A policy model of the wheat and rice economy of Pakistan.
Cornelisse, Peter A. ; Kuijpers, Bart
1. INTRODUCTION
Consumption of wheat and rice in Pakistan grows vigorously. The
causes are well-known: (i) population growth, officially estimated at
about three percent per year, is very high and, (i.i) at low levels of
income per head the income elasticities of wheat and rice consumption
are still positive. (1) Clearly, in order to achieve or maintain
self-sufficiency in wheat and rice, domestic production of these
products has to increase, at least at the same pace as consumption. When
viewing the production performance of recent years in this light there
is reason for satisfaction. Volumes of wheat imports, expressed as a
percentage of domestic production, have tended to fall over the past ten
to fifteen years, while rice exports have increased to, and then
stabilized around, a level of one million tons per year.
The favourable development in the domestic supply of wheat and rice
has called forth a new situation and, concomitant with it, the possible
need for a policy adaptation. In this connection a few questions arise
naturally. With regard to wheat, such a question is, for example,
whether it will be possible for Pakistan to become fully self-sufficient
under the prevailing policies. If the answer to this question is
negative, a policy of production promotion may be considered desirable.
But if the answer is positive, the question can be raised if Pakistan
should attempt to become a wheat exporter. And with regard to rice, one
may wonder if exports should perhaps be raised even further through a
policy of promoting production.
It is not at all self-evident, however, that grain exports should
be attractive. In fact, barfing unforeseen catastrophes in world-wide
grain production, the prospects for suppliers in the international grain
markets are not favourable. First, the acceleration in the growth of
grain production experienced in Pakistan also occurred in other Asian
countries, reducing import needs and even turning some importing
countries into net exporters. Secondly, the price-support measures
applied in the United States and in the countries of the European
Community resulted in an increase of wheat production in these countries
which the world market has been unable to absorb. Prices have
consequently dropped to a low level and there are no signs that this
situation will change much in the near future. Thus, exporting wheat
does not seem to be an attractive proposition and the problems that
Pakistan already has with the export of rice are not likely to be of a
short-term nature.
If this reasoning is correct, the growth of wheat and rice
production needs to be carefully controlled. On the one hand, the
increase in output must be large enough to meet the increase in domestic
demand, while, on the other hand, it should not be so high as to create
a surplus production for which there is no market. It is to this matter
that the present paper addresses itself by setting up a simple policy
model. In essence, the model consists of equations explaining the
volumes of domestic production and consumption of wheat and rice.
Because of its preoccupation with policy formulation the model includes
variables which can be used by the government to influence the domestic
balances of wheat and rice.
The presentation is organized as follows. The next section is
concerned with the domestic production of wheat and rice. Results of
statistical tests of sets of functions relating to production are
presented there. Thereafter aggregate consumption functions for wheat
and rice are discussed and tabulated in Section 3. The combined findings
are then used in Section 4 to obtain projections of wheat and rice
balances under different policy regimes.
2. THE DEVELOPMENT OF WHEAT AND RICE PRODUCTION
Inspection of production volumes of wheat since 1961 reveals
accelerated growth after 1965 with an average rate of growth for the
entire period of 4.9 percent per year. For rice the annual growth, rate
for the period after 1969 is found to be 2.9 percent. (2) These figures
are highly significant as Equations W.1.1 and R. 1.1 in Table 1 show.
Still they are not entirely satisfactory for our purposes because they
suggest a mechanical expansion of production. Not only do we know that
this is not an accurate picture of reality. Our foremost aim is
precisely to find out how growth can be affected through policy
measures. It follows that a more refined approach must be adopted. So,
in order to allow for more detail, we divide production Volumes into
their component parts, viz. area sown and yield. (3) Next, we attempt to
explain the development of each of these variables in regression equations reflecting farmer's behaviour and policy measures
influencing that behaviour.
