Residential demand for electricity and natural gas in Pakistan.
Iqbal, Mahmood
A model for residential demand for fuel in Pakistan was developed
on the basis of stock of fuel-consuming appliances and their rate of
utilization. Income and price elasticities of natural gas and
electricity are estimated by the OLS and GLS methods. The income
elasticity of natural gas and electricity and price elasticity of
natural gas are found statistically significant and consistent with a
priori knowledge of economic theory. Several policy implications are
pointed out and suggestions are made for improvement in future
estimations.
**********
The energy sector in Pakistan has received close attention in the
various national development plans. The share of the fuel and power
sector rose from about 12 percent to 18 percent of the development
outlay during the 1955-80 period [10]. However, few studies have focused
on the sectoral consumption of various forms of energy in Pakistan. The
aim of this study is to analyze the consumption pattern of commercial
energy, namely, natural gas and electricity, in the residential sector
of Pakistan. These two sources of energy provide 58 percent of the total
supply of commercial energy; 19 percent of this supply was consumed by
the residential sector alone [13].
Using the standard theory of demand, this study will analyze the
importance of fuel expenditure in the consumer's budget and its
sensitivity to changes in income and prices. It should help policy
makers in examining the effectiveness of measures of demand management
and price regulation used from time to time.
This paper is divided into three sections. In Section I, we develop
a model of consumer demand for fuel. The basic hypothesis is that the
demand for fuel depends on the stock of appliances and the intensity
with which they are used. In Section II, the OLS technique is used to
estimate the demand equations. Equations with autocorrelated residuals
are estimated by the GLS method to obtain the non-serially correlated
residuals. The results of the regression equations and income and price
elasticities of demand for fuel are also explained in this section.
Finally, in Section III, we point out some policy implications. We also
make some suggestions, based on our model, for further study of
residential demand for fuel in Pakistan.
I. MODEL
The model of residential demand for fuel is based on the postulates
of the traditional micro-economic theory. A consumer's objective is
to maximize utility, subject to a budget constraint. In this study, an
additional constraint is imposed: the amount of fuel consumed is less
than or equal to the 'capacity'--measured in TOE--of the
consumer's stock of appliances. (1) This stock is in turn dependent
on the price of fuel, prices of appliances and the real income of the
consumer.
Therefore, if 'F' stands for the demand for fuel,
'[delta]' for the rate of utilization of appliances--assumed
to be constant and same for all appliances--and 'K' for the
stock of appliances, the demand equation can be expressed as [1;9;18]:
F = [delta]K .. .. (1)
In the log-linear form, Eq. (1) can be written as: (2)
In F = ln [delta] + ln K .. .. .. (2)
Further, we assume that '[delta]' is a log-linear
function of m-variables, the '[X.sub.i]' (income, relative
prices of different kinds of fuel, temperature, etc.) as:
ln [delta] = [m.summation over (i = 1)] [[alpha].sub.i] ln
[X.sub.i] + u .. .. (3)
where u is the random error in the log form. Substituting Eq. (3)
into Eq. (2):
ln F = [m.summation over (i = 1)] [[alpha].sub.i] ln [X.sub.i] + u
+ ln K .. .. .. (4)
or
ln K = ln F - [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i] ln [X.sub.i] - u .. .. .. (5)
To eliminate the need for data on 'K', we assume that
consumer is in the process of continuous partial adjustment towards a
desired level of appliance holdings, [K.sup.*]. [K.sup.*] is assumed to
depend on l-variables, '[Y.sub.j]', all of which may have
appeared in '[X.sub.i]'. In the log-linear form, it can be
written as:
ln [K.sup.*] = (l.summation over (j = 1)) [[beta].sub.j] ln
[Y.sub.j] + [member of] .. .. .. (6)
where [member of] is a random error in log form. We also assume
that the partial adjustment process takes the form:
ln [K.sub.t] - ln [K.sub.t-1] = [phi](ln [K.sup.*.sub.t] - ln
[K.sub.t-1]) 0 < [phi] [less than or equal to] 1 .. (7)
Substituting Eq. (5) into Eq. (7):
ln [F.sub.t] - [m.summation over (i = 1)] [[alpha].sub.i] ln
[X.sub.it] - [u.sub.t] - ln [F.sub.t-1] + [m.summation over (i = 1)]
[[alpha].sub.i] ln [X.sub.it=1] + [u.sub.t-1] =[phi] ln [K.sup.*.sub.t]
- [phi] ln [F.sub.t-1] + [phi] [m.summation over (i = 1)]
[[alpha].sub.i] ln [X.sub.it-1] + [phi] [u.sub.t-1] .. (8)
After some rearrangement and substituting Eq. (6) into Eq. (8):
ln [F.sub.t] = [phi] [l.summation over (i = 1)] [[beta].sub.j]
[Y.sub.jt] + [m.summation over (i = 1)] [[alpha].sub.i] ln [X.sub.it] +
(1 - [phi]) ln [F.sub.t-1] - (1 - [phi]) [m.summation over (i = 1)]
[alpha].sub.i] ln [X.sub.it-1] - (1 - [phi]) [u.sub.t-1] + [phi]
[[member of].sub.t] + [u.sub.t] .. (9)
If the consumer adjusts instantaneously ([phi] = 1), Eq. (9) is
reduced to:
ln [F.sub.t] = [m.summation over (i = 1)] [alpha].sub.i] ln
[X.sub.it] + [l.summation over (j = 1)] [[beta].sub.j] ln [Y.sub.jt] +
[v.sub.t] .. .. (10)
where [v.sub.t] = [u.sub.t] + [[member of].sub.t].
