Some econometric evidence on the relative importance of monetary and fiscal policy in Pakistan.
Saqib, Najam us ; Yasmin, Attiya
I. INTRODUCTION
Economists agree that both monetary and fiscal policies can
influence the pace of aggregate economic activity. However, their
relative importance still remains a widely debated and complicated
issue. Given the mushroom growth of different types of economic models,
it seems almost impossible to decide their relative importance, at a
purely theoretical level. So in this paper, we have tried to deal with
this issue empirically in the context of Pakistan.
In surveying the literature, we can find a number of empirical
studies on this issue, but most of them are for the developed countries.
Similar studies for the developing countries are rare. We have been able
to find only two such studies for Pakistan, one by Hussain (1982) and
the other by Masood and Abroad (1980).
The study by Hussain (1982) covers the period from 1949-50 to
1970-71, and the data used in this study pertain to united (East and
West) Pakistan. So the results of his study can hardly be of much
relevance to present Pakistan. Masood and Ahmad (1980) use data for
present Pakistan from 1959-60 to 1976-77 in their study. They regress induced expenditures on autonomous expenditures and money supply and
assess the relative importance of the two exogeneous variables, on the
basis of t-values and beta-coefficients. Their definition of induced and
autonomous expenditures seems to be a little arbitrary. Agricultural
income, an independent variable in their regressions, turns out to be a
dominant variable in a number of equations. The negative sign of the
autonomous expenditures in some regressions is difficult to justify.
Their efforts, to determine the lag structure, have also been
unsuccessful. Although their data are from many individual sources, they
have not applied any formal tests to check the consistency of the data
and the possible structural change that might have taken place due to
the separation of East Pakistan.
In the present study, we intend to improve on the previous work on
several accounts. First, we shall update the previous studies up to
1984-85. Second, at PIDE, some studies [Fatima (1983); Kemal, Bilquees
and Khan (1980)] have been undertaken to provide consistent data for
present Pakistan. We plan to make use of these data in our study. Since
these data, up to 1970-71, are calculated on the basis of some
assumptions and there is also some possibility of structural change in
the economy after 1970-71, due to the separation of East Pakistan, slope
and intercept dummies will also be used to see whether these influences
were statistically significant. The role of fiscal policy will be
explored in greater detail and the issue of the length of lags
associated with the two policies will also be probed more thoroughly.
II. METHODOLOGY
In order to evaluate the relative importance of monetary and fiscal
policies, we can start with a reduced form Anderson-Jordan type equation
(Anderson and Jordan 1968) which relates monetary and fiscal policy
actions to aggregate economic activity. Our dependent variable is GDP,
while total government expenditures and, alternatively, narrow and broad
definitions of money supply are taken as independent variables. To see
whether monetary or fiscal policy alone is sufficient to explain changes
in GDP simple regressions employing either monetary or fiscal variables
will also be estimated. We shall compare beta-coefficients (1) and
t-values associated with the two types of policy variables. A higher
value of the beta-coefficient for a variable will imply its stronger
effect on GDP, while dependability or predictability of a variable will
be judged by the value of the t-statistic associated with it.
In the mixed economies of the developing countries, government
expenditures are not used merely as a tool of stabilization policy. They
are planned to achieve many other objectives relating to economic
development. It is not only the aggregate level of government
expenditures that matters but also their composition. To take care of
this aspect of government expenditures, we have deviated a little from
the standard Anderson-Jordan type methodology by replacing a single
variable of total government expenditures with its components, namely
current consumption expenditures, investment and subsidies.
The relative speed of the monetary and fiscal policies depends upon
the length of lag associated with the variables representing these
policies. However, the choice of appropriate lag length is a complicated
matter and no simple formal statistical procedure is available for this
purpose. We plan to estimate regressions with different lengths of lags
and then try to choose a regression with the lowest estimated standard
error, as suggested by Theil (1961). Clearly, this criterion does not
guarantee the choice of a regression which makes sense in terms of the
signs and the magnitudes of the coefficients and the length of lag.
However, for the want of any better criterion, we have to rely on it. We
shall also postulate that lag effects of the two policies continue
indefinitely but dampen geometrically in successive periods. A
Koyck-type distributed-lag equation will be estimated to test this
hypothesis, assigning some geometrically declining weights to monetary
and fiscal policy variables. The Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) estimation
technique will be employed throughout this study.
III. DATA
The data used in this study cover the period from 1959-60 to
1984-85. The sources of data, for the two concepts of money supply, are
Kemal et al. (1980) and various issues of the Bulletin, State Bank of
Pakistan. The GDP deflators are used to convert these data to real
magnitudes. The data on GDP and the various components of government
expenditures at current and constant prices are taken from the Pakistan
Economic Survey 1985-86.
