The potential for economic-demographic development: Whither Theory?
Sirageldin, Ismail
1. INTRODUCTION
Changes in stable socio-demographic systems, barring environmental
accidents have occurred when major new production technologies are
widely adopted and socially institutionalized. In most instances, this
process of change is associated with a high degree of specialization and
through it with the opening up of local markets and their integration
into the wider regional and international system of trade and exchange.
It must be emphasized that major technological changes are but one
facet, albeit a central one, in the development of our ever-evolving
technological civilization. But as major new "production
technologies" take hold, a new system of human settlements and
social relations evolves which is in harmony with the new wave of
emerging "techniques".
During these periods of structural changes, mortality and
reproductive behaviour tend to adjust themselves to new levels that are
compatible with these new sets of production relations and their
associated social formations. This movement from one equilibrium level of vital rates to another is called in the population literature a
"demographic transition". Indeed, the current
"demographic transition" (1) is the consequence of the world
dramatic experience with new technological changes (dubbed industrial
revolution). This socio-demographic transition that has its origin in
the seventeenth century and accelerated during the second part of this
century has influenced all the parameters of human and non-human life,
including the vital rates, and has apparently set the world society on
the path of irrevocable "technicalization". (2)
Demographic transitions, accordingly, cannot be defined
independently of their socioeconomic context and, more fundamentally,
the prevailing production technology. It is possible for demographic
parameters to change as a result of changes in social relations without
associated significant changes in the technological parameters. But such
changes are necessarily limited by that system's production
potential, which, in the final analysis, should be able to provide the
necessary biological support for the growth of population.
Contemporary discussions of demographic change that theorize or
prescribe ways and means of influencing fertility or migration behaviour
without first considering the structural causes that caused those
changes are doomed to failure. It does not follow, however, that
knowledge about structural causes alone is sufficient for a correct
diagnosis and prescription of development issues. Once set in motion,
demographic change has its own momentum that interacts with the
socioeconomic parameters of society. Understanding both the determinants
and consequences of demographic change is extremely essential.
Accordingly, discussions regarding economic development or the
choice of appropriate developmental styles that do not integrate
population dynamics in the sense just outlined are deficient. Indeed it
is the main thesis of this paper that for most analyses of socioeconomic
development, this is the case. As will be evident from the present
discussion, while a localized analysis of demographic change is not
necessarily complete, an integrated "world view" of
socio-economic development that does not endogenize the dynamics of
demographic change is internally inconsistent. Our focus, however, is
diagnostic rather than prescriptive.
In the second section we examine demographic trends in the less
developed countries with emphasis on the Arab Region up to the end of
the present century and evaluate their momentum. Our focus will be on
vital rates. The important phenomenon of intra-regional migration will
be examined later in the paper. In the third section we review various
development paradigms to examine the role of population dynamics in
their specified structures. Our next step is to assess, in the fourth
section, the applicability of these various paradigms to the
economic-demographic potential of the developing countries, with the
Arab World as a case study. In the concluding section we discuss briefly
some theory and policy implications.
2. DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD: A PREDETERMINED DESTINY?
In 1960, crude birth rates in low-income and middle-income
countries were 40 or more births per thousand population for all
countries with only five exceptions, and were closer to 50 for most of
them. (3) Crude death rates, on the other hand, were over 16 per
thousand for all except thirteen countries and few Asian countries. In
1982, fertility continued to maintain its high levels, with a few
exceptions attaining somewhat lower levels. However, mortality declined
dramatically, reflecting a combination of improved health status and
young age structure, thus creating a dramatic increase in the natural
rate of population growth. Figure 1 illustrates for the Arab countries,
Pakistan, Bangladesh and Thailand the situation between 1960 and 1980
and the expected trends up to the year 2000. Basic demographic data are
presented in Table 1.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
It is evident that with few exceptions, the rate of growth of these
populations of Arab countries will be over two percent per year and for
the majority will exceed three percent by the year 2000. The potential
for high rates of population growth will continue to persist through the
twenty-first century. In other words, the completion of the demographic
transition in its narrow sense will not materialize in Pakistan,
Bangladesh, Thailand, or the Arab World, for example, until well through
the twenty-first century. The following question presents itself:
What are the socio-economic implications of this demographic
picture and how do they affect the developmental potential or limit
the viability of the available policy options?
In attempting to answer this fundamental question we may follow two
possible paths. The first is to project and examine a battery of
consequence indicators in order to illustrate what the developing
countries have to deal with during the next few decades. For example,
the aggregate size of the Arab population is estimated at between 190
million and 200 million in 1985. With some plausible assumptions
regarding the paths of fertility, mortality and net migration, it is
expected that between 140 million and 150 million births will be added
between 1985 and the end of this century, and about 40-45 million deaths
will occur during the same period. Assuming a net out-migration of about
5-10 million, we would expect the total size of the Arab population to
reach between 275 million and 305 million people by the year 2000. We
can safely assume that about half the 40-45 million deaths will be among
infants and that the family income and wealth distributions of these
40-45 million deaths will be very skewed (e.g. a Gini co-efficient
exceeding 0.6).
Similar guestimates can be made for Pakistan, Bangladesh or
Thailand. For example, the populations of these countries are expected
to increase by 41 million, 45 million and 15 million people respectively
by the year 2000. Most of that increase will be of rural origin. About
71 percent, 88 percent, and 83 percent of the increase will originate in the rural areas of Pakistan, Bangladesh and Thailand respectively. The
momentum for population growth will continue to have its effect through
the end of the twenty-first century. It is a long-term analysis. For
details, see Demeny [27].
On a more programmatic plane, demographers, economists and
sociologists may quibble about the assumptions underlying the
projections in order to improve the various guestimates, especially when
attempting to estimate, for planning purposes, the number of additional
jobs that need to be created in the various sectors and regions by the
end of the century. In principle, such an exercise should be a
relatively easy task since for the next twenty years the labour force is
already "on board". Controversies arise, however, not only
with regard to data quality and the realism of the fertility and
mortality assumptions, but, more importantly, to expectations regarding
labour force participation rates (especially for females), skill
composition, and the geographical distribution of the work force within
and across the various countries. Such estimates are necessary for the
calculation of the size and structure of investment outlays required to
maintain or attain a desired level of labour productivity. Similarly,
the implication of population growth to social investments necessary for
education, health, housing and other basic needs and their incorporation
in a macro-economic framework opens up a very substantial role for a
skilled technocratic cadre of economists, sociologists and demographers.
It has even created a sub-discipline labelled "planning for growing
populations" Cassen and Wolfson, [23]. It also provides a lively
numbers game--a serious game notwithstanding.
This is the approach that is most widely used in dealing with
population implications. It does not, however, probe the fundamental
forces that brought the demographic picture to its present status.
The second approach, which is the one we will adopt, is to
investigate the determinants of the system parameters and relate them to
consequences. More specifically, it seeks to investigate how endogenous the demographic factors in the current phase of the developing
countries' socioeconomic experience are. But the policy conclusions
derived from such an examination can only be interpreted in the context
of developmental paradigms. For that purpose we need to understand how
population is treated within the various development perspectives. It is
not our aim to secure a consensus or to provide a comprehensive
assessment of the current debate regarding development paradigms. Such a
task is too large and fundamental and is clearly beyond the scope of the
present study. The aim is to present our own understanding of the role
of population dynamics in the various developmental paradigms in order
to relate the demographic situation just outlined to the context of the
developing world within a coherent framework. For the purpose of
focusing the discussion, the Arab experience will be taken as a case
study.
3. POPULATION IN DEVELOPMENT PARADIGMS
It seems that the pace and diversity of national and international
events and the associated structural changes that took place in the
world during the past two decades have had the effect of discrediting a
number of comfortable generalizations that have been nurtured and
cherished with respect to a spectrum of development paradigms. These
events include the changing role of China in both its internal and
international policies; the changing fortunes of OPEC; the emergence,
from within the ranks of the less developed countries, of a set of Newly
Industrialized Countries that may be labelled semi-imperialistic; the
apparent decline of some previously industrial nations, the rise in
Latin America of a new brand of military-bureaucratic regimes in close
alliance with international capital; and the disillusionment with the
progress of the North-South negotiations. These events have created
disillusionment among soical scientists concerned with development
studies. As Portes and Walton observed [59, p. 1], for those whose
perceptions of the world are based instant analysis, the 1970s and 1980s
must have surely projected a state of confusion. Regardless of
one's ideological leanings, it was increasingly difficult to
identify either international friends or enemies or to predict even
short-term trends during that period. As a result, development economics
as a sub-discipline was put to task:
It is apparent that the current status of development economics is
rather fluid. We need not b e dogmatic in taking stances before a
careful survey of the grounds. In what follows we present a brief review
of various development paradigms starting with the classical model. Our
interest is to illustrate how population is treated in these models. We
must, however, be aware that our rejection of a given paradigm, if based
on moral (or emotional) grounds, may not spring so much from the
unsoundness of its analytical structure, as from its unsound application. The same knife may save or take a life depending on whether
it was used by a surgeon or by a criminal.
a. From Malthus to Marx
Malthus, as a system of analysis and not of exploitation, was born
a long time before the birth of the man of that name. From this
viewpoint, the Malthusian assumption that the average productivity of
labour declines with an increase in population size, as well as the
familiar Malthusian assumptions of a fixed resource base and a fixed
technology that implies the idea of an optimal population size, defined
in the context of a desirable average level of welfare (or subsistence),
was elucidated by Confucius and his followers in China almost a
millennium before Malthus's time (Hammel, [39]). It is hard to
perceive Confucius as Malthusian.
Malthus was a classical economist, although he anticipated Keynes
in questioning the stability of the system. According to the classical
(as well as the neoclassical) thesis, in a perfectly competitive economy
and in the absence of externalities, market forces operating through the
price mechanism assure both a stable system and an optimum allocation of
resources, statically and dynamically. This paradigm has been open to
three major lines of criticism. One that it is unjust and exploitative.
Two, that it is unstable, prone to crises and doomed to collapse. Three,
that its alleged optimum allocative conclusions are not guaranteed
because its very quintessential mechanism of market forces operating
through the price system fails to work, either because of a distorted
signalling mechanism, an inadequate response of labour and other factors
of production to price signals, or because of the lack of mobility of
such factors. (5) Our focus will be on the first two lines of criticism,
exploitative and instability, because of the critical nature of their
assumed demographic behaviour.
A critical examination of the classical system can be made in the
light of Marx's critique. Marx considered the exploitative nature
of the capitalistic system as inherent in the internal working rules of
the system. As put eloquently by J. Robinson,
Exploitation is the great engine for accumulation and what is
nowadays called economic growth. The capitalists extract surplus
value, not to enjoy luxury, but to accumulate the means of
increasing employment so as to extract more surplus [65, p. 27].
The surplus of production over wages belongs to the capitalists.
They use it partly to supply their own wants but mostly to build up more
capital to extract more surplus. In essence, the "bourgeoisie"
class is viewed in this paradigm as being "programmed" to
accumulate-like bees. It is evident that investment (i.e. profits minus
luxury consumption) in the capacity to produce wage goods is a necessary
condition for growth, but the viability of the system is based on an
objective, albeit contradictory, relationship between profits and real
wages. To an individual firm, an increase in the wage bill represents a
"loss", while for the capitalist class as a whole it is the
precondition for an expansion of the market and, accordingly, a
continuation of the accumulation process. Furthermore, for the system to
operate without real wages overtaking profits, the labour force must be
increasing all the time, and at the same time there exists a reserve
army of potential unemployed workers.