If the stock of appliance holdings and their rate of utilization
include the same explanatory variables, namely, income, price of gas,
price of electricity, temperature etc., Eq. (10) can be simplified:
ln [F.sub.t] = [n.summation over (K = 1)] [[gamma].sub.K] ln
[Z.sub.Kt] + [v.sub.t]
where
[[gamma].sub.K] = ([[alpha].sub.K] + [[beta].sub.K]) .. .. .. (11)
[Z.sub.K] = [X.sub.K] = [Y.sub.K]
Eq. (11) is estimated separately for per capita consumption of
electricity, per capita consumption of gas and per capita joint
consumption of gas and electricity as dependent variables, and real per
capita income, real price of gas, real price of electricity, and
temperature as independent variables. In each regression equation a
trend variable, T, is also included to capture the influence of changes
in tastes and preferences.
The parameter estimates of Eq. (11) are the long-run elasticities.
(3) The short-run elasticities can be derived by eliminating the
adjustment lag from the parameters of Eq. (11). To this, we first
regress ln [F.sub.t] on the explanatory variables, [phi] [m.summation
over (K = 1)] [[gamma].sub.K] ln [Z.sub.Kt] and the lagged value, (1 -
[phi])ln[F.sub.t-1]. (4) This will give the value of the adjustment
coefficient, [phi]. We then multiply the parameter estimates of Eq. (11)
with the adjustment coefficient, [phi], as:
[[eta].sub.Kf] = [phi] [[gamma].sub.K] K = 1, ..., n (12)
where [[eta].sub.Kf] is the short-run elasticity of F with respect
to variable [Z.sub.K] (K= 1,...,n).
Economic theory suggests that if fuel is a normal good, an increase
in (real) income will lead to greater utilization of the existing
fuel-consuming appliances or addition to the stock of these appliances.
Therefore, the expected sign of the coefficient of income would be
positive. The sign of coefficients of own prices of natural gas and
electricity would be negative. The cross price effect for natural gas
and electricity would be positive if they are substitutes and negative
if they are complements. The high mean annual temperature in Pakistan
suggests that consumption of fuel should increase with the rise in
temperature: the coefficient for temperature should be positive.
II. DATA AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Each demand equation was estimated from the annual data for 1960 to
1981. The data for total residential consumption of natural gas and
electricity are taken from the Energy Data Book, 1979 [14] and Energy
Year Book, 1981 [13]. Data on consumption of all fuels are measured in
per capita TOE per year. Data on consumption of natural gas and
electricity are obtained from the same sources. The price of natural gas
is measured in Rupees per Million Cubic Feet and the price of
electricity is measured in Rupees per Million KWH. Prices of furs were
first converted into Rupees per TOE and then expressed in real term by
deflating them with the Wholesale Consumer Price Index of 1959-60 as the
base year. Data for population, the wholesale consumer price index
(1959-60 = 100) and real gross domestic product at constant factor cost
(1959-60 = 100) are taken from Pakistan Economic Survey, 1980-81 [10].
An average of the difference of the Mean of Maximum and Mean of Minimum
temperatures of Karachi, Lahore, Rawalpindi, Peshawar and Quetta is
calculated in Celsius. The figures for temperature are taken from the
Statistical Yearbook [11].
