Inequality in the four provinces of Pakistan.
de Kruijk, Hans
1. INTRODUCTION
The purpose of this paper is to analyse, compare and explain income
inequalities in the four provinces of Pakistan on the basis of
decomposition analysis. Overall income inequality is decomposed into
various categories of inequalities in such a manner that the relative
importance of each category can be quantified. Decomposition analysis
searches for the main origins of income inequality not only within or
between provinces, but also within and between urban and rural areas,
labour income and non-labour income, etc. Identification of origins of
inequality is important if policies aiming at reducing inequalities are
considered. Clearly, different causes require different policies. A
large 'decomposition tree' built for Pakistan recently [2]
which provides information on the components of inequality is presented
in the accompanying chart. The structure of inequalities in the four
provinces is analysed on the basis of this 'decomposition
tree'.
One of the most striking and counter-intuitive findings is that, in
relative terms, income inequality between provinces is very minor.
Though in absolute terms, average monthly household income in
Baluchistan is about Rs 100/-lower than in the Punjab and about Rs
200/-lower than in Sind and the NWFP, this gap explains less than one
percent of the overall income inequality in the country. We come back to
this issue in Section 2. Overall inequality in Pakistan appears to be
almost exclusively due to inequalities within provinces. Inequality is
highest within the NWFP, and is followed in a descending order by Sind,
the Punjab and, finally, Baluchistan. Reasons for these differences in
inequality will be discussed in Section 3.
A detailed dynamic analysis of structural changes of distributions
within provinces is not feasible yet, because only the Household Income
and Expenditure Survey of 1979 gives income distribution data by
province. Therefore, studies of the development of income inequality
during the 1970s could only be carried out at a higher level of
aggregation, i.e. for Pakistan as a whole [3; 4]. (1) By comparing
distributions relating to different years, such analyses reveal changes
in the structure of income distribution. A number of structural shifts
appear to play an important role in explaining increasing inequality in
Pakistan over time. Section 3 considers whether the dynamic factors thus
identified can also explain static differences in the level and
structure of inequalities in the four provinces of Pakistan in 1979.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The tool of analysis is the Theil coefficient which is a measure of
income inequality that is additively decomposable. This means that as
far as population sub-groups are concerned total inequality can be
written as the sum of the weighted averages of inequality within
subgroups and the inequality between these groups. As far as factor
components are concerned, the measure can be split up into the
contributions made by the different factors and those made by the
participation effect.
In summary, the outline of the paper is as follows. Section 2
discusses the 'decomposition tree'. Section 3 considers
whether important factors explaining dynamic changes in inequality also
play a rote in understanding static differences in inequality in the
four provinces. Some concluding remarks are made in Section 4.
Appendices contain mathematical formulas and a discussion of the data
base.
2. DECOMPOSITION TECHNIQUES
The structure of income inequality can be derived by decomposing
income inequality according to occupation, industrial sector, location,
production factor, etc. A comparison of different income-distribution
structures in different provinces of the same country may provide
further insight into causes behind overall income inequality in that
country.
Decomposition analysis subdivides the two elements which define
income distribution, viz. income and population groups, into various
components. Income is disaggregated by source of income, like labour
income and non-labour income, while population groups can be split up
according to locality, like provinces, or socio-economic groups.
Theil's measure for overall inequality (T) is used because it
can easily be decomposed. T can be written as
T = [SIGMA] [Y.sub.i] ln ([Y.sub.i]/[N.sub.i])
in which
[y.sub.i] = income share of income class i, and
[N.sub.i] = household share of income class i.
In a differentiation by provinces, overall inequality can be
written as the weighted sum of inequalities within each province plus
the inequality between provinces, where weights are the respective
income shares of each province.
T: [SIGMA] ([Y.sub.p] * [T.sub.p]) + [T.sub.b]
in which
[Y.sub.p] = provincial income shares;
[T.sub.p] = provincial Theft coefficients; and
[T.sub.b] = inequality between provinces, which can be written as:
[T.sub.b] = [SIGMA] [Y.sub.p] ln ([Y.sub.p]/[N.sub.p])
in which [N.sub.p] = provincial household shares.
Provincial Theil coefficients are calculated with data from the
Household Income and Expenditure Survey (HIES) for 1979 [7]. Provincial
income shares are calculated using average household income for urban
and rural areas in each province, as reported by HIES, weighted with
provincial urban and rural household shares, as reported by the 1981
Population Census. Filling in the figures, we get
contribution of contribution of contribution of
inequality inequality inequality inequality
within within within within
Pakistan Punjab Sind NWFP
0.2713 = (.5547 * .2504) + (.2583 * .2842) + (.1412 * .3448)
(100%) (51%) (27%) (18%)
contribution of contribution of
inequality inequality
within between
Baluchistan provinces
(.0459 * 0.1937) + 0.0014
(3%) (1%)
With regard to inequality within provinces, it appears that the
Theil coefficient of 0.3448 for the NWFP is relatively high and clearly
higher than the corresponding coefficient for the Punjab (0.2504).