Indeed, it is a tight-rope game. If capital accumulates faster than
the labour force growth, including the exhaustion of the reserve of
labour, real wage rates rise and profit per worker falls, thus slowing
down accumulation relative to the growth of labour. A new cycle begins
where the relative increase of the labour force will tend to reduce real
wages and, accordingly, increase surplus and accumulation. It is evident
from this analysis that
In a class society (whether feudal or capitalist) a growth of
numbers is advantageous to the owners of property. It provides them
with more people to exploit, as tenants, servants, slaves or
workers. [65, p. 8]
It is a mercantilistic world that favours population increase in
order to maximize wealth while being oblivious to problems of inequality
of income and wealth or accepting its inevitability. It is also the Age
of Malthus. The attack on the Malthusian framework has to do with its
analytic focus and moral implication. Teitelbaum summarizes the
ideological issue succinctly when he said that
Malthus argued that the English poor laws and the utopian socialism
of Godwin and Condorcet were doomed to failure by the 'principle of
population'. According to Malthus, the effect of social welfare
measures was simply to lower mortality while fertility stayed high.
Hence the population will grow to the margin of subsistence, and
thereby leave eventual overall welfare improved not at all. Unless
fertility could be reduced, he (Malthus) held, the ultimate
population restraints of famine, war and disease would be imposed
by nature. [91, p.831]
In essence, Malthus considered the inequality in the functional
distribution of income as datum necessary for the stability of his
system and, accordingly, blamed the reproductive behaviour of the
working class for excessive poverty and unemployment. It is the growing
subsistent consumption needs of this group that outgrow output
growth--thus reducing profit and accumulation. The cure from misery lies
squarely on the shoulders of the proletariat and not in the
characteristics of the social structure of the capitalistic system and
its production relations.
It is evident, therefore, that population plays an important,
albeit different, role in the functioning of both the classical and the
Marxist systems.
In the Malthusian framework (ignoring its reactionary
interpretation) population is treated endogenously in the sense that its
rate of growth is a positive function of real wages. But the conceptual
framework that underlies the relationship is never articulated and is
mainly based on biological forces of passion. It must be emphasized that
there is nothing "sacred" about the distribution mechanism
perceived by Malthus. As John Stuart Mill wrote in his Autobiography,
partly a reflection of his utilitarian convictions,
"Malthus's population principle was quite as much a
banner and point of union among us [utilitarians], as any opinion
specially belonging to Bentham. This great doctrine, originally brought
forward as an argument against the indefinite improvability of human
affairs, we took up with ardent zeal in the contrary sense, as
indicating the sole means of realizing that improvability by securing
full employment as high wages to the whole labouring population through
a "voluntary" restriction of the increase of their numbers.
(Quoted in [16, pp. 220-21]; emphasis added.)
Indeed, as Blaug observed, one can read in Mill's principle
"a relentless insistence that every conceivable policy measure must
be judged in terms of its effects upon the birth rate" [16, p.
220]. It seems that Mill assumed the presence of a divergence between
individual and social demographic objectives--a divergence that required
a conscious policy intervention. But he also assumed a
"voluntary" adjustment mechanism on the micro level. However,
Mill did not provide the necessary "behavioural" theory of
population dynamics, essential for the viability and stability of his
harmonious economic-demographic system.
It is of interest, however, that the recent revival of the
classical theory of profit ignored even this weak link and treated
population as completely outside the system [96]. In Von Neumann's
world the employment of labour grows automatically as the flow of output
of wage goods increases. Such state of affairs implies either that
population is always growing at just the right rate, or that there is an
indefinite reserve of potential labour living on nuts in the jungle,
always ready to take up employment when the standard real wage is
offered. Such treatment is most evident in Morishima's (1969)
extension of the Von Neumann model. G. McNicoll describes this aspect of
Morishima's specification more vividly when he says that in
Morishima's model,
People in excess of the minimum needed to work with the available
physical inputs to the set of production processes at a given time
can be excluded from participation in the economy either dying of
starvation or becoming otherwise unemployable without being a
burden on the economy! [52, p.2]
In the Marxist framework, although the role and influence of
population are central to the system, its dynamics are not given careful
consideration. Marx's prediction about the fate of the capitalist
system is that the very mechanism inherent in the process of production
will result in constantly increasing numbers of the working class that
would be trained, united and organized to finally revolt and take over
the system for their own benefit. This vision includes the element of a
rudimentary population theory which shares the same response mechanism
as that of Malthus. But Marx's system could equally accommodate an
alternative population theory where the response mechanism differs. For
example, as Joan Robinson [65] argues, (6) it is possible that
Marx, in his desire to combat the reactionary doctrines of Malthus,
did not stress the point that growth of population, under
capitalism, is inimical to the interests of the working class,
though his own theory clearly indicates that this is the case ...
when the labour force is not growing, accumulation takes the form
of technical change which raises output per man employed. Then
organized labour can catch a share in the growth of productivity by
raising real wage rates. This, indeed, has happened in the Western
economies. The moral seems clear, but some fanatical dogmatic
Marxists have joined with the Pope in refusing to admit that the
growth of population, in modern conditions, is an impediment to the
growth of human welfare. (p. 8).... (evidently, Marx) neglected
demography. (p. 26)
Indeed, classical Marxism puts forward the thesis that each
socio-economic formation has its demographic law. Marx believed that (7)
Men establish certain links and relations to produce, and it is
only in the context of these links and social relations that their
relationship to nature exists and their production takes place....
(accordingly) every special historic mode of production has its own
special law of population ... under the demographic law of
capitalism, the working population, by producing capital
accumulation, increasingly produces resources that run into a
relatively surplus population; and this demographic law is inherent
in the capitalist mode of production ... that characterizes the
degree and kind of use of labour resources.
These Marxist demographic laws are basically "methods of
understanding". (8) They may provide refutable hypotheses. But our
point of view is that they are not backed by a clear theoretical
framework that elucidates the behavioural mechanisms of the implicit but
necessary micro and macro demographic adjustments. This analytic
weakness is evident in Volsky's discussion [95] of Latin
America's demographic problems and socioeconomic development.
Volsky, a member of the Moscow-based USSR Institute of Latin American
Studies, argues that accelerated population growth in Latin American
countries creates difficulties, that Latin American countries need a
well-grounded demographic policy, that such policy as exists in Latin
America is divorced from general socioeconomic policy (demographic
policy is used only for the purpose of measurement), that it (population
policy) suffers from the "negative attitude of the Catholic Church
on the use of artificial means to limit births", and that attention
must be given to "the struggle by the masses to have demographic
problems solved within the framework of radical overall changes"
(pp. 304-308). However, it seems that with few exceptions the decline in
mortality has been dramatic and uniform across the Latin American
countries and that the decline in fertility seems to be negatively
correlated with per capita income [102]. Cuba is the exceptional leader
in the decline of both mortality and fertility. But close contenders
include such socially and politically diverse countries as Chile,
Uruguay, Trinidad and Tobago, Jamaica and Argentina! Evidently, there is
a need for clearer conceptual guidelines. Does the neoclassical
perspective or the new World-System vision of development and
underdevelopment provide such needed conceptual guidelines?
b. The Neoclassical Perspective
The neoclassical (neo-Malthusian) school developed the Malthusian
analytical framework in two directions: macro growth models and micro
household economics. As mentioned earlier, neoclassical growth models
are based on the presence of perfect competition in both the product and
factor markets as well as on the assumption of constant returns to
scale. The literature is enormous and the relevance of this body of
theory to explaining actual situations even in the developed world has
been highly questioned. For a review and assessment, see Eltis [30] and
Pitchford [58]. For our purpose we narrow our focus on how population
growth is treated in these models. Three possibilities may be identified
[58]: (i) as an independent variable, (ii) as an endogenous variable,
and (iii) as a policy instrument. The first assumes a constant
population growth rate and may be labelled a descriptive neoclassical
growth model. To a large extent, the absolute size of population plays
no essential part in determining the results of this class of models.
Pitchford, critical of such implication, sums the lack of relevance of
such analysis to the developing countries' context as follows:
The originators of this approach were, of course, aware of this
sort of implication of their models, and it is true that for some
purpose it need not be a serious limitation ... yet there were
underdeveloped countries where there seemed to be a conflict
between population growth and economic welfare, and casual
observation of the real world would suggest that the time must come
when the same applied to developed countries. For these situations
the neoclassical growth model was not relevant. [58, p. 54]
As "the previous discussion illustrates, the Malthusian and
Ricardian growth paradigms treat population endogenously but the assumed
demographic behaviour is rather weak. Attempts to endogenize population
in the neoclassical framework were also questioned with regard to the
plausibility of their assumed demographic behaviour. Underlying recent
development is the concept of an "optimum population" size or
path which requires explicit assumptions about the adjustment process of
population. In most cases the adjustment is assumed instantaneous.
Again, according to Pitchford [58, p. 90] the utility of the models
diminishes greatly if it is assumed that
Population can be freely and instantaneously adjusted to any value
or that ... an adjustment process does take place [;] but the level
of population at any time is adjusted relative to the capital
movements and the process does not take into account the realities
of costs and restrictions on population movements. The "optimum"
level of population at any time may have no relevance at all to a
level that can be attained.
These classical-neoclassical conclusions may be illustrated by the
use of a variant of a graph developed by Eltis [30].
In Figure 2, the horizontal axis shows the rate of population
growth while the vertical axis shows the real wage rate. The Ss schedule
illustrates the hypothesized 'classical' supply curve of
population. At [W.sub.s], the rate of population growth (n) is zero. Its
rate of growth increases whenever [W.sub.1] exceeds W along the
[S.sub.s] schedule. The DD curve illustrates the society's demand
curve for population. It shows the rate of growth of population that the
economy can support, and
This depends on the rate of growth of circulating capital (i.e. the
rate of growth of the 'wage fund'), and this will grow more rapidly
in given technical conditions where wages are low so that profits
(which are largely reinvested) are high, than where wages are high,
leaving little surplus for accumulation. [30, p. 203]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Its negative slope indicates that a country will only accumulate
enough capital to support faster population growth at a lower real wage.
At [E.sub.1] there is a rate of growth of population [n.sub.1] and
real wage rate [W.sub.1] that are compatible with a rate of net capital
accumulation and an implied profit rate. But [W.sub.1] exceeds the
subsistent wage [W.sub.s]. The question is whether [W.sub.i] is a stable
econodemographic equilibrium? Various scenarios may be examined by the
use of Figure 2. In a Malthusian-Ricardian world [D.sub.2] will shift to
[D.sub.s] at [W.sub.s] the subsistent wage, the only long-term
equilibrium perceived by Malthus or Ricardo. In an optimistic neo-Malthusian world [D.sub.2] will shift outwards to [D.sub.3] through
new inventions and advanced technology. In a "population push"
scenario technological advance is a function of the rate of population
growth itself [17; 18]. However, it seems that this latter scenario
attempts to apply long-term historical experience to the recent
experience of developing countries with large exogenous shocks that took
place in relatively very short periods of time. It seems to compress a
thousand-year adjustment process into a 0.025 scale! Finally, according
to the neo-Malthusian scenario S will shift to [S.sub.2] where [W.sub.2]
exceeds [W.sub.s], implying a rising subsistence level, either through
increasing labour bargaining power or a more complex dynamic process of
economicdemographic household behaviour that includes reproduction as an
argument in an individual welfare function that is being maximized while
the level of "subsistent aspiration" is rising. One debatable policy implication is that total welfare may be maximized if demographic
behaviour is left to adjust itself freely in response to market forces.
