alternative interpretation to the Singer-Prebisch thesis.
(11) For a brief description of the model see Appendix-II.
(12) In the standard H-O-S or N-H-O framework dr/dK = 0.
(13) See also Laing (1961) and Panagariya (1983).
NADEEM A. BURNEY, The author is Research Economist at the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. This paper is a part of
his Ph.D. dissertation submitted to the Johns Hopkins University. He is
deeply indebted to Tatsuo Hatta, his supervisor, for his able guidance
and many long discussions which helped to improve the analysis. Thanks
are also due to Bruce Hamilton for many helpful comments. He would like
to express his gratitude to Professor Syed Nawab Haider Naqvi, Director,
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, for his valuable
suggestions. The comments made by anonymous referees of this Review are
also gratefully acknowledged. The author alone, of course, is
responsible for the analysis and conclusions.