Income inequality in Pakistan: an analysis of existing evidence.
Mahmood, Zafar
To study the consequences of an economic change on income
distribution we rank distributions of income at different points in time
and quantify the degree of income inequalities. Changes in income
distribution can be ascertained either through drawing the Lorenz curves
or through estimating different inequality indices, such as Gird
Coefficient, coefficient of variation, standard deviation of logs of
incomes, Theil's Index and Atkinson's Index.
Ranking the distributions of income through Lorenz curves is, of
course, possible only as long as they do not intersect. Moreover, when
Lorenz curves do not intersect each other, all inequality measures rank
income distributions uniformly. However, if the Lorenz curves do
intersect each other, different inequality measures may rank income
distributions differently (1) and thus the direction of change cannot be
determined unambiguously. For this reason, the use of a single measure
would be misleading. Accordingly, the use of a 'package' of
inequality measures becomes essential.
Most of the previous studies on income distribution in Pakistan
measure income inequality by using Gini Coefficient, Theil's Index
and Coefficient of Variation. (2) These studies provide no explicit
reason for preferring one measure to another. As a result, these studies
do not give due consideration to the conceptual underpinnings of these
measures, which are essential for understanding the implications of the
results regarding various measures of income inequality.
Our main concern in this study is to compare the results regarding
changes in income distribution derived from the various measures of
inequalities. Such an analysis can be extended to analyse the impact of
any income/asset redistribution policy.
The schematic details of the study are as follows. Section I deals
with methodological and data issues. Section II contains empirical
results of the study. Finally, Section III presents conclusions and
recommendations.
I. METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES
Dalton [2;7] has laid down the following two principles for a
satisfactory measurement of inequality:
(i) Inequality index should remain unchanged relative to
proportional increases in all income (i.e. index is independent of
mean). It is known as Dalton's Principle of Population.
(ii) A strictly positive transfer from a rich person to a poor
person ought to lead to a reduction in inequality index. (3) It is known
as Dalton's Principle of Transfers.
We shall analyse various measures of income inequality in terms of
the above two principles and will discuss the various properties of
these measures.
To depict income distribution, Lorenz [17] devised a diagram, in
which percentages of population from the lowest income group to the
highest income group are represented on the horizontal axis and the
percentage of income received by the bottom 'X' percent of the
population is shown on the vertical axis. This curve gives the relation
between the cumulative percentage of the income recipients and the
cumulative percentage of income. If the curve is equidistant from the
two axes, it coincides with the line of equality--a situation of
absolute equality of all incomes. If only one person gets the whole
income, then the curve will coincide with the bottom axis and the right
hand vertical axis. Lorenz curve traces the pattern of income
distribution at a given point of time. As long as the Lorenz curves
corresponding to different points of time do not intersect, we can
unambiguously determine the direction of change in income distribution.
However, when the two Lorenz curves intersect, it is difficult to say
whether the income distribution has improved or worsened.
Gini's concentration ratio (G) can best be explained through
Lorenz curves and can be computed by the following formula [8] :
G = 1 - [n.summation over (i=1)] [S.sub.pi] ([y.sub.i] +
[y.sub.i-1]) 0 [less than or equal to] G [less than or equal to] 1
where [S.sub.pi] is the population share of the ith income group
and [y.sub.i] is cumulated income share of the ith income group.
Since population is concentrated around the mean income, Gini
attaches more weight to transfers affecting middle income classes and
not much weight to changes in the extreme income classes. Gini
coefficient ignores intragroup inequalities in incomes, and as such it
understates income inequalities.
Variance attaches the highest weight to transfers taking place at
the extreme income ranges. However, since the variance is not
independent of unit of measurement, a proportional increase in income
across the board will be shown by variance as an increase in income
inequality while it has remained constant. Therefore, it fails to
satisfy the Principle of Population. A better measure which does not
suffer from the deficiency is the coefficient of variation (C V.), which
is defined as
C.V. = Standard Deviation of Incomes/ Mean Income
The coefficient of variation is sensitive to income transfers for
all income levels and is independent of the mean income level. The
coefficient of variation attaches equal weights to transfers of income
at different income levels, i.e. the impact of redistribution from one
income group to another income group would be the same, irrespective of the level of income. It is, however, possible that the impact of a
transfer would be greater at a lower income level than at the high
income level.