Logically, such discussion leads to the study of the micro economic
foundation of demographic behaviour. The literature and debate on the
neoclassical theory of household fertility behaviour are known and need
no elaboration. It attempts to show, through the calculus of maximizing
behaviour based on individual self-interest, that fertility behaviour is
responsive to changes in the relative costs and benefits associated with
different reproductive strategies. The paradigm has been criticized on
various grounds [81; 85]. The debate, however, has advanced knowledge
about the complexity of the reproductive structure and its time
dimension. But, in the analysis, the focus is on individual action. It
has isolated individual behaviour from the long-term dynamics of
economic growth and social class formation. It is assumed that the
worker can improve his/her situation regardless of the pattern of class
development and without appeal to class solidarity--a questionable
proposition. It is a development paradigm that focuses its attention on
the micro elements of society, whether national or international, as
being "responsible for" their current undesirable status and
as being "able to change" such environment through individual
actions alone. In this neoclassical paradigm, group interactions,
whether intra- or inter-country, are basically ignored. This brings us
to an alternative viewpoint: a global view of development and
underdevelopment.
c. A World-System Vision
Development studies tend to regard underdevelopment as a social
"problem"--a syndrome in which Third World countries suffer
from a disease called underdevelopment or lack of modernity. The less
developed countries should consider the industrial nations as their
model of a healthy body and follow their path in terms of either
specific processes or historical stages. But the disease is diagnosed as
self-inflicted and localized inside the patient's body. Research
and policy analysis guided by this modernization syndrome concentrates
on problems internal to Third World countries. Linkage mechanisms
between the developing and the developed nations are outside the
paradigm and are not examined. The World-System vision, on the other
hand, treats development as part of integral totality. It must be
emphasized that the World-System paradigm is not a uniform entity. There
are differences of opinion with regard to conceptualization and
empirical methods.
As a historical note, the World-System view may be regarded as
starting with the insight of Lenin [49] into world imperialism and
Luxemburg's analysis of accumulation on a world scale [50]. (9) In
her analysis, she was able to show that accumulation and market
expansion in the industrial countries take place simultaneously with the
continuation of primitive accumulation in backward areas. Capitalism
does not only coexist with different economic structures but, being the
hegemonic mode of production, relies on less developed periphery
structures, those that are located in industrial countries (the urban
working class) and in the less developed ones (peasant labour) for the
extraction of surplus value.
Application to the Latin American case by Prebisch [60] and
associates includes some specification weaknesses and so does the
remedial attempt by Frank [35]. For example, Prebisch and associates of
the Economic Commission of Latin America (ECLA) fail to consider the
rise of monopoly capital that, in the face of technical innovation, is
able to simultaneously displace labour at the centre and also permit a
partial transfer of productivity rises among those not displaced.
Alternatively, Frank viewed the system as a single hierarchical vertical
chain of exploitation that extends the capitalist link in a descending
order from the capitalist world in the centre, to the national level,
the metropolises, all the way to the small peasants and the landless labourers; see Laclau [48], cited in [59]. The validity of this linear
conceptualization of the world has been questioned on theoretical and
empirical grounds.
However, Frank's vision of a hierarchical continuum of
exploitation cannot be completely ignored. For example, in pre-Nasser
rural Egypt, with cotton as the main cash crop, tenants squeezed the
landless workers (taraheel) below subsistence wages; landlords, in their
turn, squeezed as much surplus as they could from tenants; landlords,
seeking cash, made future cotton sales through financial intermediators
(mostly foreign), far below international market prices, and, finally,
at the core centre, the latter group was squeezed by industrialists and
traders in England.
In both visions, however, the process of reproduction of the labour
force in the periphery is not adequately explained [59, p. 8].
At present there has been a return, beyond the conceptualization of
Lenin and Luxemburg, to the original Marx. This is being accomplished
through the elucidation by A. Emmanuel (1972) and S. Amin [8] of a World
System based on the principle of Unequal Exchange. (10)
In general, the World System paradigm views the word economy as one
of a dual dialectic [26] : the dialectic between production and
circulation internal to each sector of the system, and the dialectic
between centre and periphery. (11)
Unequal exchange implies that surplus value, after allowing for
different capital investment or differential productivity, flows from
peripheral production into the core because of different levels of
remuneration to labour. S. Amin estimated that the value of this hidden
transfer was about US $ 22 billion in 1966 [8, p. 144], almost twice the
amount of "aid" and the private capital that the periphery
received.
Based on World-System analysis, what is the population mechanism
underlying this conceptual framework? This question was put more clearly
by Wallerstein as follows:
(What are the) mechanisms which permit the reduction of money wages
in peripheral activities below the level minimally required for the
reproduction of the labour-force and yet maintain the labour force
in existence? [97, p. 10]
Indeed, according to this paradigm, the continuing existence of a
labour surplus in the periphery is a necessary condition for depressing
wage rates and, accordingly, perpetuating the system of unequal
exchange. Samir Amin elaborates the dynamic nature of accumulation on a
world-wide scale as follows:
... the system tends to reproduce unceasingly the reserve army
which it needs to ensure the profitability of capital. This
fundamental law of accumulation
... inherent in the capitalist mode of production, operates in our
time on worldwide scale and no longer on that of each of the
central regions.. (and).. have now reached the state of
establishing a world-wide labour market. [7, p. xiii; emphasis
added]
But what is the mechanism through which this "unceasing
reproduction" of the labour surplus or "reserve army",
which is essential for this fundamental law of accumulation, takes
place? The determinants of this implied demographic behaviour is not
articulated in the system's analytic framework. For example, it is
not evident why the reproduction of the peripheral labour force should,
as a behavioural response, be automatic?
Recent empirical demographic evidence (e.g. The World Fertility
Survey Findings) seem not to support these hypothesized general laws of
reproductive response. There has been a secular fertility decline across
the various social classes in industrial countries. This secular decline
has been led by the educated and the professionals (core!), while the
cyclical behaviour of fertility cuts across all social groups. In the
less developed countries the experience suggests that reproductive
behaviour is a very complex phenomenon. This is the case, since, as we
argued elsewhere [85, pp. 10-14],
The current stage of the demographic transition, in which fertility
starts a sustained downward trend, might occur under different
styles and/or at different levels of socio-economic development.
But to understand the process of social and economic change,
four basic elements of the social system--and their
interrelationships--need attention.
The first, fundamental elements is the decision process at the
individual level.
The second is the institutional framework, which is responsible
for the formation and maintenance of social values and norm and
thereby limits and conditions individual action and choices, during
the course of development.
The third element is the role of the state. In its growing and
accepted role as an active agent of change and social engineering,
the state attempts to develop rational, co-ordinated plans to
initiate, spur and steer a process of social and economic
development.
The fourth element is related to the third: To what extent is
the local market integrated within and dependent upon the national
and international system of trade and finance?
During the course of socio-economic change, individual and group
relative positions in the social order change. Some of these,
although a consequence of the development process, may not have
been planned or anticipated, e.g. an increased occupational
differentiation that reduces the rigidity of social stratification,
or an improved system of information flow that reduces the cost of
mobility. Other changes, depending on the style of development, may
have been engineered by the corporate authority as, for example,
attempts to reduce inequity and/or enhance the process of social
mobility.
This process of change creates new roles, eliminates some
established ones and reduces the relative importance of others by
establishing new rules that govern their terms of exchange. The
result is tension and conflict between and within groups. It is the
dynamics of this conflict, the extent of its universality and the
path society takes for its resolution (i.e. its influence on the
trade-offs among individual needs, group needs and the more general
social needs) that produce different patterns of demographic
change.
It is evident that generalization about demographic change should
be guarded and context-pecific; see also [80; 83].
However, a key point to consider is this: if reproductive behaviour
could be modified by public policy, and the experience of the last
quarter-century illustrates the viability of such possibility [25; 53],
then why is it that the World-System framework ignored the possibility
of such social engineering in the analysis? For example, it did not
examine the implication of a potential dramatic decline in the
peripheral rate of population growth (i.e. labour force and reserve
army) to the behavioural dynamics of the system of accumulation on a
world-wide scale and, accordingly, to the welfare of the periphery. This
crucial question needs careful analysis. (12) Similarly, the implication
of the apparent secular decline in the rate of the population growth of
the capitalist group of countries needs equal attention. For example,
given the current declining fertility trends, it is estimated that the
size of the annual immigration flow required to stabilize the population
size in the Western industrial countries will be in the order of 2-3
million people by the dawn of the twenty-first century [19]. It seems
that the dualism between global theorizing and intermediate sub-process
analysis has created a conceptual gap yet to be bridged in the
development literature.
To summarize, population plays an important role in the various
development paradigms reviewed in this section. Its growth is important
for capital accumulation in the capitalistic system. In the Marxist
system, its differential growth by social classes provides the bases for
exploitation as well as for the ultimate demise of the capitalistic
system and for paving the way for socialism. The paradigm of unequal
exchange expands this last proposition to a world-wide scale. However,
the determinants and consequences of population dynamics are not
critically examined in either case. The neoclassical analysis attempts
to develop a behavioural theory of reproduction, but, being
individualistic in scope, it divorces itself from the very context of
development as a social issue.
However, regardless of whether it is the classical, Marxist, or the
Unequal Exchange system, an important conclusion (partly an outgrowth of
J.S. Mill's insight discussed above) emerges:
Changes in the structure and growth of population are assumed to
have causal linkage to the dynamics of production, accumulation,
and distribution. There is a delicate balance between the
reproduction of population and that of capital. The system of
distribution of the social product determines the stability of the
system. Population change is an integral part of the socioeconomic
system; it does not act in a vacuum.
This is an essential point to keep in mind when we examine, in the
following section, the applicability of the various paradigms to the
developing countries' situation, with the Arab countries as a case
study.
4. DEVELOPMENT PARADIGMS: HOW APPLICABLE TO THE ARAB CASE?
a. The Setting
The current phase of population and economic change in the Arab
world is unique in terms of the magnitude of change in its parameters,
but is not unexpected. The general demographic-economic characteristics
of the system are rather simple. The story is familiar. Our purpose is
not to document events and trends but rather to evaluate the
applicability of the various development paradigms in explaining and
predicting the emerging general patterns.
The general outline of the demographic picture has been presented
earlier. The Arab population is one of the fastest growing in the world
and because of its young age structure has a long-term built-in growth
momentum. Arab demography follows the familiar transitions of the less
developed countries that experienced colonial domination. Our contention
is that this transition is part and parcel of the technological
development of capitalism and its implied international exchange system.
At the turn of the century, investment in public health measures started
slowly and was limited to ensuring the adequate reproduction of the work
force involved in the production of the export primary goods needed to
fuel the engine of the industrial revolution (e.g. cotton in Egypt and
the Sudan), and in the civil and police administration required for
ensuring an efficient flow of these goods and safety of the colonial
presence. Countries or areas outside this international exchange system
did not have this limited social benefit! A global conscience for an
international health policy had not been born at the time. However, as
evident from our discussion, exogenous health improvement that occurs in
isolation from an integrated economicdemographic development policy is
not a "sufficient" condition for increasing "net"
social welfare. Under such conditions, public health could turn in the
longer term into public hazard!