Nevertheless, the contribution of the Punjab to overall inequality is
more than fifty percent because of its high income-share. Further
decomposition is required to discover reasons for different levels of
inequality in the provinces.
Apparently, household income inequality between provinces is very
small--less than one percent of total inequality. This counter-intuitive
result requires further examination. Table 1 shows that average income
in Baluchistan is about Rs 100/--lower than in the Punjab and about Rs
200/--lower than in the NWFP and Sind, which is a substantial
difference. However, income differences within provinces are much
larger. For example, comparing average monthly household income of the
highest income class in urban NWFP (constituting 4 percent of the
households) amounting to Rs 13,000/--with the average income of Rs
250/--for the lowest income class (2 percent of the households), it
becomes clear that inequalities within provinces are of another order of
magnitude. When measuring inequalities between provinces, account is
taken only of differences between average incomes, assuming that all
households within a certain province earn exactly the same income. Of
course, income inequality in a country would be very low if the
difference between the highest and the lowest income is Rs 200/-, or 20
percent only.
Provincial Theil coefficients are decomposed further into
inequalities within and between urban and rural areas. (2) In the
following formula,
[T.sub.p] = ([T.sub.pu] * [T.sub.pu]) + ([Y.sub.pr] * [T.sub.pr]) +
[T.sub.pb]
for each province,
[Y.sub.pu] = urban income share;
[Y.sub.pr] = rural income share;
[T.sub.pu] = Theil coefficient urban areas;
[T.sub.pr] = Theil coefficient rural areas; and
[T.sub.pb] = inequality between urban and rural areas.
Filling in data for, for example, Sind and the NWFP (see also the
Chart), one can see immediately that the structures of inequality in
these provinces are completely different.
Sind: 0.2842 = (0.59 * 0.3118) + (0.41 * 0.1308) + 0.0473
(100%) (64%) (19%) (17%)
NWFP: 0.3448 = (0.23 * 0.5743) + 0.77 * 0.2549) + 0.0148
(100%) (39%) (57%) (4%)
Both the level and the relative importance of [T.sub.pb] are higher
in Sind than in the NWFP. It is not surprising that the difference
between Karachi and the rural areas in Sind appears to be larger than
the difference between Peshawar and the rural NWFP (see also Table 1).
It is also understandable that inequality in cities is higher than in
the countryside. Furthermore, urban inequality has more impact on
provincial inequality in Sind than in the NWFP owing to a higher urban
income weight. Note, however, that urban income inequality is
considerably lower in urban Sind than in urban NWFP. But the reasons why
the level of inequality in both urban and rural areas is higher in the
NWFP than in Sind are not immediately clear. Therefore, further
decomposition is required.
Apart from decomposing T into inequalities within and between
groups of households, T is also decomposable according to different
sources of income (see Section 2). In this way, the extent to which
household income inequality is due to inequalities in labour earnings or
to inequalities in property incomes can be located. Formulas for this
kind of decomposition are presented in Appendix 1 while the results are
shown in the Chart. It can be seen that the above-mentioned high
inequality in the NWFP is mainly due to non-labour incomes. We come back
to this issue in Section 3.
Another important factor in explaining differences between
household incomes is the number of earners per household. Clearly, it
makes a great difference whether a household has one earner or two or
even more. Therefore, household labour incomes are converted into labour
incomes per earner, and labour income inequalities are decomposed into
earners' inequalities and into inequalities of the number of
earners per household both within urban areas and within rural areas.
Again, earners' income inequalities are expressed by a Theil
coefficient. (For formulas, see Appendix 1.) Finally, these regional
earners' income Theil coefficients are decomposed into inequalities
within and between occupational groups.
The Chart shows that the relative contributions of various
components are different for each province. Roughly speaking, overall
household income inequality in the country is due to the following
components:
--inequality between provinces = 1%,
--inequality between urban and rural areas = 9%,
--inequality in non-labour incomes = 29%,
--inequality due to different number of earners per household =
29%,
--inequality between occupational groups = 4%, and
--inequality within occupational groups = 28%.
Factors behind different structures in the four provinces are
discussed in the next section.
