Real wages in Pakistan: structure and trends, 1970-84 (1).
Irfan, Mohammad ; Ahmed, Meekal Aziz
INTRODUCTION
The structure of wages in any economy has profound implications for
labour utilization, income distribution and the incentive to invest in
human capital. This paper aims at measuring and analysing the level and
trend of nominal and real wages in different sectors of the economy of
Pakistan for the 1970-84 period. The broad patterns of wage change are
then looked at in terms of their implications for employment promotion,
human capital formation and other related policy issues. The analysis is
based on the best available information but the usual caveats
appropriate to empirical work in Pakistan apply.
The pattern of wages at the broad sectoral level in Pakistan has
not been well explored. Thus far, only two researchers have endeavoured
to address this question. Guisinger and Hicks [4] examined the indices
of real wages/incomes in four major sectors: agriculture, large-scale
manufacturing, government employees and the urban informal sector. Their
analysis showed that, except those for government employees, real wages
improved for all categories of workers in the '60s. A major source
of the improvement in real wages in agriculture and the urban informal
sectors was the rapid pace of growth in agriculture while institutional
forces such as labour and wage policies were responsible for the rise in
the real wages of production workers in large-scale manufacturing. There
appeared to have been a narrowing in wage differentials between the
formal and informal sectors, which, according to the authors, furnished presumptive evidence of an improvement in income distribution in
Pakistan.
In a second study, Irfan [7] investigated inter-sectoral wage
trends in the urban areas of the economy, using data for roughly the
same time period. According to his analysis, all workers, including
government servants, experienced a gain, albeit a modest one, in real
wage in the '60s. In the case of government employees, a
distinction was made between the rates at the time of entry into a job
specified by the pay scales and the wages of public employees. The
author concluded that the latter must have improved because the annual
increments, generally around 3-5 percent of the basic pay, were higher
than the rise in the cost-of-living index. The rise in the real wages of
production workers in manufacturing was ascribed to an interaction of
market and non -market forces while the improvement in real wages in the
urban informal sector was attributed to the growth in that sector and in
agriculture, the pace of urbanization and, possibly, a spill-over effect
of 'protected' sector wage settlements. Taken together, these
trends pointed to a modest contraction in the wage structure (which
appeared to have been partially reversed in the early '70s) but any
strong inference about movement in wage differentials and income
distribution was precluded by the low share of wages in total income.
The purpose of this paper is to extend the analysis undertaken in
the earlier studies for the 1970--84 period. In what follows, we first
describe briefly the pattern of wage-income trends in four major
sectors: large-scale manufacturing, government employment, agriculture
and the urban informal sector. The data are presented in Appendix Tables
I and II. This is followed by a discussion of the forces responsible for
generating these trends. The implications of the changing structure of
earnings for the labour absorptive capacity of the economy and other
relevant policy aspects are then addressed in the final section. (2)
FORMAL SECTOR WAGE STRUCTURE
Wages in Large-scale Manufacturing
The trend in the wages of production workers in the large-scale
manufacturing sector during the 1960-70 period has been investigated by
a number of researchers. Khan [8] found that in the 1954-63 period real
wages declined. Guisinger and Irfan [3], using a broader definition of
wages to include non-cash benefits and a longer time period (1954-70),
concluded that real wages improved, with most of the gain having
occurred in the late '60s. For the subsequent period, there has
been no comprehensive study of real wage trends in large-scale
manufacturing covering all Pakistan, although one study by Ahmed and
Naeem, subsequently updated to include the years 1972-84 [1], analysed
real wage trends in six key manufacturing industries in the Punjab
province in the 1972-82 period.
Table 1 presents information on nominal, and real-wage trends of
production and non-production workers in the large-scale manufacturing
sector for the 1970-81 period based on information that is now available
from the published Census of Manufacturing Industries (CMI) reports.
Since CMI reports are not available for all the years, we have chosen to
present the data in terms of two sub-periods: 1970-76 and 1976-81. This
is not only convenient but important analytically since the trends in
the two sub-periods differ markedly. The lack of a comprehensive time
series on an all-Pakistan basis is partly made up for by the time-series
data that are available for six major manufacturing industries in the
Punjab for the years 1972-84 (see Appendix Table I).