As "direct" colonialism declined, interest in economic
development among the newly independent nations became a primary focus,
at both national and international levels. In many countries,
"average" health status improved. Among the Arab countries,
the decline in mortality became more dramatic after World War II and
accelerated, especially in the oil-exporting countries, after the oil
boom. Fertility, on the other hand, did not show any significant
departure from its high level up to the present [104]. Accordingly, the
rate of population growth accelerated. This demographic picture raises a
pivotal question: is the accelerated reproduction of the potential
labour force in the Arab world warranted by the pace and structure of
capital accumulation and by the structure of the production relation in
the region? Our answer is in the negative. We even assert that within
the present socio-political context, the long-term demographic trends,
implied in the current structure and parameters of the population could
have dire consequences for the countries of the region as a whole,
whether they be importers or exporters of labour/ capital. How could we
reach such conclusions in the face of what appeared to be clear
contradictory evidence as illustrated, for example, by
(i) a huge inflow of expatriate non-Arab labour;
(ii) apparent underpopulation as illustrated by such crude measures
as density; or
(iii) a large financial capital outflow that finds no adequate
internal outlet.
The combination of these three elements may constitute, on the
basis of "Says" prediction, the possibility of a process of
self-sustained growth in the area, since the supply of national labour
(replacing expatriates over time) may create its own demand, especially
if low density implies the presence of unutilized natural resources and
of the potential creation of a large market through an efficient
accumulation of capital financed by oil revenue. However, on close
examination, the viability of such argument depends on the presence of
specific internal and external conditions that may not materialize
within the present system of international capital accumulation and its
underlying dynamics of the world demographic transition. Our main
argument depends on a modified classical-Marxist dictum:
Capital has no feelings for any negative consequences resulting
from disequilibrium in human reproduction. It only reproduces what
it needs for its own reproduction and accumulation. On a world-wide
scale, where national or community bondages are weaker, it disposes
more freely of redundancy. As the world society becomes more
"technicalized", where "technique" controls "technology", the
criterion of efficiency takes supreme status--disposing of
redundancy becomes more cruel. (13)
Let us elaborate. First we briefly review current efforts to
develop an Arab population development paradigm. Then we outline and
evaluate the current Arab--international system of production and
exchange from the viewpoint of a worldwide system paradigm.
b. A Note on Arab Population-Development Paradigm
Is there an "Arab Population Development Paradigm" that
differs from those reviewed above? This is a difficult question to
answer. There has been a large and growing literature on Arab
development styles by Arab economists and social scientists but no
dominant "Arab" development philosophy similar, for example,
to the "Latin American School" has emerged. At the cost of
under-representation (and probably over-simplification) we will focus on
four recent contributions. The first, by G. Amin [4], is an attempt at
classification and evaluation of the various development paradigms
reflecting the planning experience in the Arab world. The second is a
collection of articles on Arab development [24]. It includes
contributions on the subject published in the Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi in
1983-84, reviewed by Abdel-Khalik [2]. The third is an interview by S.
Amin [6] on Independent Development and the Third World. The recent
works of R. Zaki [106] and N. Fergani [33] on the population problems
with emphasis on Arab development constitute the fourth contribution.
Galal Amin [4] argues that the development experience in the Arab
world has been a result of the dynamic interaction of three schools of
thought: laical liberalism, laical Marxism and traditionalism.
Traditionals, dominated by the Islamic movement, regained purpose after
the collapse of the Nasserist experience--by blaming its collapse on the
system's failure to acknowledge religion as the foundation and
blueprint for inspiring and specifying development strategies. The
negative economic and social side-effects of the Sadat "open
policy" and the spectacular success of the Iranian Islamic
revolution in ousting a strong regime backed by the strongest of
super-powers reinforced the traditional stance, defining the development
problem as a lack of purpose. In their view, societal problems have
solutions in Islamic principles and not in imported ideologies.
Laical liberalism also gained ground after Nasser and Sadat. The
real problem of underdevelopment is seen as being a lack of scientific
development and the application of scientific methods and techniques not
only in production and organization, but also in governing and in
personal relations. They view independent development as unrealistic in
a highly interdependent world. They adhere to the principle of the
market, competition, and a small government. To a large extent, laical
liberalism may be labelled neoclassical.
Laical Marxists, according to the typology of G. Amin [4], are
equally enthusiastic about the power of science and technology but see
the international system of dependency and unequal exchange as major
obstacles to development. They also differ from the laical liberals in
stressing the need for restructuring the society as a prerequisite of
ensuring long-term equity even if it means a slower pace of development.
With the exception of the traditionals, the liberals
(neoclassicals) and the Marxists do not present new paradigms. It is
curious that the traditional paradigm was not represented in that
important collection of articles on Arab Development: Present and
Potential [24]. (14) What is included has been categorized by
Abdel-Khalik [2] as belonging to various themes of Marxism. Both
Abdel-Khalik [4] and Fergani [33] argue that no dominant Arab
development paradigm exists at present. We may also add that the
demographic content in the theoretical analysis presented in the book is
limited. In his introduction to the volume, A. Hossain [42] provided a
deep and penetrating assessment of the theoretical contributions but
does not dwell on the absence of population-development analysis in the
book. We can safely conclude that in the discussions of the six
theoretical contributions there is no attempt made to provide the
conceptual basis for a unified population and development policy.
In a stimulating interview, S. Amin [6] examines development in the
Arab world from his familiar world-wide Unequal Exchange System. The
solution, similar to that in his other work [7], is to focus on the
agricultural sector, fully utilize the potential labour force, increase
demand through more equity (wage equalization), and in the initial stage
make industry subordinate to agricultural development, i.e. produce what
is required to enhance agricultural productivity. It is reminiscent of
the original Chinese model. The discussion provides a general outline.
Details, especially as to how this development vision relates to the
particular nature of population dynamics and labour mobility in the
region, are left out at this stage.
The book by R. Zaki is an ambitious attempt to provide such a
vision. It provides a well-researched historical viewpoint on population
in economic thought. Most of it, however, is an attack on the
neo-Malthusian framework, repeating and reinforcing well-known
reservations. Zaki's main thesis (p. 455) is that the present
population problem is not a Malthusian race between population growth
and the development of resources but rather a race between high
population growth and a stagnant socioeconomic structure that is unable
to ignite the engine for true development. We certainly agree with the
diagnosis but we do not understand the rationale for excluding
controlling of population change as a policy parameter, especially if,
as our previous analysis of the various paradigms illustrates, the
"stagnant" socioeconomic structure is a function of population
growth! Actually the result of Zaki's contribution is a set of
standard propositions calling for liberating the economy, realizing
independent developments, self-reliance and more equity based on
well-intentioned social criteria. The analysis, however, falls far short
of integrating population dynamics with development in a systematic
framework. The same reservations apply to Fergani's discussion of
population and development in the Arab world [33]. (15) One of the
possible sources of confusion is mixing of short-term with long-term
changes in population, and, accordingly, their determinants and
consequences [81] .
c. The Anatomy of Arab Economic-Demographic Development
The Arab region has witnessed dramatic socio-economic and political
shocks during the past three decades that are unparalleled, in terms of
size or intensity, by other historical events that took place in the
region arid that influenced significantly the structural pattern of
production and consumption. On an abstract level, the present experience
of the Arab region provides a classic study or a test-lab to examine the
applicability of many assertions and conclusions derived from the
various development paradigms discussed earlier. Indeed, the dynamics
and the relations involved are very complex. But, given our
economic-demographic focus, we abstract ourselves from many of the fine,
albeit important, details.
To facilitate the discussion, the complex relations will be reduced
to three main actors. The first represents the source of demand for oil
and supplier of industrial goods and technology (Industria). The second
is the owner of the primary resource (oil) required for industrial
production (Resourcia). The third has a rate of population growth
(supply) that is faster than the demand for labour generated by its
present local condition of production and capital accumulation
(Subsistencia). Figure 3 provides a schematic presentation of the
operation of this simplified system. As mentioned earlier, the story is
a familiar one and needs no detailed elaboration or documentation. For
simplicity, only Arab and industrial countries are identified in Figure
3. The implication to other developing countries can be inferred. The
basic data discussed in the text are presented in Table 2. The Arab
countries are divided into two main groups: Resourcia and Subsistencia
(16). The third group represents the industrial nations (the core) and
labelled Industria. There are three direct pairs of relations: (a)
Resourcia-Industria, (b) Subsistencia-Resourcia, and (c)
Subsistencia-Industria. Each relation has its own past history, present
short-term dynamics, and future long-term paths. The first two relations
will be examined in turn, first from the viewpoint of each group in
isolation, then as an integrated Arab community within a world-wide
system vision. Discussion of the third relation will be incorporated in
the discussion of the second relation and in the concluding remarks.
a. Resourcia--Industria
The past experience of this relation is wide-ranging. It takes its
roots from the reminiscence of the Ottoman Empire and the French
colonization of Algeria to that of the Italian in Libya and the British
in Iraq and Arabia. The colonial past is important in understanding the
present pattern of development. But the present is largely dominated and
shaped by oil. The shape of recent ten-year history of Resourcia's
changing fortunes may be summarized as follows:
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
1. Resourcia exports oil to Indusria.
2. Oil revenue exceeds Resourcia's initial capacity to invest.
Between 1973 and 1983, Arab oil-exporting countries earned a total of
approximately US $ 1,347 billion in which Saudi Arabia's share was
28 percent and Kuwait's was 9 percent; see Editorial in [87].
3. Resourcia embarks on a spectacular programme of building
physical and human infrastructures.
4. Excess revenue is ploughed back to Industria.
5. Resourcia has limited manpower relative to the pace of its
investment expenditure.
6. Resourcia opens its door to expatriate labour.
7. Resourcia (with the exception of Iraq) does not adopt
naturalization as an option for reducing the "transitional"
shortage of its national labour supply.
8. Resourcia adopts a strong pro-natalist policy.
9. Resourcia transfers part of its new wealth in terms of producer
and consumer subsidies to its nationals for social and political
reasons, and, with an open door policy for admitting expatriates from
all nationalities, new high levels of per capita consumption in general,
and conspicuous consumption in particular, take hold in a very short
period.
10. Resourcia gets committed to an expensive arms purchase
programme and to financing local wars and uprisings. According to some
estimates Saudi Arabia's annual military expenditure alone
increased from U.S. $ 7 billion to U.S. $ 22 billion between 1976 and
1981 and has remained at that high level since; see Editorial in [87].
11. Resourcia's expenditure plans are based initially on
optimistic "expectations" of trends in oil demand and prices.
12. Prices and volumes of Resourcia's imports increase
relative to the value of oil exports "realized" (short of
"expectations"). It is estimated that the import price for
OPEC increased by 350 percent between 1973 and 1977.
13. Resourcia, being committed to OPEC production, ambitious
development plans, and social welfare expenditures, runs a sizeable
deficit. In the first quarter of 1985 Resourcia's trade deficit in
relation to USA alone increased by 23 percent from the 1984 level of $
1.25 billion [54(b), p. 5]. Since the early '80s Resourcia's
position was reversed from one of a net buyer to that of a just seller
of equities and securities in the US market, ha 1984 Resourcia was a net
seller of $ 2 billion of U.S. equities, corporate bonds and
treasuries--a 60-percent increase over the 1983 level [54(b), p. 21].
The dramatic change in the economic position of Saudi Arabia--the giant
of OPEC--is illustrative. At present, the Saudi budget deficit is second
only to that of the USA: its oil revenue fell by 60 percent between 1981
and 1984, its foreign exchange reserve fell by 40 percent between 1983
and 1984, and it is estimated that foreign workers left the Kingdom at
the rate of 50,000 a month during 1984 [28, p. 55].
14. Resourcia has to evaluate its stance on OPEC oil policy, on
foreign investment criteria, on international assistance programmes, on
its national subsidy and welfare policies, and on expatriate labour
policy.