If one wishes to attach greater importance to income transfers at
lower end, then the neutrality property of coefficient of variation
poses serious doubts. A measure of inequality that gives more importance
to lower income levels is the standard deviation of logs of incomes
(S.D.):
S.D. = [[n.summation over (i+1)] [([bar.log Y] - Log
[Y.sub.i]).sup.2] 1/n].sup.1/2]
where [Y.sub.i] is average income of the ith income group, Y is
economy-wide mean income and n is the number of income groups.
A logarithmic transformation reduces the deviation and highlights
the differences at the lower end of the income scale. Therefore, this
measure has relevance if inequalities at the lower income levels are
important. However, as income levels increase, the logarithmic values
shrink so rapidly that we may find S.D. even rising when there are
income transfers from the rich to the poor and thus failing to satisfy
the Principle of Transfers.
Theil [18] introduced an inequality measure which is derived from
the notion of 'entropy' in information theory. The basic idea
behind the 'entropy' is that occurrences which differ greatly
from what was expected should receive more weight than events which
conform with prior expectations. Thus entropy index is the expected
information content of each outcome. Theil's index can be presented
as follows:
T = Log N - [n.summation over (i=1)] [Y.sub.i] Log 1/[Y.sub.i]
where [Y.sub.i] is income share of the ith income group and N is
the number of income groups. When T = 0, we get complete equality and
when T = Log N, we get complete inequality. This index can be useful if
inequality in the high or medium ranges is more important.
As mentioned earlier, different inequality measures attach
different weights to transfers taking place at different income levels.
These weights are the implicit values that each measure embodies for a
desirable distribution of income. Atkinson [2] argues that the
conventional measures should be rejected in favour of direct
consideration of the values we should like to see embodied. Atkinson
defines the "equally distributed equivalent level of income"
as "the level of income per head which, if equally distributed,
would give the same level of social welfare as the present
distribution" [2, p. 250]. Atkinson's Index can be put as:
[A.sub.t] = 1 - [[n.summation over (i=1)]
[([[bar.Y].sub.i]/[bar.Y]).sup.1-[epsilon]] f([Y.sub.i])].sup.1/1 -
[epsilon]] for [epsilon] ([double dagger]) 1 0 [less than or equal to]
[A.sub.t] [less than or equal to] 1
where [Y.sub.i] is mean income of the ith income class; Y is
economy-wide mean income; f([Y.sub.i]) is percentage of population in
the ith income class; and e is inequality aversion parameter.
The inequality aversion parameter, e, represents the weight
attached by society to inequality in the distribution: high values of
[epsilon] mean that the society is particularly averse to inequality,
(4) whereas a zero value means that it is indifferent to inequality.
Data Issues
We have made use of the surveys conducted and compiled by the
Federal Bureau of Statistics. Although commendable efforts have been
made to ensure the representativeness of the data and to minimize the
sampling errors, yet the data suffer from certain drawbacks which should
be kept in mind when drawing any implications from the results of the
present study.
A major shortcoming of the survey data is the small sample size for
the highest income group which leads to an understatement of the incomes
of the group. This problem arises owing to non-response and
understatement of incomes. Moreover, the data do not include the
corporate retained earnings, which leads to a further understatement of
income.
To pool rural-urban data, weights of 1962 are used, which do not
consider the effect of increased urbanization and emergence of new urban
areas and hence would give lower weights to urban inequalities. The 1979
survey data are simply pooled without assigning any weights to rural and
urban areas. Therefore, by according proper weights to rural and urban
areas, we have pooled the data for total Pakistan.
We made an attempt to remove the understatement of incomes in the
data for the highest income group by splicing the income tax data in the
urban areas. Even the use of the income tax data did not affect the
results, (5) because of the narrow coverage of the income tax data [12]
and the widespread evasion of income tax. Moreover, the data given in
income tax statistics are for the assessable income. Because of the
various allowances which are not uniformally available to the taxpayers,
it is difficult to determine the income of each taxpayer from his
assessed income.
