首页    期刊浏览 2025年02月22日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The potential for economic-demographic development: Whither Theory?
  • 作者:Sirageldin, Ismail
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:1986
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:Changes in stable socio-demographic systems, barring environmental accidents have occurred when major new production technologies are widely adopted and socially institutionalized. In most instances, this process of change is associated with a high degree of specialization and through it with the opening up of local markets and their integration into the wider regional and international system of trade and exchange. It must be emphasized that major technological changes are but one facet, albeit a central one, in the development of our ever-evolving technological civilization. But as major new "production technologies" take hold, a new system of human settlements and social relations evolves which is in harmony with the new wave of emerging "techniques".
  • 关键词:Demography;Economic development;Social change

The potential for economic-demographic development: Whither Theory?


Sirageldin, Ismail


1. INTRODUCTION

Changes in stable socio-demographic systems, barring environmental accidents have occurred when major new production technologies are widely adopted and socially institutionalized. In most instances, this process of change is associated with a high degree of specialization and through it with the opening up of local markets and their integration into the wider regional and international system of trade and exchange. It must be emphasized that major technological changes are but one facet, albeit a central one, in the development of our ever-evolving technological civilization. But as major new "production technologies" take hold, a new system of human settlements and social relations evolves which is in harmony with the new wave of emerging "techniques".

During these periods of structural changes, mortality and reproductive behaviour tend to adjust themselves to new levels that are compatible with these new sets of production relations and their associated social formations. This movement from one equilibrium level of vital rates to another is called in the population literature a "demographic transition". Indeed, the current "demographic transition" (1) is the consequence of the world dramatic experience with new technological changes (dubbed industrial revolution). This socio-demographic transition that has its origin in the seventeenth century and accelerated during the second part of this century has influenced all the parameters of human and non-human life, including the vital rates, and has apparently set the world society on the path of irrevocable "technicalization". (2)

Demographic transitions, accordingly, cannot be defined independently of their socioeconomic context and, more fundamentally, the prevailing production technology. It is possible for demographic parameters to change as a result of changes in social relations without associated significant changes in the technological parameters. But such changes are necessarily limited by that system's production potential, which, in the final analysis, should be able to provide the necessary biological support for the growth of population.

Contemporary discussions of demographic change that theorize or prescribe ways and means of influencing fertility or migration behaviour without first considering the structural causes that caused those changes are doomed to failure. It does not follow, however, that knowledge about structural causes alone is sufficient for a correct diagnosis and prescription of development issues. Once set in motion, demographic change has its own momentum that interacts with the socioeconomic parameters of society. Understanding both the determinants and consequences of demographic change is extremely essential.

Accordingly, discussions regarding economic development or the choice of appropriate developmental styles that do not integrate population dynamics in the sense just outlined are deficient. Indeed it is the main thesis of this paper that for most analyses of socioeconomic development, this is the case. As will be evident from the present discussion, while a localized analysis of demographic change is not necessarily complete, an integrated "world view" of socio-economic development that does not endogenize the dynamics of demographic change is internally inconsistent. Our focus, however, is diagnostic rather than prescriptive.

In the second section we examine demographic trends in the less developed countries with emphasis on the Arab Region up to the end of the present century and evaluate their momentum. Our focus will be on vital rates. The important phenomenon of intra-regional migration will be examined later in the paper. In the third section we review various development paradigms to examine the role of population dynamics in their specified structures. Our next step is to assess, in the fourth section, the applicability of these various paradigms to the economic-demographic potential of the developing countries, with the Arab World as a case study. In the concluding section we discuss briefly some theory and policy implications.

2. DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD: A PREDETERMINED DESTINY?

In 1960, crude birth rates in low-income and middle-income countries were 40 or more births per thousand population for all countries with only five exceptions, and were closer to 50 for most of them. (3) Crude death rates, on the other hand, were over 16 per thousand for all except thirteen countries and few Asian countries. In 1982, fertility continued to maintain its high levels, with a few exceptions attaining somewhat lower levels. However, mortality declined dramatically, reflecting a combination of improved health status and young age structure, thus creating a dramatic increase in the natural rate of population growth. Figure 1 illustrates for the Arab countries, Pakistan, Bangladesh and Thailand the situation between 1960 and 1980 and the expected trends up to the year 2000. Basic demographic data are presented in Table 1.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

It is evident that with few exceptions, the rate of growth of these populations of Arab countries will be over two percent per year and for the majority will exceed three percent by the year 2000. The potential for high rates of population growth will continue to persist through the twenty-first century. In other words, the completion of the demographic transition in its narrow sense will not materialize in Pakistan, Bangladesh, Thailand, or the Arab World, for example, until well through the twenty-first century. The following question presents itself:
 What are the socio-economic implications of this demographic
 picture and how do they affect the developmental potential or limit
 the viability of the available policy options?


In attempting to answer this fundamental question we may follow two possible paths. The first is to project and examine a battery of consequence indicators in order to illustrate what the developing countries have to deal with during the next few decades. For example, the aggregate size of the Arab population is estimated at between 190 million and 200 million in 1985. With some plausible assumptions regarding the paths of fertility, mortality and net migration, it is expected that between 140 million and 150 million births will be added between 1985 and the end of this century, and about 40-45 million deaths will occur during the same period. Assuming a net out-migration of about 5-10 million, we would expect the total size of the Arab population to reach between 275 million and 305 million people by the year 2000. We can safely assume that about half the 40-45 million deaths will be among infants and that the family income and wealth distributions of these 40-45 million deaths will be very skewed (e.g. a Gini co-efficient exceeding 0.6).

Similar guestimates can be made for Pakistan, Bangladesh or Thailand. For example, the populations of these countries are expected to increase by 41 million, 45 million and 15 million people respectively by the year 2000. Most of that increase will be of rural origin. About 71 percent, 88 percent, and 83 percent of the increase will originate in the rural areas of Pakistan, Bangladesh and Thailand respectively. The momentum for population growth will continue to have its effect through the end of the twenty-first century. It is a long-term analysis. For details, see Demeny [27].

On a more programmatic plane, demographers, economists and sociologists may quibble about the assumptions underlying the projections in order to improve the various guestimates, especially when attempting to estimate, for planning purposes, the number of additional jobs that need to be created in the various sectors and regions by the end of the century. In principle, such an exercise should be a relatively easy task since for the next twenty years the labour force is already "on board". Controversies arise, however, not only with regard to data quality and the realism of the fertility and mortality assumptions, but, more importantly, to expectations regarding labour force participation rates (especially for females), skill composition, and the geographical distribution of the work force within and across the various countries. Such estimates are necessary for the calculation of the size and structure of investment outlays required to maintain or attain a desired level of labour productivity. Similarly, the implication of population growth to social investments necessary for education, health, housing and other basic needs and their incorporation in a macro-economic framework opens up a very substantial role for a skilled technocratic cadre of economists, sociologists and demographers. It has even created a sub-discipline labelled "planning for growing populations" Cassen and Wolfson, [23]. It also provides a lively numbers game--a serious game notwithstanding.

This is the approach that is most widely used in dealing with population implications. It does not, however, probe the fundamental forces that brought the demographic picture to its present status.

The second approach, which is the one we will adopt, is to investigate the determinants of the system parameters and relate them to consequences. More specifically, it seeks to investigate how endogenous the demographic factors in the current phase of the developing countries' socioeconomic experience are. But the policy conclusions derived from such an examination can only be interpreted in the context of developmental paradigms. For that purpose we need to understand how population is treated within the various development perspectives. It is not our aim to secure a consensus or to provide a comprehensive assessment of the current debate regarding development paradigms. Such a task is too large and fundamental and is clearly beyond the scope of the present study. The aim is to present our own understanding of the role of population dynamics in the various developmental paradigms in order to relate the demographic situation just outlined to the context of the developing world within a coherent framework. For the purpose of focusing the discussion, the Arab experience will be taken as a case study.

3. POPULATION IN DEVELOPMENT PARADIGMS

It seems that the pace and diversity of national and international events and the associated structural changes that took place in the world during the past two decades have had the effect of discrediting a number of comfortable generalizations that have been nurtured and cherished with respect to a spectrum of development paradigms. These events include the changing role of China in both its internal and international policies; the changing fortunes of OPEC; the emergence, from within the ranks of the less developed countries, of a set of Newly Industrialized Countries that may be labelled semi-imperialistic; the apparent decline of some previously industrial nations, the rise in Latin America of a new brand of military-bureaucratic regimes in close alliance with international capital; and the disillusionment with the progress of the North-South negotiations. These events have created disillusionment among soical scientists concerned with development studies. As Portes and Walton observed [59, p. 1], for those whose perceptions of the world are based instant analysis, the 1970s and 1980s must have surely projected a state of confusion. Regardless of one's ideological leanings, it was increasingly difficult to identify either international friends or enemies or to predict even short-term trends during that period. As a result, development economics as a sub-discipline was put to task:

It is apparent that the current status of development economics is rather fluid. We need not b e dogmatic in taking stances before a careful survey of the grounds. In what follows we present a brief review of various development paradigms starting with the classical model. Our interest is to illustrate how population is treated in these models. We must, however, be aware that our rejection of a given paradigm, if based on moral (or emotional) grounds, may not spring so much from the unsoundness of its analytical structure, as from its unsound application. The same knife may save or take a life depending on whether it was used by a surgeon or by a criminal.

a. From Malthus to Marx

Malthus, as a system of analysis and not of exploitation, was born a long time before the birth of the man of that name. From this viewpoint, the Malthusian assumption that the average productivity of labour declines with an increase in population size, as well as the familiar Malthusian assumptions of a fixed resource base and a fixed technology that implies the idea of an optimal population size, defined in the context of a desirable average level of welfare (or subsistence), was elucidated by Confucius and his followers in China almost a millennium before Malthus's time (Hammel, [39]). It is hard to perceive Confucius as Malthusian.

Malthus was a classical economist, although he anticipated Keynes in questioning the stability of the system. According to the classical (as well as the neoclassical) thesis, in a perfectly competitive economy and in the absence of externalities, market forces operating through the price mechanism assure both a stable system and an optimum allocation of resources, statically and dynamically. This paradigm has been open to three major lines of criticism. One that it is unjust and exploitative. Two, that it is unstable, prone to crises and doomed to collapse. Three, that its alleged optimum allocative conclusions are not guaranteed because its very quintessential mechanism of market forces operating through the price system fails to work, either because of a distorted signalling mechanism, an inadequate response of labour and other factors of production to price signals, or because of the lack of mobility of such factors. (5) Our focus will be on the first two lines of criticism, exploitative and instability, because of the critical nature of their assumed demographic behaviour.

A critical examination of the classical system can be made in the light of Marx's critique. Marx considered the exploitative nature of the capitalistic system as inherent in the internal working rules of the system. As put eloquently by J. Robinson,
 Exploitation is the great engine for accumulation and what is
 nowadays called economic growth. The capitalists extract surplus
 value, not to enjoy luxury, but to accumulate the means of
 increasing employment so as to extract more surplus [65, p. 27].