The response of Industria to the initial increase in the price of
oil has been an attempt to maintain a tolerable balance between negative
short-term consequences such as a rise in unemployment rates, in
balance-of-trade deficits, or in minimizing negative structural
consequences of recycling a substantial oil revenue that is flowing back
from Resourcia, on the one hand, and the longer-term central issue of
coping with the technical, institutional, and other structural
adjustments necessary for maintaining the "centre's"
dominance over the "periphery", on the other. The set of
policy tools used by Industria, given the intra-Industria contradiction
of competition on market shares, includes the direct and indirect
manipulation of the structure of interest rates, of exchange rates, and
of domestic inflation rates, as illustrated schematically in Figure 3.
However, the dynamic nature of these issues will be taken as datum and
not examined in the present analysis, since they cover a wide spectrum
of issues that go beyond the scope of the present inquiry. Our main
focus is limited to understanding the economic-demographic behavioural
response of Resourcia and Subsistencia to the present phase of the
technological-demographic transition.
What does the future hold for Resourcia? Seeking the future through
a looking glass could be misleading. We may only see our own images,
i.e. preconceived ideas and ideologies. This is more a reminder to the
present authors than a reflection on the state of the art. The future
results from interaction among the forces of accumulated experience,
external exogenous factors (whether by design or random), and the
conscious effort within Resourcia to shape its future. Let us consider
these issues within the context of the various paradigms.
To many futurists, oil is the main actor. Its course provides the
main "course" for future scenarios. As Mabro [51, p. 55-58]
and Sayegh [71], have shown, there is now a change from a sellers'
to a buyers' market. According to many scholars, during its prime,
oil has been beneficial, not only in igniting economic activities in
Resourcia but also as a weapon in the hands of the South for the
North-South negotiations [15; 78, p. 255]. This last view was also
advocated by S. Amin [6]--a champion of the Unequal Exchange paradigm.
It is ironic, since "the weapon" seems to have another edge:
integrating Resourcia into the international system of Unequal Exchange
and cementing its "dependency"! However, the relevance of a
sellers' or a buyers' market to the analysis of long-run
dynamics, especially in the context of Resourcia development, is not
evident to us.
Oil has always enjoyed a buyers' market. Its demand stems from
the technological needs of Industria. Capital needs it for its own
reproduction. This is the long-run view of the socio-demographic
transition that has taken place since the beginning of the industrial
revolution as mentioned earlier in the paper. The events of the
Seventies are short-term repercussions. The Eighties return to the
long-term course. There are important insights that arise from this last
view:
1. Oil production is a highly capital-intensive activity. The idea
of a "reserve army" of labour or the "reproduction"
of capital through labour, or the mutual benefit, though
"unequal", between core and periphery becomes irrelevant in
elucidating the Industria-Resourcia relationship.
2. The dramatic increase in revenue supports the institution of
small, otherwise non-viable states within Resourcia.
3. Maintaining high oil prices will continue until Industria
adjusts itself to the diffusion of new technologies. (17) In 1975, H.
Kissinger was reported as
presenting, in Europe, a plan for an investment programme of one
thousand billion dollars for the development of new sources of
energy ... Dr Kissinger has also been very particularly
adamant--that the price of petroleum had to rise and remain high in
order to make it profitable to develop these alternative sources of
energy [36, p. 854].
In 1979, there was another price hike. In 1980 the Iraq-Iran war
started. One of its outcomes is a reduction in oil supplies. In that
respect, M.A. Adelman indicates that
"Another cartel resource is the instability and violence of
some members ... The Iran-Iraq war has been a piece of great good luck;
the next fighting may be due more to good management"! [3, p. 20].
4. Human resource development is a long-run commitment. The fast
pace of building the necessary infrastructures implied in the
socioeconomic plans and the large inflow of expatriate labour required
for that phase of economic activities have generated confusing signals
between short-term and long-term needs. It has also created a
"segmented" labour market that violates basic neoclassical
assumptions [86]. In essence the "Dutch Disease" that is being
blamed for the decline of non-oil traded goods in the manufacturing
sector in the new oil-exporting industrial countries such as the
Netherlands and England--see, for example, [99] and [69]--might be
responsible for creating serious imbalances in the human resource sector
in the Arab world. The Dutch Disease may be labelled the Human Resource
Disease in the present context of the Arab world. There is a dire need
for a full analysis of the relationships between policies that provide
subsidies to producers, to education, to housing, and to the importation
of labour on the one hand, and the attaining of desired social
objectives on the other. (18)
5. In the midst of the expenditure euphoria generated by the
expanding oil revenue, a fundamental truth seems to have been forgotten:
the dramatic expansion of the native population could not have been
supported without the oil revenue. Without that revenue, population
growth of the native population is excessive. The vital question to be
addressed is: Do current efforts provide the base for a viable
employment of the existing and growing labour supply? As it stands, the
demand for expatriate labour is a consumption demand; it will become a
production demand if the answer to the above question is in the
affirmative.
6. Finally, the long-term negative impact of the emerging pattern
of consumption behaviour needs no emphasis. The intergenerational implication of this behaviour is yet to be assessed. What will be the
mechanism of public and private adjustment to a decline in oil revenue
and at what cost? These are questions that need inclusion in the current
research agenda of future Arab development.
These last two points have serious implication for the development
case of Subsistencia.
b. Subsistencia--Resourcia
The literature on the development experience of the Subsistencia
group is substantial. (19) Our focus is limited to highlighting a few
issues in the recent Subsistencia-Resourcia interaction. For many
analysts, inter-regional labour migration is the main focus. (20) The
emphasis has been on the role of remittances, the social and political
impact of Arab versus non-Arab expatriate labour in the receiving
countries, on the sectoral imbalances created in Subsistencia as a
result of selective immigration, and on civil rights issues. As
indicated in Figure 3, the migration flow (and its remittance counter-flow) has been substantial. This is evident in Table 2 in the
rise of unrequited transfers to Egypt from abroad, from 29 million in
1970 to 2,074 million in 1982, or expressed as a percentage of
merchandise exports, from 63.9 percent in 1973 to 72.5 percent in 1980
[44]. For Syria, official unrequited transfers went up from 7 million in
1970 to 140 million in 1982, or from 53.5 percent of merchandise exports
in 1974 to 72.0 percent in 1980. Other Subsistencia countries also show
a similar increase in unrequited transfers. We argued above that its
occurrence has been an outcome of the specific resource base
characteristic of Resourcia and the demand for oil generated in
Industria.
Another main effect of migration from Subsistencia has to do with
sectoral
imbalances. Again, the story is known, although empirical evidence is
not always conclusive. The dramatic increase in remittances has created
an equally dramatic increase in the demand for goods and services in
Subsistencia. For example, food imports increased substantially in all
countries of Subsistencia between 1974 and 1982 as illustrated in Table
2. Some countries like Egypt, Sudan, Morocco and Jordan received
substantial food aid as well. However, food production did not keep pace
with that exogenous and sudden increase in demand. The issue has been
examined extensively in the literature; see for example [100] on
agriculture and development. We argued elsewhere [79; 82] that another
important reason has to do with the dynamic interaction of emigration and agricultural production on the micro level. As a consequence of
various factors, including emigration, the merchandise balance was
negative for all countries in Subsistencia and exceeded the value of
remittances by a wide margin. Subsistencia fell into the international
debt circle. External public debt as a percentage of GNP increased from
an average of 19 percent in 1970 to 47 percent in 1982. Indeed, there
are positive elements to emigration. But whether these are short-term
gains that reverse direction over time is precisely the point being made
in this paper.
It must be emphasized that the sudden and external increase in the
demand for labour in Subsistencia is derived from the structure of the
Industria demand for oil and only conditioned by the pattern of
development expenditure in Resourcia. It seems to have diffused any
concern with serious long-term population-development policy that could
deal squarely with the imbalances between the reproduction and
accumulation of capital and labour. The fact that the reproduction and
"accumulation" of population in Subsistencia have been ignited and accelerated by forces external to the pace of social change, that
such forces are of short-term nature and its reversal as discussed above
is inevitable, and that they need to be dealt with by simultaneously
adjusting the two sides of the equation as well as the social framework
to accommodate these necessary changes, has been brushed aside. More
seriously, short-term events are being perceived as permanent phenomena,
as illustrated, for example, by proposals to maximize migration returns
through establishment of training programmes or other means that
increase the efficiency of the labour export market [75]. There is
similarity here between the rejection by the Marxist philosophy of the
neo-Malthusian population solution on the premise that it may provide a
diversion of the long-run march for the ultimate solution, and that the
acceptance by Subsistencia the short-term consequences of emigration as
a temporary relief for its demographic-economic ills without regard to
the longer-term negative impact.
5. CONCLUSIONS
The discussion in the paper relates to conceptual and application
issues. On the conceptual level, we hope we contributed a bridge between
global theorizing and intermediate process analysis. The main thesis may
be summarized as revolving around the following proposition mentioned
earlier:
Changes in the structure and growth of population are assumed to
have causal linkage with the dynamics of production, accumulation,
and distribution. There is a delicate balance between the
reproduction of population and that of capital. The system of
distributing the social product determines the stability of the
social system.
In the Western as well as the Eastern industrial transition
experiences, the balance between the demographic forces and capital
accumulation was maintained, in the natural course of events, within
tolerable bounds. When large diversions occurred (never as large as the
present experience of the developing countries), outlets were found in
the colonizations of new lands. Changes in fertility and mortality were
both a negative function of the process of industrialization. They were
endogenous to the system. Indeed, if they were not, the system must have
had a different solution and, accordingly, a different outcome. This
simple truth seems to be forgotten when applying the various paradigms.
A decline in fertility that is independent of, and achieved in the
absence of, the true forces of a self-sustained process of capital
accumulation in the context of an integrated social development
framework, cannot be considered either a necessary or sufficient
condition for development. We agree that fertility policy should be part
and parcel of development strategy. But we add that the same must be
true for mortality. To illustrate, most demographic-economic models
incorporate a population growth equation of the Lotka type [ 12;47]. The
equation relates birth per unit of time, B(t), to the preceding flow of
births, given a survival probability parameter, p(t, x), and the
probability of bearing a child, m(t, x). In their analysis of optimal
time paths, Arthur and McNicoll specified the equation as follows [12,
p. 5] :
B(t) = [[integral].sup.[omega].sub.0] B(t-x) p(t, x) m(t, x) v(t)
dx: t [??] [t.sub.0]
where
B(t) is assumed given and continuous for times [t.sub.0] - [omega]
[??] t < [t.sub.0;]
p(t, x) is the probability that a birth at time t - x survives to
age x;
m(t, x) is the probability of bearing a child (assuming no
fertility control) at time t if aged x;
[omega] is an upper bound on the length of life; and
v(t) is a policy factor manipulating the age-schedule of fertility
m(t, x). For example, v(t) = 1 implies no control, v(t) < 1 implies
policy to discourage fertility.
In an optimizing framework, the optimal economic-demographic policy
is dervied by selecting the saving rate and the fertility control
paramaters that maximize over time a specified welfare function. For a
detailed discussion of optimal accumulation paths of population and the
economy within a framework that incorporates the age dimension, the
reader is referred to Arthur and McNicoll [12]. Our present concern is
limited to the implication of the analysis to an integrated policy of
health, fertility, migration and capital accumulation. The point is that
the path of the mortality function, although the opposite image of the
fertility function, is outside the optimization policy control
procedure. But it is precisely because of the exogenous nature of the
large and accelerated mortality decline that took place in the recent
experience of the developing countries that it is imperative to reduce
fertility in a compatible pace. It seems that the pace of mortality
decline is essential for the solution of the optimization policy
exercise. On the practical side, this latter policy cannot succeed
without endogenizing the two determinants of the natural growth of
population, viz. mortality and fertility. But endogenizing the mortality
function implies a level of "effective" demand for adequate
health behaviour that is sustainable on the individual and community
levels. In short, "public" health as a commodity must be
"earned".