Income groups given in the Household Income and Expenditure Surveys
are fewer for 1963-64 and 1979 [13;16] than for the rest of the period.
Moreover, class intervals of different income groups for each year are
not equal. Such inconsistencies may create some problems, especially
when the comparison of income distribution is made over time. To
overcome any such problem, we have transformed the whole data into
income deciles by the linear-interpolation method.
II. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Analysis of Income Shares
We start analysing results by ordinal ranking of the household
income distribution in rural, urban and total Pakistan.
Table 1 presents the income share of each household decile for the
rural areas of Pakistan. The table reveals that income share of up to
the 7th decile increased between 1963-64 and 1968-69, while those of the
8th, 9th and 10th deciles decreased over the same period. However, in
the intervening period there was some fluctuation in the income shares
of various deciles. For example, in 1968-69, the income shares of the
8th and 9th deciles increased over those for 1966-67. A comparison of
income distribution in 1969-70 with that in 1968-69 reveals an increase
in the income share of the 10th decile, but a decrease or stagnation in
the income shares of all the other deciles. However, if we compare
1969-70 with the earlier period, i.e. 1963-64 and 1966-67, we see an
increase in the income shares of all the deciles except the 10th decile.
If we compare 1970-71 with any other period under consideration, we see
that this was the period when income was more equally distributed; all
the poor and middle-income classes observed an increase in their income
shares, and the rich classes observed a decrease in their income share.
The picture in 1971-72 was completely different from that in 1970-71
when the only increase in income share was experienced by the households
of the 10th decile: all other deciles recorded a decrease in their
income share. Also, compared to 1971-72, we observed a further decrease
in income share of up to the 7th decile in 1979, while the 8th and 10th
deciles recorded an increase in their income shares.
It can be seen from Table 1 that in urban Pakistan income shares of
the bottom 80 percent of households have increased over the period from
1963-64 to 1969-70. The income share of the 9th decile decreased up to
1968-69, but afterwards it showed a rising trend. The share of incomes
of the richest 10 percent of the households increased up to 1968-69, but
it went down in the following year. Income shares of both the poorest
and the richest 10 percent of the households declined in 1970-71, while
those of the remaining households showed either a slight increase or
stagnation. In contrast with 1970-71, both the poorest and the richest
10 percent households in 1971-72 recorded an increase in their income
shares while income shares of the rest of the households went down. The
year 1979 saw the most unequal income distribution of the whole period
under consideration when only the richest 10 percent of the households
showed an increase in their income share and all other households
experienced a considerable fall in their income shares.
It can be seen from Table 1 for total Pakistan that during the
period from 1963-64 to 1970-71, the bottom 70 percent of the households
saw an increase in their income shares. The 8th and the 10th deciles had
a mixed trend while the 9th decile witnessed a decrease in their income
shares. As compared to 1970-71, only the richest 10 percent households
in 1971-72 recorded an increase in their income share while all other
households experienced a decrease. However, income distribution in
1971-72 appeared to be more in favour of both the poorest and the
richest households as was observed in 1963-64 and 1966-67. As compared
to 1971-72, the lowest 70 percent households in 1979 registered a
further decrease in their income shares while the rest of the households
had an increase in their respective shares.
It is difficult to find any ranking of the distributions by
analysing income shares. Because different inequality measures give
different weights to transfers to certain income levels, there is a
possibility that different inequality measures may lead to different
ranking of the income distributions.
Ranking of Income Distributions
Although the analysis of income shares did not clearly show which
year's distribution was more equal, estimates of most of the
inequality indices reported in Table 2 for rural Pakistan do show a
uniform ranking of income distributions over the entire period under
consideration. (6) It can be seen from Table 2 that inequalities went
down over the 1963-64--1968-69 period because the poor and the middle
income classes enjoyed an increase in their income shares during this
period. In the following year (1969-70), a slight increase in inequality
was observed, which was reversed in 1970-71, when all the poor and the
middle-income classes enjoyed an increase in their income shares.