The surplus of production over wages belongs to the capitalists. They use it partly to supply their own wants but mostly to build up more capital to extract more surplus. In essence, the "bourgeoisie" class is viewed in this paradigm as being "programmed" to accumulate-like bees. It is evident that investment (i.e. profits minus luxury consumption) in the capacity to produce wage goods is a necessary condition for growth, but the viability of the system is based on an objective, albeit contradictory, relationship between profits and real wages. To an individual firm, an increase in the wage bill represents a "loss", while for the capitalist class as a whole it is the precondition for an expansion of the market and, accordingly, a continuation of the accumulation process. Furthermore, for the system to operate without real wages overtaking profits, the labour force must be increasing all the time, and at the same time there exists a reserve army of potential unemployed workers.

Indeed, it is a tight-rope game. If capital accumulates faster than the labour force growth, including the exhaustion of the reserve of labour, real wage rates rise and profit per worker falls, thus slowing down accumulation relative to the growth of labour. A new cycle begins where the relative increase of the labour force will tend to reduce real wages and, accordingly, increase surplus and accumulation. It is evident from this analysis that
 In a class society (whether feudal or capitalist) a growth of
 numbers is advantageous to the owners of property. It provides them
 with more people to exploit, as tenants, servants, slaves or
 workers. [65, p. 8]


It is a mercantilistic world that favours population increase in order to maximize wealth while being oblivious to problems of inequality of income and wealth or accepting its inevitability. It is also the Age of Malthus. The attack on the Malthusian framework has to do with its analytic focus and moral implication. Teitelbaum summarizes the ideological issue succinctly when he said that
 Malthus argued that the English poor laws and the utopian socialism
 of Godwin and Condorcet were doomed to failure by the 'principle of
 population'. According to Malthus, the effect of social welfare
 measures was simply to lower mortality while fertility stayed high.
 Hence the population will grow to the margin of subsistence, and
 thereby leave eventual overall welfare improved not at all. Unless
 fertility could be reduced, he (Malthus) held, the ultimate
 population restraints of famine, war and disease would be imposed
 by nature. [91, p.831]


In essence, Malthus considered the inequality in the functional distribution of income as datum necessary for the stability of his system and, accordingly, blamed the reproductive behaviour of the working class for excessive poverty and unemployment. It is the growing subsistent consumption needs of this group that outgrow output growth--thus reducing profit and accumulation. The cure from misery lies squarely on the shoulders of the proletariat and not in the characteristics of the social structure of the capitalistic system and its production relations.

It is evident, therefore, that population plays an important, albeit different, role in the functioning of both the classical and the Marxist systems.

In the Malthusian framework (ignoring its reactionary interpretation) population is treated endogenously in the sense that its rate of growth is a positive function of real wages. But the conceptual framework that underlies the relationship is never articulated and is mainly based on biological forces of passion. It must be emphasized that there is nothing "sacred" about the distribution mechanism perceived by Malthus. As John Stuart Mill wrote in his Autobiography, partly a reflection of his utilitarian convictions,

"Malthus's population principle was quite as much a banner and point of union among us [utilitarians], as any opinion specially belonging to Bentham. This great doctrine, originally brought forward as an argument against the indefinite improvability of human affairs, we took up with ardent zeal in the contrary sense, as indicating the sole means of realizing that improvability by securing full employment as high wages to the whole labouring population through a "voluntary" restriction of the increase of their numbers. (Quoted in [16, pp. 220-21]; emphasis added.)

Indeed, as Blaug observed, one can read in Mill's principle "a relentless insistence that every conceivable policy measure must be judged in terms of its effects upon the birth rate" [16, p. 220]. It seems that Mill assumed the presence of a divergence between individual and social demographic objectives--a divergence that required a conscious policy intervention. But he also assumed a "voluntary" adjustment mechanism on the micro level. However, Mill did not provide the necessary "behavioural" theory of population dynamics, essential for the viability and stability of his harmonious economic-demographic system.

It is of interest, however, that the recent revival of the classical theory of profit ignored even this weak link and treated population as completely outside the system [96]. In Von Neumann's world the employment of labour grows automatically as the flow of output of wage goods increases. Such state of affairs implies either that population is always growing at just the right rate, or that there is an indefinite reserve of potential labour living on nuts in the jungle, always ready to take up employment when the standard real wage is offered. Such treatment is most evident in Morishima's (1969) extension of the Von Neumann model. G. McNicoll describes this aspect of Morishima's specification more vividly when he says that in Morishima's model,
 People in excess of the minimum needed to work with the available
 physical inputs to the set of production processes at a given time
 can be excluded from participation in the economy either dying of
 starvation or becoming otherwise unemployable without being a
 burden on the economy! [52, p.2]


In the Marxist framework, although the role and influence of population are central to the system, its dynamics are not given careful consideration. Marx's prediction about the fate of the capitalist system is that the very mechanism inherent in the process of production will result in constantly increasing numbers of the working class that would be trained, united and organized to finally revolt and take over the system for their own benefit. This vision includes the element of a rudimentary population theory which shares the same response mechanism as that of Malthus. But Marx's system could equally accommodate an alternative population theory where the response mechanism differs. For example, as Joan Robinson [65] argues, (6) it is possible that
 Marx, in his desire to combat the reactionary doctrines of Malthus,
 did not stress the point that growth of population, under
 capitalism, is inimical to the interests of the working class,
 though his own theory clearly indicates that this is the case ...
 when the labour force is not growing, accumulation takes the form
 of technical change which raises output per man employed. Then
 organized labour can catch a share in the growth of productivity by
 raising real wage rates. This, indeed, has happened in the Western
 economies. The moral seems clear, but some fanatical dogmatic
 Marxists have joined with the Pope in refusing to admit that the
 growth of population, in modern conditions, is an impediment to the
 growth of human welfare. (p. 8).... (evidently, Marx) neglected
 demography. (p. 26)


Indeed, classical Marxism puts forward the thesis that each socio-economic formation has its demographic law. Marx believed that (7)
 Men establish certain links and relations to produce, and it is
 only in the context of these links and social relations that their
 relationship to nature exists and their production takes place....
 (accordingly) every special historic mode of production has its own
 special law of population ... under the demographic law of
 capitalism, the working population, by producing capital
 accumulation, increasingly produces resources that run into a
 relatively surplus population; and this demographic law is inherent
 in the capitalist mode of production ... that characterizes the
 degree and kind of use of labour resources.


These Marxist demographic laws are basically "methods of understanding". (8) They may provide refutable hypotheses. But our point of view is that they are not backed by a clear theoretical framework that elucidates the behavioural mechanisms of the implicit but necessary micro and macro demographic adjustments. This analytic weakness is evident in Volsky's discussion [95] of Latin America's demographic problems and socioeconomic development. Volsky, a member of the Moscow-based USSR Institute of Latin American Studies, argues that accelerated population growth in Latin American countries creates difficulties, that Latin American countries need a well-grounded demographic policy, that such policy as exists in Latin America is divorced from general socioeconomic policy (demographic policy is used only for the purpose of measurement), that it (population policy) suffers from the "negative attitude of the Catholic Church on the use of artificial means to limit births", and that attention must be given to "the struggle by the masses to have demographic problems solved within the framework of radical overall changes" (pp. 304-308). However, it seems that with few exceptions the decline in mortality has been dramatic and uniform across the Latin American countries and that the decline in fertility seems to be negatively correlated with per capita income [102]. Cuba is the exceptional leader in the decline of both mortality and fertility. But close contenders include such socially and politically diverse countries as Chile, Uruguay, Trinidad and Tobago, Jamaica and Argentina! Evidently, there is a need for clearer conceptual guidelines. Does the neoclassical perspective or the new World-System vision of development and underdevelopment provide such needed conceptual guidelines?

b. The Neoclassical Perspective

The neoclassical (neo-Malthusian) school developed the Malthusian analytical framework in two directions: macro growth models and micro household economics. As mentioned earlier, neoclassical growth models are based on the presence of perfect competition in both the product and factor markets as well as on the assumption of constant returns to scale. The literature is enormous and the relevance of this body of theory to explaining actual situations even in the developed world has been highly questioned. For a review and assessment, see Eltis [30] and Pitchford [58]. For our purpose we narrow our focus on how population growth is treated in these models. Three possibilities may be identified [58]: (i) as an independent variable, (ii) as an endogenous variable, and (iii) as a policy instrument. The first assumes a constant population growth rate and may be labelled a descriptive neoclassical growth model. To a large extent, the absolute size of population plays no essential part in determining the results of this class of models. Pitchford, critical of such implication, sums the lack of relevance of such analysis to the developing countries' context as follows:
 The originators of this approach were, of course, aware of this
 sort of implication of their models, and it is true that for some
 purpose it need not be a serious limitation ... yet there were
 underdeveloped countries where there seemed to be a conflict
 between population growth and economic welfare, and casual
 observation of the real world would suggest that the time must come
 when the same applied to developed countries. For these situations
 the neoclassical growth model was not relevant. [58, p. 54]


As "the previous discussion illustrates, the Malthusian and Ricardian growth paradigms treat population endogenously but the assumed demographic behaviour is rather weak. Attempts to endogenize population in the neoclassical framework were also questioned with regard to the plausibility of their assumed demographic behaviour. Underlying recent development is the concept of an "optimum population" size or path which requires explicit assumptions about the adjustment process of population. In most cases the adjustment is assumed instantaneous. Again, according to Pitchford [58, p. 90] the utility of the models diminishes greatly if it is assumed that
 Population can be freely and instantaneously adjusted to any value
 or that ... an adjustment process does take place [;] but the level
 of population at any time is adjusted relative to the capital
 movements and the process does not take into account the realities
 of costs and restrictions on population movements. The "optimum"
 level of population at any time may have no relevance at all to a
 level that can be attained.


These classical-neoclassical conclusions may be illustrated by the use of a variant of a graph developed by Eltis [30].

In Figure 2, the horizontal axis shows the rate of population growth while the vertical axis shows the real wage rate. The Ss schedule illustrates the hypothesized 'classical' supply curve of population. At [W.sub.s], the rate of population growth (n) is zero. Its rate of growth increases whenever [W.sub.1] exceeds W along the [S.sub.s] schedule. The DD curve illustrates the society's demand curve for population. It shows the rate of growth of population that the economy can support, and
 This depends on the rate of growth of circulating capital (i.e. the
 rate of growth of the 'wage fund'), and this will grow more rapidly
 in given technical conditions where wages are low so that profits
 (which are largely reinvested) are high, than where wages are high,
 leaving little surplus for accumulation. [30, p. 203]


[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

Its negative slope indicates that a country will only accumulate enough capital to support faster population growth at a lower real wage.

At [E.sub.1] there is a rate of growth of population [n.sub.1] and real wage rate [W.sub.1] that are compatible with a rate of net capital accumulation and an implied profit rate. But [W.sub.1] exceeds the subsistent wage [W.sub.s]. The question is whether [W.sub.i] is a stable econodemographic equilibrium? Various scenarios may be examined by the use of Figure 2. In a Malthusian-Ricardian world [D.sub.2] will shift to [D.sub.s] at [W.sub.s] the subsistent wage, the only long-term equilibrium perceived by Malthus or Ricardo. In an optimistic neo-Malthusian world [D.sub.2] will shift outwards to [D.sub.3] through new inventions and advanced technology. In a "population push" scenario technological advance is a function of the rate of population growth itself [17; 18]. However, it seems that this latter scenario attempts to apply long-term historical experience to the recent experience of developing countries with large exogenous shocks that took place in relatively very short periods of time. It seems to compress a thousand-year adjustment process into a 0.025 scale! Finally, according to the neo-Malthusian scenario S will shift to [S.sub.2] where [W.sub.2] exceeds [W.sub.s], implying a rising subsistence level, either through increasing labour bargaining power or a more complex dynamic process of economicdemographic household behaviour that includes reproduction as an argument in an individual welfare function that is being maximized while the level of "subsistent aspiration" is rising. One debatable policy implication is that total welfare may be maximized if demographic behaviour is left to adjust itself freely in response to market forces.