In his concluding chapter in one of the most thorough analyses of
the Egyptian economy during the Sadat era, Adel Hossain [42, pp. 641-42]
raises the question as to how it was possible to completely uproot the
foundation of Nasser's social revolution in such a short period of
time. The question was left less than partially answered. Is it possible
that, in the presence of a huge demographic imabalnce, some of the
cosmetic distribution policies of the social product, e.g. increased
public employment or consumer subsidies, were not sufficient to provide
true system stability?
The recent pragmatic shift in China's population policy and a
comparison with that of Korea may give credence to our point of view.
Comparing Korea with China provides a classic case of the fallacy of
composition. What is true for the part may not be true for the whole.
Korea, having great success in both its economic and population
policies, was also able to export its excess labour through an
export-led labour-intensive strategy, albeit at a great social cost. It
seems that China knew that it could not replicate the same strategy,
given its large scale. China's population policy is more dramatic
and, for some Marxist "believers", implied an ideological
twist. We disagree, as our analysis implied. The socio-economic cost of
China's population policy will be borne more intergenerationally
and less by letting the country be absorbed in the "Worldwide
Unequal Exchange System". We feel that the "why" needs no
more elaboration. It is the "how" that needs elucidation.
On the application side, the current socio-economic status of the
Arab world can be better understood within the long-term perspectives of
the international demographic-industrial transition--a transition that
has two known effects. The first is the latent but dramatic increase in
population rates of growth in the less developed countries--the Arab
world being no exception. This sudden and unbalanced (only mortality
declined) demographic change does not necessarily produce those positive
outcomes predicted by the optimistic neoclassical, Marxist or
post-Marxist paradigms. Logically, the same paradigms could equally
indicate an unnecessary cost if trends are left unchecked.
The second effect is the role of Resourcia as a provider of the
resource necessary for fuelling the demographic-industrial transition.
Since the decline of the textile industry in England, an industry that
relied on labour-intensive cotton cultivation, the demographic
component, essential in the hypothesized accumulation process of the
"World System" paradigm, has lost its relevance. Oil is now
the main actor in the equation. It is a highly capital-intensive
industry located in areas with national boundaries that lack other
resources. From this point of view, conventional paradigms fail to give
guidance. Economic and demographic trends in both Resourcia and
Subsistencia indicate severe imbalances.
The overall picture can be viewed as overly pessimistic. But there
are positive notes. In the context of the Middle East, the Arab
countries cannot continue to live beyond its means, expanding and
changing the pattern of its consumption far ahead of its real production
capabilities. The present national boundaries are preventing the region
from achieving its full potential. Within these limited boundaries
potential growth is limited at best and continuous dependency is
inevitable. Even if more efficient economic policies are pursued, as
long as they are pursued in isolation, this will be the case. The
momentum of population growth, if it does not find its requirements of
adequate capital accumulation to generate a real and balanced demand
within a cohesive socio-cultural framework, will write its own demise.
We feel that this will be the future as long as the Arab world continues
to be divided. Political unions based on short-term convenience are not
sufficient. The challenge to development may be characterized in G.
Myrdal's terminology as both a drama and a dilemma. Unfortunately,
this is where optimism gives way, since rejecting real medicines based
on non-scientific conclusions is a common characteristic of the real
world.
Finally, we conclude with a vision that we hope crosses national,
ideological and even species boundaries in this ever-shrinking world
that hosts us. It is evident that we are witnessing the birth of a new
scientific revolution: the post-industrial information society. A new
core will be established [19]. But, more importantly, the information
revolution will certainly imply new rules governing the
accumulation-reproduction game, thus setting the stage for a new
socio-demographic transition. The relevance of current paradigms has to
be critically and continuously reexamined. As we adjust ourselves to the
difficult present situation, we must also keep an eye on the future.
Basic researches in genetic engineering, the functioning of the brain,
and artificial intelligence are trespassing each other's domain,
producing exciting and unexpected results. It is possible, and evidence
about it is accumulating, that fundamental changes may occur which will
influence all facts of human organizations including biological and
social foundations of reproduction as we know them now.
As we mentioned earlier, we cannot judge the utility of the end
result of this relentless "march of technique", since this
"march" is not guided by a recognizable social welfare
objective. As Toynbee [92] indicated, it seems as if society is moving
its 'head' far ahead of the 'heart'! (21) On the
optimistic side, Ledyard Stebbins [88, p. 440] believes in the
"durability" of the human race even under conditions of severe
social and biological stresses. His conclusions are based on the
historical evidence of the survival ability of slaves and conquered
people under unbearable conditions. But, as the discussion illustrates,
these were the outcome of a socio-economic system that included in its
internal dynamics a maldistribution of a growing social output and not
the genesis of its destruction. There is a written rule in at least one
leading scientific research institute in the developing world that
forbids its members to sleep during working hours. But, aside from the
possibility of a lack of environmental "incentive" how could
we advance without dreams, even those including nightmares!
REFERENCES
[1.] Abdallah, Ismail Sabri. "Reflections on Planning
Experience: The Arab Nation and the Third World". In CAUS, Arab
Development: Present, Possible and the Future. Beirut. 1984. pp.
195-218. (In Arabic)
[2.] Abdel-Khalik, Gouda. "Review of Arab Development:
Present, Possible and the Future". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab
Future). No. 79. 1985. (In Arabic)
[3.] Adelman, M.A. "An Unstable World Oil Market". Energy
Journal. Vol. 6, No. 1. 1985.
[4.] Amin, Galal A. "Heritage of Arab Development".
Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 72. 1985. pp. 4-22. (In
Arabic)
[5.] Amin, Samir. Accumulation on a Worm Scale: A Critique of the
Theory of Underdevelopment. Trans. Brian Pearce. New York: Monthly
Review Press. 1974.
[6.] Amin, Samir. "Independent Development and the Third
World". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 59. January
1984. pp. 114-124. (In Arabic)
[7.] Amin, Samir. "Introduction". In S. Amin (ed.), Human
Resources: Employment and Development: Developing Countries. Vol. 5.
London: The Macmillan Press Ltd. 1984.
[8.] Amin, Samir. Unequal Development, An Essay on the Social
Formations of Peripheral Capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press.
1976.
[9.] Arab Monetary Fund (eds.). The Unified Arab Economic Report.
Arab Monetary Fund. 1984. (In Arabic)
[10.] Arab Planning Institute. Socio-economic Development in the
Arab Countries. Kuwait: Arab Planning Institute. 1982. (In Arabic)
[11.] Arndt, H.W. "The Origins of Structuralism". World
Development. Vol. 13, No. 2. 1985. pp. 151-159.
[12.] Arthur, W. Brian, and Geoffrey McNicoll. "Optimal Time
Paths with Age-Dependence: A Theory of Population Policy".
Discussion Paper. New York: The Population Council. 1975.
[13.] Azzam, Henri. "Urbanization and Economic Development in
the Arab World". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 52.
June 1983. pp. 100-117. (In Arabic)
[14.] Bach, Robert L. "The Reproduction of Trivality: Critical
Notes on Recent Attempts to Test the Dynamics of World Capitalism".
Department of Sociology, State University of New York. New York:
Binghampton. 1978. (Memeographed)
[15.] Bhagwati, Jagdish N., and John Gerard Ruggie (eds.). Power,
Passions and Purpose, Prospects for North-South Negotiations. Cambridge,
Mass.: MIT Press. 1984.
[16.] Blaug, Mark. Economic Theory in Retrospect. New York:
Cambridge University Press. 1985.
[17.] Boserup, Ester. The Condition of Agricultural Growth.
Chicago: Aldine. 1965.
[18.] Boserup, Ester. Population and Technological Change: A Study
of Long-term Trends. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 1981.
[19.] Bouvier, Leon F. Planet Earth 1984-2034: A Demographic
Vision. Washington, D.C.: Population Reference Bureau. 1984.
[20.] Brenner, R. "The Origins of Capitalist Development: A
Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism". New Left Review. Vol. 104. 1977.
pp. 21-25.
[21.] Bukharin, Nikolai Ivanovich. Economic Theory of the Leisure
Class. Connecticut: Greenwood Press. 1927.
[22.] Bukharin, Nikolai Ivanovich. Economics of the Transformation
Period. New York: Bergman Press. 1971.
[23.] Cassen, Robert, and Margaret Wolfson (eds.). Planning for
Growing Populations. Paris: Development Center of the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development. 1978.
[24.] CAUS. Arab Development: Present, Possible and the Future.
Beirut: Center for Arab Unity Studies. 1984. (In Arabic)
[25.] Cuca, Roberto. Family Planning Programs: An Evaluation of
Experience. Washington: World Bank. 1979. (Working Paper No. 345)
[26.] De Janvry, Alain, and Carlos Garramon. "Laws of Motion of Capital in the Center-periphery Structure". Review of Radical
Political Economies. Vol. 9. Summer 1977. pp. 29-38.
[27.] Demeny, Paul. "A Perspective on Long-term Population
Growth". New York: The Population Council, Center for Policy
Studies. 1984. (Working Paper No. 104)
[28.] Economist, The London Weekly. July 13, 1985.
[29.] Ellul, Jacques. The Technological Society. New York: Vintage
Books. 1964.
[30.] Eltis, W.A. Growth and Distribution. London: The Macmillan
Press Ltd. 1973.
[31.] Fergani, Nader. "The Absence of Development in the Arab
Nation". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 60. February
1984. pp. 6-34. (In Arabic)
[32.] Fergani, Nader. Migration to Oil: Dimension of Labour
Migration to the Oil Countries and its Effect on Arab Development.
Beirut: Center for Arab Policy Studies. 1983. (In Arabic)
[33.] Fergani, Nader. "Population and Development in the Arab
World". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 67. 1984. pp.
73-91. (In Arabic)
[34.] Foster-Carter, Aidan. "From Rostow to Gunder Frank:
Conflicting Paradigms in the Analysis of Underdevelopment". World
Development. Vol. 4, No. 3. March 1976. pp. 167-180.
[35.] Frank, Andre Gunder. Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin
America. New York: Monthly Review Press. 1967.
[36.] Frank, Andre Gunder. "Economic Crises, Third World and
1984". Worm Development. Vol. 4, No. 10/11. 1976. pp. 853-861.
[37.] Al-Gammal, Rasem M. "Foreign Trade and Increasing Arab
Dependency, 1970-1980". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future).
No. 53. July 1983. pp. 39-45. (In Arabic)
[38.] Gereffi, Gary. "A Critical Evaluation of Quantitative
Cross-national Studies of Dependency". Paper presented at the Panel
on Dependency Theory, meetings of the International Association,
Toronto. March 1979.
[39.] Hammel, E.A. The China Lectures. Programme in Population
Research. Berkeley: University of California. 1983. (Working Paper No.
10)
[40.] Hirschman, A.O. Essays in Trespassing. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press. 1981.
[41.] Hobson, J.A. Imperialism. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 1971.
[42.] Hossain, Adel. The Egyptian Economy: from Independence to
Dependency, 1974-1979. Two Volumes. Cairo: Dar Al-Mostaqbal Al-Arabi.
1982. (In Arabic)
[43.] Hossain, Adel. "Introduction of Arabic Development: The
Present Situation". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 6.
November 1984. (In Arabic)
[44.] International Monetary Fund. Supplement on Output Statistics.
1984. pp. iv-xiv.
