Who bears the burden of federal taxes in Pakistan?
Malik, Muhammad Hussain ; Najam-us-Saqib
INTRODUCTION
The main objective of the tax system of a country is to generate
enough revenue for the government, and it is always desired that taxes
should be such that there is less burden on the poor and more on the
rich. Such an attribute of the tax system becomes even more desirable
for a country like Pakistan where the present distribution of resources
is highly unequal and a large proportion of the population is living at
the subsistence level. As in many other developing countries, in
Pakistan also indirect taxes dominate in terms of their contribution to
total tax revenue. It is argued that indirect taxes are generally
regressive since they are levied on consumption, and people in the
lower-income classes devote relatively greater proportion of their
incomes to consumption. In this study, we have tried to estimate the
incidence of the federal taxes on households in different income groups.
We accomplished this by calculating effective tax rates (percentage of
income contributed to taxes) for them.
A large number of studies have been done for different countries to
estimate tax incidence by income classes. Some of them have been carried
out by Gillespie [5], Karageorgas [8], Salkin [23], Reynolds and
Smolensky [21], and Alauddin and Raza [1]. A critical review of the
literature for developing countries can be found in Bird and De Wulf
[2], and De Wulf [4]. (1) Here we examine very briefly the work by
Alauddin and Raza [1], since it deals with Pakistan. (2) They have
estimated the incidence of some federal taxes for 1966-67 and for the
years from 1968-69 to 1971-72. While it is a serious attempt, the study
suffers from two main weaknesses. One, it excludes import duties, an
important source of federal government tax revenue. Two, nominal rates
of excise duties and sales taxes on items of final consumption have been
used to compute the tax paid by different households. In this way, taxes
on the raw material and intermediate inputs are completely ignored,
although these taxes constitute a substantial part of the total tax
revenue. Another shortcoming of using nominal tax rates is that the
problem of tax evasion, which is quite serious in Pakistan, is
overlooked. These problems have been dealt with in the present study.
DATA AND METHODOLOGY
The latest Household Income and Expenditure Survey was conducted
for the calendar year 1979 and its findings were published in 1983.
Therefore, we have estimated the burden of federal taxes for the fiscal
year 1978-79. There are two types of taxes: indirect and direct. Their
shares in total federal tax revenue in 1978-79 were 85.41 percent and
14.59 percent respectively. Indirect taxes include customs duties,
excise duties, sales taxes, and surcharges. Customs duties were at the
top in terms of their contribution to total federal tax revenue and
their share was 43.13 percent. The share of excise duties was 29.46
percent and they were the second most important source of the federal
government's revenue. The contributions of sales taxes and
surcharges were 8.24 percent and 4.58 percent respectively. The most
important direct taxes were income tax and corporate income tax. Their
contributions to total federal tax revenue in 1978-79 were 4.98 percent
and 9.25 percent respectively. There were some minor direct taxes, too,
but their share was 0.36 percent only.
In this study all the indirect taxes except export duties, a
component of customs duties, are covered. The reason for not including
export duties is our lack of knowledge about who bears the burden of
such duties. Fortunately, their contribution to total tax payments has
always been very small, and in 1978-79 it was only 1.74 percent. The
sources consulted for data on indirect taxes are listed in the Appendix.
The distribution of direct taxes by income classes is given in [13] and
the same has been used in this study. (3) Owing to some data problems,
corporate income tax has not been included. On the whole, the taxes
covered here constitute approximately 89 percent of the total tax
revenue of the federal government in 1978-79.
Data on consumption patterns of households in different income
classes were obtained from the Household Income and Expenditure Survey
1979 [13]. As the tax data are for the fiscal year 1978-79, we are
assuming that the consumption patterns during the calendar year 1979
were the same as during the fiscal year 1978-79. This assumption is
quite harmless since the consumption patterns do not change rapidly.
To allocate different taxes among households, we have adopted
standard assumptions that indirect taxes are shifted forward to the
consumers and direct taxes stay with the legal taxpayers. The assumption
regarding direct taxes is generally accepted while there is no such
agreement of views as far as indirect taxes are concerned.