As Table 1 shows, nominal wages of production workers rose
persistently throughout the eleven-year period at roughly the same rate
in both sub-periods, i.e. by about 17-18 percent per annum. By contrast,
the earnings of non-production workers increased less sharply in the
first sub-period but accelerated thereafter to a rate close to 20
percent per annum. However, this surge in nominal wages was not
translated into commensurate gains in real wages. Because of the
acceleration of consumer price inflation in the 1970-76 period, much of
the rise in money wages was offset so that real wages of production
workers rose by only 2.9 percent per year while the real earnings of
non-production workers actually stagnated. However, it must be noted
that this rise in real wages is extremely sensitive to the choice of
end-points, viz. 1969-70 and 1975-76. Shifting the base year to 1970-71,
for example, suggests that no increase in real wages occurred; some
other studies suggest a possible decline [7]. In the latter period,
however, these trends were sharply reversed. Since the fall in inflation
was not matched by a slowing in nominal wage increases, real wages rose
for both categories of workers during the 1976-81 period.
We may summarize this section as follows. Real wages of production
and non-production workers more or less stagnated during the 1970-76
period but turned sharply upwards thereafter. As shown by the CMI data,
the differences in the rate of increase of money wages between
production and non-production workers in the two sub-periods suggest a
widening in differentials in favour of the former category of workers;
but this is almost entirely eliminated following the much sharper
acceleration in money wages of non-production workers in the latter
period Although one finds that non-production workers (as a group)
managed to regain the edge of 1969-70 over production workers, this may
not be true for the sub-group of managerial workers. The available CMI
data on the wages of managerial workers for 1970-71 and 1975-76 clearly
suggest a decline in their relative position vis-a-vis production and
other non-production workers.
Real Wages of Government Employees
The earnings of government employees include a variety of benefits
in addition to the basic wage. Since information on some of these
components such as medical and pension benefits is hard to come by,
estimates of total earnings for various categories of government
employees is subject to an unknown margin of error. Government pay
scales are revised periodically, largely in response to the perceived
erosion in real living standards caused by inflation and during the
period of our study, the national pay scales were revised throe times:
in 1972, 1977 and 1983. In addition ad-hoc relief measures were often
announced and these were subsequently incorporated in the revised pay
scales.
The available data (see Appendix Table II) show that, when measured
in terms of 1969-70 constant purchasing power, the basic pay of
government employees underwent a significant deterioration except in the
case of employees in the lowest pay category (Grade 1) where a rise of
some 18 percent occurred between 1972 and 1983. In terms of total
earnings, which include all benefits except medical and pension
benefits, the lower level employees in Grades 1-5 and Grade 17 appear to
have been protected by the 1983 pay scales. The pay scales announced in
1977 provided such protection to the lowest paid categories only. Thus,
during the period from 1972 to 77, all employees except those in Grades
1 and 17 experienced a significant deterioration in real wages. A
similar comparison in the 1977-83 period suggests a marginal rise in the
real value of total earnings in all categories except the top five
grades (Grades 18-22). It is to be noted, however, that the rise in the
real value of earnings in the 1977-83 period was still insufficient to
bring real earnings back to their 1972 levels except for those employed
in Grades 1-6 and 17. Overall, real earnings fell with the sharpest
decline having occurred in Grades 18-22. The higher increase in pay
afforded to low paid employees has resulted in a significant reduction
in differentials in pay with the ratio of Grade 1 to Grade 22 employees
in terms of basic pay having declined from 30.1 to 10.1; the
corresponding decline in terms of total earnings was from 26.1 to 13.1.
INFORMAL SECTORS
Wages in Agriculture
The measurement of wages in Pakistan's agricultural sector
represents a rather neglected field. With the exception of the study by
Guisinger and Hicks [4] there has been no systematic investigation of
the subject. This is largely a reflection of the severe constraints of
data. The present study can only hope to make a modest contribution to
information on the subject based on a patchwork of data for the 1973-84
period. As these data show (see Appendix Table I) real wages in the
agriculture sector declined between 1974 and 1975, turned upwards
thereafter and reached in 1980 the level recorded in the year 1974. A
further increase in real wages was experienced in 1981 followed by
stagnation. Nevertheless, real wages in 1984 were around 10 percent
higher than those reported for 1974.
Wages in the Construction Sector
The only evidence on wage movement in urban informal sector is that
which pertains to wages of a few categories of workers in the
construction sector which are collected and published regularly by
NESPAK and the Federal Bureau of Statistics. The general pattern which
emerges from a consideration of the data (see Appendix Table I) is one
of decline in real wages in the early '70s followed thereafter by a
fairly persistent rise until 1980. Subsequently, real wages stagnated or
declined for most of the categories of workers.