Logically, such discussion leads to the study of the micro economic foundation of demographic behaviour. The literature and debate on the neoclassical theory of household fertility behaviour are known and need no elaboration. It attempts to show, through the calculus of maximizing behaviour based on individual self-interest, that fertility behaviour is responsive to changes in the relative costs and benefits associated with different reproductive strategies. The paradigm has been criticized on various grounds [81; 85]. The debate, however, has advanced knowledge about the complexity of the reproductive structure and its time dimension. But, in the analysis, the focus is on individual action. It has isolated individual behaviour from the long-term dynamics of economic growth and social class formation. It is assumed that the worker can improve his/her situation regardless of the pattern of class development and without appeal to class solidarity--a questionable proposition. It is a development paradigm that focuses its attention on the micro elements of society, whether national or international, as being "responsible for" their current undesirable status and as being "able to change" such environment through individual actions alone. In this neoclassical paradigm, group interactions, whether intra- or inter-country, are basically ignored. This brings us to an alternative viewpoint: a global view of development and underdevelopment.

c. A World-System Vision

Development studies tend to regard underdevelopment as a social "problem"--a syndrome in which Third World countries suffer from a disease called underdevelopment or lack of modernity. The less developed countries should consider the industrial nations as their model of a healthy body and follow their path in terms of either specific processes or historical stages. But the disease is diagnosed as self-inflicted and localized inside the patient's body. Research and policy analysis guided by this modernization syndrome concentrates on problems internal to Third World countries. Linkage mechanisms between the developing and the developed nations are outside the paradigm and are not examined. The World-System vision, on the other hand, treats development as part of integral totality. It must be emphasized that the World-System paradigm is not a uniform entity. There are differences of opinion with regard to conceptualization and empirical methods.

As a historical note, the World-System view may be regarded as starting with the insight of Lenin [49] into world imperialism and Luxemburg's analysis of accumulation on a world scale [50]. (9) In her analysis, she was able to show that accumulation and market expansion in the industrial countries take place simultaneously with the continuation of primitive accumulation in backward areas. Capitalism does not only coexist with different economic structures but, being the hegemonic mode of production, relies on less developed periphery structures, those that are located in industrial countries (the urban working class) and in the less developed ones (peasant labour) for the extraction of surplus value.

Application to the Latin American case by Prebisch [60] and associates includes some specification weaknesses and so does the remedial attempt by Frank [35]. For example, Prebisch and associates of the Economic Commission of Latin America (ECLA) fail to consider the rise of monopoly capital that, in the face of technical innovation, is able to simultaneously displace labour at the centre and also permit a partial transfer of productivity rises among those not displaced. Alternatively, Frank viewed the system as a single hierarchical vertical chain of exploitation that extends the capitalist link in a descending order from the capitalist world in the centre, to the national level, the metropolises, all the way to the small peasants and the landless labourers; see Laclau [48], cited in [59]. The validity of this linear conceptualization of the world has been questioned on theoretical and empirical grounds.

However, Frank's vision of a hierarchical continuum of exploitation cannot be completely ignored. For example, in pre-Nasser rural Egypt, with cotton as the main cash crop, tenants squeezed the landless workers (taraheel) below subsistence wages; landlords, in their turn, squeezed as much surplus as they could from tenants; landlords, seeking cash, made future cotton sales through financial intermediators (mostly foreign), far below international market prices, and, finally, at the core centre, the latter group was squeezed by industrialists and traders in England.

In both visions, however, the process of reproduction of the labour force in the periphery is not adequately explained [59, p. 8].

At present there has been a return, beyond the conceptualization of Lenin and Luxemburg, to the original Marx. This is being accomplished through the elucidation by A. Emmanuel (1972) and S. Amin [8] of a World System based on the principle of Unequal Exchange. (10)

In general, the World System paradigm views the word economy as one of a dual dialectic [26] : the dialectic between production and circulation internal to each sector of the system, and the dialectic between centre and periphery. (11)

Unequal exchange implies that surplus value, after allowing for different capital investment or differential productivity, flows from peripheral production into the core because of different levels of remuneration to labour. S. Amin estimated that the value of this hidden transfer was about US $ 22 billion in 1966 [8, p. 144], almost twice the amount of "aid" and the private capital that the periphery received.

Based on World-System analysis, what is the population mechanism underlying this conceptual framework? This question was put more clearly by Wallerstein as follows:
 (What are the) mechanisms which permit the reduction of money wages
 in peripheral activities below the level minimally required for the
 reproduction of the labour-force and yet maintain the labour force
 in existence? [97, p. 10]


Indeed, according to this paradigm, the continuing existence of a labour surplus in the periphery is a necessary condition for depressing wage rates and, accordingly, perpetuating the system of unequal exchange. Samir Amin elaborates the dynamic nature of accumulation on a world-wide scale as follows:
 ... the system tends to reproduce unceasingly the reserve army
 which it needs to ensure the profitability of capital. This
 fundamental law of accumulation

 ... inherent in the capitalist mode of production, operates in our
 time on worldwide scale and no longer on that of each of the
 central regions.. (and).. have now reached the state of
 establishing a world-wide labour market. [7, p. xiii; emphasis
 added]


But what is the mechanism through which this "unceasing reproduction" of the labour surplus or "reserve army", which is essential for this fundamental law of accumulation, takes place? The determinants of this implied demographic behaviour is not articulated in the system's analytic framework. For example, it is not evident why the reproduction of the peripheral labour force should, as a behavioural response, be automatic?

Recent empirical demographic evidence (e.g. The World Fertility Survey Findings) seem not to support these hypothesized general laws of reproductive response. There has been a secular fertility decline across the various social classes in industrial countries. This secular decline has been led by the educated and the professionals (core!), while the cyclical behaviour of fertility cuts across all social groups. In the less developed countries the experience suggests that reproductive behaviour is a very complex phenomenon. This is the case, since, as we argued elsewhere [85, pp. 10-14],
 The current stage of the demographic transition, in which fertility
 starts a sustained downward trend, might occur under different
 styles and/or at different levels of socio-economic development.

 But to understand the process of social and economic change,
 four basic elements of the social system--and their
 interrelationships--need attention.

 The first, fundamental elements is the decision process at the
 individual level.

 The second is the institutional framework, which is responsible
 for the formation and maintenance of social values and norm and
 thereby limits and conditions individual action and choices, during
 the course of development.

 The third element is the role of the state. In its growing and
 accepted role as an active agent of change and social engineering,
 the state attempts to develop rational, co-ordinated plans to
 initiate, spur and steer a process of social and economic
 development.

 The fourth element is related to the third: To what extent is
 the local market integrated within and dependent upon the national
 and international system of trade and finance?

 During the course of socio-economic change, individual and group
 relative positions in the social order change. Some of these,
 although a consequence of the development process, may not have
 been planned or anticipated, e.g. an increased occupational
 differentiation that reduces the rigidity of social stratification,
 or an improved system of information flow that reduces the cost of
 mobility. Other changes, depending on the style of development, may
 have been engineered by the corporate authority as, for example,
 attempts to reduce inequity and/or enhance the process of social
 mobility.

 This process of change creates new roles, eliminates some
 established ones and reduces the relative importance of others by
 establishing new rules that govern their terms of exchange. The
 result is tension and conflict between and within groups. It is the
 dynamics of this conflict, the extent of its universality and the
 path society takes for its resolution (i.e. its influence on the
 trade-offs among individual needs, group needs and the more general
 social needs) that produce different patterns of demographic
 change.


It is evident that generalization about demographic change should be guarded and context-pecific; see also [80; 83].

However, a key point to consider is this: if reproductive behaviour could be modified by public policy, and the experience of the last quarter-century illustrates the viability of such possibility [25; 53], then why is it that the World-System framework ignored the possibility of such social engineering in the analysis? For example, it did not examine the implication of a potential dramatic decline in the peripheral rate of population growth (i.e. labour force and reserve army) to the behavioural dynamics of the system of accumulation on a world-wide scale and, accordingly, to the welfare of the periphery. This crucial question needs careful analysis. (12) Similarly, the implication of the apparent secular decline in the rate of the population growth of the capitalist group of countries needs equal attention. For example, given the current declining fertility trends, it is estimated that the size of the annual immigration flow required to stabilize the population size in the Western industrial countries will be in the order of 2-3 million people by the dawn of the twenty-first century [19]. It seems that the dualism between global theorizing and intermediate sub-process analysis has created a conceptual gap yet to be bridged in the development literature.

To summarize, population plays an important role in the various development paradigms reviewed in this section. Its growth is important for capital accumulation in the capitalistic system. In the Marxist system, its differential growth by social classes provides the bases for exploitation as well as for the ultimate demise of the capitalistic system and for paving the way for socialism. The paradigm of unequal exchange expands this last proposition to a world-wide scale. However, the determinants and consequences of population dynamics are not critically examined in either case. The neoclassical analysis attempts to develop a behavioural theory of reproduction, but, being individualistic in scope, it divorces itself from the very context of development as a social issue.

However, regardless of whether it is the classical, Marxist, or the Unequal Exchange system, an important conclusion (partly an outgrowth of J.S. Mill's insight discussed above) emerges:
 Changes in the structure and growth of population are assumed to
 have causal linkage to the dynamics of production, accumulation,
 and distribution. There is a delicate balance between the
 reproduction of population and that of capital. The system of
 distribution of the social product determines the stability of the
 system. Population change is an integral part of the socioeconomic
 system; it does not act in a vacuum.


This is an essential point to keep in mind when we examine, in the following section, the applicability of the various paradigms to the developing countries' situation, with the Arab countries as a case study.

4. DEVELOPMENT PARADIGMS: HOW APPLICABLE TO THE ARAB CASE?

a. The Setting

The current phase of population and economic change in the Arab world is unique in terms of the magnitude of change in its parameters, but is not unexpected. The general demographic-economic characteristics of the system are rather simple. The story is familiar. Our purpose is not to document events and trends but rather to evaluate the applicability of the various development paradigms in explaining and predicting the emerging general patterns.

The general outline of the demographic picture has been presented earlier. The Arab population is one of the fastest growing in the world and because of its young age structure has a long-term built-in growth momentum. Arab demography follows the familiar transitions of the less developed countries that experienced colonial domination. Our contention is that this transition is part and parcel of the technological development of capitalism and its implied international exchange system. At the turn of the century, investment in public health measures started slowly and was limited to ensuring the adequate reproduction of the work force involved in the production of the export primary goods needed to fuel the engine of the industrial revolution (e.g. cotton in Egypt and the Sudan), and in the civil and police administration required for ensuring an efficient flow of these goods and safety of the colonial presence. Countries or areas outside this international exchange system did not have this limited social benefit! A global conscience for an international health policy had not been born at the time. However, as evident from our discussion, exogenous health improvement that occurs in isolation from an integrated economicdemographic development policy is not a "sufficient" condition for increasing "net" social welfare. Under such conditions, public health could turn in the longer term into public hazard!