Theoretically, an indirect tax on a commodity can only be shifted fully
when either demand curve for the commodity is completely inelastic or
supply curve is completely elastic. One can justify tax shifting by
arguing in favour of these assumptions. However, Prest [18] has pointed
out that these assumptions, in the context of the calculation of tax
incidence, can lead to contradictory conclusions. (4) To determine
whether indirect taxes are shifted or not and, if they are shifted, in
what proportion, the approach generally followed is based on regression
analysis.
A number of studies have been done regarding the shifting of
indirect taxes in Pakistan. Radhu [20] in his study regresses changes in
prices on changes in the rates of sales and excise taxes. From
regression results, he concludes that these taxes are not shifted to the
consumers. Irfan [6] does not agree with Radhu's finding saying,
"Most of the observations [in Radhu's regression analysis]
pertained to small changes in sales tax and no attempt was made to
weight commodities by their contribution to excise and sales tax
collections. Thus, while his conclusion may have held for most
commodities it was not necessarily true for most tax collections"
[6, p. 67]. Irfan in his study selects only two commodities, cigarettes
and petroleum products, which contributed most to the total excise duty
receipts. His finding is that a "very high proportion" of
excise duties is passed on to the consumers.
Bilquees Naqvi [10] extends Irfan's work by incorporating more
commodities and by considering sales tax changes in addition to changes
in excise duties. She concludes that "excise duties and sales tax
are transferred partly to the consumers". The latest and most
comprehensive study on this issue is by Jeetun [7] in which he analyses
all the four major indirect taxes, viz. import duties, excise duties,
sales taxes, and surcharges. His results show that excise duties and
sales taxes (including surcharges) are shifted forward to the consumers.
The range of the tax shift for different commodities is from 72 to 93
percent. For import duties, he finds not only a full shifting but
"some degree of pyramiding" also. From this entire evidence,
we conclude that there can be disagreement over the degree of the shift
but indirect taxes are definitely shifted to the consumers. In this
study we go along with the standard assumption that indirect taxes are
fully passed on to the consumers.
The above-mentioned problems of tax evasion and multiple taxation
of a commodity have been tackled by using actual tax collections for
each commodity separately. Taxes collected for commodities directly
consumed are distributed among households in different income brackets according to their shares in the total consumption of those commodities.
There are certain products which either are not directly consumed at all
or only a part of them goes to final consumption and the remaining part
is used as an input for other commodities. To allocate taxes on such
commodities to final consumption, we have used the "Revised PIDE input-output Table of Pakistan's Economy: 1975-76" [22]. (5)
The findings of the Household Income and Expenditure Survey 1979
[13] show that the consumption patterns of households in the rural and
urban areas are not the same. Moreover, the sources and their
contribution to the incomes of the households in the two areas also
differ. Therefore, we have analysed tax incidence for the rural and
urban areas separately. Data on commodity-wise tax collections are for
the country as a whole. The amount of a tax on a particular commodity is
distributed to the rural and urban areas according to their shares in
the total consumption of that commodity. Once all the taxes are
allocated to households in different income groups, they are divided by
the personal incomes of the households to obtain effective tax rates.
(6)
RESULTS
In view of the limitations of data and the theoretical issues
raised in this and many other studies, the results are subject to many
qualifications and need to be interpreted with great care. Moreover,
greater confidence can be reposed in the tax incidence patterns across
income groups than in exact numerical values of the effective tax rates.
The results for rural, urban, and all areas (rural and urban areas
combined) are presented separately. For rural areas the results are
given in Table 1. The total tax system appears, with some exceptions, to
be regressive over the entire measured income range. To be more
specific, the tax system is regressive up to an income level of Rs. 500.
The effective tax rate fluctuates between income levels of Rs. 500 and
Rs. 1000, and then declines up to the income level of Rs. 3500, making
the tax system regressive again. The effective tax rate increase and
changes the direction again for the highest income bracket (Rs 3501 and
above). The highest income class is open-ended and cover's a very
large range of incomes. Also, the tax incidence pattern within this
income class is also not known. All this reduces the meaningfulness of
the effective tax rate for this income bracket. We may note that only
0.9 percent of the rural households belong to this income group.