3. DIFFERENT PROVINCIAL INEQUALITY STRUCTURES
This section presents the main differences in the structure of
inequality in the four provinces and examines a number of factors that
may be responsible for those differences. Table 2 summarizes the level
of inequality in urban and rural areas in the four provinces, while the
structure of inequality is summarized in Table 3. Table 2 shows that in
all provinces inequality is higher in urban areas than in rural areas.
Among urban areas, inequality is relatively high in Sind and the NWFP.
In urban Sind, this is mainly due to high labour income inequality,
whereas in NWFP inequality is almost exclusively embodied in non-labour
incomes (Table 3). In rural areas, inequality is relatively high in the
Punjab and the NWFP (again due to non-labour income inequality). Income
inequality is low in Baluchistan, especially when it is realized that
half of total inequality is due to a difference in the number of earners
per household.
In analysing the causes behind these interprovincial differences,
we make use of an earlier work relating to changes in income inequality
in Pakistan over time. It will be considered whether major determinants
of increasing inequality in Pakistan during the 1970s are also important
in explaining static interprovincial differences. the following five
structural shifts appear to play a major role in explaining increasing
inequality in Pakistan over time.
1. Shift from rural areas to urban areas;
2. Within urban areas: increased share of non-labour incomes;
expanding modern sector;
3. Within rural areas: increased share of non-agricultural
activities; within agriculture: shift from tenancy to ownership.
Possible structural interprovincial differences of this kind are
discussed in successive subsections.
Relative Size of Urban versus Rural Sectors within Provinces
Provincial Theil coefficients can be expressed as the weighted sum
of inequalities within urban and rural areas (plus inequality between
urban and rural areas) weighted by the respective income shares of urban
and rural areas. Since inequality is higher in urban areas than in rural
areas in all provinces (Table 2), the size of the urban income weight is
directly related to the level of inequality within provinces. In other
words, if urban Theil coefficients and urban average incomes are,
respectively, exactly the same in all provinces (similarly in rural
areas), provincial Theil coefficients would differ with the size of
their respective urban sectors.
The Punjab and, particularly, Sind have large urban sectors
compared with the NWFP and Baluchistan (Table 2). Nevertheless,
inequality is highest in the NWFP, notwithstanding the relatively small
size of its urban sector. Apparently, the countervailing power of other
factors exceeds the impact of the size of the urban sector in the NWFP.
The ranking from high inequality to low inequality for the other three
provinces, viz. Sind, Punjab and Baluchistan (T is 0.28, 0.25 and 0.19,
respectively) is in line with the ranking of the size of their urban
sectors (0.59,0.35 and 0.22, respectively).
Inequality within Urban Areas
Not only the size of the urban sector differs from province to
province, but the economic structure of the urban sectors varies as
well. Two issues are discussed below, viz. the importance of non-labour
incomes and the relative size of the formal sector in urban areas.
Share of Non-labour Incomes
Apart from inequality which can be decomposed according to
population groups, the Theil coefficient can also be decomposed
according to income sources. In that case, the Theil coefficient is not
the sum of inequality within and between groups, but T is simply split
up into two components adding to T. (For formulas, see Appendix 1.) The
reason is that one can not speak of a group of households earning income
from labour and another group of households receiving non-labour income,
because a certain household can get income from both sources. The
results of these decomposition exercises are presented in the Chart and
summarized in Table 4.
Table 4 shows that the share of non-labour income in total income
does not differ very much between urban Punjab, Sind and Baluchistan,
but both the share and the level of non-labour income are significantly
higher in urban NWFP. The major components of non-labour income are
property income, mainly from land and houses, interest and profits.
Unfortunately, the HIES does not provide detailed information about the
size of these components. Since there are no clear reasons to presume that income from land or houses is much higher in the NWFP than in other
provinces, it is likely that large trade-margins on a variety of items
play an important role in Peshawar. Inequality of non-labour incomes is
much higher than inequality of labour earnings. Average monthly
non-labour income of the richest four percent of households in urban
NWFP is about Rs 9,000! The remaining 96 percent of the households get
on average about Rs 210 per month of non-labour income, which is roughly
the same amount as similar groups in other provinces receive. Further
research is required to discover the peculiarities of this phenomenon.
Table 4 further shows that average labour incomes per earner do not
differ much between urban areas. Average earnings are a bit higher in
Karachi, but most likely costs of living are also higher in a
metropolis. Inequality between earners is lower than inequality between
households, because the average number of earners per household
increases with household income. The relatively high earners'
income inequality in Karachi is discussed below.
Size of the Modern Sector
Four indicators are used to compare the sizes of the formal sectors
in urban areas in the four provinces. These are (i) the size of the
manufacturing sector, (ii) the number Of professional, technical,
administrative, executive, managerial and clerical workers in
manufacturing, (iii) the size of the banking sector, and (iv) the number
of professional etc. workers in the non-manufacturing private sector.