As "direct" colonialism declined, interest in economic development among the newly independent nations became a primary focus, at both national and international levels. In many countries, "average" health status improved. Among the Arab countries, the decline in mortality became more dramatic after World War II and accelerated, especially in the oil-exporting countries, after the oil boom. Fertility, on the other hand, did not show any significant departure from its high level up to the present [104]. Accordingly, the rate of population growth accelerated. This demographic picture raises a pivotal question: is the accelerated reproduction of the potential labour force in the Arab world warranted by the pace and structure of capital accumulation and by the structure of the production relation in the region? Our answer is in the negative. We even assert that within the present socio-political context, the long-term demographic trends, implied in the current structure and parameters of the population could have dire consequences for the countries of the region as a whole, whether they be importers or exporters of labour/ capital. How could we reach such conclusions in the face of what appeared to be clear contradictory evidence as illustrated, for example, by

(i) a huge inflow of expatriate non-Arab labour;

(ii) apparent underpopulation as illustrated by such crude measures as density; or

(iii) a large financial capital outflow that finds no adequate internal outlet.

The combination of these three elements may constitute, on the basis of "Says" prediction, the possibility of a process of self-sustained growth in the area, since the supply of national labour (replacing expatriates over time) may create its own demand, especially if low density implies the presence of unutilized natural resources and of the potential creation of a large market through an efficient accumulation of capital financed by oil revenue. However, on close examination, the viability of such argument depends on the presence of specific internal and external conditions that may not materialize within the present system of international capital accumulation and its underlying dynamics of the world demographic transition. Our main argument depends on a modified classical-Marxist dictum:
 Capital has no feelings for any negative consequences resulting
 from disequilibrium in human reproduction. It only reproduces what
 it needs for its own reproduction and accumulation. On a world-wide
 scale, where national or community bondages are weaker, it disposes
 more freely of redundancy. As the world society becomes more
 "technicalized", where "technique" controls "technology", the
 criterion of efficiency takes supreme status--disposing of
 redundancy becomes more cruel. (13)


Let us elaborate. First we briefly review current efforts to develop an Arab population development paradigm. Then we outline and evaluate the current Arab--international system of production and exchange from the viewpoint of a worldwide system paradigm.

b. A Note on Arab Population-Development Paradigm

Is there an "Arab Population Development Paradigm" that differs from those reviewed above? This is a difficult question to answer. There has been a large and growing literature on Arab development styles by Arab economists and social scientists but no dominant "Arab" development philosophy similar, for example, to the "Latin American School" has emerged. At the cost of under-representation (and probably over-simplification) we will focus on four recent contributions. The first, by G. Amin [4], is an attempt at classification and evaluation of the various development paradigms reflecting the planning experience in the Arab world. The second is a collection of articles on Arab development [24]. It includes contributions on the subject published in the Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi in 1983-84, reviewed by Abdel-Khalik [2]. The third is an interview by S. Amin [6] on Independent Development and the Third World. The recent works of R. Zaki [106] and N. Fergani [33] on the population problems with emphasis on Arab development constitute the fourth contribution.

Galal Amin [4] argues that the development experience in the Arab world has been a result of the dynamic interaction of three schools of thought: laical liberalism, laical Marxism and traditionalism. Traditionals, dominated by the Islamic movement, regained purpose after the collapse of the Nasserist experience--by blaming its collapse on the system's failure to acknowledge religion as the foundation and blueprint for inspiring and specifying development strategies. The negative economic and social side-effects of the Sadat "open policy" and the spectacular success of the Iranian Islamic revolution in ousting a strong regime backed by the strongest of super-powers reinforced the traditional stance, defining the development problem as a lack of purpose. In their view, societal problems have solutions in Islamic principles and not in imported ideologies.

Laical liberalism also gained ground after Nasser and Sadat. The real problem of underdevelopment is seen as being a lack of scientific development and the application of scientific methods and techniques not only in production and organization, but also in governing and in personal relations. They view independent development as unrealistic in a highly interdependent world. They adhere to the principle of the market, competition, and a small government. To a large extent, laical liberalism may be labelled neoclassical.

Laical Marxists, according to the typology of G. Amin [4], are equally enthusiastic about the power of science and technology but see the international system of dependency and unequal exchange as major obstacles to development. They also differ from the laical liberals in stressing the need for restructuring the society as a prerequisite of ensuring long-term equity even if it means a slower pace of development.

With the exception of the traditionals, the liberals (neoclassicals) and the Marxists do not present new paradigms. It is curious that the traditional paradigm was not represented in that important collection of articles on Arab Development: Present and Potential [24]. (14) What is included has been categorized by Abdel-Khalik [2] as belonging to various themes of Marxism. Both Abdel-Khalik [4] and Fergani [33] argue that no dominant Arab development paradigm exists at present. We may also add that the demographic content in the theoretical analysis presented in the book is limited. In his introduction to the volume, A. Hossain [42] provided a deep and penetrating assessment of the theoretical contributions but does not dwell on the absence of population-development analysis in the book. We can safely conclude that in the discussions of the six theoretical contributions there is no attempt made to provide the conceptual basis for a unified population and development policy.

In a stimulating interview, S. Amin [6] examines development in the Arab world from his familiar world-wide Unequal Exchange System. The solution, similar to that in his other work [7], is to focus on the agricultural sector, fully utilize the potential labour force, increase demand through more equity (wage equalization), and in the initial stage make industry subordinate to agricultural development, i.e. produce what is required to enhance agricultural productivity. It is reminiscent of the original Chinese model. The discussion provides a general outline. Details, especially as to how this development vision relates to the particular nature of population dynamics and labour mobility in the region, are left out at this stage.

The book by R. Zaki is an ambitious attempt to provide such a vision. It provides a well-researched historical viewpoint on population in economic thought. Most of it, however, is an attack on the neo-Malthusian framework, repeating and reinforcing well-known reservations. Zaki's main thesis (p. 455) is that the present population problem is not a Malthusian race between population growth and the development of resources but rather a race between high population growth and a stagnant socioeconomic structure that is unable to ignite the engine for true development. We certainly agree with the diagnosis but we do not understand the rationale for excluding controlling of population change as a policy parameter, especially if, as our previous analysis of the various paradigms illustrates, the "stagnant" socioeconomic structure is a function of population growth! Actually the result of Zaki's contribution is a set of standard propositions calling for liberating the economy, realizing independent developments, self-reliance and more equity based on well-intentioned social criteria. The analysis, however, falls far short of integrating population dynamics with development in a systematic framework. The same reservations apply to Fergani's discussion of population and development in the Arab world [33]. (15) One of the possible sources of confusion is mixing of short-term with long-term changes in population, and, accordingly, their determinants and consequences [81] .

c. The Anatomy of Arab Economic-Demographic Development

The Arab region has witnessed dramatic socio-economic and political shocks during the past three decades that are unparalleled, in terms of size or intensity, by other historical events that took place in the region arid that influenced significantly the structural pattern of production and consumption. On an abstract level, the present experience of the Arab region provides a classic study or a test-lab to examine the applicability of many assertions and conclusions derived from the various development paradigms discussed earlier. Indeed, the dynamics and the relations involved are very complex. But, given our economic-demographic focus, we abstract ourselves from many of the fine, albeit important, details.

To facilitate the discussion, the complex relations will be reduced to three main actors. The first represents the source of demand for oil and supplier of industrial goods and technology (Industria). The second is the owner of the primary resource (oil) required for industrial production (Resourcia). The third has a rate of population growth (supply) that is faster than the demand for labour generated by its present local condition of production and capital accumulation (Subsistencia). Figure 3 provides a schematic presentation of the operation of this simplified system. As mentioned earlier, the story is a familiar one and needs no detailed elaboration or documentation. For simplicity, only Arab and industrial countries are identified in Figure 3. The implication to other developing countries can be inferred. The basic data discussed in the text are presented in Table 2. The Arab countries are divided into two main groups: Resourcia and Subsistencia (16). The third group represents the industrial nations (the core) and labelled Industria. There are three direct pairs of relations: (a) Resourcia-Industria, (b) Subsistencia-Resourcia, and (c) Subsistencia-Industria. Each relation has its own past history, present short-term dynamics, and future long-term paths. The first two relations will be examined in turn, first from the viewpoint of each group in isolation, then as an integrated Arab community within a world-wide system vision. Discussion of the third relation will be incorporated in the discussion of the second relation and in the concluding remarks.

a. Resourcia--Industria

The past experience of this relation is wide-ranging. It takes its roots from the reminiscence of the Ottoman Empire and the French colonization of Algeria to that of the Italian in Libya and the British in Iraq and Arabia. The colonial past is important in understanding the present pattern of development. But the present is largely dominated and shaped by oil. The shape of recent ten-year history of Resourcia's changing fortunes may be summarized as follows:

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

1. Resourcia exports oil to Indusria.

2. Oil revenue exceeds Resourcia's initial capacity to invest. Between 1973 and 1983, Arab oil-exporting countries earned a total of approximately US $ 1,347 billion in which Saudi Arabia's share was 28 percent and Kuwait's was 9 percent; see Editorial in [87].

3. Resourcia embarks on a spectacular programme of building physical and human infrastructures.

4. Excess revenue is ploughed back to Industria.

5. Resourcia has limited manpower relative to the pace of its investment expenditure.

6. Resourcia opens its door to expatriate labour.

7. Resourcia (with the exception of Iraq) does not adopt naturalization as an option for reducing the "transitional" shortage of its national labour supply.

8. Resourcia adopts a strong pro-natalist policy.

9. Resourcia transfers part of its new wealth in terms of producer and consumer subsidies to its nationals for social and political reasons, and, with an open door policy for admitting expatriates from all nationalities, new high levels of per capita consumption in general, and conspicuous consumption in particular, take hold in a very short period.

10. Resourcia gets committed to an expensive arms purchase programme and to financing local wars and uprisings. According to some estimates Saudi Arabia's annual military expenditure alone increased from U.S. $ 7 billion to U.S. $ 22 billion between 1976 and 1981 and has remained at that high level since; see Editorial in [87].

11. Resourcia's expenditure plans are based initially on optimistic "expectations" of trends in oil demand and prices.

12. Prices and volumes of Resourcia's imports increase relative to the value of oil exports "realized" (short of "expectations"). It is estimated that the import price for OPEC increased by 350 percent between 1973 and 1977.

13. Resourcia, being committed to OPEC production, ambitious development plans, and social welfare expenditures, runs a sizeable deficit. In the first quarter of 1985 Resourcia's trade deficit in relation to USA alone increased by 23 percent from the 1984 level of $ 1.25 billion [54(b), p. 5]. Since the early '80s Resourcia's position was reversed from one of a net buyer to that of a just seller of equities and securities in the US market, ha 1984 Resourcia was a net seller of $ 2 billion of U.S. equities, corporate bonds and treasuries--a 60-percent increase over the 1983 level [54(b), p. 21]. The dramatic change in the economic position of Saudi Arabia--the giant of OPEC--is illustrative. At present, the Saudi budget deficit is second only to that of the USA: its oil revenue fell by 60 percent between 1981 and 1984, its foreign exchange reserve fell by 40 percent between 1983 and 1984, and it is estimated that foreign workers left the Kingdom at the rate of 50,000 a month during 1984 [28, p. 55].