THE SOURCE OF WAGE CHANGES
The evidence presented above is suggestive of a general rise in
real wages of all categories of workers except government employees.
However, the improvement in real wages did not occur at a uniform pace;
in most cases studied, real wages remained static or increased
marginally during the 1970-75 period and then followed an upward course
in the 1976-81 period. For the large-scale manufacturing sector, the
data on six industries in the Punjab show that the positive trend in
real wages was sustained up to 1984. The wages in agriculture and
construction exhibit near constancy for the most recent sub-period
(1981-83), however. The factors underlying these changes are briefly
discussed below.
Emigration
Emigration, a spontaneous response to increased demand for labour
in the Middle East, appears to be a major force bearing upon labour
market conditions in Pakistan. The exodus of labour from Pakistan, which
commenced in the early '70s, rose rapidly in volume and peaked in
1980-81. Thereafter the net outflow of workers has tended to stagnate.
Thus, over a short span of a decade or so, around two and a half million
workers emigrated to the Middle East countries [S]. The sharp reduction
in labour supply that this out-migration engendered was not, however,
the only factor affecting the labour market in Pakistan. An equally
important factor has been the inflow of workers' remittances and
their use. Thus, the inter-temporal confluence of these two flows
influenced labour market conditions both through the supply side--by
reducing the labour supply--and through the demand side--i.e. through
strong aggregate demand pressures arising from the expenditure of the
remittance income.
The link between out-migration and wage levels is, however,
modified by a conjuncture of a number of factors. Institutional
intervention in the wage determination process such as the enactment of
wage policies and trade union pressures will help to shape and modify
the adjustment process of wages in the 'protected' or formal
sectors of the economy. Similarly there is the scope for substitution
across occupations and between labour and capital. Finally, changes in
demand stemming from the patterns of expenditure out of remittances may
accentuate or moderate the supply effects of labour out-migration on
wage levels in the domestic market.
The direct effect of labour exodus on wage levels has been
investigated earlier by Irfan [6]. Making a comparison of the incomes
reported for different occupational categories in the Household Income
and Expenditure Surveys of 1971-72 and 1979, Irfan concluded that the
larger percentage gain in income of production and service workers
relative to professionals reflected the impact of out-migration. In
order to support the contention that labour exodus directly contributed
to the rise in the real wage in informal sectors, Irfan regressed the
average real wage of carpenters and masons taken together against the
stock of labour in the Middle East for the 1971-82 period. The equation
clearly showed that the latter variable explained more than half of the
variance of the former and was highly singificant. (3)
The trend of nominal and real wages in the largo-scale
manufacturing sector did not remain immune to the progressive tightening
of the labour market in the informal sectors. A time-series regression
of real wages of production workers in the six manufacturing industries
in the Punjab shows that real wages were strongly correlated with
productivity changes and with the stock of labour in the Middle East.
(4) The latter variable may be seen to exert a direct positive influence
on the course of wage settlements in manufacturing, or serve as a proxy
for the tightness in the domestic labour market. The only labour market
segment which appears to have remained immune to the influence of
emigration is that of government employees where wages were subject to
the parameters laid down by the National Pay Scales and thereby lagged
behind the rate of inflation in the '70s.
Institutional Intervention
The Government's labour and wage policies and trade union
'pushfulness' constitute the mechanism of institutional
intervention in the wage determination process. The introduction of the
new labour policy in early 1970 extended a number of benefits to labour.
The enactment of these measures during a period when the economy was
beset by stagnation in the commodity-producing sectors and high
inflation, and insignificant out-migration, failed to improve the real
standards of workers in the manufacturing sector in the 1972-76 period.
While the workers in the unprotected informal sectors may have benefited
partly from the spill-over effects of these wage policies, their real
wages in 1974 were in fact lower than that recorded in 1970 [7].
Although the high domestic inflation experienced during the early
'70s contributed to the near stagnation of the living standard of
workers in the large-scale manufacturing sector, the resistence of trade
unions to a fall in their real wage is manifest in the very high level
of strike activity during 1975-76. It is following this period, however,
that the exodus of labour gathered momentum, stimulating wage increases
in the unprotected informal sectors like construction, which, in turn,
exerted a strong upward push to wage trends of production workers in the
large-scale manufacturing sector. This is clearly borne out by both the
CMI and the Punjab data for the 1976-81 and 1976-84 periods
respectively. In addition, although strike activities were banned by the
military regime after 1977 and no wage or labour policy was or has since
been announced, the possibility that trade unions continued to influence
the outcome of wage settlements through collective bargaining pressures
cannot be ruled out.
IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE CHANGES
In the preceding sections we have discussed the overall trends and
structure of wage changes in Pakistan's economy and identified the
principal factors that underlay these developments. In this final
section an attempt is made to draw out some of the implications of these
changes for the labour absorptive capacity of the economy, the
incentives for individuals to invest in human capital and the long-run
sustainability of the existing structure of differentials.
Employment Generation
One of the most significant developments to have occurred in recent
years has been the substantial and widespread decline in the elasticity
of employment with respect to real output growth in all major sectors of
the economy. Of course, not all of the decline in the employment
elasticity can be attributed to wage cost pressures; but the
unprecedented rise in wages over the past decade certainly provided an
important stimulus to the choice of more capital-intensive techniques.
In agriculture, for example, during the 1973-83 period, the number of
tractors imported was over five times the total number existing in 1973,
a trend which sharply reinforced the mechanization already under way in
the form of threshers and harvesters. Clearly, the farmer's
investment decision was influenced by out-migration--estimated at about
8 percent of the rural male labour force--its attendant labour shortage,
and the rise in wages that followed. The degree of labour utilization in
other sectors such as construction also appears to have fallen. The
extensive use of conveyor belts, vibrators, crushers and mixers is
suggestive of the widespread displacement of labour in this sector.
According to one estimate, labour requirements per unit of output in
construction fell by about 20-30 percent during the 1975-82 period [6].
The CMI data on manufacturing industry permit a closer look at what
has happened to employment growth in this sector. During the 1970-76
period, as shown by Table 2, total manufacturing employment rose by 3.3
percent per annum largely on account of the rapid growth in employment
of production workers (4.9 percent per annum). Since manufacturing
output rose by only 4.3 percent per year, the arc elasticity of
employment with respect to output growth yielded by these data is 0.767.
Between 1976 and 1981 total employment in large-scale manufacturing
dropped by some 55000 workers or by 2.2 percent per year with almost
two-thirds of the decline in the textile sector alone. Since real
manufacturing output expanded by 12.3 percent per year, the fall in
employment yielded negative employment elasticity (-0.186) compared with
an elasticity of 0.76 in the previous six years and a long-term
elasticity of about 0.5 [1].
The most plausible explanation for the fall in employment during
the 1976-81 period is that it represented the unwinding of a long lagged
response to the disappointingly low output and demand levels in the
early '70s and the severe cost pressures experienced by
manufacturing industry in these years. But it appears that employers
shed labour rather earlier and faster than in previous periods of slow
growth by adopting the most capital-intensive technique available--a
search touched off by the earlier explosion of wages and the near
stagnation of labour productivity growth which had combined so
powerfully to squeeze manufacturers' profit margins.
Although the large-scale manufacturing sector found itself in a
'virtuous circle' of rising productivity and profits in the
1976-81 period and it was thereby able to recoup some of the ground lost
during the stagflation of the early '70s, the implications of this
recovery have been severely damaging to employment growth. Of course,
one could argue that as output and productivity growth is consolidated
and employment returns to levels more consistent with changed factor
costs and prices, a continuing demand growth will bring a return to
positive employment growth as well. However, the important point to note
is that any prospective slowing in productivity growth will have to be
matched by an easing in real wage growth if renewed cost pressures and a
further shift towards labour-displacing technologies are to be avoided.
The more recent data that are available for the manufacturing sector of
the Punjab show that neither of these presumptions has been fulfilled.
Earnings and productivity growth remained strong up to 1984, and
although the continuing rapid growth in productivity has provided an
important foundation for more restrained unit cost and price increases,
the pressure on manufacturers to rebuild their profit margins through
further adjustment in manning practices and investment in more
capital-intensive plant and equipment has remained great. The recent
fall in the employment elasticity in large-scale manufacturing could, in
our view, prove to be irreversible at least over the medium term.