The regressivity of the entire tax system is mainly due to the
regressive nature of the indirect taxes. Import duties, which rank at
the top in terms of their contribution to the federal tax revenue, have
exactly the same incidence pattern as all taxes combined. This result
contradicts the general impression that necessities are either totally
exempt from import duties or subject to much lower rates as compared to
luxuries. In fact, import duties on items of common use, raw material,
intermediate products, and machinery make this tax regressive. The
incidence pattern exhibited by sales taxes is similar to that of import
duties. One possible explanation for this could be that a substantial
proportion of sales taxes collected comes from imported goods. Another
major source of the federal government revenue is excise duties. We may
describe them as proportional up to an income level of Rs. 1000, even
though there are small fluctuations in the effective tax rate. The
effective tax rate consistently declines between income levels of Rs.
1000 and Rs. 3500, making the excise duties regressive over this income
range. The effective tax rate increases for the top income class of Rs.
3501 and above. Surcharges contribute a small proportion to the total
tax receipts. Their share in 1978-79 was 4.58 percent. Surcharges are
levied on a few products--mostly intermediate goods like fertilizer and
petroleum products. Consequently, their impact spreads over the entire
economy. Surcharges, on the whole, are slightly regressive.
Direct taxes do not display any systematic incidence pattern. Also
the effective tax rates are very low--ranging from .006 percent to .053
percent. This is not very unexpected. The main component of the direct
taxes is income tax while the major source of income in the rural areas
is agriculture which is exempt from income tax. We may remind the reader
that effective rates of the direct taxes are based on the data reported
in the Household Income and Expenditure Survey 1979 [13].
The results for the urban areas are presented in Table 2. They show
that the overall tax system is regressive up to an income level of Rs.
3000, with one exception where the effective tax rate increases. The tax
system becomes progressive beyond the income level of Rs. 3000. Direct
taxes play a major role in making the tax structure progressive in the
upper income range.
Indirect taxes, as a whole, up to an income level of Rs. 3500 have
an incidence pattern similar to that of all taxes combined. It is only
in the top income bracket of 'Rs. 3501 and above', where the
two differ. The effective tax rate in the case of indirect taxes
declines while it increases for all taxes combined. It may be pointed
out that the top open-ended income class contains 4.4 percent of the
urban households. This number is much higher than that of the rural
areas, and the caveat noted there applies with greater force in the
present case. Coming to the components of the indirect taxes, import
duties have exactly the same incidence pattern as that of the total
indirect taxes. Excise duties are slightly regressive in the few bottom-
and middle-income brackets; they are virtually proportional in all other
brackets. Sales taxes, on the whole, can be classified as proportional.
Surcharges are virtually proportional up to an income level of Rs. 1000
and slightly regressive beyond that.
Direct taxes do show some progressivity if we ignore the bottom
three income classes for which the effective tax rate fluctuates. A
comparison of the results of the rural and urban areas shows that the
urban households in different income classes face higher effective tax
rates as compared to their counterparts in the rural areas.
The incidence patterns of various taxes for the country as a whole
are reported in Table 3. The overall tax system as well as all the
indirect taxes exhibits incidence patterns very similar to those of the
rural areas. On the other hand, the effective direct taxes follow the
pattern very close to that assumed by them in the urban areas.
CONCLUSIONS
In this study we have estimated incidence of the federal taxes for
households in different income brackets. Most of the major direct and
indirect taxes are covered, and taxes on the raw material and
intermediate inputs have been allocated to final consumption through the
input-output table. The major source of revenue of the government is
indirect taxes which are generally regressive. The overall tax structure
is also more or less regressive.
Households in the urban areas pay relatively more taxes. However,
the incidence patterns of all the taxes combined are not very much
different in the two areas. It is only in the top income brackets that
we find relatively more consistent tax progressivity in the urban areas.
The direct taxes show some progressivity for the country as a
whole, if we exclude a few bottom income brackets. But the effective tax
rates are quite low. Consequently, their progressivity is not much
reflected in the incidence pattern of the overall tax structure. The
effective rates of the direct taxes in the rural areas do not show any
systematic pattern and their values are extremely low. On the other
hand, those in the urban areas, though not quite high, exhibit
progressivity, barring a few bottom income classes.