14. Resourcia has to evaluate its stance on OPEC oil policy, on foreign investment criteria, on international assistance programmes, on its national subsidy and welfare policies, and on expatriate labour policy.

The response of Industria to the initial increase in the price of oil has been an attempt to maintain a tolerable balance between negative short-term consequences such as a rise in unemployment rates, in balance-of-trade deficits, or in minimizing negative structural consequences of recycling a substantial oil revenue that is flowing back from Resourcia, on the one hand, and the longer-term central issue of coping with the technical, institutional, and other structural adjustments necessary for maintaining the "centre's" dominance over the "periphery", on the other. The set of policy tools used by Industria, given the intra-Industria contradiction of competition on market shares, includes the direct and indirect manipulation of the structure of interest rates, of exchange rates, and of domestic inflation rates, as illustrated schematically in Figure 3. However, the dynamic nature of these issues will be taken as datum and not examined in the present analysis, since they cover a wide spectrum of issues that go beyond the scope of the present inquiry. Our main focus is limited to understanding the economic-demographic behavioural response of Resourcia and Subsistencia to the present phase of the technological-demographic transition.

What does the future hold for Resourcia? Seeking the future through a looking glass could be misleading. We may only see our own images, i.e. preconceived ideas and ideologies. This is more a reminder to the present authors than a reflection on the state of the art. The future results from interaction among the forces of accumulated experience, external exogenous factors (whether by design or random), and the conscious effort within Resourcia to shape its future. Let us consider these issues within the context of the various paradigms.

To many futurists, oil is the main actor. Its course provides the main "course" for future scenarios. As Mabro [51, p. 55-58] and Sayegh [71], have shown, there is now a change from a sellers' to a buyers' market. According to many scholars, during its prime, oil has been beneficial, not only in igniting economic activities in Resourcia but also as a weapon in the hands of the South for the North-South negotiations [15; 78, p. 255]. This last view was also advocated by S. Amin [6]--a champion of the Unequal Exchange paradigm. It is ironic, since "the weapon" seems to have another edge: integrating Resourcia into the international system of Unequal Exchange and cementing its "dependency"! However, the relevance of a sellers' or a buyers' market to the analysis of long-run dynamics, especially in the context of Resourcia development, is not evident to us.

Oil has always enjoyed a buyers' market. Its demand stems from the technological needs of Industria. Capital needs it for its own reproduction. This is the long-run view of the socio-demographic transition that has taken place since the beginning of the industrial revolution as mentioned earlier in the paper. The events of the Seventies are short-term repercussions. The Eighties return to the long-term course. There are important insights that arise from this last view:

1. Oil production is a highly capital-intensive activity. The idea of a "reserve army" of labour or the "reproduction" of capital through labour, or the mutual benefit, though "unequal", between core and periphery becomes irrelevant in elucidating the Industria-Resourcia relationship.

2. The dramatic increase in revenue supports the institution of small, otherwise non-viable states within Resourcia.

3. Maintaining high oil prices will continue until Industria adjusts itself to the diffusion of new technologies. (17) In 1975, H. Kissinger was reported as
 presenting, in Europe, a plan for an investment programme of one
 thousand billion dollars for the development of new sources of
 energy ... Dr Kissinger has also been very particularly
 adamant--that the price of petroleum had to rise and remain high in
 order to make it profitable to develop these alternative sources of
 energy [36, p. 854].


In 1979, there was another price hike. In 1980 the Iraq-Iran war started. One of its outcomes is a reduction in oil supplies. In that respect, M.A. Adelman indicates that

"Another cartel resource is the instability and violence of some members ... The Iran-Iraq war has been a piece of great good luck; the next fighting may be due more to good management"! [3, p. 20].

4. Human resource development is a long-run commitment. The fast pace of building the necessary infrastructures implied in the socioeconomic plans and the large inflow of expatriate labour required for that phase of economic activities have generated confusing signals between short-term and long-term needs. It has also created a "segmented" labour market that violates basic neoclassical assumptions [86]. In essence the "Dutch Disease" that is being blamed for the decline of non-oil traded goods in the manufacturing sector in the new oil-exporting industrial countries such as the Netherlands and England--see, for example, [99] and [69]--might be responsible for creating serious imbalances in the human resource sector in the Arab world. The Dutch Disease may be labelled the Human Resource Disease in the present context of the Arab world. There is a dire need for a full analysis of the relationships between policies that provide subsidies to producers, to education, to housing, and to the importation of labour on the one hand, and the attaining of desired social objectives on the other. (18)

5. In the midst of the expenditure euphoria generated by the expanding oil revenue, a fundamental truth seems to have been forgotten: the dramatic expansion of the native population could not have been supported without the oil revenue. Without that revenue, population growth of the native population is excessive. The vital question to be addressed is: Do current efforts provide the base for a viable employment of the existing and growing labour supply? As it stands, the demand for expatriate labour is a consumption demand; it will become a production demand if the answer to the above question is in the affirmative.

6. Finally, the long-term negative impact of the emerging pattern of consumption behaviour needs no emphasis. The intergenerational implication of this behaviour is yet to be assessed. What will be the mechanism of public and private adjustment to a decline in oil revenue and at what cost? These are questions that need inclusion in the current research agenda of future Arab development.

These last two points have serious implication for the development case of Subsistencia.

b. Subsistencia--Resourcia

The literature on the development experience of the Subsistencia group is substantial. (19) Our focus is limited to highlighting a few issues in the recent Subsistencia-Resourcia interaction. For many analysts, inter-regional labour migration is the main focus. (20) The emphasis has been on the role of remittances, the social and political impact of Arab versus non-Arab expatriate labour in the receiving countries, on the sectoral imbalances created in Subsistencia as a result of selective immigration, and on civil rights issues. As indicated in Figure 3, the migration flow (and its remittance counter-flow) has been substantial. This is evident in Table 2 in the rise of unrequited transfers to Egypt from abroad, from 29 million in 1970 to 2,074 million in 1982, or expressed as a percentage of merchandise exports, from 63.9 percent in 1973 to 72.5 percent in 1980 [44]. For Syria, official unrequited transfers went up from 7 million in 1970 to 140 million in 1982, or from 53.5 percent of merchandise exports in 1974 to 72.0 percent in 1980. Other Subsistencia countries also show a similar increase in unrequited transfers. We argued above that its occurrence has been an outcome of the specific resource base characteristic of Resourcia and the demand for oil generated in Industria.

Another main effect of migration from Subsistencia has to do with sectoral

imbalances. Again, the story is known, although empirical evidence is not always conclusive. The dramatic increase in remittances has created an equally dramatic increase in the demand for goods and services in Subsistencia. For example, food imports increased substantially in all countries of Subsistencia between 1974 and 1982 as illustrated in Table 2. Some countries like Egypt, Sudan, Morocco and Jordan received substantial food aid as well. However, food production did not keep pace with that exogenous and sudden increase in demand. The issue has been examined extensively in the literature; see for example [100] on agriculture and development. We argued elsewhere [79; 82] that another important reason has to do with the dynamic interaction of emigration and agricultural production on the micro level. As a consequence of various factors, including emigration, the merchandise balance was negative for all countries in Subsistencia and exceeded the value of remittances by a wide margin. Subsistencia fell into the international debt circle. External public debt as a percentage of GNP increased from an average of 19 percent in 1970 to 47 percent in 1982. Indeed, there are positive elements to emigration. But whether these are short-term gains that reverse direction over time is precisely the point being made in this paper.

It must be emphasized that the sudden and external increase in the demand for labour in Subsistencia is derived from the structure of the Industria demand for oil and only conditioned by the pattern of development expenditure in Resourcia. It seems to have diffused any concern with serious long-term population-development policy that could deal squarely with the imbalances between the reproduction and accumulation of capital and labour. The fact that the reproduction and "accumulation" of population in Subsistencia have been ignited and accelerated by forces external to the pace of social change, that such forces are of short-term nature and its reversal as discussed above is inevitable, and that they need to be dealt with by simultaneously adjusting the two sides of the equation as well as the social framework to accommodate these necessary changes, has been brushed aside. More seriously, short-term events are being perceived as permanent phenomena, as illustrated, for example, by proposals to maximize migration returns through establishment of training programmes or other means that increase the efficiency of the labour export market [75]. There is similarity here between the rejection by the Marxist philosophy of the neo-Malthusian population solution on the premise that it may provide a diversion of the long-run march for the ultimate solution, and that the acceptance by Subsistencia the short-term consequences of emigration as a temporary relief for its demographic-economic ills without regard to the longer-term negative impact.

5. CONCLUSIONS

The discussion in the paper relates to conceptual and application issues. On the conceptual level, we hope we contributed a bridge between global theorizing and intermediate process analysis. The main thesis may be summarized as revolving around the following proposition mentioned earlier:
 Changes in the structure and growth of population are assumed to
 have causal linkage with the dynamics of production, accumulation,
 and distribution. There is a delicate balance between the
 reproduction of population and that of capital. The system of
 distributing the social product determines the stability of the
 social system.


In the Western as well as the Eastern industrial transition experiences, the balance between the demographic forces and capital accumulation was maintained, in the natural course of events, within tolerable bounds. When large diversions occurred (never as large as the present experience of the developing countries), outlets were found in the colonizations of new lands. Changes in fertility and mortality were both a negative function of the process of industrialization. They were endogenous to the system. Indeed, if they were not, the system must have had a different solution and, accordingly, a different outcome. This simple truth seems to be forgotten when applying the various paradigms.

A decline in fertility that is independent of, and achieved in the absence of, the true forces of a self-sustained process of capital accumulation in the context of an integrated social development framework, cannot be considered either a necessary or sufficient condition for development. We agree that fertility policy should be part and parcel of development strategy. But we add that the same must be true for mortality. To illustrate, most demographic-economic models incorporate a population growth equation of the Lotka type [ 12;47]. The equation relates birth per unit of time, B(t), to the preceding flow of births, given a survival probability parameter, p(t, x), and the probability of bearing a child, m(t, x). In their analysis of optimal time paths, Arthur and McNicoll specified the equation as follows [12, p. 5] :

B(t) = [[integral].sup.[omega].sub.0] B(t-x) p(t, x) m(t, x) v(t) dx: t [??] [t.sub.0]

where

B(t) is assumed given and continuous for times [t.sub.0] - [omega] [??] t < [t.sub.0;]

p(t, x) is the probability that a birth at time t - x survives to age x;

m(t, x) is the probability of bearing a child (assuming no fertility control) at time t if aged x;

[omega] is an upper bound on the length of life; and

v(t) is a policy factor manipulating the age-schedule of fertility m(t, x). For example, v(t) = 1 implies no control, v(t) < 1 implies policy to discourage fertility.

In an optimizing framework, the optimal economic-demographic policy is dervied by selecting the saving rate and the fertility control paramaters that maximize over time a specified welfare function. For a detailed discussion of optimal accumulation paths of population and the economy within a framework that incorporates the age dimension, the reader is referred to Arthur and McNicoll [12]. Our present concern is limited to the implication of the analysis to an integrated policy of health, fertility, migration and capital accumulation. The point is that the path of the mortality function, although the opposite image of the fertility function, is outside the optimization policy control procedure. But it is precisely because of the exogenous nature of the large and accelerated mortality decline that took place in the recent experience of the developing countries that it is imperative to reduce fertility in a compatible pace. It seems that the pace of mortality decline is essential for the solution of the optimization policy exercise. On the practical side, this latter policy cannot succeed without endogenizing the two determinants of the natural growth of population, viz. mortality and fertility. But endogenizing the mortality function implies a level of "effective" demand for adequate health behaviour that is sustainable on the individual and community levels. In short, "public" health as a commodity must be "earned".