[45.] Jalal-Eddine, M. Al-Awadh. "Cooperation among Arab
Countries in Manpower Development and Labor Exchanges". Oil and
Arab Cooperation. Vol. 10, No. 3. 1984. pp. 78-110. (OAPEC)
[46.] Jalal-Eddine, M. Al-Awadh. "Labour Immigration in the
Arab World: The Present Situation". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab
Future). No. 74. 1985. pp. 80-97. (In Arabic)
[47.] Keyfitz, N. Introduction to the Mathematics of Population.
Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley. 1968.
[48.] Laclau, Ernest. "Feudalism and Capitalism in Latin
America". New Left Review. Vol. 67. May-June 1971.
[49.] Lenin, V.I. Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism. New
York: International Publishers. 1939.
[50.] Luxemburg, Rosa. The Accumulation of Capital. London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul. 1959.
[51.] Mabro, Robert. "Economic Consequences of Future Decline
in Oil Prices" Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 78.
1985. pp. 54-70. (In Arabic)
[52.] McNicoll, Geoffrey. "On Demographic Turnpikes".
IUSSP International Population Conference. Liege: IUSSP. 1973. pp.
463-475.
[53.] Mauldin, Parker W., and Bernard Berelson (with a Section by
Zenas Sykes). "Conditions of Fertility Decline in Developing
Countries, 1965-75". Studies in Family Planning. Vol. 9, No. 5.
1978. pp. 89-147.
[54.] Mid-East Report. (a) May 1,1985. (b) May 15, 1985.
[55.] Myrdal, Gunnar. Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of
Nations. Vol. III. New York: Pantheon. 1968.
[56.] Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider. "Development Economists in
Emperior's Clothes?" Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXIII,
Nos. 2 & 3. Summer-Autumn 1984. pp. 121-144.
[57.] O'Brien, Philip. "A Critique of Latin American
Theories of Dependency". In Ivar Oxaal et al. (eds.), Beyond the
Sociology of Development. Economy and Society in Latin America and
Africa. London: Routledge and Keyan Paul. 1975.
[58.] Pitchford, J.D. Population in Economic Growth. Amsterdam:
North-Holland Publishing Co. 1974.
[59.] Portes, Alejandro, and John Walton. Labour, Class and the
International System. New York: Academic Press. 1981.
[60.] Prebisch, Raul. The Economic Development of Latin America and
its Principal Problems. New York: United Nations. 1950.
[61.] Prebisch, Raul. The Economic Development of Latin America in
the Post War Period. New York: United Nations. 1964.
[62.] Prebisch, Raul. "The Latin American Periphery in the
Global System of Capitalism". In Shigeto Tsuru (ed.), Human
Resources, Employment and Development, Volume 1: the Issues. London: The
Macmillan Press Ltd. 1983. pp. 3-19.
[63.] Preobrazhensky, Evgeny. The New Economics. Oxford: Clarendon
Press. 1965.
[64.] Ramses, Nadia. 'Western Theory and Arab
Development". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 64.
1984. pp. 31-50 (In Arabic)
[65.] Robinson, Joan. Aspects of Development and Underdevelopment.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1979.
[66.] Robinson, Joan. Economic Heresies. New York: Basic Books,
Inc. 1973.
[67.] Robinson, Joan. Economic Philosophy. Chicago: Aldine. 1962.
[68.] Saadudin, Ibrahim, and M. Abdel-Fadel. Arab Labor Migration:
Problems, Consequences and Policies. Beirut: Center for Arab Unity
Studies. 1983. (In Arabic)
[69.] Al-Sabah, Mohammad Sabah S. "General Equilibrium Analysis of Government Expenditure in an Oil Exporting Country: The Case
of Kuwait". Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, Harvard University,
Cambridge, USA. 1985.
[70.] Al-Samak, M.A.S. "The Geo-political Dimension of the
Main Formation of Population Structure in the Arab World".
Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 67. 1984. pp. 92-115. (In
Arabic)
[71.] Sayegh, Yusuf. "Current Oil Crises and Arab Economic
Future". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 59. January
1984. pp. 14-29. (In Arabic)
[72.] Sayegh, Yusuf. "Dimensions of Arab Economic Development
in the '80s". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 65.
July 1984. pp. 76-106. (In Arabic)
[73.] Schumpeter, Joseph. Imperialism/Social Classes: Two Essays.
New York: New American Library. 1974.
[74.] Seers, Dudley. "Births Life and Death of Development
Economics". Development and Change. London : Sage. 1979.
[75.] Serageldin, M. Ismail, and M. Yusuf. "Maximizing Returns
from Arab labour Migration". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab
Future). No. 63. 1984. pp. 69-82. (In Arabic)
[76.] Serageldin, M. Ismail, and Others. Manpower and International
Labour Migration in the Middle East and North Africa. London: Oxford
University Press. 1983.
[77.] Al-Shaar, Munzir. "The Use of Jordanian Labor Migration
Remittances. The Kuwait Case". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab
Future). No. 63. 1984. pp. 100-114. (In Arabic)
[78.] Singer, Hans W. "Further Thoughts on North-South
Negotiations: A Review of Bhagwati and Ruggie". World Development.
Vol. 13, No. 2. February 1985. pp. 255-260.
[79.] Sirageldin, Ismail. "Agricultural Development and
Population Dynamics in Egypt: Planning and Potential in the
'80s". In Evaluating Planning Experiences in the Arab Nation.
Part two. Kuwait: Arab Planning Institute. 1984. pp. 279-429. (In
Arabic)
[80.] Sirageldin, Ismail, "The Demographic Aspects of Income
Distribution". Warren Robinson (ed.), Population and Development
Planning. New York: The Population Council. 1975.
[81.] Sirageldin, Ismail. Lecture on Population Policies and
Development in the '80s. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics. 1984. (Lectures in Development Economics, No. 3)
[82.] Sirageldin, Ismail. "Some Issues in Middle Eastern
International Migration". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXII,
No. 4. Winter 1984.
[83.] Sitageldin, Ismail, and John F. Kantner. "Equity, Social
Mobility and Fertility Control Policies". Research in Human Capital
and Development. Vol. 1. Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press, Inc. 1979.
[84.] Sirageldin, Ismail, and John F. Kantner. "The Ultimate
Resource: Cornucopian Fables'. Population and Development Review.
March 1982.
[85.] Sirageldin, Ismail, and United Nations Secretariat.
"Demographic Transition and Socio-Economic Development".
Demographic Transition and Socio-Economic Development. United Nations:
Department of International Economic and Social Affairs. 1979.
(Population Studies, No. 65)
[86.] Sirageldin, Ismail, N. Sherbiny, and M. I. Serageldin. Saudis
in Transition: The Challenges of a Changing Labor Market. London: Oxford
University Press. 1984.
[87.] South, The. September 1985.
[88.] Stebbins, G. Ledyard. Darwin to DNA, Molecules to Humanity.
San Francisco: W.H. Freeman and Company. 1982.
[89.] Steward, Ian. 'Funding for the Arts and Libraries".
The Three Bank Review. No. 146. 1984.
[90.] Tabbarah, Riad. "Population, Human Resources, and
Development in the Arab World". Population and Development in the
Middle East. Beirut: United Nations, Economic Commission for West Asia.
1982.
[91.] Teitelbaum, Michael S. "Comments". Worm
Development. Vol. 4, No. 10-11. 1976. pp. 831-835.
[92.] Toynbee, A. A Study of History. New York: Oxford University
Press. 1953.
[93.] Tsuru; Shigeto. Human Resources, Employment and Development:
The Issues. London: The MacMillan Press Ltd. 1983 edition.
[94.] United Nations. Worm Population Prospects. New York: United
Nations. 1985.
[95.] Volsky, Victor. "Latin America: Demographic Problem and
Socio-economic Development". V.L. Urquidi and S. T. Reyes (eds.),
Human Resources: Employment and Development. Vol. 4. Latin America.
London: The Macmillan Press Ltd 1983. pp. 229-310.
[96.] Von Neumann. "A Model of General Economic
Equilibrium". Review of Economic Studies. Vol. XIII (1), No. 30.
1945-46.
[97.] Wallerstein, Immanuel Maurice. The Capitalist World-economy:
Essays. New York: Cambridge University Press. 1979.
[98.] Weisskoph, Thomas E. "Economic Development and the
Development of Economics: Some Observations from the Left". World
Bank. Vol. 11, No. 10. 1983. pp. 895-899.
[99.] Wijnbergen, S. Van. "Dutch-Disease: 'A Disease
After All?" The Economic Journal. Vol. 94, No. 373. March 1984. pp.
41-55.
[100.] World Bank. World Bank Report 1982. London: Oxford
University Press. 1982.
[101.] World Bank. World Development Report 1983. London: Oxford
University Press. 1983.
[102.] World Bank. Worm Development Report 1984. London: Oxford
University Press. 1984.
[103.] World Bank. World Development Projections 1984. Washington,
D.C.: The World Bank. 1984.
[104.] World Fertility Survey. World Fertility Survey: Major
Findings and Implications. London: Alden Press. 1984.
[105.] Al-Zahir, Ahmed. "Labor Immigration in the Arab
Gulf". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 63. 1984. pp.
82-99. (In Arabic)
[106.] Zaki, Ramzi. The Population Problem: The New Malthusian
Myth. Kuwait: Aalam al-Maarifa. 1984. (In Arabic)
(1) As is well known, the current demographic transition associated
with the industrial revolution has not been the only experience of
mankind, nor will it be the last. For a review and discussion, see [81].
(2) "Technicalization" and "techniques" are
used in the sense in which Ellul [29] defines them, and thus differ from
technology. In this frame of reference, technique refers to "any
complex of standardized means for attaining a predetermined result"
(p. vi), or to "compel the qualitative to become quantitative ...
(and) ... force every stage of human activity and man himself to submit
to its mathematical calculation" (p. xvi).
(3) The exceptions were China, Haiti and Jamaica with CBR equal to
39, Sri Lanka and Cuba with CBR equal to 36 and 32 respectively [101, p.
186].
(4) The response by development economists has been varied. See,
for example, Joan Robinson [67], Hirschman [40], D. Seers [74], the
special issue on "Economic Development and the Development of
Economics, "World Development (1983), Bhagwati and Ruggie [15] on
North South Negotiations and its review by H. Singer [78]. the IEA (1983) volumes on Human Resources, Employment and Development [93],
especially Vol. 1, S. Tsuru ed., and S. Amin contribution to Volume 5;
Weisskoph [98], Portes and Walton [59] that also includes, aside from a
penetrating analysis, an extensive bibliography, Naqvi [56] on defence
of the "discipline" of development economics, and Arndt [11]
on the Origins of Structuralism, among others.
(5) See for example the discussion by Arndt [11].
(6) Notice, however, the conceptual similarity between Joan
Robinson's remark on Marx's economic-demographic system, and
that of John Stuart Mill's on Malthus quoted above.
(7) The quotation is from Volsky [95, p. 300]. He quotes K. Marx
and F. Engels, Obras Completas, Vol. 6, pp. 441 and 645-6.
(8) S. Amin [7, p. xi] argues that Marxism is a "method"
and not a "theory". Accordingly it "does not imply
logically necessary unilateral conclusions".
(9) As Blaug [16, pp. 259-60] observes, "if Marxism is alive
today, it is so more by virtue of the Marxist theory of imperialism than
of any other aspect of Marxian Economics". However, Blaug (pp.
260-64) provides a critical examination of the empirical foundation of
Lenin's proposition.
(10) For a brief survey of the issues see Portes and Walton [59],
especially the first and last chapters. A detailed review should include
Bukharin [21; 22], Lenin [49], Preobrazhensky [63], Luxemburg [50],
Prebisch [60; 61; 62], Frank [35], Hobson [41], Wallerstein [97] ,and
Amin [6; 8]. And for critique: Brenner [20], O'Brien [57], Laclau
[48], Bach [14] Foster-Carter [34], Gereffi [38], Blaug [16] and P.