However, this trend could not last long in 1971-72, when inequality went
up owing to the only increase in income share of the richest 10 percent
households. A rising trend in inequality was also observed in 1979 when
the poor and the middle-income classes suffered a further decrease in
their income shares.
Estimates of inequality indices for urban areas reported in Table 2
show divergent trends in income distributions. For example, on the basis
of Gini Coefficient, Atkinson's Index for [epsilon] = 0.5 and
Theil's Index, the inequality was at the lowest level in 1969-70.
However, on the basis of the standard deviation of the logs of incomes
and Atkinson's Index for [epsilon] = 3.0, it was the year 1971-72
in which the inequalities in income distribution were the least, while
the coefficient of variation suggests that the inequality was at the
minimum in 1970-71. Therefore, without any reference to the welfare
functions, it is difficult to conclude whether the degree of inequality
has improved or worsened.
It is interesting to note that while all other indices for urban
areas showed an increase in inequality in 1971-72 over that in 1970-71,
Atkinson's Index for [epsilon] = 3.0 and the standard deviation of
the logs of incomes showed a decrease in inequality. This is due to the
fact that only the poorest and the richest households enjoyed an
increase in their income share but the change in the income share of the
poorest households was more than that of the richest households. The
Atkinson's Index for [epsilon] = 3.0 and the standard deviation of
the logs of incomes share the property of assigning more weights to
transfers to the lower income groups. That is why both the measures
highlighted this change as a decrease in inequalities although the
income share of the richest class had also increased.
For urban areas, both the Theil's Index and Atkinson's
Index for [epsilon] = 0.5 move in the same direction in five out of
seven years, and the Gini Coefficient and the coefficient of variation
show very divergent trends. It is worth noting that while for the year
in which income inequality was the least there was no agreement among
inequality measures, they all agree for the period in which inequality
was the maximum, viz. 1979. This probably is due to the fact that the
richest 10 percent of the households received most of the income.
In the case of total Pakistan, all the inequality measures agree in
ranking 1970-71 as the year of greater equality and 1963-64 as the year
of greater inequality. (7) However, we do observe some disagreement on
ranking for the rest of the period. It can be seen from Table 2 that
Gini Coefficient, Coefficient of Variation and Atkinson's Index for
[epsilon] = 0.5 provide the same ranking except that the Coefficient of
Variation strikes a discordant note for 1966-67. Similarly,
Atkinson's Index for [epsilon] = 3.0, the standard deviation of the
logs of incomes and Theil's Index provide the same ranking.
III CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
Besides discussing the properties of measures of income inequality,
we have presented, in this study, the estimates of these measures to
help analyse changes in the income distribution. The results show that
reliance on the use of a single measure may lead us to erroneous conclusions. While in the case of the rural areas of Pakistan, most of
the inequality measures will give us the correct direction underlying
the changes in income distribution, any reliance on Gini coefficient or
any other single measure of income inequality in the absence of a
certain welfare function will yield misleading results for the urban
areas and hence for total Pakistan.
The analysis shows a declining trend in income inequalities for
both the rural and urban Pakistan up to the year 1970-71 but a rising
trend soon afterwards. While in the rural areas the income inequality in
1979 was still lower than that in 1963-64, the income inequality in the
urban areas in 1979 was at the maximum level.
It should be noted that income inequalities in urban areas have
always been much higher than those observed in the rural areas. As a
matter of fact, the difference in inequalities in the two areas has even
widened. This is disturbing, because the inequalities have grown faster
in those areas which are fast expanding, with the result that income
inequalities have worsened over time.
From the trends of the inequalities observed in Pakistan one can
question the distribution of benefits of growth which the country has
achieved over time. From these trends, it seems that Kuznet's
thesis is very much valid for the urban areas of Pakistan if not for the
rural areas. All the industrial growth taking place in urban areas has
gone into the hands of the urban elite. This situation is a cause for
serious concerns as the urban sector of Pakistan is growing rapidly, and
if urban inequalities also grow with it, then there are chances of a
further deterioration of the situation. (8) These trends in inequality
give an indication of a worsening situation to the policy makers and
require that redistributive policies be formulated in favour of the poor
and middle-income classes.