IV. RESULTS
Table 1 presents estimates of the various versions of the
Anderson-Jordan type equation in nominal terms. (2) A comparison of
simple and multiple regressions reveals that the addition of one more
policy variable to a regression results in a visible reduction in the
value of the estimated coefficients and the estimated standard error of
the regression. This shows that both monetary and fiscal policies are
effective in influencing the level of aggregate economic activity. In
all regressions, both the beta-coefficients and the t-values, associated
with the money supply variables, have larger values as compared to those
of government expenditure. This leads us to conclude that the impact of
monetary policy on GDP is stronger, as well as, more predictable than
that of fiscal policy, though both the policies, significantly,
influence the level of GDP. The regressions, estimated with all
variables in real terms, give similar results which are not reported
here.
The regressions with money supply and various components of
government expenditures as independent variables are reported in Tables
2 and 3 in nominal and real terms respectively. Money supply is again
highly significant in all these regressions. A glance at these
regression results also shows that government current consumption
expenditures are significant both in real and nominal terms. On the
other hand, government investment outlays are significant only in the
regressions estimated with all variables in nominal terms. A possible
explanation of this phenomenon would be that the supply of consumption
goods is relatively flexible and government demand for goods and
services does not compete with that of the private sector. On the other
hand, the supply of capital goods is not so flexible and any increase in
government demand for capital goods crowds out private investment.
Hence, the effect of increase in government investment is reflected only
in increased prices. The supply-side effects of government investment
are also dubious. In previous years, the government has spent a
considerable amount of its investment outlays for providing
infrastructure and other facilities to stimulate private investment.
But, unfortunately, owing to a number of economic and non-economic
factors, these effects have not been very fruitful.
These results also provide some insight into the role of subsidies.
They are insignificant when regressions are estimated in nominal terms
but become significant in regressions with real magnitudes. This shows
that subsidies do exert a significant positive influence on real GDP. A
large proportion of government subsidies is spent on essential food
items, agricultural inputs and exports. (3) As a result, the prices of
these commodities for the consumers are reduced and, hence, their demand
increases at a given price level. This explains why the coefficient of
government subsidies is insignificant when the regressions are estimated
in nominal terms.
To estimate the length of lag in the effect of the two policies, we
started by, first, keeping government expenditures at current period and
increasing the length of lags in money supply from one to five years in
successive regressions. Then, the same procedure was repeated with the
lags of government expenditures, keeping money supply at current period.
The standard errors of both the sets of regressions, resulting from this
exercise, were examined but no overall pattern seemed to emerge. After
the failure of this procedure, all possible combinations of the lags of
the two types of policy variables, up to five years, were tried but no
sensible results could be obtained. Even, the regressions based on the
Koyck-type, distributed-lag pattern, did not make much sense. Hence, our
efforts to estimate the log structure associated with the two policies
remained unsuccessful.
V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
In this paper, we have tried to find out, which one of the monetary
and fiscal policies is more vigorous, more dependable and takes a
shorter time in exerting its influence on GDP. We have updated and
improved previous work by using a better data base, studying the role of
the various components of government expenditures in influencing GDP and
probing thoroughly the length of lag in the effect of monetary and
fiscal policies. Not surprisingly, our results are different from those
of the two previous studies.
The main finding of this study is that monetary impulses have
greater leverage and are more dependable. However, these results may, by
no means, be taken to imply that fiscal policy should be discarded altogether in favour of monetary policy. Our regression results show
that fiscal policy can still be used as a second tool of stabilization
policy along with monetary action.
A close look at the role of different components of government
expenditures, by regressing them on GDP along with money supply, has
uncovered some interesting aspects of fiscal policy. While current
consumption expenditures are very effective in influencing GDP both in
real and nominal terms, the effect of government investment is mainly
felt on prices. This highlights the need for restructuring the
government's investment policy. On one hand, resources should be
diverted towards the capital goods industry in order to make the supply
of capital goods more flexible and thus curb the crowding-out effects of
government investment, while, on the other hand, steps should be taken
at the political, social and economic levels to induce private investors
to utilize the infrastructure and other facilities provided through
government investment. This will enhance the supply-side effects of
government investment.
The role of government subsidies also deserves attention. Most of
the government subsidies are given on essential food items, agricultural
inputs and exports. This increases demand for these items at a given
price. As subsidies result in an increase in real GDP, without pushing
up prices, so they can be used as an anti-inflationary expansionary policy tool.
As regards the shape of the lag structure of the fiscal and the
monetary policy variables, our results indicate that there is no
systematic pattern of lags associated with the two types of variables.