Samuelson (1976).
(11) Portes and Walton [59, p. 68].
(12) Shifting the responsibility for the reproduction of the
peripheral labour force from rural subsistence enclaves to urban
unemployed enclaves, as suggested by some writers, does not solve the
logical or the empirical contradictions.
(13) For definitions of the terms techniques and technology see fn.
2. The supreme status of "efficiency as a value system" may be
illustrated by a Western prescription for a system of incentives to
reduce fertility in socialist China [39, p. 39] :
"Some attention might be given to denying increases in land
allotment for higher order births. Care will have to be taken to achieve
such measures on a per-couple, not a per-household basis, peasants
throughout history have been quite clever about "dividing"
complex households to make their work units small to
tax-collectors!" (emphasis added).
The concern is clearly with efficiency rather than equity and the
possibility of a harmonious inter-class solution does not exist! Is Marx
right after all? Is Capitalism with its class struggle a necessary stage
before the attaining of true socialism?
Although not evident which direction the technological society is
leading us, i.e. Panglossian or demise, it is certain that
techniques' relentless march for efficiency is imposing more
standardization in all facets of human affairs--and the process is
cumulative. If the road leads to collapse, it will be ironic that man,
being a unique creature--since he alone creates sanctuary for his own
victims (witness the sanctuaries maintained for the endangered species),
will not find such help when needed either from self or from other
surviving species.
(14) The volume includes, aside from the penetrating review by Adel
Hossain, contributions by N. Fergani, Y. Sayegh, A. Al-Kawari, M.
Masoud, M.A. Saeed, N. Ramses, and I.S. Abdallah among others.
(15) Fergani [32] adopts the view that the assessment of the impact
of population on development can only be done within a socio-economic
and historical context. He also asserts that theoretical frameworks that
link population and development are not applicable for the Third World
situation (pp. 78-79). However, he takes a strong policy stance.
(16) Resourcia includes the major oil-exporting
financial-capital-surplus countries (Algeria, Iraq, Qatar, Libya, Saudi
Arabia, Kuwait, UAE, Bahrain and Oman). Subsistencia includes the rest
of the Arab countries, mainly the labour-surplus, capital-deficit ones.
This classification follows that of the Unified Arab Economic Report,
called the Report henceforth [9], also adopted by Sayegh [71 ; 72]. We
put group one and two of the Report together under Resourcia and added
to them Bahrain and Oman. Although the classification of the Report is
more detailed and refined, it will complicate the discussion without
affecting its general conclusions. For example, it is arguable that some
countries may be misclassified in our schematic presentation. Morocco or
Tunisia has little labour migration to the Gulf. Its link is mainly to
Europe, especially France. Or that Iraq and Algeria have a demographic
and natural resource base that is different from the rest of Resourcia.
However, the fact that there is an overlap seems to reinforce our main
thesis regarding the long-term dynamic nature of the system. Using a
Physical Quality of Life Index (PQLI) that includes various indicators
of social and economic development, Riad Tabbarah [90] arrives at a
different classification. Tabbarah's work, although important and
relevant for social planning, is not relevant for our present purpose.
(17) Maintaining high oil prices is primarily directed towards
consumers and not producers. This can be achieved for example through a
reduction of the price of crude and a retail tax on gasoline.
(18) For example, housing subsidies may discourage labour mobility.
So will import of labour in critical skills that may depress relative
wages and reduce incentives for training and occupational mobility for
the national labour. Also educational incentives that do not
discriminate between short- and long-term skill requirements create the
wrong signals for individual choices and create a divergence between
private and social objectives, especially when public sector employment
is perceived as a major resort to national employment. (For an analysis
of Saudi Arabia case, see [86].)
(19) The recent growth of Literature, Conferences or Symposiums on
the development experience of the non-oil Arab countries (Subsistencia)
has been exponential. For recent global assessment see the Arab Planning
Institute [10] and I.S. Abdallah [1 ; also in 24] and the references
cited therein.
(20) The literature on international migration to the Gulf and oil
countries (Resourcia) is substantial. For recent contributions and
references see [86], Jalal-Eddine [45; 46] or Fergani [32]. For a recent
assessment of the Egyptian case see Adel Hossain [43, Vol. 2, pp.
560-625]. In general, the important economic consequences of emigration
to the labour-exporting countries relate to the effect of the flow of
workers' remittances, to its influence on employment, its effect on
the structure of the labour market, on income distribution, on urban
growth, and on fertility.
(21) "Pray, Sir, will political economy uphold the Athenian
theatre?" asked the Rev. Dr Follitt. "Surely not. It will be a
very unproductive investment," answers Mr MacQuody. Quotation in
Ian Steward [89, p. 20].
ISMAIL SIRAGELDIN, The author is Professor at the Johns Hopkins
University, and also associated with the Kuwait Institute for Scientific
Research. The present revised version has benefited from discussions
with Dr Yusuf Al-Ebraheem. The author also acknowledges the valuable
research assistance of Haneen Sayed and Julietta Dahdah. The views
expressed in the paper are those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect those of the institutions with which he is affiliated.
This paper is a revised version of the Quaid-i-Azam Lecture
delivered at the First Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society of
Development Economists, held at Islamabad in March 1984.
Table 1
Demographic Change: Arab Countries and South-East
Asia: 1960-2000 *
* 1960 ** 1970 ** 1980
Country BR DR BR DR BR DR
Bangladesh 47 22 48 21 46 18
Pakistan 49 23 47 19 43 16
Thailand 44 15 39 10 30 8
Sudan 47 25 47 22 47 18
Yemen PDR 50 29 49 24 48 20
Yemen AR 50 29 49 27 49 23
Egypt 44 20 40 17 40 13
Morocco 50 21 48 17 45 13
Tunisia 47 19 40 14 35 11
Lebanon 43 14 36 11 30 9
Syria 47 18 47 14 47 8
Jordan 47 20 48 16 46 10
Algeria 51 20 49 16 46 13
Iraq 49 20 48 16 46 12
Oman 51 28 50 22 48 17
Libya 49 19 49 16 47 12
Saudi Arabia 49 23 48 18 45 13
Kuwait 44 10 48 6 40 4
U.A.E. 46 19 36 11 29 6
1990 2000
Country BR DR BR DR
NRR = 1
Bangladesh 43 15 36 12 2035
Pakistan 41 14 34 11 2035
Thailand 26 7 23 7 2010
Sudan 44 16 41 12 2035
Yemen PDR 48 17 44 14 2040
Yemen AR 48 20 45 16 2040
Egypt 33 10 27 8 2015
Morocco 41 11 33 8 2025
Tunisia 32 8 25 7 2015
Lebanon 28 8 24 7 2005
Syria 43 6 34 4 2020
Jordan 47 7 42 5 2020
Algeria 45 11 40 8 2025
Iraq 43 9 36 7 2025
Oman 42 13 35 10 2020
Libya 44 10 41 8 2025
Saudi Arabia 43 11 40 8 2030
Kuwait 32 3 25 3 2010
U.A.E. 26 4 25 5 2015
Source: World Development Report, 1984, IBRD
World Population Projection 1984, IBRD
Note: * IBRD
** UN
Table 2
Selected Economic Indicators
Arab World Selected South-East Asian Countries 1970-82 *
(with Percentages)
VA
Agriculture
(MS)
Country '70 % '82 %
Bangladesh 9475 58 11027 53
Pakistan 3258 20 4406 20
Thailand 3591 22 5837 27
Sudan 1367 19 2127 23
Yemen PDR - - - -
Yemen AR 221 3 401 4
Egypt 2683 38 3878 42
Morocco 1725 24 1836 20
Tunisia 480 7 816 9
Lebanon -
Syria 595 8 .. -
Jordan 92 1 132 2.0
Algeria 952 36 1375 57
Iraq 1172 45 .. -
Oman .. - .. -
Libya 126 5 388 16
Saudi Arabia 331 13 616 26
Kuwait 20 1 30 1
U.A.E. .. - .. -
Cereal Imports
(000 tons)
Country '74 % '82 %
Bangladesh 1719 56 1375 74
Pakistan 1274 41 361 19
Thailand 97 3 133 7
Sudan 125 2 611 5
Yemen PDR 149 2 271 3
Yemen AR 158 3 560 4
Egypt 3877 60 6703 53
Morocco 891 14 1913 15
Tunisia 307 5 946 8
Lebanon 354 6 529 4
Syria 339 5 426 3
Jordan 171 3 668 5
Algeria 1816 45 3831 28
Iraq 870 21 2510 18
Oman 52 1 217 2
Libya 612 15 849 6
Saudi Arabia 482 12 5584 41
Kuwait 101 3 439 3
U.A.E. 132 3 282 2
Per
Food Aid Capita Average
(000 tons) Income($) Growth(%)
Country '74-75 % '81-2 % 1982 '60-'82
Bangladesh 2130 77 1076 74 140 .3
Pakistan 619 23 368 25 380 2.8
Thailand 0 0 5 1 740 4.5
Sudan 50 5 185 7 440 (0.4)
Yemen PDR 38 4 25 .9 470 6.4
Yemen AR 0 0 13 .5 500 5.1
Egypt 610 66 1952 69 690 3.6
Morocco 75 8 465 6.4 870 2.6
Tunisia 1 .1 96 3.4 1390 4.7
Lebanon 21 2 11 .4 -1500 -
Syria 47 5 8 .3 1680 4.0
Jordan 63 7 73 3 1690 6.9
Algeria 54 5 2350 3.2
Iraq 1 .. -6000 -
Oman - - 6090 7.4
Libya - - 8510 4.1
Saudi Arabia - - 16000 7.5
Kuwait - - 19870 (0.1)
U.A.E. - - 23770 (0.7)
Current
Account Merchandise
Balance Balance Remittance
(m$) (m$) (m$)
Country '70 '82 1982 '70 '82
Bangladesh - (632) (1531) - 329
Pakistan (667) (811) (2993) - 2580
Thailand (250) (1144) (1603) - 616
Sudan (42) (248) (786) - 131
Yemen PDR (4) (221) (613) 60 411
Yemen AR - (610) (1943) - 1118
Egypt (148) (2216) (5958) 29 2074
Morocco (124) (1876) (2256) 63 849
Tunisia (53) (657) (1334) 29 372
Lebanon - - (2644) - -
Syria (69) (493) (1989) 7 140
Jordan (20) (336) (2488) - 1084
Algeria (125) 85 1596 211 447
Iraq 105 - (9972) - -
Oman - 358 1739 - 43
Libya 645 (2977) 977 - -
Saudi Arabia 71 (45125) 38469 - -
Kuwait - 5786 8519 - -
U.A.E. - - 7464 - -
Month of External
Import Public
Reserve Debt. %
(month) of GNP
Country 1982 '70 '82
Bangladesh .9 - 39
Pakistan 3.0 31 32
Thailand 3.0 5 17
Sudan .2 16 48
Yemen PDR 3.4 - 80
Yemen AR 2.9 - 36
Egypt 1.9 24 53
Morocco 1.1 18 61
Tunisia 2.1 38 42
Lebanon .. 4 ..
Syria 1.5 13 15
Jordan 3.8 23 43
Algeria 4.6 19 32
Iraq - 9 -
Oman 4.8 - 12
Libya 6.9 - -
Saudi Arabia 5.9 - -
Kuwait 7.5 - -
U.A.E. - - -
Source: World Development Report, 1984, IBRD
.. Not available
* Selected countries