Erosion of Education Margins
The general compression of the wage structure has substantially
diminished the relative advantage of being educated. This compression of
wages is borne out by both inter- and intra-sectoral comparisons. The
differentials in pay between production workers and managers in the
large-scale manufacturing sector have narrowed and a similar tendency is
evident in a comparison of the wage of a lower level government employee
compared with the earnings of the higher-level staff. In an
inter-sectoral comparison, one finds that the real wage of government
employees has fallen sharply. The decline in the real content of the
entry rates implicit in the government pay scales relative to the rates
of wages earned by an unskilled labourer and carpenter in the
construction sector led to a rise in the ratio of the informal-formal
pay structure. This rise is more pronounced when a comparison is made
between the informal sector worker and a senior government official
(Grades 19 and above). Caven that the majority of the output of the
educational institutions in Pakistan is absorbed in the services sector,
particularly as public employees, the relative deterioration in
government wage scales may adversely bear upon the incentive to invest
in human capital.
Not only the relative but the absolute differentials in pay,
generally regarded as more appropriate to decisions to invest in human
capital [2], have moved in favour of unskilled and semi-skilled workers.
In 1983, for example, an unskilled labourer earned the equivalent to the
earnings of a staff member in Grade 5. This is equivalent to a Lower
Division Clerk, with the minimum entry qualification being Matric. The
relative edge of a highly educated professional underwent a diminution.
A Grade 18 officer in 1972 earned Rs. 646 more than a carpenter; this
differential was reduced to Rs. 210 by 1983. Similarly, a Grade 20
employee in 1972 was worth 7 to 8 carpenters but in 1983 his conversion
ratio approximated to 3 in terms of constant purchasing power.
How far the fall in differentials in pay has affected rates of
return to education merits careful investigation. Since decisions
regarding educational investment are based on large-term considerations,
it could be argued that the recent compression of the wage structure has
had only a marginal effect on educational investment decision. However,
the limited success in raising the enrolment rate and the literacy ratio
along with the failure of the educational system to arrest drop-out
rates could well be explained in terms of the adverse repercussions of
the change in the structure of wages.
CONCLUSIONS
The evidence presented above suggests that with the exception of
government employees, the average wage earner in Pakistan enjoyed a
higher real wage in 1984 than in 1970. Most of the improvement in real
wages occurred in the eight-year period from 1976 to 1984 in contrast to
the near stagnation and, in some cases a decline, in the earlier period,
1970-75. The improvement in real wages has been broad-based: wage
earners both in the informal sectors such as agriculture and
construction, and the formal sectors such as large-scale manufacturing,
experienced a rise in their real wages. Government employees were an
exception to this general trend. The unequal rates at which real wages
have been augmented has led to a narrowing in the differentials in pay
between the formal and informal sectors. This is evident from the
reduction in the differentials between the wages of the less educated
and the highly educated or members of the professional and managerial
class.
A major factor which has determined the level and structure of wage
trends has been a sharp reduction in labour supply occasioned by
emigration and the return flow or workers' remittances. Since these
forces are potentially reversible and unrelated to the productive
structure of the economy, they have posed a number of problems. The
shift from the commodity-producing sector to the service sector of the
economy has boon attended by a significant reduction in the
economy's labour absorptive capacity. While the service orientation
of the economy can be attributed to the expenditure pattern of
remittances income, the widespread fall in labour use primarily stems
from the rise in wage costs pot unit of output. The adoption of more
capital-intensive techniques of production in agriculture, manufacturing
and construction at a time when the economy is faced with the prospect
of an accelerating flow of returnees has potentially serious
consequences for future employment growth.
The high incidence of migration amongst the loss educated and
semi-skilled workers, in conjunction with domestic wage policies
designed to protect the living standards of low-wage employees, has led
to a narrowing of the wage differential between the educated and the
less educated. The presumption that this narrowing in differentials has
tended to be egalitarian is not supported by data on income distribution
since wage incomes account for less than one-third of total incomes. The
reduction in the margins for higher education may, however, have
adversely affected the incentive to invest in human capital. The
relationship between educational planning, the structure of wages and
manpower needs of the economy needs to be reckoned with in development
planning exercises.
Comments on "Real Wages in Pakistan: Structure and Trends
1970-84"
Dr Mohammad Irfan and Dr Meakal Ahmed are well-known economists of
the country. The topic, too, is of great importance not only for the
economic theoreticians but also to the economic planners and policy
makers.
I must appreciate the authors' commendable job in putting
scattered data on wages in one place. It will certainly be of great help
to the researchers and policy makers to utilize these data for their own
analysis and interpretation. Here, I would like to raise some issues
that come to my mind while examining the data.