Let us first consider areas under wheat or rice. It has been
assumed here that farmers' decision processes regarding the areas
to be sown with wheat or rice conform to the adaptive expectations hypothesis. In other words, farmers are assumed to enlarge or reduce
areas sown on the basis of their experiences during the past growing
season. For example, if wheat-growing gave a good return over the past
season, farmers will tend to expand the area under wheat in the next
season. In the present case, in order to test farmers' reactions to
price changes, the (revenue) prices of wheat and rice respectively and
the (cost) price of fertilizer have been included as explanatory variables. For simplicity, revenue and cost prices have been combined in
a single price ratio. The results of the tests carried out along these
lines are given in Equations W.1.2 and R.1.2 for wheat and rice
respectively. It can be observed that both equations are well-behaved in
the sense that farmers appear to react to price changes in the way
economic theory expects them to do.
Now we come to the other component variable, yield per hectare.
After a series of experiments with a variety of explanatory variables,
the functions presented as Equations W.1.3 and R.1.3 in Table 1 appeared
to give the best results. In the wheat equation the time variable was
introduced originally as a proxy for such developments as the gradual
adoption of superior production technologies and the improved
availability of high-yielding seed varieties. So the regression
coefficient was expected to be positive. The present tests suggest,
however, that the effect of time on wheat yield is negative, an outcome
which is alarming. The use of fertilizer as an explanatory variable is
self-evident. On rice fields fertilizer is applied early in the
agricultural year, so the fertilizer purchases preceding application
relate to the foregoing year. Hence, the lagged relation between rice
yield and fertilizer consumption. It must further be stressed that the
data on fertilizer consumption used in the tests relate to the entire
agricultural sector for lack of figures specifying fertilizer use by
individual crops.
In a policy model it is, of course, inappropriate to treat
fertilizer consumption, a variable which is the subject of policy
concern, as an exogenous variable. So an effort has also been made to
explain farmers' behaviour regarding fertilizer use. The results
are given in Equation F. 1 (Table 1). It appears that fertilizer
consumption is a function of time--a proxy of a variety of parameters,
among others a widening recognition among farmers of the favourable
effect on yield--and fertilizer price corrected for inflation. Note that
the relation between consumption and price is indeed negative.
If we now write
Xi = [(Xi/Ai).sup.*] Ai,
where X=production, A=area,/=index indicating wheat or rice, and
substitute Equations W.1.2, W.1.3 and F.1 into this equation, we obtain
a reduced-form production function of wheat expressed in the following
variables: time, area under wheat in the preceding year and the prices
of wheat and fertilizer. A similar exercise can be carried out for rice.
Compared with the mechanical production functions embodied in Equations
W.1.1 and R.1.1 the advantage is of course that a direct relation has
now been established with sets of prices which can in fact be seen as
policy instruments. These results strongly suggest that the levels of
production of wheat and rice are indeed sensitive to government
policies.
The effect of prices on areas sown and yields according to Equations W.1.2, W.1.3, R.1.2, R.1.3 and F.1 can conveniently be
expressed in terms of price elasticities. The values obtained for these
elasticities have been presented in Table 2. (4) Note that according to
the present findings a considerable difference exists between short-term
elasticities (expressing the effect of a price change over a period of
one year) and long-term elasticities (expressing the accumulated effects
of a price change over a long period). It can be seen that the long-term
elasticities are indeed considerable. For example, if the price of wheat
is raised by 10 percent, production of wheat is expected to be raised in
the long run by about 5.5 percent. Still, it should be realized that
such a one-time price increase just lifts production gradually to a
higher level, until the effect is worn out. A single price increase does
not yield continuous output growth. We come back to this in Section 4.