Import duties on the whole appear to be regressive. This is
contrary to the general belief that import duties are mostly levied on
luxuries. In fact, import duties on the raw materials, intermediate
products, machinery and also on necessities make them regressive.
The overall tax system is regressive as it heavily depends on
indirect taxes, and these taxes are on items of common use, raw
materials, intermediate inputs, and machinery. To make this tax system
progressive more reliance should be placed on direct taxes. Moreover,
taxes on the raw materials, intermediate inputs, and machinery should be
avoided. Only those commodities of final use should be taxed which are
consumed mainly by households in the upper income brackets.
Comments on "Who Bears the Burden of Federal Taxes in
Pakistan?"
The paper which seems to be an attempt to extend and improve upon
the earlier work by Alauddin & Raza [1] does represent an
improvement in two respects:
(i) It includes all indirect taxes while import duties which
account for over 40 percent of total federal tax receipts were ignored
in the earlier study.
(ii) It estimates tax burden by using effective tax rates rather
than nominal tax rates. In other words, it takes into account multiple
taxation of commodities, i.e. the taxes levied at different stages of
production rather than on final consumption. By doing so, it naturally
avoids the problem of tax evasion.
However, despite these improvements, the study remains very
preliminary partly because of its limited scope of just computing tax
incidence, and partly because of the simplified assumptions used in
these computations. Four points need to be highlighted in this regard.
1. The analysis relates to 1978-79 as the latest data on
consumption across income groups are available for 1979. But assuming
that consumption habits persist and consumption patterns do not change
rapidly (as the authors themselves have pointed out), the analysis could
have been done for a more recent year, possibly for 1983-84. In a study
like this, where the objective is to analyse a given structure rather
than carrying out a simulation exercise of a policy change in this
structure, time factor is vital in determining its usefulness. Narrating
conclusions regarding the regressiveness or progressiveness of tax
structure that prevailed five years ago serves hardly any purpose for
the policy-maker who at present is interested in making recommendations
for future. No doubt, using the 1979 consumption pattern in estimating
tax burden for 1983-84 would have introduced certain biases in the
results, yet the time relevance would have enhanced the usefulness of
the study.
2. Though there is no disagreement on the forward shifting of
indirect taxes, disagreement does exist on the issue of complete or
partial shifting. Empirical studies in this area (some of which have
been cited by the authors also) reveal that the extent of shift for
different commodities ranges between 70 percent and 90 percent. In the
presence of such an evidence, a standard assumption of a l00-percent
shifting, as used in the present study, appears highly unrealistic.
Moreover, it makes the study suffer from the same defect as was found in
the earlier work. A more reasonable assumption would have been to take
the average, i.e., 80 percent, or alternatively to use different rates
of shifting for different kinds of commodities. The former may yield
different conclusions about the degree of regressivity though it may not
change the incidence pattern across income groups while the alternative
assumption may even change the incidence pattern.
3. Based on the computed effective rates for import duties, the
paper concludes that the "result contradicts the general impression
that necessities are either totally exempt from import duty or subject
to much lower rates as compared to luxuries". To qualify such a
conclusion, it would be worth while to decompose the effective rates
into those for final consumer goods and capital/intermediate goods. Only
then can one compare the incidence across necessities and luxuries.
4. If one looks at the results, one finds that in the case of some
taxes, the computed effective tax rates for different income classes
lack any systematic trend, such as direct taxes in rural sector or sales
tax in urban sector. In such cases, it is hard to conclude whether the
tax structure is definitely regressive or progressive. Some kind of test
is needed for this purpose. Otherwise, conclusions derived on the basis
of merely looking at the computed rates may be misleading since it is
quite likely that part of the observed differences in the rates may have
been contributed by the sampling error.
Dr M. Shaukat Ali
Deputy Economic Adviser, Ministry of Finance, Islamabad
REFERENCE
[1.] Alauddin, Talat and Bilquees Raza. "Tax Progressivity in
Pakistan". Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
February 1981. (Research Report Series No. 133)
Appendix
DATA SOURCES
A number of sources have been consulted in compiling data
concerning different types of taxes collected for various commodities.