We may note that the feeling that inequalities in income in
Pakistan have been high is suggested by the fact that wages have
increased less rapidly than the per capita income. However, one should
remember that such an analysis is related to the functional distribution
of income and not to the size distribution of income. The two can be
related only if we have data on assets, which unfortunately do not exist
in Pakistan. A study of size distribution of income, coupled with asset
distribution, can prove more fruitful.
Comments on "Income Inequality in Pakistan: An Analysis of
Existing Evidence"
This is purely a statistical paper. The author studies the pattern
of income inequality in Pakistan, using several inequality measures. The
reader's expectations are aroused with the promises of being
provided with an 'explicit reason for preferring one measure rather
than another' as well as potential in the analysis for extension to
study the impact of any income or asset redistribution policy. But what
is provided by way of 'explicit reason' is simply a catalogue
of formulas and their properties. This purpose could well have been
served if the author had simply guided the reader to standrad works on
the subject, such as those by Sen [1] and Szal and Robinson [2]. The
other claim, too, is an overstatement. Extensions of the formulas
reported in this study whereby one can readily gauge the impact of
redistribution policies still elude economists. These, however, are not
the main reasons for this study on the author's part.
The author bases his theoretical argument for taking into
consideration more than one summary measure of income inequality on the
possibility of the Lorenz Curves for various years intersecting one
another. An appropriate statistical response in such a case would have
been the estimation of the functional forms of income distributions with
the help of such relative-frequency functions as lognormal, gamma or
beta densities. This is so because an increase in the number of the
parameters at one's disposal to describe income distributions in
various years is most likely to enhance one's ability to identify
the direction of change in income inequality. No doubt, Atkinson does
point to a way out of the dilemma situations by means of the
Atkinson's Index. However, such an index depends on the existence
of a particular welfare function which, too, does not carry to its
credit the consensus supposedly absent in the case of inequality
measures, such as the Gini coefficient, when Lorenz Curves for different
years do intersect. The functional-form approach has considerable
promise in this regard.
The author's case for relying on a basket of summary measures
is weak on empirical grounds too. One can form a priori judgements about
the course of overall income inequality from one data year to the next
on the basis of the decile estimates reported by the author in Table 1
of the paper. For example, in the rural areas there seems to have been a
redistribution away from the three top deciles to all the seven lower
deciles in 1966-67, as compared with 1963-64. (1) Thus the year 1966-67
is a clear-cut case of decline in income inequality. Similarly, one can
make the following observation for 1969-70, as compared with 1968-69.
Below the median, there is no change in income shares of the first,
fourth and fifth decries, and there are compensating changes between the
second and third deciles. But, above the median, there is a
redistribution away from the sixth, seventh, eighth and ninth deciles
toward the tenth decile. In this situation, one would expect overall
income inequality to have gone up in 1969-70 as compared with 1968-69.
This reasoning can be extended to all the data years, for both rural and
urban areas. As a result, one may envisage the following pattern of
income inequality in rural and urban areas:
Change in Income Inequality as compared with
the Previous Data Year
1966-67 1968-69 1969-70
Rural [down arrow] [down arrow] [down arrow]
Urban [down arrow] [down arrow] [down arrow]
1970-71 1971-72 1979
Rural [down arrow] [down arrow] [down arrow]
Urban [down arrow] [down arrow] [down arrow]
Note: [down arrow] implies decrease and [up arrow] increase.
If one compares the coefficient estimates reported in Table 2 of
the paper for the rural category, all the measures rank all income
distributions for rural areas in line with this stipulated pattern. In
the case of the urban areas, none of the Standard Deviation of log
income, Coefficient of Variation, Atkinson's Index (for both
[epsilon] = 0.5 and [epsilon] = 0.3) and Theil's Index provides a
ranking in conformity with the expected ranking. Surprisingly, only the
Gini Coefficient correctly gauges the expected pattern of income
inequality for urban areas also. This is certainly not what the reader
is led to believe in this paper. Leaving the justification issue aside,
let us turn to a more fundamental problem in the paper. This concerns
the interpolation procedure adopted by the author to derive the decile
estimates on which the income inequality parameter estimates, in turn,
are based.