The comparison of wages in industrial sector (which the authors
refer to as formal sector) with the wages in construction sector (which
the authors refer to as informal sector) reflects a peculiar
relationship as shown below:
Trends in the Wages Trends in the
in Industrial Sector Wages in
in the Punjab Construction Sector
1972-74 Declining Increasing
1975-78 Stagnant Increasing
1978-83 Increasing Declining
Note: It would be more instructive if we could compare the
trends in the wages in the industrial sector in the Punjab
with the trends in construction sector wages in the same
province. Federal Bureau of Statistics (as well as NESPAK)
publishes data by major urban centres. Hence it should be
possible to compare data of wages in industrial sectors in
the Punjab with the construction sector wages in the
same sector.
The negative relationship is curious and needs to be carefully
studied and explained.
The comparative trends become more curious if we take into account
the fact that wages in industrial sector reflect the labour incomes
whereas construction sector data show only the wage rates. This means
that construction sector data do not tell how much the labour is earning
unless we know how many day-labour gets employed at the reported wage
rate. Labour in construction sector is not employed on as regular a
basis as it is employed in the industrial sector. Construction sector
was witnessing construction boom in 1972-78. It means that the employed
days per month for the labour in this sector are not likely to be higher
in the 1978-84 period compared to that in the 1972-78 period. Hence the
declining trend in wage rates in the construction sector during 1978-84
is quite likely reflecting the decline in labour incomes.
How can the increasing trend in the industrial sector be sustained
while wages in other urban sectors are declining. This question needs
further investigations as it has several implications for the industrial
development and growth in the economy.
A more interesting relationship can be seen in the comparison of
wages in industrial sector and the wages in agriculture (both refer to
the province of Punjab). The relationship has been positive. If we say
that industrial wages are determined by agricultural wages, then the
question we need to answer is: what determines the movements in
agricultural wages? And if we say that there are some common factors
that determine the movements in wages in both urban and rural sectors
then we need to identify these common factors. (1)
Another interesting point to raise is the regional differences in
the daily wage rates quoted for the construction labour. These
differences cannot be seen in the paper under review. But the data on
regional differences in wage rates are available from the same sources
from where the authors have collected data on construction wages. It is
curious to see that the growth of wages in the underdeveloped regions is
much higher than the growth of wages in the developed regions. Such
pattern of growth can have several implications for regional
developments and hence needs to be carefully analysed in more detail.
Another issue revealed by the data given in the paper also needs
attention. Political regime in early 1970s came with the slogan of
redistribution of income and made massive intervention in the labour
market. (All this intervention, however, was confined to the formal
sector only.) The real wages of production workers failed to respond to
this in substantial terms. On the other hand, the real wages in 1976-81
(when government did not try to intervene in the labour market--not even
through minimum wage legislations) increased at a rate much higher than
what was achieved during 1970-76 through government intervention.
Does this mean, government intervention in labour market to improve
labour is counter-productive in Pakistan? (2) Does this mean we should
leave labour market free if we want to improve labour welfare? The
answer cannot be given by arithmetics of statistics. We need a rigorous
analysis of the structure and trends in the labour market in Pakistan.
Dr M. Fahim Khan
Professor/Director
International Institute of Islamic Economics, International Islamic
University, Islamabad
(1) I am in favour of the latter and I have given elsewhere my own
theory along with empirical analysis.
(2) It will be useless to argue that higher wages in the formal
sector in late 1970s came with a decline in employment in the
large-scale manufacturing sector unless we can convincingly argue that
the labour displaced from manufacturing sector failed to get absorbed
anywhere else at the same or better terms. We know that unemployment
rate in the economy in 1981 was not worse than that in 1971 and that the
growth of real wages in agriculture (where all the surplus labour gets
absorbed) increased by 60 percent during the 1976-81 period compared to
the 44-percent increase in the manufacturing sector.
Appendix Table I
Nominal and Real Wages of Workers in Different
Sectors of Pakistan's Economy 1970-84
Production Worker in Large Scale
Manufacturing
Six Major Ind.
Year All Pakistan Punjab
Money Real Money Real
Wages Wages Wages Wages
Rs/Month
1969-70 167 167 N. A. N.A.
1970-71 183 173 N.A. N.A.