Data on import duties are drawn from the Monthly Statistical Bulletin,
October 1982 [14], while figures for the federal excise duties and
surcharges are taken from the Explanatory Memorandum on the Budget
1979-80 [15]. A breakdown of sales taxes by commodities is not available
for the year 1978-79. We therefore have tried to estimate it by using
the following available information. The Explanatory Memorandum on the
Budget 19 79-80 [15] reports total amounts of sales tax collected for
imported commodities (Rs. 1476 million) and domestically produced
commodities (Rs. 370 million). The share of the tax on domestic goods is
relatively small (20%). Moreover, most of this tax is paid by
large-scale manufacturing industries as goods produced by the domestic
"cottage industry" are exempt from sales tax [17, p. 24]. The
Census of Manufacturing Industries (CMI) reports sales tax paid by
different industries on their products, but unfortunately it was not
published for the year 1978-79. Therefore, we have allocated the total
amount of the tax on domestically produced goods for 1978-79 to
different commodities according to the distribution of the tax given in
the CMI for 1977-78 [12], by assuming that the distribution in the two
years was the same.
The procedure used to estimate sales tax on imported commodities is
slightly complicated. As stated earlier, amounts of import duty by
commodities are given in the Monthly Statistical Bulletin [ 14]. Rates
of import duty and sales tax on imported commodities are also available
from the Pakistan Customs Tariff and Import Trade Guide [11] and [9]. We
may point out that sales tax is ad valorem and levied on the duty-paid
value of a commodity. The following formula has been used to calculate
sales tax paid on an imported commodity.
Sales Tax Amount = Sales Tax Rate X {Import Duty Amount/Import Duty
Rate + Import Duty Amount}
Distribution of the direct taxes by income class for the rural and
urban areas is taken from the Household Income and Expenditure Survey
1979 [13]. The distribution of the direct taxes for all areas as
reported in the Survey is not correct as it is arrived at without
assigning appropriate population weights to the rural and urban
distributions. The results reported for the direct taxes in this study
have been corrected for this problem.
REFERENCES
[1.] Alauddin, Talat, and Bilquees Raza. "Tax Progressivity in
Pakistan". Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
February 1981. (Research Report Series, No. 133)
[2.] Bird, Richard M., and Luc Henry De Wulf. "Taxation and
Income Distribution in Latin America: A Critical Review of Empirical
Studies". IMF Staff Papers. Vol. 20, No. 3. November 1973. pp.
639-682.
[3.] Conard, Alfred H. "On the Calculation of Tax
Burdens". Economica (New Series). Vol. 22, No. 88. November 1955.
pp. 342-348.
[4.] De Wulf, Luc. "Fiscal Incidence Studies in Developing
Countries: Survey and Critique". IMF Staff Papers. Vol. 22, No. 1.
March 1975. pp. 61-131.
[5.] Gillespie, W. Irwin. The Redistribution of Income in Canada.
Ottawa: Gage Publishing (in association with the Institute of Canadian
Studies, Carleton University). 1980.
[6.] Irfan, Mohammad. "Shifting and Incidence of Indirect
Taxes on Tobacco and Petroleum Products in Pakistan". Pakistan
Development Review. Vol. 13, No. 1. Spring 1974. pp. 66-87.
[7.] Jeetun, Azad. "Tax Shifting in Pakistan: A Case Study of
Excise Duties, Sales Tax and Import Duties". Karachi: Applied
Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi. August 1978.
Discussion Paper No. 28
[8.] Karageorgas, D. "The Distribution of Tax Burden by Income
Groups in Greece". Economic Journal. Vol. 83, No. 330. June 1973.
pp. 436-448.
[9.] Kemal, A.R., Nadeem A. Burney and Shahid Hamid. "Quota Restrictions, Tariffs and the Scarcity Premium of Licences".
Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics. June 1981.
Statistical Paper Series No. 2.
[10.] Naqvi, Bilquees. "Forward Shifting of Indirect Taxes: A
Further Study". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. 14, No. 2. Summer
1975. pp. 174-184.