According to an earlier version of this paper, the author adopts
the route of mean income in order to arrive at the percentage of total
income accruing to various deciles of households. This is done by means
of a two-stage interpolation procedure. This method utilizes the
following information: the lower income bound f([x.sub.1]) of the income
group containing a decile point, its upper income bound f([x.sub.2]) and
its mean income f([x.sub.o]), where x is a cumulative percentage of
households and f([x.sub.o]) lies between f([x.sub.1]) and f([x.sub.2]).
The problem at hand is to find mean income f([x.sup.*]) for the
[x.sup.*] decile, where [x.sup.*] lies between [x.sub.1] and [x.sub.2].
In the first stage, points ([x.sub.1], f([x.sub.1])) and ([x.sub.2],
f([x.sub.2])) are used to determine [x.sub.o], the cumulative percentage
of households corresponding to the known mean income f([x.sub.o]). In
the second stage, either points ([x.sub.1], f([x.sub.1])) and
([x.sub.o], f([x.sub.o])) or ([x.sub.o], f([x.sub.o])) and ([x.sub.2],
f([x.sub.2])), depending on whether [x.sup.*] falls between [x.sub.1]
and [x.sub.o] or between [x.sub.o] and [x.sub.2], are used to find the
desired [f(x.sup.*])..sup.2] In each of the two stages, a straight-line
interpolation method is used. There is a basic problem with this method
in its application to the income distribution data. It does not enable
one to carry out mean-preserving adjustments in the data. In other
words, no decile pattern constructed with the help of this method can be
claimed to belong to the original income distribution which it is
supposed to represent. In the presence of this anomaly, the income
inequality estimates reported in Table 2 are meaningless. Thus there is
a need to re-do the entire exercise with the help of the standard
linear-interpolation procedure, using data on cumulative percentage of
income received along with cumulative percentage of households--without
any reference to the mean income data.
Sayyid Tahir
Associate Professor, International Institute of Islamic Economics,
Islamic University, Islamabad
REFERENCES
[1.] Sen, A. K. On Economic Inequality. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
1973.
[2.] Szal, R., and S. Robinson. "Measuring Income
Inequality". In C. R. Frank, Jr., and R. C. Webb (eds.), Income
Distribution and Growth in the Less-Developed Countries. Washington,
D.C.: The Brookings Institution. 1977.
(1) In principle, the term "redistribution" is to be used
with reference to a given mean in come, but in a time-series framework
it is used with reference to aggregate and, hence, mean income change.
Thus the use of the term here is ad hoe. It is just to facilitate
comparative statements about the degree of income inequality between two
years.
(2) My interpretation of the second stage is based on my
discussions with the author on this subject. However, even if one sticks
to the formula reported in the paper's version circulated at the
conference, the problem noted here remains. It may also be mentioned
that according to the formula reported by the author, the likelihood of
negative weights is very much there, whenever [x.sub.1] is greater than
[x.sub.o]. Such weights are hard to rationalize, to say the least.
REFERENCES
[1.] Alauddin, T. "Mass Poverty in Pakistan: A Further
Study". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XIV, No. 4. Winter 1975.
[2.] Atkinson, A. B. "On the Measurement of Inequality".
Journal of Economic Theory. Vol. 2. 1970.
[3.] Ayub, M. A. "Income Inequality in a Growth--Theoretic
Context: The Case of Pakistan". Ph.D. Thesis submitted to Yale
University. 1977.
[4.] Azfar, J. "The Distribution of Income in Pakistan:
1966-67". Pakistan Economic and Social Review. Vol. XIV, Nos. 1-4.
1976.
[5.] Bergan, A. "Personal Income Distribution and Personal
Savings in Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. VII, No. 2.
Summer 1967.
[6.] Chaudhry, M. Ghaffar. "Green Revolution and
Redistribution of Rural Incomes: Pakistan's Experience".
Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXI, No. 3. Autumn 1982.