Before we move on to an analysis of aggregate consumption of wheat
and rice, it remains to be seen whether an indirect estimate of
production along the lines described in the preceding paragraph is
sufficiently accurate and, more precisely, how this approach compares
with a direct estimate applying Equations W.1.1 and R.1.1. For this
purpose annual volumes of production have been calculated for both
approaches using observed values of exogenous variables only. This
exercise shows that the indirect approach provides more realistic
results. It is especially noteworthy that the indirect estimates for
wheat as well as rice reproduce very well the alternating periods of
relatively rapid and relatively slow production growth. The superior
performance of the indirect approach can also be expressed in
quantitative terms, of course. Several measures can be applied in this
regard. A simple measure is, for example, the average deviation of
estimated volumes from actual volumes of production expressed as a
percentage of actual production. For wheat this deviation is 7.89
percent in the direct approach and 5.27 percent in the indirect
approach. For rice the corresponding figures are 5.52 and 3.99 percent
respectively. Application of other measures yields similar results.
3. THE PATTERN OF DEMAND FOR WHEAT AND RICE
When analysing the development of consumption of wheat and rice the
data problem looms large. Direct estimates of consumption levels are
available only for those years in which the Household Income and
Expenditure Surveys or other pertinent surveys have been organized.
However, the data thus obtained are too few to allow a statistical test
of consumption behaviour over time.
In order to cope with this problem one can, of course, derive
indirect estimates of consumption with the use of the balance equation:
C(t) = X(t-1) + M(t)-E(t) - F(t) - 1S(t),
where C = consumption, M = imports, E = exports, F = feed, seed and
losses, IS = increment in stocks.
This approximation has been used in the exercise underlying the
findings presented in this section, but it is important to realize the
shortcomings involved. First, as consumption volumes are derived from
production figures, an analysis of excess demand or supply is
infeasible. Secondly, the quality of the consumption estimates depends
directly on the availability and reliability of data for the other
variables. Figures on F, for example, are not easily available, while
figures on IS do not seem to be reliable and are available only for a
few recent years. Thirdly, it is remarkable that the indirect estimates
of wheat consumption per head are consistently about 20 kg lower (5)
than the directly estimated consumption figures obtained by means of
expenditure surveys.
The consumption estimates for wheat and rice derived with the
abovementioned equation for the period 1961-1985 expressed on a per
capita basis have been used for tests of a variety of consumption
functions. A selection of the results of these tests has been presented
in Table 3. It seems safe to conclude from the figures presented there
that volumes of consumption of wheat and rice depend to a large extent
on variations in population size and national income. It also follows
from the parameters in the functions tested that the income elasticities
of both wheat and rice consumption are less than one. Thus, the shares
of wheat as well as rice consumption in national income tend to
decrease. With a view to Engel's Law this observation does not come
as a surprise. Notice further that the functional forms chosen for
Equations W.2.1 and R.2.1 allow the elasticities to vary with income. It
appears then that the income elasticities for both products fall as
income increases, a finding that is in line with the experience in other
countries. According to Equation W.2.1 the income elasticity of wheat
was approximately .61 in 1961. while it dropped to .42 in 1985. The
corresponding values for the income elasticity of rice according to
Equation R.2.1 were .46 and .34 respectively. Finally it must be added
that prices of wheat and rice did not contribute significantly to the
explanation of consumption volumes of these goods. (6)
So far we have been concerned only with human consumption of wheat
and rice; let us now also consider animal consumption. Here we
concentrate on wheat, because rice is not normally used as feed.
Unfortunately, reliable data on the use of wheat for feed are not
readily available. The information that has been published so far lump
feed together with seed and other uses, but even then it is worthwhile
noting that the share of animal feed, seed and other uses in total wheat
use which stands at 11 percent now tends to increase by 0.24 percent per
year. (7) This implies that the demand for wheat as feed etc. increases
considerably faster than demand for human consumption. Such a
development can easily be explained by the shift in diets towards animal
protein products going hand in hand with growth of income per head and
resulting in a rapid increase in demand for grains for feed.