All indicators point in the same plausible direction (Table 5): urban
Sind (Karachi) has the largest modern sector, followed by urban Punjab.
Since both average income and inequality are higher in the modern sector
than in the informal sector, the relative size of the modern sector
affects the level of earners' inequality (Table 4) in two ways.
Firstly, inequality between the two sectors is more pronounced with a
relatively large modern sector. (See formulas in Appendix 1 .) Secondly,
the high inequality within the modern sector gets more weight with a
large modern sector.
The ranking from high to low earners' income inequality for
urban areas in the four provinces is in line with the ranking of the
size of their modern sectors in the sense that urban Sind is definitely
Number One and the Punjab is Number Two, while the size of the modern
sector as well as earners' inequality are both small in urban NWFP
and Baluchistan.
Inequality within Rural Areas
The contribution of rural areas to overall inequality in Pakistan
is about 50 percent, while approximately 75 percent of households are
living in rural areas [7; 9]. Apparently, inequality is lower in rural
than in urban areas. Though Theft coefficients confirm this conclusion,
one must be very careful in interpreting this differential in equality.
For what is measured is inequality between households living in rural
areas and not inequality of income generated in rural areas. Income
transfers between rural and urban areas may cause a bias. Landlords
living in urban areas get income from their property located in rural
areas. This income is reported as urban income and contributes to urban
inequality, whereas it is the result of inequalities in rural areas,
like land inequality. Further, urban workers may transfer remittances to
family members living in the countryside. The amount of transfers is not
known, which hampers the analysing of causes of inequality in the
distribution of income in rural areas. Keeping this in mind, we will
consider differences in the economic structure of rural areas in the
four provinces.
Size of the Agricultural Sector
Table 6 presents for each province the percentage of earners
working in agricultural and non-agricultural sectors. Rural Sind has the
smallest non-agricultural sector, but it has hardly any impact on
interprovincial differences in inequality because differences in
earnings between and within occupational groups are very small. Income
differences between households in rural areas are mostly due to
differences in the number of earners per household (see also Table 3).
Different Agrarian Systems
The mode of agricultural production varies greatly with provinces.
Feudalism is widespread in Sind; great parts of the NWFP and Baluchistan
still have a tribal character; and in the Punjab a mixed system of
ownership and tenancy prevails (Table 7). Different agrarian systems
lead to different patterns of the level and distribution of agricultural
incomes. In a feudal system, the share of non-labour incomes is
relatively high (payments from tenants to landlords are classified as
non-labour incomes of landlords) and the distribution between landlords
and tenants is relatively skewed. Therefore, it is to be expected that
average income of agricultural workers is low and the share of
non-labour incomes and inequality are relatively high in rural Sind.
Table 6 shows that average income of agricultural workers indeed is
significantly lower in Sind than in other provinces, but inequality is
not higher (see Chart). Probably, the reason is that many landlords are
living in cities. In that case, payments from tenants to landlords are
income transfers from rural to urban areas, which may be another cause
of large inequality between urban and rural areas in Sind. Further
research is required to discover the amount of these transfers.
As far as the distribution of labour incomes among agricultural
workers living in rural areas is concerned, inequality is low in rural
Sind in spite of large numbers of landless agricultural labourers (Table
6). The average size of tenants' cultivated area in Sind is eight
acres, with small variation. Their income is low because 50 percent of
their produce from eight acres is handed over to landlords. Income of
landless labourers may be lower but not much. Inequality between
agricultural workers is higher in the NWFP and the Punjab because land
inequality between owner cultivators is always higher than land
inequality between tenants.
4. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
A large 'decomposition tree' has been presented, which is
a useful framework for analysing income distribution in the four
provinces of Pakistan. The following categories of inequalities are
distinguished: inequalities between and within urban and rural areas,
inequalities of labour and non-labour incomes, inequalities due to
differences in the number of earners per household, and inequalities
between and within occupational groups. This list is not exhaustive and
can be enhanced by inserting more categories. Especially non-labour
incomes require further decomposition. By putting all these inequalities
into one consistency framework it is possible to localize the
inequalities and sense their proportions.
Currently held perceptions on income inequality are based on
'visible' differences like different wage rates in urban and
rural areas or different remuneration rates for different occupations
(which happen to explain only a few percentages of total inequality) or
inequality between provinces (whose contribution to overall inequality
is less than one percent). However, the origin of household income
inequality in Pakistan is mainly embodied in two factors, explaining
about 30 percent of overall inequality each, viz. inequality of
non-labour incomes and differences in the number of earners per
household.