[7.] Donaldson, D., and John A. Weymark. "A Single-Parameter
Generalization of the Gini Indices of Inequality". Journal of
Economic Theory. Vol. 22, No.1. February 1980.
[8.] Jain, S., and A. E. Tiemann. Size Distribution of Income:
Compilation of Data. Washington, D.C.: I.B.R.D., Development Research
Center. August 1973. (Discussion Paper No. 4)
[9.] Jeetun, A. "Trends in Inequality of Income Distribution
in Pakistan". Karachi: University of Karachi, Applied Economic
Research Centre. September 1978. (Discussion Paper No. 29)
[10) Kemal, A. R. "Income Distribution in Pakistan: A
Review". Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
April 1981. (Research Report Series No. 123)
[11.] Khandkar, R.H. "Distribution of Income and Wealth in
Pakistan". Pakistan Economic and Social Review. Vol. XIV, Nos. 1-4.
1976.
[12.] Pakistan. Central Board of Revenues. All Pakistan Income Tax
Reports and Returns. Islamabad. (Various years)
[13.] Pakistan. Economic Affairs Division. Central Statistics
Office. Report on the Quarterly Survey of Current Economic Conditions in
Pakistan: Household Income and Expenditure (July 1963 to June 1964).
Karachi. 1967.
[14.] Pakistan. Economic Coordination and External Assistance
Division. Central Statistical Office. Report on the Quarterly Survey of
Current Economic Conditions in Pakistan: Household Income and
Expenditure Survey (July 1966 to June 1967). Karachi. 1971.
[15.] Pakistan. Ministry of Finance, Planning and Development.
Statistical Division. Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 1968-69,
1969-70, 1970-71 and 1971-72. Karachi. 1973.
[16.] Pakistan. Statistics Division. Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 1979. Karachi. 1983.
[17.] Sen, A. On Economic Inequality. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
1973.
[18.] Theil, H. Economics and Information Theory. Amsterdam:
North-Holland. 1967.
(1) Different inequality measures give different weights to income
transfers at different in come levels.
(2) These studies are: Alauddin [1], Ayub [3], Azfar [4], Bergan
[5], Chaudhry [6], Jeetun [9] and Khandkat [11]. For a detailed review
of these studies, see Kemal [10].
(3) This property rejects the measures such as relative mean
deviation and the interquartile range, because they are unaffected by
transfers on the same side of the mean.
(4) It should be mentioned here that Atkinson's measure
violates the basic assumption of strict concavity on either extremum,
where welfare derived from a change in income remains same.
(5) Owing to insignificant improvement in our results, we did not
report these results in this study.
(6) It should be mentioned here that the standard deviation of logs
of income and Atkinson's Index for [epsilon] = 3.0 disagree with other indices in the cases of a few years.
(7) The standard deviation of the logs of income and
Atkinson's Index [epsilon] = 3.0 are exceptions, which report
1963-64 as the period of high inequality.
(8) We may also note that these results emerge despite the fact
that the survey data leave out the big capitalists who have been the
main beneficiaries of the industrial growth during the Sixties and also
later.
ZAFAR MAHMOOD, Research Economist, Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad (Pakistan).