4. WHEAT AND RICE BALANCES UNDER DIFFERENT POLICY REGIMES
The foregoing sections dealt with the development of domestic
production and use of wheat and rice. The various components in the
dynamics of supply and demand were considered separately in order to
obtain a better idea of the origins of the patterns of change. The
knowledge thus obtained will be used in this section to outline the
wheat and rice balances for the final years of three successive
five-year plan periods, i.e. 1988, 1993 and 1998. Projections will be
made on the basis of fixed assumptions regarding income and population
growth and of alternative assumptions regarding price policies.
The estimated volumes of production of wheat and rice presented in
Table 4 have been calculated using what we have called the indirect
approach. As indicated, the advantages compared with the direct approach
are, first and foremost, that a link exists with policy instruments and,
secondly, that the predictions tend to be more accurate. Application of
this approach requires specification of the values of exogenous
variables assumed to hold in the future. Here it concerns the ratio of
the price of wheat (or rice) to the price of fertilizer and the real
price of fertilizer. In selecting the values to be substituted in the
relevant equations, values observed for these variables since 1961 have
served as points of orientation. Thus, for each exogenous variable three
values have been considered: the highest value observed, the lowest
value and the average value. Production volumes corresponding with five
selected combinations of values of exogenous variables are presented in
Table 4. The five cases in question are:
1. A case of output restriction combining a low price of wheat (or
rice) with a high price of fertilizer
2. A combination of low prices for wheat (or rice) and for
fertilizer;
3. A combination of average prices for both wheat(or rice)and
fertilizer;
4. A combination of high prices for wheat (or rice) and fertilizer;
and
5. A case of output promotion combining a high price of wheat (or
rice) with a low price of fertilizer.
The estimates tabulated below illustrate clearly the considerable
impact of prices on volumes of wheat and rice production. Note, for
example, that under a production promoting price regime (case 5) wheat
output in 1998 is estimated to be approximately 54 percent higher than
under a production-discouraging regime (case 1). For rice the
corresponding-difference is even higher (70 percent). It can, therefore,
be concluded that ample opportunity exists for policy-makers to control
wheat and rice production through the application of pertinent price
policies. We return to these findings below, but first we examine some
estimates of future aggregate consumption of wheat and rice.
The rate of growth of domestic demand for the two products examined
here must not be underestimated. First we consider human consumption.
The analysis in Section 3 has shown that population and income are the
main determinants of this component of demand, so the projected growth
paths of these two explanatory variables must now be decided upon.
Population has been assumed to continue increasing by 2.9 percent
annually. For national income a growth rate of 6.3 percent per year has
been adopted--equal to the planned rate of growth of national income for
the Sixth Five-Year Plan ending in 1988. Substituting the projected
values of these exogenous variables into Equations W.2.1 and R.2.1 one
obtains the estimated quantities of future human consumption of wheat
and rice as presented in the first column of Table 5. (8)
The share of feed, seed and other uses in total wheat use is likely
to continue rising, if relative prices of grains will not undergo much
change. With reference to the pattern observed in the past. This share
is assumed to increase by 0.24 percent annually starting from the
present level of 11 percent. For rice the corresponding share is assumed
to remain constant at 5 percent of total use. The estimates obtained on
the basis of these assumptions can be found in the second column of
Table 5. The quantities of total use of wheat and rice foreseen of 1988,
and 1993 and 1998 are given in the last column.
Comparison of the figures in Table 5 with those given in Table 4
provides a preliminary indication of the balances of domestic demand and
supply of wheat and rice in the three future years for which the
calculations have been carried out. A positive balance can be
interpreted as an exportable surplus. While a deficit indicates a need
for supplementary imports.