1971-72 N.A. N.A. 163 147
1972-73 N.A. N.A. 175 144
1973-74 N.A. N.A. 219 138
1974-75 N.A. N.A. 282 145
1975-76 435 194 324 145
1976-77 N.A. N.A. 351 144
1977-78 625 240 382 147
1978-79 712 253 420 149
1979-80 N.A. N.A. 518 167
1980-81 938 266 594 169
1981-82 N.A. N.A. 677 171
1982-83 N.A. N.A. 760 184
1983-84 N.A. N.A. 881 196
Construction Worker Wages.
Rs/Day
Year Carpenter Masons
Money Real Money Real
Wages Wages Wages Wages
1969-70 12.2 12.0 13.0 13.0
1970-71 13.0 12.3 13.5 12.7
1971-72 13.9 12.5 14.5 13.4
1972-73 14.2 11.7 15.0 12.3
1973-74 18.6 11.8 19.0 12.0
1974-75 25.0 12.5 25.1 12.6
1975-76 30.0 13.4 30.0 13.4
1976-77 37.0 15.2 38.3 15.7
1977-78 45.0 17.3 46.5 17.8
1978-79 49.5 17.5 49.8 17.6
1979-80 57.7 18.5 57.7 18.5
1980-81 61.1 17.2 63.7 18.0
1981-82 69.0 17.5 69.1 17.5
1982-83 69.0 16.8 72.0 17.6
1983-84 N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A.
Construction
Worker Wages.
Rs/Day
Agriculture Unskilled
Year Unskilled Labour Labour Rs/Day
Money Real Money Real
Wages Wages Wages Wages
1969-70 5.1 5.1 N. A. N. A.
1970-71 5.5 5.1 N. A. N. A.
1971-72 5.4 4.9 N.A. N.A.
1972-73 5.7 4.7 5.8 4.7
1973-74 8.6 5.4 7.9 5.0
1974-75 11.8 5.9 7.5 3.8
1975-76 14.5 6.5 7.7 3.5
1976-77 17.9 7.3 9.1 3.7
1977-78 21.3 8.2 10.0 3.8
1978-79 22.8 8.1 11.7 4.2
1979-80 24.3 7.8 14.7 4.7
1980-81 26.5 7.5 19.5 5.5
1981-82 29.0 7.3 20.0 5.0
1982-83 30.7 7.3 20.5 5.0
1983-84 N.A. N.A. 23.2 5.2
Notes: 1. Real wages are arrived at by using the consumer
price index 1969-70 = 100.
2. Production worker wages for all Pakistan are based on
Census of Manufacturing Industries. While Punjab data
pertain to six major industries of Punjab.
3. Construction sector wages are taken from Price Index
NESPAK various issues.
4. Agriculture worker wages are taken from I.L.O. year
book for 1973-1978. For 1979-80 to 1981-82 wages are the
average of I.L.O. year book and the ones reported in "Cost
of Production of Major Crops as reported by leading farmers
in Punjab" Government of Pakistan, Planning Division.
For 1982-84 wages are taken from a survey conducted
by PIPO. (unpublished).
Appendix Table II
Basic Pay and Total Earnings as Specified by National
Pay Scales at the Time of Entry
Rs/Month
Current Prices
1972 1977
Grades
Basic Total Basic Total
Pay Earnings Pay Earnings
1 110 143 250 385
5 150 198 290 436
11 275 341 430 632
16 400 470 625 936
17 500 590 900 1320
18 1000 1150 1350 2040
19 1800 2070 2250 3275
20 2300 2745 2600 4575
21 2750 3363 3000 6335
22 3000 3750 3250 6885
In Constant Prices
Current Prices of 1969-70
1983 1972
Grades Basic Total Basic Total
Pay Earnings Pay Earnings
1 440 723 99 129
5 520 824 135 178
11 700 1085 248 307
16 1050 1593 360 423
17 1600 2470 450 532
18 2100 3195 901 1036
19 3200 4790 1622 1865
20 3800 6985 2072 2473
21 4200 9165 2478 3030
22 4500 10000 2703 3379
In Constant Prices of 1969-70
1977 1983
Grades Basic Total Basic Total
Pay Earnings Pay Earnings
1 103 159 100 165
5 120 180 118 188
11 178 261 159 247
16 258 387 239 363
17 372 546 365 563
18 558 843 478 728
19 930 1353 729 1091
20 1075 1891 * 866 * 1591 *
21 1240 2618 ** 959 ** 2088 **
22 1343 2845 ** 1025 ** 2278 **
* Includes entertainment, orderly. and other allowance.