One of the main findings of this paper is that not only the level
but also the structure of inequality differs substantially among the
provinces. About 60 percent of inequality in the NWFP is due to
non-labour income inequality. Differences in the numbers of earners per
household contribute to 50 percent of total inequality in Baluchistan.
Inequality in Sind is mainly due to inequalities within urban areas
(relatively large modern sector) and to income differences between urban
and rural areas, whereas inequality in Punjab is mainly located in rural
areas.
Localizing various categories of inequality is important if
policies for reducing inequality are considered, because different types
of inequality require different policy instruments.
This static comparative study of the structure of inequality in the
four provinces of Pakistan has made use of findings from earlier work on
dynamic changes in income distribution in Pakistan at an aggregate
level. But a greater advantage of decomposition analysis can be gained
by comparing disaggregated charts for different years, so that
disaggregated changes in inequalities can be located and analysed. That
will be our subject for further research.
Comments on "Inequality in the Four Provinces of
Pakistan"
Mr Hans de Kruijk's continuing interest in the phenomena of
poverty and inequality in Pakistan is highly commendable, especially as
this set of studies seems to be receiving decreasing attention from
Pakistani economists. In the PSDE meeting last year, he presented to us
the work undertaken by him, jointly with another Erasmus colleague, on
changes in poverty and income inequality in Pakistan during the 1970s.
The present paper, using the same data and methodology, concentrates on
the regional dimensions of economic inequalities in Pakistan. The
analysis relates to 1979-1980, the latest year for which the Household
Income and Expenditure Survey (HIES) data were available.
Mr de Kruijk, using the Theil Inequality Index, attempts to
decompose the total index into its provincial and interprovincial
components. He then further decomposes, for each province, the
contribution of inequality for urban and rural areas, as well as that
between them. Intra-rural and intra-urban inequalities are further
decomposed into labour and non-labour income inequalities and the
process is carried through, where data are available, to discover the
contribution of occupational structure to total inequality.
Some of the results obtained by Mr de Kruijk's analysis seem
counter-intuitive, if not counterfactual, the least startling of which
is the one pointed out by the author himself, viz. the contribution of
interprovincial differences in average incomes being nominal. In the
table which reports average monthly household incomes by provinces, the
Punjab ranks third in total households, second in rural households and
last in urban households. In terms of inequality rankings also, the
Punjab is third in total households, second in rural households and
third in urban households. Thus, neither in terms of per capita (ignoring the differences in household sizes which are not reported)
incomes, nor in terms of inequality indices does the Punjab fare as
badly as the popular perception of its being the most prosperous and
highly inegalitarian province. Its ranking in terms of level of incomes
is distorted partly by the inclusion of Karachi as part of Sind and
partly by the more general problem, acknowledged by the author, of urban
incomes including a large proportion generated in the rural areas.
Karachi is a cosmopolitan city and part of the income of its residents
is generated in different parts of the country, including the Punjab. A
comparison of the figures in Table 1 with those on gross provincial
product on a per capita or per household basis would have served to
illustrate this difference. Account would also need to be taken of
income transfers, especially remittances from both within the country
and abroad, in measuring both the level and distribution of incomes. I
am not certain whether this is adequately done in the data used by the
author.
An analysis of interregional differences is a very complex
exercise. The author is naturally limited in his task by the quality and
content of the data available to him. He does use other available data,
such as those from the Agriculture Census and the Labour Force Survey,
to account for difference in inequality between the provinces. However,
a more rigorous analysis would need a closer interfacing of data on a
comparable basis than is available at present. A possible way of
enriching the analysis would have been to use district-level data rather
than the much more aggregated data on the provinces. It would also be
possible then to group together districts according to other criteria
than the existing political and administrative boundaries, such as
availability of irrigation, degree of urbanization, level of education,
etc.
It is unfortunate that Mr de Kruijk has only chosen to analyse
regional differences in terms of overall income inequality. In last
year's paper, he presented the interesting finding that whereas
inequality had been rising in Pakistan in the 1970s, there was a fall in
the percentage of the people below the poverty line. It would be
interesting to know whether this phenomenon occurred in all the
provinces (or districts) or whether it was confined to only a few of
them.
S. M. Naseem
Development Planning Division, ESCAP, Bangkok (Thailand)
Appendix I
MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSIONS
1. Population Subgroups (1)
The Theil coefficient (T) can be written as.