Examining first the situation regarding wheat, it can be concluded
that there does not seem to be reason for unconstrained optimism. It is
particularly noteworthy that considerable and increasing deficits are
foreseen even under a scenario of historically favourable price ratios
(case 5). And in case 3 which can be considered a normal case as it is
based on average price ratios observed during the period 19611985, the
deficits are of disastrous magnitude. When the "unfavourable"
cases 1 and 2 are assumed to hold, the situation is, of course, still
worse. At first sight these observations seem to be in conflict with the
trend of the wheat balance in the recent past which suggests a much
brighter future than the one painted here. (See for example the opening
paragraph of this paper.) So let us examine the results of our exercise
a bit more closely.
Recall that the historical growth rate of wheat output was found to
be 4.9 percent per year (see Equation W.1.1). However, when inspecting
the development of wheat production according to the "normal"
case 3, it will immediately be seen that the growth rate is much lower.
Even the increase in output implied by case 5 does not match the
performance of the past twenty-five years. The explanation of this
paradox is rather simple. In the past the production of wheat has been
stimulated by step-wise increments in the ratio of wheat to fertilizer
prices. Thus, in a mechanical extrapolation of output on the basis of
observed production statistics (as is done when using Equation W.1.1) it
is implicitly assumed that this price ratio will continue to rise in the
future. In our exercise, however, the ratios of wheat to fertilizer
prices have been kept constant at levels which differ only among the
various cases examined. The results show that the impact on output is
dramatic. If our findings are correct, it follows that self-sufficiency
in wheat cannot be achieved by maintaining the presently prevailing,
relatively favourable ratio of wheat to fertilizer prices. The latter
ratio needs to be raised continuously for such a goal to be reached.
The picture obtained for rice is considerably less precarious.
Compared with wheat, already the starting position--a consistent and
sizeable exportable surplus is of course more favourable. But this lead
seems to grow with the passage of time. For one thing, total use does
not expand as rapidly, because the income elasticity of consumption is
lower for ice than for wheat and because the share of feed, seed and
other uses in total use remains constant for rice, while it increases
for wheat. Further, the production estimates listed in Table 4 indicate
that in nearly all cases rice production increases at a faster pace than
wheat production. As a result, a policy regime in accordance with case 4
would maintain the exportable surplus at about one million tons while a
scenario according to case 5 would even enlarge the surplus in the
course of time. Thus, it may seem advisable to adopt a policy of price
moderation with regard to rice, in strong contrast to the need for
steadily increasing prices for wheat in order to avoid a rise in wheat
imports.
Comments on "A Policy Model of the Wheat and Rice Economy of
Pakistan"
Before commenting upon the paper, I would like to thank the
organizers of the Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society of
Development Economists for inviting me to participate in the Meeting.
This has provided me with an excellent opportunity to meet many friends
and exchange experiences and ideas about the issues facing
Pakistan's economy. The paper, "A Policy Model of the Wheat
and Rice Economy of Pakistan" Cornelisse and Kuijpers, which I have
been asked to discuss, purports to analyse policy issues relating to two
of the most important foodgrains of Pakistan and may have important
bearings for our food policy. It is an interesting paper, lucid and
systematically organized. The arguments provided are quite sound and
well-grounded in economic theory. However, I have a few reservations,
about some aspects of the analysis presented in the paper, which are
discussed below:
In the introductory section, the authors pose a question whether it
will be possible for Pakistan to become self-sufficient in the near
future and under what conditions such a situation could be achieved?
However, it is not clear in what context this question has been posed?
Whether in the context of wheat or of rice? If the question of
self-sufficiency relates to wheat then, I think it is not the question
of achieving self-sufficiency but more of its maintenance. This is
because during 1983-84, 1984-85, 1985-86, wheat imports in Pakistan were
only marginal and may have been mainly meant for Afghan refugees. In the
case of rice, it hardly needs to be mentioned that Pakistan has been a
net exporter of rice for some length of time.