** Staff car valued at Rs. 1500 per month.
REFERENCES
[1.] Ahmed, M. A., and Naeem, A. M. "Real Wages of Production
Workers in the Large-Scale Manufacturing Sector of the Punjab,
1972-84". Forthcoming in the Pakistan Manpower Review.
[2.] Becker S. Gary. Human Capital (2nd ed.), New York: National
Bureau of Economic Research. 1975.
[3.] Guisinger, S. E., and Mohammad Irfan. "Real Wages of
Industrial Workers in Pakistan 1954-70". Pakistan Development
Review. Vol. XIII, No. 4. Winter 1974.
[4.] Guisinger, Stephen, and Norman L. Hicks "Long Term Trends
in Income Distribution in Pakistan". World Development. Vol. 6,
Nos. 11-12. November-December 1978.
[5.] Irfan, Mohammad, Lionel Demery and G. M. Arif. "Migration
Patterns in Pakistan: Preliminary Results from the PLM Survey
1979". Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
1983. (PLM Project Report No. 6)
[6.] Irfan, Mohammad. "Consequences of Out-Migration on
Domestic Labour Market". 1984. (Mimeographed)
[7.] Irfan, Mohammad. "Wage Structure in Pakistan". Ph.D.
Thesis, Cornell University. 1979.
[8.] Khan, A. R. "What has been Happening to Real Wage in
Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. VII, No. 3. Autumn
1967.
[9.] NESPAK Price Index. Vol. 1, No. 1. July 1974.
[10.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Monthly Statistical
Bulletin. Vol. 32, No. 11. November 1984.
[11.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Census of
Manufacturing Industries. Karachi. (Various issues)
(1) This is a substantially edited version of an earlier paper
presented at the Second Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society
of Development Economists in May 1985. Almost all statistical tables
have been removed. These are available from the authors on request.
(2) It is well to note that the average wage at the sectoral level
is a high aggregative concept and masks large variations around it.
Furthermore, comparisons of inter-sectoral wage movements assume that
the skill mix of employment in each sector has undergone a broadly
uniform change during the period studied.
(3) The regression equation was:
WCON = 14.25 + 0.005 STK
[[bar.R].sup.2] =
.056 (3.890)
where WCON is the average of the daily real wage of carpenters and
masons in Karachi, and STK is the stock of labour in the Middle East in
thousands. The figure in parenthesis is the t-ratio.
(4) The equation for the 1972-82 period is:
Log RW = -2.669 + 0.754 Log PRTY + 0.463 Log STK
[[bar.R].sup.2] =
.975 (2.736) (19.891)
where RW = real wage of production workers; PRTY = productivity;
STK = stock of workers in the Middle East, and the figures in
parenthesis are t-values.
MOHAMMAD IRFAN and MEEKAL AZIZ AHMED *
* The authors are, respectively, Chief of Research at the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad, and Chief, Planning and
Development Division, Government of Pakistan, Islamabad. The authors are
thankful to Abdul Majeed Naeem, Research Officer, Planning Division, for
his assistance in compilation and analysis of data.
Table 1
Nominal- and Real-wage Trends in Large-scale Manufacturing
1970-81
(Percent per annum)
1970-76 1976-81
I. Nominal Wages
All Workers 15.8 17.0
Production Workers 17.3 16.6
Non-production Workers 14.5 19.6
II. Real Wages
All Workers 1.4 7.6
Production Workers 2.6 6.5
Non-production Workers 0.4 9.2
III. Consumer Prices 14.4 9.5
Source: [11], various issues.
Table 2
Changes in Output, Employment Costs, Prices and Productivity,
Large-scale Manufacturing: 1970-81
(Percent per annum)
1970-76 1976-81
I. Output 4.3 12.3
II. Employment
Total 3.3 -2.2
Production Workers 4.9 -1.1
III. Cost, Prices and Labour's Share
Unit wage cost 14.4 22.2
Ratio of value added to output -4.5 -1.0
Producers' prices 12.4 9.0
Labour's share in value added 4.5 -5.5
IV. Productivity and Factor Intensity
Labour productivity 1.0 15.0
Capital productivity 3.6 0.0
Capital-labour ratio -10.0 11.3
Source. [11], various issues; [10], various issues.