T = [[mu].sub.i] [[summation] over (i)] [n.sub.i]/[n.sub.[mu]] ln
([[mu].sub.i]/[mu] ... ... ... ... (1)
in which
[[mu].sub.i] = average income of income class i
[n.sub.i] = number of households in income class i
n = total number of households
[mu] = average income
Total inequality T can be written as the weighted sum of
inequalities within subgroups and inequality between subgroups. If each
household belongs to one and only one subgroup (e.g. the province in
which the household lives) then inequality [T.sub.r] for each subgroup r
can be calculated by
[T.sub.r] = [[mu].sub.ir][[summation] over (i)]
[n.sub.ir]/[n.sub.r][[mu].sub.r] ln ([[mu].sub.ir]/[[mu].sub.r]) ... ...
... ... (2)
in which
[n.sub.r] = number of households in subgroup r
[[mu].sub.r] = average income of subgroup r
[n.sub.ir] = number of households in income class i of subgroup r
[[mu].sub.ir] = average income in income class i of subgroup r
Inequality between the subgroups [T.sub.b] is
[T.sub.r] = [[mu].sub.r][[summation] over (r)] [n.sub.r]/[mu] ln
([[mu].sub.r]/[mu]) ... ... ... ... (3)
It follows that total inequality can now be written as
T = [T.sub.b] + [n.sub.r][[mu].sub.r]/n[mu] [[summation] over (r)]
[T.sub.r] ... ... ... ... (4)
[T.sub.b] is called the explained part of total inequality. The
relative contribution of between-group inequality to total inequality
is: Tb/T x 100 percent. The rest of inequality is located within
subgroups.
A successive decomposition analysis of unexplained parts requires
further breakdowns within subgroups, e.g. by distinguishing more
disaggregated subgroups (e.g. urban and rural areas within provinces) or
by a breakdown of household incomes into factor components. The latter
will be discussed now.
2. Income Factor Components (2)
In this case incomes of households are broken down into incomes
from various sources. If two sources are distinguished, viz. labour
income and non-labour income, the formula for T becomes:
T = [[mu].sup.a.sub.i] + ([[mu].sub.i] - [[mu].sup.a.sub.i]]
[[summation] over (i)] [n.sub.i]/n[mu] ln ([[mu].sub.i]/[mu] ... ... (5)
in which
[[mu].sup.a.sub.i] = average labour income in income class i, and
[[mu].sub.i] - [mu].sup.a.sub.i] = average non-labour income in
income class i.
The part of total inequality that is attributable to labour income
([S.sub.a]) is then
[S.sub.a] = [[mu].sup.a.sub.i] [[summation] over (i)]
[n.sub.i]/n[mu] ln ([mu].sub.i]/[mu] ... ... ... ... (6)
and the part that is attributable to non-labour income ([S.sub.na])
is
[S.sub.na] = T - [S.sub.a] = [[mu].sub.i] - [[mu].sup.a.sub.i]
[[summation] over (i)] [n.sub.i]/n[mu] ln ([[mu].sub.i]/[mu] ... ... (7)
3. Participation within Households
An important determinant of household labour income is the number
of earners per household. Of course, it counts whether a household has
one earner or two earners (or even more). The contribution of this
effect is measured as follows.
As mentioned before, the Theil coefficient for households (T) can
be written as follows.
T = [[summation] over (i)] [n.sub.i][[mu].sub.i]/n[mu] ln
[[mu].sub.i]/[mu] ... ... ... ... (8)
Similarly, the expression for the Theil coefficient for earners
(Te) is
Te = [[summation] over (i)]
[n.sub.ie][[mu].sub.ie]/[n.sub.e][[mu].sub.e] ln
[[mu].sub.ie]/[[mu].sub.e] ... ... ... ... (9)
[n.sub.ie] = number of earners in income class i
[[mu].sub.ie] = average income of earners in income class i
[n.sub.e] = total number of earners
[[mu].sub.e] = average income of earners
Since [n.sub.ie][[mu].sub.ie]/[n.sub.e][[mu].sub.e] =
[n.sub.i][[mu].sub.i]/n[mu] (the income share per income class remains
the same)
and: [[mu].sub.ie] = [[mu].sub.i--]/[e.sup.h.sub.i], and
[[mu].sub.e] = [mu]/[e.sup.h] by definition
in which
[e.sup.h] = average number of earners per household
[e.sup.h.sub.i] = average number of earners per household in income
class i,
it follows that
[T.sub.e] = T + [[summation] over (i)] [n.sub.i][[mu].sub.i]/n[mu]
ln ([e.sup.h]/[e.sup.h.sub.i]) ... ... ... ... (10)
The contribution of different number of earners per household to
inequality of household labour income is therefore
-[[summation] over (i)] [n.sub.i][[mu].sub.i]/n[mu] ln
([e.sup.h]/[e.sup.h.sub.i])
Appendix 2
THE DATA BASE
The only source publishing data on household incomes in Pakistan
and covering the entire income range is the Household Income and
Expenditure Survey (HIES).