Nevertheless, I agree with the authors that there is a substantial
potential for increasing the production of both wheat and rice. This can
be achieved by improving production efficiency. This should also lower
unit cost of production and facilitate, exports by making them more
competitive. The yields within Pakistan's agriculture vary widely
across various farmer groups. Farmers using modern inputs and adopting
better husbandry practices are reported to have much higher yields than
those obtaining on the majority of farms Agricultural Prices Commission,
(1986). However, the questions of improving efficiency of marketing
operations and access to markets assume greater importance for having a
larger share in export markets. The provision of regular marketable
surplus of that quality which is in demand in the world markets is
equally important in developing export markets. However, the
developments in wheat and rice production and marketing would need to be
carefully monitored to have sufficient exportable surpluses at
competitive prices. Monitoring the situation in the international
markets to keep abreast of the developments and establishing efficient
marketing channels would assume special importance if export markets are
to be exploited to the best advantage.
Development of Wheat and Rice Production
There are a few problems of specification in Section 2, providing
empirical estimates of various parameters of the models used in
explaining production behaviour of wheat and rice. For example in
Equations W.l.2 and R.1.2 of the paper reproduced below :
[Aw.sub.t] = 436.4 + 0.8775 [Aw.sub.t-1] + 4.02 [(Pw/Pf).sub.t] ...
W.1.2
[Ar.sub.t] = 174.9 + 0.8144 [Ar.sub.t-1] + 1.52 [(Pr/Pf).sub.t] ...
R.1.2
The variables [(Pw/Pf).sub.t], [(Pr/Pf).sub.t], where Pw = price
index of wheat, Pr = price index of rice and Pf = price index of
fertilizer, are perhaps meant to assess the influences of changes in the
real prices of wheat and rice, respectively, on the changes in wheat and
rice acreage. If so, the appropriate deflator in these cases may have
been some index of the annual inflation rates in the economy rather than
the prices of chemical fertilizers. Fertilizer is no doubt an important
purchased input in wheat and rice farming but its contribution in the
total costs is no more than 20 percent at best, (Government of Pakistan 1986).
Another observation which I have about the specification of the
yield equation on rice i.e., Equation R. 1.3 in the paper is the
inclusion of aggregate fertilizer use level as a lag variable to explain
the current yields of rice. It is rather difficult to understand how the
fertilizer use in the previous year may have affected current yields.
Moreover, use of total fertilizer data hides the real picture of
fertilizer use on rice. I may add here that data on fertilizer in
Pakistan are available in fairly disaggregated form. From these data,
with some ingenuity, one can estimate the amount of the fertilizer used
in rice production to a fairly satisfactory extent and its use in the
model may have provided a better explanation for the performance of rice
yield. Another problem With respect to the rice equations is the
aggregation of data relating to fine and coarse varieties. As the
production technology of these varieties is quite different, therefore
their combined treatment may not be of much help to policy planners.
The Pattern of Demand for Wheat and Rice
The problems of calculating per capita consumption of food
commodities through the balance sheet approach are too well known to be
repeated here. Nevertheless, it is worth noting as the authors have
pointed out that through this approach, it is not possible to analyse
excess demand or supply. Moreover, the consumption figures derived from
the production data represent availability and not actual consumption
and also hide the equity and distribution aspects.
It is not surprising that per capita consumption of wheat derived
from production data through the balance sheet approach does not tally
with the consumption estimates obtained from the expenditure survey. A
few points about the estimation of consumption figures from the
expenditure surveys are in order as data problems loom really large,
here. To obtain precise consumption estimates through expenditure
surveys, in a society where (i) the literacy rate is barely about 26
percent, (ii) no consumption records are available and (iii) bulk of the
population living in rural areas does not rely on formal markets to meet
their food requirements, is at best problematic. Therefore, it would
have been really surprising if the consumption data obtained through the
balance sheet approach had matched with the data available from the
expenditure surveys.
One is rather surprised at the authors' remark that the prices
of wheat and rice did not contribute significantly to the explanation of
consumption volumes of these goods. The price variable is conspicuous by
its absence in the consumption equations estimated by the authors. In
such a situation one wonders how the authors could conclude about the
insignificance of the price variable in explaining the consumption
behaviour.