Table 1
Income Shares of Households for Rural,
Urban & Total Pakistan
DECILE
Year Area 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th
1963-64 Rural 2.7 4.2 5.4 6.4 7.4
Urban 2.7 4.1 4.9 5.8 6.7
Total 2.7 4.2 5.3 6.3 7.2
1966-67 Rural 3.3 4.7 5.8 6.7 7.7
Urban 3.0 4.1 5.0 5.9 6.8
Total 3.1 4.4 5.4 6.3 7.2
1968-69 Rural 3.3 5.0 6.1 6.9 7.9
Urban 3.1 4.2 5.2 5.8 6.9
Total 3.1 4.7 5.6 6.4 7.5
1969-70 Rural 3.3 5.1 6.0 6.9 7.9
Urban 3.2 4.4 5.3 6.2 7.1
Total 3.2 4.7 5.5 6.7 7.5
1970-71 Rural 3.6 5.1 6.0 6.9 8.0
Urban 3.1 4.4 5.3 6.1 7.1
Total 3.4 4.8 5.7 6.6 7.6
1971-72 Rural 3.5 4.9 6.0 6.9 7.9
Urban 3.8 4.2 5.1 5.9 6.8
Total 3.2 4.6 5.6 6.5 7.3
1979 Rural 3.4 4.8 5.8 6.6 7.5
Urban 2.7 3.8 4.6 5.5 6.4
Total 3.1 4.5 5.3 6.1 7.1
DECILE
Year Area 6th 7th 8th 9th 10th
1963-64 Rural 8.6 10.1 12.1 15.2 27.9
Urban 7.8 9.1 10.7 19.7 28.5
Total 8.5 9.9 12.0 15.3 28.6
1966-67 Rural 8.8 10.3 11.9 14.3 26.5
Urban 7.7 9.2 11.2 14.8 32.3
Total 8.4 9.7 11.5 14.9 29.1
1968-69 Rural 9.1 10.4 12.1 14.9 24.3
Urban 7.9 9.3 11.0 14.1 32.5
Total 8.6 9.8 11.7 14.6 28.0
1969-70 Rural 9.0 10.3 12.0 14.7 24.9
Urban 8.1 9.4 11.3 14.2 30.8
Total 8.6 9.9 11.6 14.6 27.7
1970-71 Rural 9.1 10.4 12.2 14.7 24.1
Urban 8.1 9.5 11.4 14.5 30.6
Total 8.7 10.0 11.8 14.6 26.8
1971-72 Rural 8.8 10.0 11.7 14.4 25.9
Urban 7.8 9.1 11.4 14.3 31.7
Total 8.4 9.7 11.4 14.3 29.0
1979 Rural 8.6 9.7 11.9 14.4 27.4
Urban 7.4 8.9 10.6 14.1 36.1
Total 8.1 9.3 11.2 14.4 30.9
Sources: [13;14;15;16].
Table 2
Estimates of Household Income Inequalities in
Rural, Urban & Total Pakistan
Measures of
Inequality 1963-64 1966-67 1968-69 1969-70
Gini Rural 0.350 0.318 0.300 0.303
Coefficient Urban 0.381 0.380 0.374 0.357
Total 0.356 0.349 0.335 0.331
Standard Rural 0.632 0.562 0.540 0.543
Deviation of Urban 0.674 0.648 0.636 0.610
Log Income Total 0.640 0.610 0.590 0.582
Coefficient Rural 0.694 0.634 0.577 0.591
of Variation Urban 0.764 0.815 0.813 0.759
Total 0.715 0.718 0.681 0.671
Atkinson's Index Rural 0.098 0.081 0.072 0.073
[epsilon] = 0.5 Urban 0.116 0.117 0.115 0.103
Total 0.102 0.098 0.090 0.088
Atkinson's Index Rural 0.427 0.357 0.339 0.340
[epsilon] = 3.0 Urban 0.452 0.426 0.414 0.390
Total 0.433 0.397 0.381 0.373
Theil's Index Rural 0.204 0.172 0.147 0.153
Urban 0.246 0.257 0.253 0.226
Total 0.215 0.211 0.193 0.187
Measures of
Inequality 1970-71 1971-72 1979
Gini Rural 0.295 0.307 0.324
Coefficient Urban 0.360 0.363 0.414
Total 0.321 0.340 0.360
Standard Rural 0.523 0.540 0.565
Deviation of Urban 0.619 0.606 0.699
Log Income Total 0.562 0.589 0.619
Coefficient Rural 0.567 0.611 0.658
of Variation Urban 0.757 0.786 0.927
Total 0.645 0.706 0.766
Atkinson's Index Rural 0.069 0.075 0.085
[epsilon] = 0.5 Urban 0.105 0.107 0.141
Total 0.082 0.093 0.106
Atkinson's Index Rural 0.320 0.332 0.354
[epsilon] = 3.0 Urban 0.400 0.377 0.473
Total 0.349 0.376 0.401
Theil's Index Rural 0.143 0.159 0.179
Urban 0.227 0.237 0.315
Total 0.176 0.203 0.23
Sources: [13; 14; 15; 16].