It is likely that quarterly data could help in resolving this issue, but
for most of the variables used in this study, such data are not
available.
In conclusion, this study shows that monetary policy is more
effective and more dependable, compared to fiscal policy, as a tool of
influencing GDP, though fiscal policy is important in its own right. It
has also shed light on some interesting policy implications of the
composition of government expenditures.. The choice of an optimal
combination of the two policies is, of course, left to the
policy-makers.
Comments on "Some Econometric Evidence on the Relative
Importance of Monetary and Fiscal Policy in Pakistan"
Not being an econometrician, I have to confine my comments to the
problems of general macro-economic policy questions, which are raised by
the authors, sometimes inter alia, sometimes explicitly.
(1) One can only agree with the authors' view, that the
question of the relative importance of monetary and fiscal policy, on
the pace and level of general economic activity of a country can only be
decided by empirical research. No doubt, the well known "golden
rules" (formulated, for instance, by Howard S. Ellis in 1951) on
the relative importance of the two groups of policy tools must always be
interpreted according to the macro, micro and (last, but not the least)
the institutional conditions of the country we are dealing with.
(2) The present study is a good first step in elucidating this
problem in the light of Pakistani conditions: First, a comprehensive set
of statistical data on the relevant macro-economic variables has been
prepared. And second, certain instrument variables have been specified.
But it seems that the authors have not gone far enough in this respect.
For instance, one could question, if under the conditions of the
Pakistani monetary system, one can really rely on the definition of
textbook variables such as [M.sub.1] or [M.sub.2] and government
expenditure in toto as independent instruments. On the contrary, under
the special circumstances prevailing in this country (i.e. with weak
connection between the Government and the Monetary Authorities), the
interdependence of the two policy instruments may be a substantial one.
In this case, several of the authors' findings must be read with
caution.
(3) The results presented in this paper raise several questions:
--Could it be that the stronger impact of monetary policy, which
the authors have detected, is only a superficial impression, because the
value of the fiscal deficit is implicit in the development of the
monetary variables?
--Could it be that the authors' contention, that global
government investment has a very small impact on general economic
activity derives from the fact that the authors did not disaggregate this variable far enough?
For, we know, that the multiplier of infrastructural investment is
very low and implies long lags, whereas the multiplier of government
investment, in directly productive activities, is comparatively high and
works in short periods. Could it be proven that most government
investment in Pakistan consists of infrastructural activities. The
authors' crowding-out argument (which in the case of Pakistan is
not very convincing) appears to be superfluous.
(4) Finally, the question may be asked, if the authors'
correlation study could not be read the other way round. For, if we
assume that the Government, with its policy instruments, is reacting to
the development of GNP over time--be it in an automatic or in a
discretionary manner--the policy variables are the dependent ones.
Whether this problem is relevant or not can only be decided an the basis
of better knowledge about the institutional background of
Pakistan's economic policy system. Therefore, it would be very
expedient, if the authors could widen the scope of their study by adding
a discussion on the institutional background of monetary and fiscal
policy in Pakistan.
Heiko Korner
Technical University of Darmstadt, West Germany
REFERENCES
Anderson, L. C., and J. L. Jordan (1968). "Monetary and Fiscal
Actions: A Test of their Relative Importance in Economic
Stabilization". Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review. Vol. 50.
pp. 11-24.
Fatima, Asmat (1983). Estimates of Private and Public Savings and
Consumption for (West) Pakistan (1959-60 to 1979-80). Islamabad:
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics. (Statistical Papers Series,
No. 4)
Hussain, Muhammad (1982). "The Relative Effectiveness of
Monetary and Fiscal Policy. An Econometric Case Study of Pakistan".
Pakistan Economic and Social Review. Vol. 20, No. 2. pp. 159-181.
Kemal, A. R., Faiz Bilquees and A. H. Khan (1980). Money Supply in
West Pakistan. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
(Statistical Papers Series, No. 1)
Maddala, G. S. (1977). Econometrics. Kogakusha: McGraw-Hill, Inc.
Masood, Khalid, and Eatzaz Ahmad (1980). "The Relative
Importance of Autonomous Expenditures and Money Supply in Explaining the
Variations in Induced Expenditures in the Context of Pakistan".
Pakistan Economic and Social Review. Vol. 18, Nos. 3-4. pp. 84-99.
Pakistan, Government of (1986). Pakistan Economic Survey 1985-86.
Islamabad: Finance Division, Economic Advisor's Wing.
State Bank of Pakistan. Bulletin. Karachi. (Various Issues)
Theil, H. (1961). Economic Forecasts and Policy. Amsterdam:
North-Holland Publishing Company.