Wheat and Rice Balance under Different Policy Regimes
Under this section the authors have provided interesting scenarios
about the production and uses of wheat and rice under various policy
options. The analysis provided herein is quite revealing.
The authors have pointed out that despite improvement in the yields
in Pakistan, international comparison indicates much scope for
improvement. It is true that tremendous scope exists for raising crop
yields in Pakistan as this is evident from the yields obtained by
'progressive' farmers. However, international comparisons of
yields involving widely dissimilar agricultural and climatic conditions
may be spurious and not provide practical guidelines for improving the
situation.
Ahdul Salam
Agricultural Prices Commission
Islamabad
REFERENCES
Cornelisse, Peter A, and Bart Kuijpers (1987). "A Policy Model
of the Wheat and Economy of Pakistan". (Paper Presented at the
Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society of Development
Economists, held at Islamabad in August 1987).
Pakistan, Government of (1986). Cost of Production of Field Crops:
Methodology and Empirical Results (Rice, Cotton and Wheat). Islamabad:
Agricultural Prices Commission.
REFERENCES
Abroad, E., H.M. Leung and N. H. Stern (1987). "The Demand for
Wheat Under Non-Linear Pricing in Pakistan". The Development
Research Programme of the London School of Economics. (Discussion Paper
No. 5)
International Wheat Council (Various Issues). World Wheat
Statistics. London.
Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues). Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Finance Division, Economic Adviser's Wing.
(1) Statistical confirmation of this observation is provided in
Section 3 of this paper.
(2) The annual rate of growth of rice production during the period
1961-1986, the period corresponding with the period of observation of
Eq. W.1.1, is 4.3 percent. The difference with the growth rate observed
during the shorter period after 1969 is remarkable. It illustrates the
variable growth performances in rice output over time, a phenomenon to
which we return subsequently.
(3) Although increments in yield have made a larger contribution to
production growth, the effect of increases in areas under wheat and rice
must not be underestimated.
(4) The price elasticities obtained by means of the above-mentioned
relations vary with time. The values in Table 2 relate to 1986.
(5) Considering that, according to various recent surveys, wheat
consumption per head is approximately 140 kg, the difference is
considerable.
(6) However, in a cross-section analysis presented in Ehtesham
Ahmad et al. (1987) using figures relating to 1977 the compensated price
elasticity of wheat consumption was found to be -0.63.
(7) Based on data obtained from various issues of World Wheat
Statistics.
(8) Equations. W.2.1 and R.2.1 incorporate the tendency for the
income elasticity of wheat and rice consumption to fall as income rises.
On the other hand, Equations. W.2.2 and R.2.2 imply constant income
elasticities and this renders them less suitable for projection
purposes.
PETER A. CORNELISSE and BART KUIJPERS, The authors are
respectively, Professor and Technical Assistant at the Centre for
Development Planning, Erasmus University Rotterdam. A very useful
contribution by Ivo Havinga is gratefully acknowledged.