In his concluding chapter in one of the most thorough analyses of the Egyptian economy during the Sadat era, Adel Hossain [42, pp. 641-42] raises the question as to how it was possible to completely uproot the foundation of Nasser's social revolution in such a short period of time. The question was left less than partially answered. Is it possible that, in the presence of a huge demographic imabalnce, some of the cosmetic distribution policies of the social product, e.g. increased public employment or consumer subsidies, were not sufficient to provide true system stability?

The recent pragmatic shift in China's population policy and a comparison with that of Korea may give credence to our point of view. Comparing Korea with China provides a classic case of the fallacy of composition. What is true for the part may not be true for the whole. Korea, having great success in both its economic and population policies, was also able to export its excess labour through an export-led labour-intensive strategy, albeit at a great social cost. It seems that China knew that it could not replicate the same strategy, given its large scale. China's population policy is more dramatic and, for some Marxist "believers", implied an ideological twist. We disagree, as our analysis implied. The socio-economic cost of China's population policy will be borne more intergenerationally and less by letting the country be absorbed in the "Worldwide Unequal Exchange System". We feel that the "why" needs no more elaboration. It is the "how" that needs elucidation.

On the application side, the current socio-economic status of the Arab world can be better understood within the long-term perspectives of the international demographic-industrial transition--a transition that has two known effects. The first is the latent but dramatic increase in population rates of growth in the less developed countries--the Arab world being no exception. This sudden and unbalanced (only mortality declined) demographic change does not necessarily produce those positive outcomes predicted by the optimistic neoclassical, Marxist or post-Marxist paradigms. Logically, the same paradigms could equally indicate an unnecessary cost if trends are left unchecked.

The second effect is the role of Resourcia as a provider of the resource necessary for fuelling the demographic-industrial transition. Since the decline of the textile industry in England, an industry that relied on labour-intensive cotton cultivation, the demographic component, essential in the hypothesized accumulation process of the "World System" paradigm, has lost its relevance. Oil is now the main actor in the equation. It is a highly capital-intensive industry located in areas with national boundaries that lack other resources. From this point of view, conventional paradigms fail to give guidance. Economic and demographic trends in both Resourcia and Subsistencia indicate severe imbalances.

The overall picture can be viewed as overly pessimistic. But there are positive notes. In the context of the Middle East, the Arab countries cannot continue to live beyond its means, expanding and changing the pattern of its consumption far ahead of its real production capabilities. The present national boundaries are preventing the region from achieving its full potential. Within these limited boundaries potential growth is limited at best and continuous dependency is inevitable. Even if more efficient economic policies are pursued, as long as they are pursued in isolation, this will be the case. The momentum of population growth, if it does not find its requirements of adequate capital accumulation to generate a real and balanced demand within a cohesive socio-cultural framework, will write its own demise. We feel that this will be the future as long as the Arab world continues to be divided. Political unions based on short-term convenience are not sufficient. The challenge to development may be characterized in G. Myrdal's terminology as both a drama and a dilemma. Unfortunately, this is where optimism gives way, since rejecting real medicines based on non-scientific conclusions is a common characteristic of the real world.

Finally, we conclude with a vision that we hope crosses national, ideological and even species boundaries in this ever-shrinking world that hosts us. It is evident that we are witnessing the birth of a new scientific revolution: the post-industrial information society. A new core will be established [19]. But, more importantly, the information revolution will certainly imply new rules governing the accumulation-reproduction game, thus setting the stage for a new socio-demographic transition. The relevance of current paradigms has to be critically and continuously reexamined. As we adjust ourselves to the difficult present situation, we must also keep an eye on the future. Basic researches in genetic engineering, the functioning of the brain, and artificial intelligence are trespassing each other's domain, producing exciting and unexpected results. It is possible, and evidence about it is accumulating, that fundamental changes may occur which will influence all facts of human organizations including biological and social foundations of reproduction as we know them now.

As we mentioned earlier, we cannot judge the utility of the end result of this relentless "march of technique", since this "march" is not guided by a recognizable social welfare objective. As Toynbee [92] indicated, it seems as if society is moving its 'head' far ahead of the 'heart'! (21) On the optimistic side, Ledyard Stebbins [88, p. 440] believes in the "durability" of the human race even under conditions of severe social and biological stresses. His conclusions are based on the historical evidence of the survival ability of slaves and conquered people under unbearable conditions. But, as the discussion illustrates, these were the outcome of a socio-economic system that included in its internal dynamics a maldistribution of a growing social output and not the genesis of its destruction. There is a written rule in at least one leading scientific research institute in the developing world that forbids its members to sleep during working hours. But, aside from the possibility of a lack of environmental "incentive" how could we advance without dreams, even those including nightmares!

REFERENCES

[1.] Abdallah, Ismail Sabri. "Reflections on Planning Experience: The Arab Nation and the Third World". In CAUS, Arab Development: Present, Possible and the Future. Beirut. 1984. pp. 195-218. (In Arabic)

[2.] Abdel-Khalik, Gouda. "Review of Arab Development: Present, Possible and the Future". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 79. 1985. (In Arabic)

[3.] Adelman, M.A. "An Unstable World Oil Market". Energy Journal. Vol. 6, No. 1. 1985.

[4.] Amin, Galal A. "Heritage of Arab Development". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 72. 1985. pp. 4-22. (In Arabic)

[5.] Amin, Samir. Accumulation on a Worm Scale: A Critique of the Theory of Underdevelopment. Trans. Brian Pearce. New York: Monthly Review Press. 1974.

[6.] Amin, Samir. "Independent Development and the Third World". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 59. January 1984. pp. 114-124. (In Arabic)

[7.] Amin, Samir. "Introduction". In S. Amin (ed.), Human Resources: Employment and Development: Developing Countries. Vol. 5. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd. 1984.

[8.] Amin, Samir. Unequal Development, An Essay on the Social Formations of Peripheral Capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press. 1976.

[9.] Arab Monetary Fund (eds.). The Unified Arab Economic Report. Arab Monetary Fund. 1984. (In Arabic)

[10.] Arab Planning Institute. Socio-economic Development in the Arab Countries. Kuwait: Arab Planning Institute. 1982. (In Arabic)

[11.] Arndt, H.W. "The Origins of Structuralism". World Development. Vol. 13, No. 2. 1985. pp. 151-159.

[12.] Arthur, W. Brian, and Geoffrey McNicoll. "Optimal Time Paths with Age-Dependence: A Theory of Population Policy". Discussion Paper. New York: The Population Council. 1975.

[13.] Azzam, Henri. "Urbanization and Economic Development in the Arab World". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 52. June 1983. pp. 100-117. (In Arabic)

[14.] Bach, Robert L. "The Reproduction of Trivality: Critical Notes on Recent Attempts to Test the Dynamics of World Capitalism". Department of Sociology, State University of New York. New York: Binghampton. 1978. (Memeographed)

[15.] Bhagwati, Jagdish N., and John Gerard Ruggie (eds.). Power, Passions and Purpose, Prospects for North-South Negotiations. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. 1984.

[16.] Blaug, Mark. Economic Theory in Retrospect. New York: Cambridge University Press. 1985.

[17.] Boserup, Ester. The Condition of Agricultural Growth. Chicago: Aldine. 1965.

[18.] Boserup, Ester. Population and Technological Change: A Study of Long-term Trends. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 1981.

[19.] Bouvier, Leon F. Planet Earth 1984-2034: A Demographic Vision. Washington, D.C.: Population Reference Bureau. 1984.

[20.] Brenner, R. "The Origins of Capitalist Development: A Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism". New Left Review. Vol. 104. 1977. pp. 21-25.

[21.] Bukharin, Nikolai Ivanovich. Economic Theory of the Leisure Class. Connecticut: Greenwood Press. 1927.

[22.] Bukharin, Nikolai Ivanovich. Economics of the Transformation Period. New York: Bergman Press. 1971.

[23.] Cassen, Robert, and Margaret Wolfson (eds.). Planning for Growing Populations. Paris: Development Center of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1978.

[24.] CAUS. Arab Development: Present, Possible and the Future. Beirut: Center for Arab Unity Studies. 1984. (In Arabic)

[25.] Cuca, Roberto. Family Planning Programs: An Evaluation of Experience. Washington: World Bank. 1979. (Working Paper No. 345)

[26.] De Janvry, Alain, and Carlos Garramon. "Laws of Motion of Capital in the Center-periphery Structure". Review of Radical Political Economies. Vol. 9. Summer 1977. pp. 29-38.

[27.] Demeny, Paul. "A Perspective on Long-term Population Growth". New York: The Population Council, Center for Policy Studies. 1984. (Working Paper No. 104)

[28.] Economist, The London Weekly. July 13, 1985.

[29.] Ellul, Jacques. The Technological Society. New York: Vintage Books. 1964.

[30.] Eltis, W.A. Growth and Distribution. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd. 1973.

[31.] Fergani, Nader. "The Absence of Development in the Arab Nation". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 60. February 1984. pp. 6-34. (In Arabic)

[32.] Fergani, Nader. Migration to Oil: Dimension of Labour Migration to the Oil Countries and its Effect on Arab Development. Beirut: Center for Arab Policy Studies. 1983. (In Arabic)

[33.] Fergani, Nader. "Population and Development in the Arab World". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 67. 1984. pp. 73-91. (In Arabic)

[34.] Foster-Carter, Aidan. "From Rostow to Gunder Frank: Conflicting Paradigms in the Analysis of Underdevelopment". World Development. Vol. 4, No. 3. March 1976. pp. 167-180.

[35.] Frank, Andre Gunder. Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. New York: Monthly Review Press. 1967.

[36.] Frank, Andre Gunder. "Economic Crises, Third World and 1984". Worm Development. Vol. 4, No. 10/11. 1976. pp. 853-861.

[37.] Al-Gammal, Rasem M. "Foreign Trade and Increasing Arab Dependency, 1970-1980". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 53. July 1983. pp. 39-45. (In Arabic)

[38.] Gereffi, Gary. "A Critical Evaluation of Quantitative Cross-national Studies of Dependency". Paper presented at the Panel on Dependency Theory, meetings of the International Association, Toronto. March 1979.

[39.] Hammel, E.A. The China Lectures. Programme in Population Research. Berkeley: University of California. 1983. (Working Paper No. 10)

[40.] Hirschman, A.O. Essays in Trespassing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1981.

[41.] Hobson, J.A. Imperialism. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 1971.

[42.] Hossain, Adel. The Egyptian Economy: from Independence to Dependency, 1974-1979. Two Volumes. Cairo: Dar Al-Mostaqbal Al-Arabi. 1982. (In Arabic)

[43.] Hossain, Adel. "Introduction of Arabic Development: The Present Situation". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 6. November 1984. (In Arabic)

[44.] International Monetary Fund. Supplement on Output Statistics. 1984. pp. iv-xiv.