(1) For definition see Maddala (1977).
(2) All these equations were also estimated with slope and
intercept dummies to see whether the data for pre. and post-1971 are
consistent and whether structural change in the economy, due to the
separation of East Pakistan, is statistically significant. These dummies
turned out to be insignificant and were dropped in later analysis.
(3) In 1984-85, the distribution of total government subsidies was
58 percent on wheat, sugar and edible oil, 22 percent on agricultural
inputs, 15 percent on exports and 5 percent on other items. (Source:
Pakistan Economic Survey 1985-86).
NAJAM US SAQIB and ATTIYA YASMIN, The authors are respectively,
Research Economist and Staff Economist at the Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad. They are grateful to Dr M. H. Malik for his constant encouragement and valuable comments on an earlier draft
of this paper.
Table 1
Regressions of GDP on Government Expenditures and Money Supply at
Current Prices
S. No. Constant G [M.sub.1] [M.sub.2]
1. 6479.69 3.7484
0.9980
(3.0662) (77.6331)
2. 1191.19 3.5542
0.9985
(1.1786) (89.8704)
3. 5798.42 2.2718
0.9986
(3.2065) (91.0090)
4. 3817.50 1.5810 2.0607
0.4209 0.5789
(2.4520) (3.7545) (5.1637)
5. 5906.97 1.5559 1.3322
0.4143 0.5856
(4.0392) (3.7031) (5.2345)
[[bar.R].
S. No. sup.2] S.E. D.W.
1. 0.9959 7802.68 0.85
2. 0.9969 6743.61 1.20
3. 0.9970 6659.49 1.45
4. 0.9980 5424.15 1.29
5. 0.9980 5384.38 1.51
Notes: (1.) The figures in parentheses are t-values. Beta-coefficients
are reported just above them. The values at the top are the estimated
coefficients of regression.
(2.) The symbols used in the Table are defined as follows:
G = Total government expenditures.
[M.sub.1] = Narrow money supply (currency + demand deposits).
[M.sub.2] = Broad money supply ([M.sub.1] + time deposits).
(3.) All variables are measured in millions of current rupees.
Table 2
Regressions of GDP on Components of Government Expenditures and Money
Supply at Current Prices
S. No. Constant GC GI GS [M.sub.1]
1. 4052.84 2.3957 1.0284 0.7483 1.9638
0.3198 0.1122 0.0197 0.5517
(2.8l02) (4.8871) (0.7026) (5.3223)
2. 5843.35 1.9553 1.6102 1.0084
0.2610 0.1757 0.0265
(3.7360) (2.7966) (0.8419)
[[bar.R].
S. No. [M.sub.2] sup.2] S.E. D. W.
1. 0.9984 4911.65 1.49
2. 1.2295 0.9989 5550.46 1.45
0.5404
(4.1984)
Notes: (1.) The figures in parentheses are t-values. Beta-coefficients
are reported just above them. The values at the top are the estimated
coefficients of regression.
(2.) The symbols used in the Table are defined as follows:
[G.sub.C] = government current consumption expenditures.
[G.sub.I] = government investment.
[G.sub.S] = government subsidies.
[M.sub.1] = Narrow money supply (currency + demand deposits).
[M.sub.2] = Broad money supply ([M.sub.1] + time deposits).
(3.) All variables are measured in millions of current rupees.
Table 3
Regressions of GDP on Components of Government Expenditures and Money
Supply at Constant Prices of 1959-60
S. No. Constant GE GI GS [M.sub.1]
1. 6234.14 3.4184 -0.3126 3.5005 1.3972
0.5051 -0.0291 0.1271 0.4170
(5.4499) (4.0777) (-0.3769) (2.7026) (3.6665)
2. 7306.37 2.6649 -0.0028 3.4913
0.3938 -0.0003 0.1267
(7.750l) (3.0652) (-0.0036) (2.9588)
[bar.R].
S. No. [M.sub.2] sup.2] S.E. D.W.
1. 0.9864 1838.41 1.45
2. 1.0366 0.9884 1701.31 1.55
0.5012
(4.3839)
Notes: (1.) The figures in parentheses are t-values. Beta-coefficients
are reported just above them. The values at the top are the estimated
coefficients of regression.
(2.) The symbols used in the Table are defined as follows:
[G.sub.E] = government current consumption expenditures.
[G.sub.I] = government investment.
[G.sub.S] = government subsidies.
[M.sub.1] = Narrow money supply (currency + demand deposits).
[M.sub.2] = Broad money supply ([M.sub.1] + time deposits).
(3.) All variables are measured in millions of current rupees.