Table 1
Statistical Explanation of Components of Wheat and Rice Production
Eq. No. Period Regression Equation
W.1.1 1960-61-1985-86 [Xw.sub.t] = 3841.3 1.0493 (T)
(20.62) (403.23)
R1.1 1968-69-1985-86 [Xr.sub.t] = 1680.3 1.0290 (T)
(14.7) (288.4)
W.1.2 1960-61-1985-86 [Aw.sub.t] = 436.4 + 0.8775
[Aw.sub.t-1]
+ 4.02 [(Pw/Pf).sub.t]
(l.45) (15.20) (2.11)
W.1.3 1960-61-1985-86 ln [(Xw/Aw).sub.t] = -1.38 -
0.21 ln t + 0.35
ln [F.sub.t]
(15.30) (4.17)
(10.39)
R.1.2 1960-61-1985-86 [Ar.sub.t] = 174.9 + 0.8144
[Ar.sub.t-1]
+ 1.52 [(Pr/Pf).sub.t]
(2.23) (11.80) (2.30)
R.1.3 1969-70-1985-86 [(Xr/Ar).sub.t] = 1.42 + 0.00022
[F.sub.t-1]
(40.80) (4.83)
F.1 1968-1986 ln [F.sub.t] = 5.10 + 0.10
t - 0.0034
[(Pf/Pg).sub.t]
(19.78) (12.54)
(2.35)
Eq. No. Reliability Test
W.1.1 [[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.095 F = 446 DW = 1.41
R.1.1 [[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.81 F = 72 DW = 0.91
W.1.2 [[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.94 F = 187 DW = 2.01
W.1.3 [[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.96 F = 309 DW = 1.60
R.1.2 [[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.94 F = 202 DW = 1.55
R.1.3 [[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.57 F = 23.4 DW = 1.50
F.1 [[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.97 F = 340 DW = 1.26
Notes. Figures in parentheses are t-values.
Meaning of symbols:
Ar = area sown with rice
Aw = area sown with wheat
F = total fertilizer consumption
Pf = price index of fertilizer
Pg = general price index
Pr = price index of rice
Pw = price index of wheat
t = time index
T = time variable (base year = 1)
Xr = production of rice
Xw = production of wheat.
Table 2
Price Elasticities in Wheat and Rice Production, 1986
Area Yield Production
Short Long Short Long Short Long
Own Price Elasticities
Wheat .068 .554 0 0 .068 .554
Rice .093 .502 0 0 .093 .502
Elasticities of Fertilizer Price
Wheat -.068 -.554 -.195 -.195 -.263 -.641
Rice -.093 -.502 -.107 -.107 -.200 -.555
Table 3
Consumption Functions for Wheat and Rice, 1961-1985
Equations Regression Equation
W.2.1 (Cw/D) = -232.7 + 53.7 ln(Y/D)
(-4.65) (6.84)
R.2.1 (Cr/D) = -29.7 + 7.83 ln (Y/D)
(-2.90) (4.86)
W.2.2 ln (Cw/D) = 1.42 + 0.51 ln (Y/D)
(-2.90) (4.86)
R.2.2 ln (Cr/D) = 0.47 + 0.40 ln (Y/D)
(0.95) (5.13)
Equations [R.sup.2] F D.W.
W.2.1 0.69 46.7 1.60
R.2.1 0.52 23.6 2.01
W.2.2 0.69 47.7 1.47
R.2.2 0.55 26.4 1.98
Notes: Figures in parenthesis are t-values.
Meaning of symbols:
(Ci/D) = Consumption per head of wheat or rice in kgs,
(Y/D) = Income per head in constant Rs of 1959-60.
Consumption volumes have been derived using data published in
various issues of the Pakistan Economic Survey.
Values of national income have been obtained from the same source.
Table 4
Estimates of Wheat and Rice Production
under Five Price-policy Regimes, 1988, 1993 and 1998
(in 000 tons)
Years Case 1 Case 2 Case 3 Case 4 Case 5
Wheat Production
1988 11602 12847 12872 12736 14103
1993 12216 13528 14527 15617 17295
1998 13446 14889 16629 18641 20642
Rice Production
1988 2994 3182 3317 3463 3680
1993 2977 3251 3689 4166 4549
1998 3345 3776 4392 5024 5672
Note: See the text for an explanation of the five policy cases.
Table 5
Estimates of Volumes of Wheat and Rice uses,
1988, 1993 and 1998
(in '000 ton)
Years Human Feed, Seed Total
Cons. etc. use
Wheat
1988 14155 1894 16049
1993 17402 2599 20001
1998 21313 3551 24864
Rice
1988 2515 132 2647
1993 3057 161 3218
1998 3707 195 3902