[11.] Pakistan. Central Board of Revenue. Pakistan Customs Tariff
and Import Trade Guide. Karachi. November 1979.
[12.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Census of
Manufacturing Industries 1977-78. Karachi. December 1983.
[13.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Household Income and
Expenditure Survey 1979. Karachi. March 1983.
[14.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Monthly Statistical
Bulletin. Karachi. October 1982.
[15.] Pakistan. Finance Division. Explanatory Memorandum on the
Budget 1979-80. Islamabad. June 1979.
[16.] Pakistan. Finance Division. Economic Adviser's Wing.
Pakistan Economic Survey 1983-84. Islamabad. June 1984.
[17.] Pakistan. Finance Division. Taxation Structure of Pakistan
1979-80. Islamabad. February 1980.
[18.] Prest, A. R. "Statistical Calculations of Tax
Burdens". Economica (New Series). Vol. 22, No. 87. August 1955. pp.
234-245.
[19.] Prest, A. R. "On the Calculation of Tax Burdens: A
Rejoinder". Economica (New Series). Vol. 23. August 1956. pp.
270-272.
[20.] Radhu, Ghulam Mohammad. "The Relation of Indirect Tax
Changes to Price Changes in Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review.
Vol. 5, No. 1. Spring 1965. pp. 54-63.
[21.] Reynolds, Morgan, and Eugene Smolensky. "The Post Fisc
Distribution: 1961 and 1970 Compared". National Tax Journal Vol.
27, No. 4. December 1974. pp. 515-530.
[22.] Saleem, Mohammad, et al. "'Revised P.I.D.E.
Input-Output Table of Pakistan's Economy: 1975-76". Islamabad:
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics. November 1983. (Research
Report Series, No. 139)
[23.] Salkin, Jay S. "On the Direct Measurement of Tax
Progressivity in Thailand". National Tax Journal. Vol. 27, No. 2.
June 1974. pp. 301-317.
(1) The survey article by Bird and De Wulf [2] covers only Latin
American countries, while De Wulf [4] adds some other developing
countries too.
(2) There is a reference to Jawaid Azfar's work on tax
incidence in Pakistan in De Wulf [4] and in some other studies too. But
unfortunately his work (unpublished Ph.D. thesis) was not available to
us.
(3) Direct taxes are not defined in the Survey but obviously their
main component is income tax.
(4) See Prest [18; 19] and Conard [3] for an exchange of views on
this topic.
(5) The input-output table is for the year 1975-76 while the taxes
to be allocated axe for the year 1978-79. Therefore, we assume that the
input-output coefficients remain unchanged between 1975-76 and 1978-79.
We expect that this assumption will not do much harm to our results as
the gap between the two periods is very short.
(6) Since personal incomes of the households in different income
brackets as reported in the Survey [13] are sample values, they have
been blown up to national level to calculate effective tax rates.
MUHAMMAD HUSSAIN MALIK and NAJAM-US-SAQIB *
* The authors are, respectively, Senior Research Economist and
Research Economist at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
(PIDE), Islamabad.