Four different versions of the final model (Equation 11) have been
estimated. In the first version of the model, the regression equations
of natural gas and electricity are estimated using five explanatory
variables, viz. income, price of natural gas, price of electricity,
temperature and the trend variable. In each equation, prices of both
natural gas and electricity are included to test the interrelationship between these two types of fuels as competitors or complements.
In the second version of the model, we have regressed consumption
of natural gas and electricity on income, temperature and the trend as
explanatory variables. The price of natural gas as an explanatory
variable enters only in the equation of natural gas, and the price of
electricity only in the equation of electricity. If our regression
results are not significant with the former specification of the demand
function, then we hypothesize that a mere inclusion of own price as
explanatory variable would make the parametric estimates more reliable.
In the third case, we have attempted the above two sets of
equations together. Consumption of natural gas and electricity is summed
up and regressed on five explanatory variables, viz. income, price of
gas, price of electricity, temperatures and the trend. The hypothesis
tested here is whether the consumption level changed during the period
taking each fuel separately and then jointly.
The fourth case is similar to the third, with the difference that a
weighted average of prices of natural gas and electricity is substituted
for their separate price.
Regression Results
The OLS technique is applied to estimate per capita consumption of
natural gas and electricity. The results are presented in Table 1. The
sign of the income elasticity of consumption of natural gas and
electricity or both fuels together is positive and statistically
significant at the 0.05 level.
The value of the long-run income elasticity is relatively higher
than found in studies for developed countries. It seems reasonable
because in developing countries as incomes rise additional expenditures
are allocated more than proportionately to heat, light, electrical
appliances, etc. Therefore, expenditures on fuel would represent a large
fraction of the consumer's budget in low-income countries,
producing a relatively higher income elasticity estimate [16].
The estimates for income elasticity in this study are also higher
than those for other developing countries. This may be explained by
several factors. First, our estimate for income elasticity is based on
only commercial fuels consumed in the residential sector, while studies
for other developing countries have estimated income elasticity from
commercial and non-commercial fuels consumed in all sectors of the
economy. Since there is considerable substitution within different types
of fuels in the aggregate energy consumption, income elasticity would be
smaller for it than for consumption of natural gas and electricity in a
particular sector of the economy [4].
Secondly, natural gas and electricity are not the basic household
fuels in Pakistan. A vast majority of people in the country rely on
non-commercial sources of energy for cooking, heating, etc. Commercial
fuels are consumed mainly in urban centres and where the real per capita
income is higher than the national average [12].
The price elasticities of natural gas and electricity show a
somewhat heterogeneous pattern. The own price elasticity of natural gas
in the OLS estimate was significant for all equations. It became
relatively insignificant when estimated by the GLS method. The own price
elasticity of electricity was either positive, though statistically
insignificant (see Reg. Eqs. 2 and 7), or negative but low and with poor
level of significance (see Reg. Eqs. 3, 5, 6 and 8).
According to official estimates in Pakistan, the ratio of
consumption of natural gas to electricity was 2:1 in 1959-60, increasing
to 65:1 in 1980-81. In the twenty-two-year period, consumption of
natural gas increased 30 times more than the increase in the consumption
of electricity. On the other hand, prices of both natural gas and
electricity decreased by almost the same proportion in real terms
[13;14]. Therefore, a very large percentage increase in the consumption
of natural gas relative to electricity, with the same percentage decline
in prices of each, resulted in a large and statistically significant
price elasticity of natural gas. The price elasticity of electricity had
either a negative sign or positive and was inconsistent with economic
theory. The magnitude of increase in natural gas relative to electricity
also suggests that demand for natural gas was supply-constrained,
particularly in early years, causing the estimation problem.
The same argument applies to other regression equations
representing joint consumption of natural gas and electricity. In Reg.
Eq. 7, the price elasticity of natural gas remains negative and
statistically significant while the price elasticity of electricity
becomes positive but statistically insignificant. The effect of a
weighted average percentage change in prices of natural gas and
electricity on the joint consumption of natural gas and electricity is
negative and statistically significant (see Reg. Eq. 9).
From the price elasticities of natural gas and electricity, we can
also conclude that natural gas and electricity in Pakistan are not
competitors (see Reg. Eqs. 1 and 8). In fact, each fuel has its own
specific use. Natural gas is used for cooking, space heating, water
heating, etc. Electricity is used for lights, fans, refrigerators,
air-conditioners, televisions, stereo components, etc.