[45.] Jalal-Eddine, M. Al-Awadh. "Cooperation among Arab Countries in Manpower Development and Labor Exchanges". Oil and Arab Cooperation. Vol. 10, No. 3. 1984. pp. 78-110. (OAPEC)

[46.] Jalal-Eddine, M. Al-Awadh. "Labour Immigration in the Arab World: The Present Situation". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 74. 1985. pp. 80-97. (In Arabic)

[47.] Keyfitz, N. Introduction to the Mathematics of Population. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley. 1968.

[48.] Laclau, Ernest. "Feudalism and Capitalism in Latin America". New Left Review. Vol. 67. May-June 1971.

[49.] Lenin, V.I. Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism. New York: International Publishers. 1939.

[50.] Luxemburg, Rosa. The Accumulation of Capital. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. 1959.

[51.] Mabro, Robert. "Economic Consequences of Future Decline in Oil Prices" Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 78. 1985. pp. 54-70. (In Arabic)

[52.] McNicoll, Geoffrey. "On Demographic Turnpikes". IUSSP International Population Conference. Liege: IUSSP. 1973. pp. 463-475.

[53.] Mauldin, Parker W., and Bernard Berelson (with a Section by Zenas Sykes). "Conditions of Fertility Decline in Developing Countries, 1965-75". Studies in Family Planning. Vol. 9, No. 5. 1978. pp. 89-147.

[54.] Mid-East Report. (a) May 1,1985. (b) May 15, 1985.

[55.] Myrdal, Gunnar. Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations. Vol. III. New York: Pantheon. 1968.

[56.] Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider. "Development Economists in Emperior's Clothes?" Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXIII, Nos. 2 & 3. Summer-Autumn 1984. pp. 121-144.

[57.] O'Brien, Philip. "A Critique of Latin American Theories of Dependency". In Ivar Oxaal et al. (eds.), Beyond the Sociology of Development. Economy and Society in Latin America and Africa. London: Routledge and Keyan Paul. 1975.

[58.] Pitchford, J.D. Population in Economic Growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co. 1974.

[59.] Portes, Alejandro, and John Walton. Labour, Class and the International System. New York: Academic Press. 1981.

[60.] Prebisch, Raul. The Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems. New York: United Nations. 1950.

[61.] Prebisch, Raul. The Economic Development of Latin America in the Post War Period. New York: United Nations. 1964.

[62.] Prebisch, Raul. "The Latin American Periphery in the Global System of Capitalism". In Shigeto Tsuru (ed.), Human Resources, Employment and Development, Volume 1: the Issues. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd. 1983. pp. 3-19.

[63.] Preobrazhensky, Evgeny. The New Economics. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1965.

[64.] Ramses, Nadia. 'Western Theory and Arab Development". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 64. 1984. pp. 31-50 (In Arabic)

[65.] Robinson, Joan. Aspects of Development and Underdevelopment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1979.

[66.] Robinson, Joan. Economic Heresies. New York: Basic Books, Inc. 1973.

[67.] Robinson, Joan. Economic Philosophy. Chicago: Aldine. 1962.

[68.] Saadudin, Ibrahim, and M. Abdel-Fadel. Arab Labor Migration: Problems, Consequences and Policies. Beirut: Center for Arab Unity Studies. 1983. (In Arabic)

[69.] Al-Sabah, Mohammad Sabah S. "General Equilibrium Analysis of Government Expenditure in an Oil Exporting Country: The Case of Kuwait". Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, Harvard University, Cambridge, USA. 1985.

[70.] Al-Samak, M.A.S. "The Geo-political Dimension of the Main Formation of Population Structure in the Arab World". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 67. 1984. pp. 92-115. (In Arabic)

[71.] Sayegh, Yusuf. "Current Oil Crises and Arab Economic Future". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 59. January 1984. pp. 14-29. (In Arabic)

[72.] Sayegh, Yusuf. "Dimensions of Arab Economic Development in the '80s". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 65. July 1984. pp. 76-106. (In Arabic)

[73.] Schumpeter, Joseph. Imperialism/Social Classes: Two Essays. New York: New American Library. 1974.

[74.] Seers, Dudley. "Births Life and Death of Development Economics". Development and Change. London : Sage. 1979.

[75.] Serageldin, M. Ismail, and M. Yusuf. "Maximizing Returns from Arab labour Migration". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 63. 1984. pp. 69-82. (In Arabic)

[76.] Serageldin, M. Ismail, and Others. Manpower and International Labour Migration in the Middle East and North Africa. London: Oxford University Press. 1983.

[77.] Al-Shaar, Munzir. "The Use of Jordanian Labor Migration Remittances. The Kuwait Case". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 63. 1984. pp. 100-114. (In Arabic)

[78.] Singer, Hans W. "Further Thoughts on North-South Negotiations: A Review of Bhagwati and Ruggie". World Development. Vol. 13, No. 2. February 1985. pp. 255-260.

[79.] Sirageldin, Ismail. "Agricultural Development and Population Dynamics in Egypt: Planning and Potential in the '80s". In Evaluating Planning Experiences in the Arab Nation. Part two. Kuwait: Arab Planning Institute. 1984. pp. 279-429. (In Arabic)

[80.] Sirageldin, Ismail, "The Demographic Aspects of Income Distribution". Warren Robinson (ed.), Population and Development Planning. New York: The Population Council. 1975.

[81.] Sirageldin, Ismail. Lecture on Population Policies and Development in the '80s. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics. 1984. (Lectures in Development Economics, No. 3)

[82.] Sirageldin, Ismail. "Some Issues in Middle Eastern International Migration". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXII, No. 4. Winter 1984.

[83.] Sitageldin, Ismail, and John F. Kantner. "Equity, Social Mobility and Fertility Control Policies". Research in Human Capital and Development. Vol. 1. Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press, Inc. 1979.

[84.] Sirageldin, Ismail, and John F. Kantner. "The Ultimate Resource: Cornucopian Fables'. Population and Development Review. March 1982.

[85.] Sirageldin, Ismail, and United Nations Secretariat. "Demographic Transition and Socio-Economic Development". Demographic Transition and Socio-Economic Development. United Nations: Department of International Economic and Social Affairs. 1979. (Population Studies, No. 65)

[86.] Sirageldin, Ismail, N. Sherbiny, and M. I. Serageldin. Saudis in Transition: The Challenges of a Changing Labor Market. London: Oxford University Press. 1984.

[87.] South, The. September 1985.

[88.] Stebbins, G. Ledyard. Darwin to DNA, Molecules to Humanity. San Francisco: W.H. Freeman and Company. 1982.

[89.] Steward, Ian. 'Funding for the Arts and Libraries". The Three Bank Review. No. 146. 1984.

[90.] Tabbarah, Riad. "Population, Human Resources, and Development in the Arab World". Population and Development in the Middle East. Beirut: United Nations, Economic Commission for West Asia. 1982.

[91.] Teitelbaum, Michael S. "Comments". Worm Development. Vol. 4, No. 10-11. 1976. pp. 831-835.

[92.] Toynbee, A. A Study of History. New York: Oxford University Press. 1953.

[93.] Tsuru; Shigeto. Human Resources, Employment and Development: The Issues. London: The MacMillan Press Ltd. 1983 edition.

[94.] United Nations. Worm Population Prospects. New York: United Nations. 1985.

[95.] Volsky, Victor. "Latin America: Demographic Problem and Socio-economic Development". V.L. Urquidi and S. T. Reyes (eds.), Human Resources: Employment and Development. Vol. 4. Latin America. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd 1983. pp. 229-310.

[96.] Von Neumann. "A Model of General Economic Equilibrium". Review of Economic Studies. Vol. XIII (1), No. 30. 1945-46.

[97.] Wallerstein, Immanuel Maurice. The Capitalist World-economy: Essays. New York: Cambridge University Press. 1979.

[98.] Weisskoph, Thomas E. "Economic Development and the Development of Economics: Some Observations from the Left". World Bank. Vol. 11, No. 10. 1983. pp. 895-899.

[99.] Wijnbergen, S. Van. "Dutch-Disease: 'A Disease After All?" The Economic Journal. Vol. 94, No. 373. March 1984. pp. 41-55.

[100.] World Bank. World Bank Report 1982. London: Oxford University Press. 1982.

[101.] World Bank. World Development Report 1983. London: Oxford University Press. 1983.

[102.] World Bank. Worm Development Report 1984. London: Oxford University Press. 1984.

[103.] World Bank. World Development Projections 1984. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank. 1984.

[104.] World Fertility Survey. World Fertility Survey: Major Findings and Implications. London: Alden Press. 1984.

[105.] Al-Zahir, Ahmed. "Labor Immigration in the Arab Gulf". Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi (The Arab Future). No. 63. 1984. pp. 82-99. (In Arabic)

[106.] Zaki, Ramzi. The Population Problem: The New Malthusian Myth. Kuwait: Aalam al-Maarifa. 1984. (In Arabic)

(1) As is well known, the current demographic transition associated with the industrial revolution has not been the only experience of mankind, nor will it be the last. For a review and discussion, see [81].

(2) "Technicalization" and "techniques" are used in the sense in which Ellul [29] defines them, and thus differ from technology. In this frame of reference, technique refers to "any complex of standardized means for attaining a predetermined result" (p. vi), or to "compel the qualitative to become quantitative ... (and) ... force every stage of human activity and man himself to submit to its mathematical calculation" (p. xvi).

(3) The exceptions were China, Haiti and Jamaica with CBR equal to 39, Sri Lanka and Cuba with CBR equal to 36 and 32 respectively [101, p. 186].

(4) The response by development economists has been varied. See, for example, Joan Robinson [67], Hirschman [40], D. Seers [74], the special issue on "Economic Development and the Development of Economics, "World Development (1983), Bhagwati and Ruggie [15] on North South Negotiations and its review by H. Singer [78]. the IEA (1983) volumes on Human Resources, Employment and Development [93], especially Vol. 1, S. Tsuru ed., and S. Amin contribution to Volume 5; Weisskoph [98], Portes and Walton [59] that also includes, aside from a penetrating analysis, an extensive bibliography, Naqvi [56] on defence of the "discipline" of development economics, and Arndt [11] on the Origins of Structuralism, among others.

(5) See for example the discussion by Arndt [11].

(6) Notice, however, the conceptual similarity between Joan Robinson's remark on Marx's economic-demographic system, and that of John Stuart Mill's on Malthus quoted above.

(7) The quotation is from Volsky [95, p. 300]. He quotes K. Marx and F. Engels, Obras Completas, Vol. 6, pp. 441 and 645-6.

(8) S. Amin [7, p. xi] argues that Marxism is a "method" and not a "theory". Accordingly it "does not imply logically necessary unilateral conclusions".

(9) As Blaug [16, pp. 259-60] observes, "if Marxism is alive today, it is so more by virtue of the Marxist theory of imperialism than of any other aspect of Marxian Economics". However, Blaug (pp. 260-64) provides a critical examination of the empirical foundation of Lenin's proposition.

(10) For a brief survey of the issues see Portes and Walton [59], especially the first and last chapters. A detailed review should include Bukharin [21; 22], Lenin [49], Preobrazhensky [63], Luxemburg [50], Prebisch [60; 61; 62], Frank [35], Hobson [41], Wallerstein [97] ,and Amin [6; 8]. And for critique: Brenner [20], O'Brien [57], Laclau [48], Bach [14] Foster-Carter [34], Gereffi [38], Blaug [16] and P. Samuelson (1976).