Table 1
Federal Taxes paid in 1978-79 by Rural Households in Different
Income Classes as Percentage of their Personal Incomes
Indirect Taxes
Monthly Income Import Excise Sales Sur-
Class (Rupees) Duties Duties Taxes charges
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Up to 300 6.718 4.270 1.315 1.022
301-400 6.387 4.310 1.260 0.964
401-500 5.992 3.990 1.167 0.886
501-600 6.428 4.170 1.236 0.868
601-800 5.772 3.979 1.123 0.824
801-1000 6.304 4.152 1.233 0.853
1001-1500 5.377 3.840 1.068 0.731
1501-2000 5.013 3.509 1.014 0.665
2001-2500 4.694 3.310 0.953 0.613
2501-3000 4.503 3.334 0.939 0.561
3001-3500 2.974 2.079 0.631 0.349
3501 and above 4.882 2.916 1.080 0.560
Total 5.618 3.811 1.133 0.768
Indirect
Taxes
Monthly Income Total Direct All Taxes
Class (Rupees) (Cols. 2+3+ Taxes (Cols. 6+7)
4+5)
(1) (6) (7) (8)
Up to 300 13.325 0.004 13.329
301-400 12.921 0.006 12.927
401-500 12.035 0.013 12.048
501-600 12.702 0.005 12.707
601-800 11.698 0.013 11.711
801-1000 12.542 0.012 12.554
1001-1500 11.016 0.012 11.028
1501-2000 10.201 0.053 10.254
2001-2500 9.570 0.033 9.603
2501-3000 9.337 0.024 9.361
3001-3500 6.033 0.006 6.039
3501 and above 9.438 0.051 9.489
Total 11.330 0.019 11.349
Table 2
Federal Taxes Paid in 1978-79 by Urban Households in
Different Income Classes as Percentage of their
Personal Incomes
Indirect Taxes
Monthly Income Import Excise Sales Sur-
Class (Rupees) Duties Duties Taxes charges
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Up to 300 7.474 6.372 1.717 1.066
301-400 6.045 5.902 1.180 0.967
401-500 5.880 5.834 1.174 0.965
501-600 7.192 5.991 1.478 0.972
601-800 6.236 6.087 1.298 0.953
801-1000 6.132 5.829 1.307 0.953
1001-1500 6.819 5.230 1.221 0.832
1501-2000 5.796 4.975 1.243 0.768
2001-2500 5.550 5.166 1.221 0.718
2501-3000 5.424 4.653 1.228 0.663
3001-3500 6.249 4.629 1.480 0.658
3501 and above 5.676 4.779 1.393 0.567
Total 5.888 5.230 1.298 0.776
Indirect
Taxes
Monthly Income Total Direct All Taxes
Class (Rupees) (Cols. 2+3+ Taxes (Cols. 6+7)
4+5)
(1) (6) (7) (8)
Up to 300 16.629 0.013 16.642
301-400 14.094 0.008 14.102
401-500 13.853 0.065 13.918
501-600 15.633 0.021 15.654
601-800 14.574 0.049 14.623
801-1000 14.221 0.057 14.278
1001-1500 13.102 0.099 13.201
1501-2000 12.782 0.182 12.964
2001-2500 12.655 0.285 12.940
2501-3000 11.968 0.262 12.230
3001-3500 13.016 0.634 13.650
3501 and above 12.415 1.416 13.831
Total 13.192 0.432 13.624
Table 3
Federal Taxes Paid in 1978-79 by All Households in Different
Income Classes as Percentage of their Personal Incomes
Indirect Taxes
Monthly Income Import Excise Sales Sur-
Class (Rupees) Duties Duties Taxes charges
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Up to 300 6.802 4.502 1.359 1.027
301-400 6.339 4.532 1.249 0.964
401-500 5.972 4.320 1.168 0.900
501-600 6.564 4.495 1.279 0.887
601-800 5.871 4.430 1.161 0.851
801-1000 6.255 4.630 1.247 0.882
1001-1500 5.538 4.347 1.124 0.768
1501-2000 5.371 4.180 1.119 0.712
2001-2500 5.131 4.258 1.090 0.667
2501-3000 5.060 4.131 1.114 0.623
3001-3500 4.644 3.380 1.064 0.527
3501 and above 5.391 4.113 1.281 0.564
Total 5.716 4.327 1.180 0.771
Indirect
Taxes
Monthly Income Total Direct All Taxes
Class (Rupees) (Cols. Taxes (Cols. 6+7)
2+3+4+5)
(1) (6) (7) (8)
Up to 300 13.690 0.005 13.695
301-400 13.084 0.006 13.090
401-500 12.360 0.022 12.382
501-600 13.225 0.008 13.233
601-800 12.313 0.021 12.334
801-1000 13.014 0.025 13.039
1001-1500 11.777 0.044 11.821
1501-2000 11.382 0.112 11.494
2001-2500 11.146 0.161 11.307
2501-3000 10.928 0.168 11.096
3001-3500 9.615 0.326 9.941
3501 and above 11.349 0.928 12.277
Total 11.994 0.169 12.183