The lowest level of aggregation of the latest published HIES 1979
is that for twelve income classes (less than 300 rupees per month, Rs
301 -400, Rs 401 -500, etc.) in eight regions (urban and rural areas in
the four provinces). For each income class in each region, data are
presented on the components of household income (labour income and
non-labour income), on the number of earners per household, and on the
occupation of the earners. Some remarks are due with respect to using
this data base for the present analysis.
Firstly, doubts about the reliability of data refer mainly to an
understatement of incomes accruing to the highest income group, but not
to the scope and coverage of the survey which seems excellent. A sample
size of almost 20,000 households, which is more than 120,000 persons,
for a country with a population of about 80 million persons is very
reasonable.
Secondly, this paper makes use of published data in the form of
grouped data and not of the unpublished individual income data from data
tapes. Inequality indicators derived from grouped data underestimate
true inequality because inequality within brackets is neglected. The
extent of underestimation depends on the number of income brackets. It
appears from empirical exercises that when using 10 or more income
brackets the underestimation error is no more than a few percentages.
Gastwirth (1972) calculated an upper bound (maximum inequality within
brackets) and a lower bound (no inequality within brackets) of the Gird
coefficient of U.S. household incomes which are classified in 10 income
brackets. The difference between the upper bound and the lower bound of
the Gird coefficient is 5 percent only. Odink and Imhoff (1984)computed
the difference between the Theil coefficient based on grouped data and
the Theil coefficient based on individual income data for 5,666 gross
incomes of heads of households in 1979 in the Netherlands, ranging from
300 to 250,000 guilders. They found a difference of 0.3 percent, using
30 income brackets. In another exercise, using data on wages of 775
employees of a moderate large Dutch firm in the food industry ranging
from 80 to 13,500 guilders, they found an underestimation error of 1.4
percent with 10 income brackets only. Since the HIES distinguishes 12
income brackets the Theil coefficient computed from published data
should not differ significantly from the true Theil coefficient computed
from individual incomes.
Thirdly, the units of measurement in this paper are income per
household and income per earner. The reason that we measure income
inequalities on the basis of total household income and not on the basis
of per person household income is the lack of sufficient information
about the extent of economies of scale of households in Pakistan. For
total expenditures of an 8-person household are much lower than the
eightfold of total expenditures of a one-person household.
Finally, this paper considers inequalities in income and not in
purchasing power. The latter requires data on price differentials
between provinces and between rural and urban areas.
(1) See [10].
(2) See [11].
REFERENCES
[1.] Adelman, Irma, and Amnon Levty. "Decomposing Theil's
Index of Income Inequality into, between and within Components".
Review of Income and Wealth. Series 30, No. 1. March 1985.
[2.] de Kruijk, Hans. Income Inequality Decomposition: The Case of
Pakistan. Rotterdam: Erasmus University, Centre for Development
Planning. April 1986. (Discussion Papers Series, No. 75)
[3.] de Kruijk, Hans. When Poverty Declines and Inequality
Increases: The Case of Pakistan during the 1970s. Rotterdam: Erasmus
University, Centre for Development Planning. 1986. (Discussion Papers
Series)
[4.] de Kruijk, Hans, and Myrna van Leeuwen. "Changes in
Poverty and Income Inequality during the 1970s". Pakistan
Development Review. Vol. XXIV, Nos. 3&4. Autumn-Winter 1985.
[5.] Pakistan. Ministry of Food and Agriculture. Agricultural
Census Organization. Pakistan Census of Agriculture, 1972. Province
Report: Baluchistan. Lahore 1975.
[6.] Pakistan. Statistics Division. Agricultural Census
Organization. Pakistan Census of Agriculture. 1980: All-Pakistan Report.
Lahore. 1983.
[7.] Pakistan. Statistics Division. Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 1979. Karachi. 1983.
[8.] Pakistan. Statistics Division. Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Labour Force Survey, 1978-79. Karachi. 1982.
[9.] Pakistan. Statistics Division. Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Statistical Pocket Book of Pakistan. 1982. Karachi. 1982.
[10.] Shorrocks, A.F. "The Class of Additively Decomposable
Inequality Measures". Econometrica. Vol. 48. No. 3. 1980. pp.
613-625.
[11.] Shorrocks, A.F. "Inequality Decomposition by Factor
Components". Econometrica. Vol. 50, No. 1. 1982.
(1) In an earlier study [4] we show that in both rural and urban
areas poverty has declined while at the same time income inequality has
increased. We used four inequality measures and also four poverty
indicators. All measures and indicators pointed to the same conclusion.
That is our earlier papers use aggregate figures for some groups. That
is why those results differ slightly from the results presented here.