(11) Portes and Walton [59, p. 68].

(12) Shifting the responsibility for the reproduction of the peripheral labour force from rural subsistence enclaves to urban unemployed enclaves, as suggested by some writers, does not solve the logical or the empirical contradictions.

(13) For definitions of the terms techniques and technology see fn. 2. The supreme status of "efficiency as a value system" may be illustrated by a Western prescription for a system of incentives to reduce fertility in socialist China [39, p. 39] :

"Some attention might be given to denying increases in land allotment for higher order births. Care will have to be taken to achieve such measures on a per-couple, not a per-household basis, peasants throughout history have been quite clever about "dividing" complex households to make their work units small to tax-collectors!" (emphasis added).

The concern is clearly with efficiency rather than equity and the possibility of a harmonious inter-class solution does not exist! Is Marx right after all? Is Capitalism with its class struggle a necessary stage before the attaining of true socialism?

Although not evident which direction the technological society is leading us, i.e. Panglossian or demise, it is certain that techniques' relentless march for efficiency is imposing more standardization in all facets of human affairs--and the process is cumulative. If the road leads to collapse, it will be ironic that man, being a unique creature--since he alone creates sanctuary for his own victims (witness the sanctuaries maintained for the endangered species), will not find such help when needed either from self or from other surviving species.

(14) The volume includes, aside from the penetrating review by Adel Hossain, contributions by N. Fergani, Y. Sayegh, A. Al-Kawari, M. Masoud, M.A. Saeed, N. Ramses, and I.S. Abdallah among others.

(15) Fergani [32] adopts the view that the assessment of the impact of population on development can only be done within a socio-economic and historical context. He also asserts that theoretical frameworks that link population and development are not applicable for the Third World situation (pp. 78-79). However, he takes a strong policy stance.

(16) Resourcia includes the major oil-exporting financial-capital-surplus countries (Algeria, Iraq, Qatar, Libya, Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, UAE, Bahrain and Oman). Subsistencia includes the rest of the Arab countries, mainly the labour-surplus, capital-deficit ones. This classification follows that of the Unified Arab Economic Report, called the Report henceforth [9], also adopted by Sayegh [71 ; 72]. We put group one and two of the Report together under Resourcia and added to them Bahrain and Oman. Although the classification of the Report is more detailed and refined, it will complicate the discussion without affecting its general conclusions. For example, it is arguable that some countries may be misclassified in our schematic presentation. Morocco or Tunisia has little labour migration to the Gulf. Its link is mainly to Europe, especially France. Or that Iraq and Algeria have a demographic and natural resource base that is different from the rest of Resourcia. However, the fact that there is an overlap seems to reinforce our main thesis regarding the long-term dynamic nature of the system. Using a Physical Quality of Life Index (PQLI) that includes various indicators of social and economic development, Riad Tabbarah [90] arrives at a different classification. Tabbarah's work, although important and relevant for social planning, is not relevant for our present purpose.

(17) Maintaining high oil prices is primarily directed towards consumers and not producers. This can be achieved for example through a reduction of the price of crude and a retail tax on gasoline.

(18) For example, housing subsidies may discourage labour mobility. So will import of labour in critical skills that may depress relative wages and reduce incentives for training and occupational mobility for the national labour. Also educational incentives that do not discriminate between short- and long-term skill requirements create the wrong signals for individual choices and create a divergence between private and social objectives, especially when public sector employment is perceived as a major resort to national employment. (For an analysis of Saudi Arabia case, see [86].)

(19) The recent growth of Literature, Conferences or Symposiums on the development experience of the non-oil Arab countries (Subsistencia) has been exponential. For recent global assessment see the Arab Planning Institute [10] and I.S. Abdallah [1 ; also in 24] and the references cited therein.

(20) The literature on international migration to the Gulf and oil countries (Resourcia) is substantial. For recent contributions and references see [86], Jalal-Eddine [45; 46] or Fergani [32]. For a recent assessment of the Egyptian case see Adel Hossain [43, Vol. 2, pp. 560-625]. In general, the important economic consequences of emigration to the labour-exporting countries relate to the effect of the flow of workers' remittances, to its influence on employment, its effect on the structure of the labour market, on income distribution, on urban growth, and on fertility.

(21) "Pray, Sir, will political economy uphold the Athenian theatre?" asked the Rev. Dr Follitt. "Surely not. It will be a very unproductive investment," answers Mr MacQuody. Quotation in Ian Steward [89, p. 20].

ISMAIL SIRAGELDIN, The author is Professor at the Johns Hopkins University, and also associated with the Kuwait Institute for Scientific Research. The present revised version has benefited from discussions with Dr Yusuf Al-Ebraheem. The author also acknowledges the valuable research assistance of Haneen Sayed and Julietta Dahdah. The views expressed in the paper are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the institutions with which he is affiliated.

This paper is a revised version of the Quaid-i-Azam Lecture delivered at the First Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society of Development Economists, held at Islamabad in March 1984.
Table 1
Demographic Change: Arab Countries and South-East
Asia: 1960-2000 *

 * 1960 ** 1970 ** 1980

Country BR DR BR DR BR DR

Bangladesh 47 22 48 21 46 18
Pakistan 49 23 47 19 43 16
Thailand 44 15 39 10 30 8

Sudan 47 25 47 22 47 18
Yemen PDR 50 29 49 24 48 20
Yemen AR 50 29 49 27 49 23
Egypt 44 20 40 17 40 13

Morocco 50 21 48 17 45 13
Tunisia 47 19 40 14 35 11
Lebanon 43 14 36 11 30 9
Syria 47 18 47 14 47 8
Jordan 47 20 48 16 46 10

Algeria 51 20 49 16 46 13
Iraq 49 20 48 16 46 12
Oman 51 28 50 22 48 17
Libya 49 19 49 16 47 12
Saudi Arabia 49 23 48 18 45 13
Kuwait 44 10 48 6 40 4
U.A.E. 46 19 36 11 29 6

 1990 2000

Country BR DR BR DR
 NRR = 1

Bangladesh 43 15 36 12 2035
Pakistan 41 14 34 11 2035
Thailand 26 7 23 7 2010

Sudan 44 16 41 12 2035
Yemen PDR 48 17 44 14 2040
Yemen AR 48 20 45 16 2040
Egypt 33 10 27 8 2015

Morocco 41 11 33 8 2025
Tunisia 32 8 25 7 2015
Lebanon 28 8 24 7 2005
Syria 43 6 34 4 2020
Jordan 47 7 42 5 2020

Algeria 45 11 40 8 2025
Iraq 43 9 36 7 2025
Oman 42 13 35 10 2020
Libya 44 10 41 8 2025
Saudi Arabia 43 11 40 8 2030
Kuwait 32 3 25 3 2010
U.A.E. 26 4 25 5 2015

Source: World Development Report, 1984, IBRD

World Population Projection 1984, IBRD

Note: * IBRD

** UN

Table 2
Selected Economic Indicators
Arab World Selected South-East Asian Countries 1970-82 *
(with Percentages)

 VA
 Agriculture
 (MS)

Country '70 % '82 %

Bangladesh 9475 58 11027 53
Pakistan 3258 20 4406 20
Thailand 3591 22 5837 27

Sudan 1367 19 2127 23
Yemen PDR - - - -
Yemen AR 221 3 401 4
Egypt 2683 38 3878 42

Morocco 1725 24 1836 20
Tunisia 480 7 816 9
Lebanon -
Syria 595 8 .. -
Jordan 92 1 132 2.0

Algeria 952 36 1375 57
Iraq 1172 45 .. -
Oman .. - .. -
Libya 126 5 388 16
Saudi Arabia 331 13 616 26
Kuwait 20 1 30 1
U.A.E. .. - .. -

 Cereal Imports
 (000 tons)

Country '74 % '82 %

Bangladesh 1719 56 1375 74
Pakistan 1274 41 361 19
Thailand 97 3 133 7

Sudan 125 2 611 5
Yemen PDR 149 2 271 3
Yemen AR 158 3 560 4
Egypt 3877 60 6703 53

Morocco 891 14 1913 15
Tunisia 307 5 946 8
Lebanon 354 6 529 4
Syria 339 5 426 3
Jordan 171 3 668 5

Algeria 1816 45 3831 28
Iraq 870 21 2510 18
Oman 52 1 217 2
Libya 612 15 849 6
Saudi Arabia 482 12 5584 41
Kuwait 101 3 439 3
U.A.E. 132 3 282 2

 Per
 Food Aid Capita Average
 (000 tons) Income($) Growth(%)

Country '74-75 % '81-2 % 1982 '60-'82

Bangladesh 2130 77 1076 74 140 .3
Pakistan 619 23 368 25 380 2.8
Thailand 0 0 5 1 740 4.5

Sudan 50 5 185 7 440 (0.4)
Yemen PDR 38 4 25 .9 470 6.4
Yemen AR 0 0 13 .5 500 5.1
Egypt 610 66 1952 69 690 3.6

Morocco 75 8 465 6.4 870 2.6
Tunisia 1 .1 96 3.4 1390 4.7
Lebanon 21 2 11 .4 -1500 -
Syria 47 5 8 .3 1680 4.0
Jordan 63 7 73 3 1690 6.9

Algeria 54 5 2350 3.2
Iraq 1 .. -6000 -
Oman - - 6090 7.4
Libya - - 8510 4.1
Saudi Arabia - - 16000 7.5
Kuwait - - 19870 (0.1)
U.A.E. - - 23770 (0.7)

 Current
 Account Merchandise
 Balance Balance Remittance
 (m$) (m$) (m$)

Country '70 '82 1982 '70 '82

Bangladesh - (632) (1531) - 329
Pakistan (667) (811) (2993) - 2580
Thailand (250) (1144) (1603) - 616

Sudan (42) (248) (786) - 131
Yemen PDR (4) (221) (613) 60 411
Yemen AR - (610) (1943) - 1118
Egypt (148) (2216) (5958) 29 2074

Morocco (124) (1876) (2256) 63 849
Tunisia (53) (657) (1334) 29 372
Lebanon - - (2644) - -
Syria (69) (493) (1989) 7 140
Jordan (20) (336) (2488) - 1084

Algeria (125) 85 1596 211 447
Iraq 105 - (9972) - -
Oman - 358 1739 - 43
Libya 645 (2977) 977 - -
Saudi Arabia 71 (45125) 38469 - -
Kuwait - 5786 8519 - -
U.A.E. - - 7464 - -

 Month of External
 Import Public
 Reserve Debt. %
 (month) of GNP

Country 1982 '70 '82

Bangladesh .9 - 39
Pakistan 3.0 31 32
Thailand 3.0 5 17

Sudan .2 16 48
Yemen PDR 3.4 - 80
Yemen AR 2.9 - 36
Egypt 1.9 24 53

Morocco 1.1 18 61
Tunisia 2.1 38 42
Lebanon .. 4 ..
Syria 1.5 13 15
Jordan 3.8 23 43

Algeria 4.6 19 32
Iraq - 9 -
Oman 4.8 - 12
Libya 6.9 - -
Saudi Arabia 5.9 - -
Kuwait 7.5 - -
U.A.E. - - -

Source: World Development Report, 1984, IBRD

.. Not available

* Selected countries
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有