In the second set of regressions, multicollinearity (not reported
here) has decreased; the level of significance of the own price
elasticity of natural gas has increased; and, more importantly, the own
price elasticity of electricity has become consistent with theory. This
supports our hypothesis that besides income, temperature and the trend
variable, the own price of the fuel should be included in the equations
of natural gas and electricity.
The income and price elasticities of joint consumption of natural
gas and electricity are equivalent, in magnitude and significance, to
the elasticities of natural gas and electricity when used separately.
This rejects our hypothesis that consumption behaviour differs between
joint and separate uses of natural gas and electricity. The mean maximum
and minimum temperatures for large cities in Pakistan show that there
was little variation in temperature over the period under study.
Therefore, the elasticity of temperature was small and statistically
insignificant. The positive sign of the elasticity of temperature
implies that due to tropical climate of the country, fuel is required to
operate fans, air conditioners, refrigerators, generators, suction pumps, etc. (5)
The regression equations estimated by OLS had small Durbin Watson
statistics, reflecting a high degree of autocorrelation. This in turn
results in smaller variance or overstatement of t-values of parameters.
This was corrected by estimating these equations by GLS of
autoregressive of order 1. This considerably improved the DW statistics
and made the parametric estimates more reliable. The high values of
R-square for all equations demonstrate that they have a 'good'
fit. About 99 percent of the variation in the demand for natural gas and
electricity could be explained by the independent variables. However, a
note of caution is necessary here. The large intercepts with significant
t-values represent the fact that the excluded variables could have
significant effect on the consumption of natural gas and electricity.
Moreover high R-square and low levels of significance of the
coefficients require great care in interpreting the results. However, a
high R-square and statistically significant values of income, price of
natural gas and weighted average price of natural gas and electricity
establish the importance of this study.
Income and Price Elasticities
The long- and short-run income and price elasticities of demand for
natural gas and electricity are given in Table 2. The availability of
substitutes of a good and possibility of reallocation of resources from
one good to another are usually greater in the long than in the short
run. Therefore, elasticity of demand of a good would tend to be larger
in the long run. The difference in long- and short-run elasticities can
be obtained by the magnitude of adjustment coefficient, [phi]. The
smaller the value of [phi], the lower is the possibility of
instantaneous adjustment and the larger will be the deviation of
long-run elasticity from its short-run magnitude. In this study, the
values of [phi] are estimated as .29 for electricity, .28 for natural
gas and .27 for both natural gas and electricity. This implies a slow
rate of adjustment of fuel-consuming appliances in the residential
sector of Pakistan.
This is understandable because of insufficient information and
limited opportunity of diffusion of new products in low income
countries. The low rate of increase of real per capita income in
Pakistan during the period under study was another factor that greatly
constrained the households to hold on to the existing stock of
appliances. To this we should add the argument that the repair
facilities for appliances were available at reasonable cost [3].
III. POLICY IMPLICATIONS AND CONCLUSION
The aim of this study was to estimate elasticities of residential
demand for fuel in Pakistan and to verify if they were consistent with a
priori economic theory. Values of the demand elasticities for all fuels
with respect to income and price were statistically significant and
consistent with the theory. These results on elasticities of residential
demand for fuel have important policy implications. They can help in
answering several important questions; e.g. by how much should the price
of a particular fuel increases in order to restrain the excess demand
for that fuel? What proportion of the additional income would a consumer
spend on fuel? Does he consider different types of fuels as substitutes
or complements? The answers to these questions would be critical to
authorities regulating the market for fuel. For example, our results
would allow them to estimate the required adjustment in the direction
and magnitude of a shock in the fuel sector.
Several possible suggestions for further research emerge from this
study. For one thing, all economic variables could be defined with
reference to the household and not to the consumer. Secondly, the
different blocked prices of natural gas and electricity could be used
for a single (average) price of natural gas and electricity. Finally,
the figures for urban and rural per capita income should be substituted
for national per capita income.