(2) The order of decomposition slightly influences the results; see
[1].
HANS DE KRUIJK, The author is Lecturer in Economics of the Centre
for Development Planning, Erasmus University, Rotterdam (the
Netherlands). He would like to express his gratitude to Prof. P. A.
Cornelisse, Dr S. I. Cohen and Dr S. L. Lodder for their stimulating
comments.
Table 1 Average Monthly Household Income by Province
Punjab Sind NWFP Baluchistan
Urban 1,214 1,476 1,607 1,357
Rural 828 794 936 762
Total * 931 1,089 1,032 845
Sources: [7] for Rows 1 and 2; [9].
* Total averages differ from those obtained from HISS [7] data
because of the differences in the weights applied. The
above-mentioned figures are calculated using average household
income for urban and rural areas in each province as reported by
HIES, but weighted with provincial urban and rural household shares
as reported by the 1981 Population Census.
Table 2 Theil Coefficients, Income Shares and
Household Shares for Urban and Rural Areas,
by Province
Province/ Theil Income Household
Urban, Rural Coefficient Share (%) Share (%)
Punjab .25 100 100
Urban .26 35 27
Rural .22 65 73
Sind .28 100 100
Urban .31 59 43
Rural .13 41 57
NWFP .34 100 100
Urban .57 23 14
Rural .25 77 86
Baluchistan .19 100 100
Urban .25 22 14
Rural .14 78 86
Table 3
Provincial Inequality Structures
(Percentages)
Punjab Sind NWFP Baluchistan
Total Inequality
within Provinces 100 100 100 100
Inequality between
Urban and Rural Areas 6 17 4 13
Inequality within Urban Areas
Non-labour Incomes 13 10 34 6
Labour Incomes
Number of Earners 10 19 3 17
Earners' Inequality
Between Occupations 1 6 0 1
Within Occupations 13 29 2 8
Inequality within Rural Areas
Non-labour Incomes 17 3 26 7
Labour Incomes
Number of Earners 21 8 19 34
Earners' Inequality
Between Occupations 3 - 1 3
Within Occupations 16 8 11 11
Table 4 Inequality in Labour and Non-labour Incomes
by Province, Urban Areas
Average Percentage
Monthly Non-labour of
Urban Household Household Non-labour
Areas Income Income Income
Punjab 1214 256 22%
Sind 1476 291 20%
NWFP 1607 564 35%
Baluchistan 1357 312 23%
Average
Non-labour Labour Labour
Urban Income Household Income
Areas Inequality Income Inequality
Punjab 0.47 957 0.22
Sind 0.31 1184 0.34
NWFP 1.65 1038 0.21
Baluchistan 0.29 1048 0.27
Average
Labour Earners'
Urban Income Income
Areas per Earner Inequality
Punjab 575 0.12
Sind 675 0.21
NWFP 595 0.09
Baluchistan 580 0.09
Table 5 Percentage Distribution of Employed Persons by Sector,
Occupational Groups and Provinces, Urban Areas
Punjab Sind NWFP Baluchistan
Manufacturing 26.67 26.71 16.3 9.79
(prof., techn., 1.41 2.28 1.3 36
admn., cler.
workers)
Financing, Insurance,
Real Estate and
Business Services 237 3.60 1.87 1.30
Prof., Tech., Adm.,
Cler. Workers
in Non-manufacturing
Private Sector 5.12 7.53 5.02 5.01
Source: [8].
Table 6 Inequality and Average Income by
Sector and Province, Rural Areas
Punjab Sind NWFP Baluchistan
Percentage of
Agricultural Workers 63% 82% 55% 64%
Non-agricultural Workers 37% 18% 45% 36%
Average Income
Agricultural Workers 370 288 433 351
Non-agricultural Workers 353 324 424 379
All Rural Workers 363 294 429 362
Theil Coefficient
Agricultural Workers 0.08 0.05 0.07 0.05
Non-agricultural Workers 0.09 0.09 0.08 0.03
All Rural Workers 0.08 0.06 0.07 0.04
Source: Calculations based on [7] .
Table 7
Distribution of Rural Households According to Activity,
Status and Provinces, Pakistan 1979-80
(Percentages)
Activity/Status Punjab Sind NWFP Baluchistan
All rural households 100 100 100 100
Activity
Non-agricultural 37 18 45 36
Agricultural 63 82 55 64
Status
Landless 18 34 19 36
Not landless 45 48 36 28
Owner 25 19 25 21
Owwer-cum-tenant 11 5 5 2
Tenant 10 23 7 5
Sources: [5, for Baluchistan] ; [6] ; [7] ; [8] and [9].