Appendix A
Due to the assumption of instantaneous adjustment ([phi]=l), the
coefficients of Equation 11 are long-run elasticities of demand. The
long-run elasticity of demand for fuel with respect to [Z.sub.K] is:
dln[F.sub.t] / dln[Z.sub.Kt] = d[F.sub.t] / [F.sub.t] / d[Z.sub.Kt]
/ [Z.sub.Kt] = [[lambda].sub.K] ; K = 1,..., n (A-1)
The short-run elasticity of demand can be estimated by the
following method. Assume that [X.sub.it] = [X.sub.it-1]. Equation 9 can
be written as:
ln[F.sub.t] = [phi] [l.summation over (j=1)] [[beta].sub.j]
ln[Y.sub.jt] + [phi] [m.summation over (i=1)] [[alpha].sub.i]
ln[X.sub.it] + (1-[phi]) ln[F.sub.t-1] - (1-[phi]) [u.sub.t-1] +
[phi][[member of].sub.t] + [u.sub.t] (A-2)
Corresponding to Equation 11, Equation A-2 can be written as:
ln[F.sub.t] = [phi] [n.summation over (K = 1)] [[lambda].sub.K]
ln[Z.sub.Kt] + (1-[phi]) ln[F.sub.t-1] - (1- [phi])[u.sub.t-1] +
[phi][[member of].sub.t] + [u.sub.t] (A-3)
The short-run elasticity of demand for fuel with respect to
[Z.sub.K] (from Equation A-3) will be :
dln[F.sub.t] / d[Z.sub.Kt] = d[F.sub.t] / [F.sub.t] / d[Z.sub.Kt] /
[Z.sub.Kt] = [phi][[lambda].sub.K] ; K=1,...,n (A-4)
Appendix B
The value of [phi] can be estimated by the following method:
Assume that ln [X.sub.it] = ln [X.sub.it-1] ; Eq. (9) can be
written:
ln[F.sub.t] = [phi] [l.summation over (j=1)] [[beta].sub.j]
ln[Y.sub.jt] + (1-[phi]) [m.summation over (i=1)] [[alpha].sub.i]ln
[X.sub.it] + [phi]) [m.summation over (i=1)] [[alpha].sub.i]ln
[X.sub.it] + (1-[phi]) ln[F.sub.t-1] - (1-[phi]) [m.summation over
(i=1)] [[alpha].sub.i] ln [X.sub.it] + [phi][v.sub.t] (B-1)
or ln [F.sub.t] = [phi] ([l.summation over (j=1)] [[beta].sub.j] ln
[Y.sub.jt] + [m.summation over (i=1)] [a.sub.i] ln [X.sub.it]) +
(1-[phi]) ln [F.sub.t-1] + [phi] [v.sub.t] (B-2)
Corresponding to Eq. (11), Eq. (B-2) can be written:
ln[F.sub.t] = [phi] [n.summation over (K = 1)] [[lambda].sub.K] ln
[Z.sub.Kt] + (1-[phi]) ln [F.sub.t-1] + [phi] [v.sub.t] (B-3)
The parametric estimates of Eq. (B-3) will give the value of [phi].
REFERENCES
[1.] Berndt, E. R. and G. C. Watkins. "Demand for Natural Gas:
Residential and Commercial Markets in Ontario and British
Columbia". Canadian Journal of Economies. February 1977.
[2.] Dutta, M. Econometric Methods. Cincinnati, Ohio: South-Western
Publishing Co. 1975.
[3.] Ebinger, C. K. Pakistan: Energy Planning in a Vortex.
Bloomington: Indiana University Press. 1981.
[4.] Hoffman, Lutz. "Energy Demand in Developing Countries:
Approaches to estimation and Projection". Workshop on Energy Data
of Developing Countries. Vol. 1. Paris: Organisation for Economic
Cooperation and Development. 1979.
[5.] Houthakker, S., P. Vediger, and D. Sheehan. "Dynamic
Demand Analyses for Gaasoline and Residential Electricity".
American Journal of Agricultural Economics. No. 2. May 1974. pp.
412-418.
[6.] Iqbal, Mahmood. "Estimates of Gasoline Demand for
Automobiles in Pakistan". Canada: Simon Fraser University. 1983.
(Unpublished)
[7.] Javed, Anees. "Household Demand for Natural Gas in
Pakistan". The Pakistan Development Review. Winter 1978.
[8.] Koutsoyiannis, A. Theory of Econometrics. The Macmillan Press
Ltd. 1973.
[9.] Murray P., R. Spann, L. Pulley and E. Beavris. "The
Demand for Electricity in Virginia". The Review of Economics and
Statistics. October 1978.
[10.] Pakistan. Ministry of Finance. Pakistan Economic Survey,
1980-81. Islamabad.
[11.] Pakistan. Central Statistical Office. 25 Years of Pakistan in
Statistics, 1947-72. Karachi.
[12.] Pakistan. Central Statistical Office. Household Income and
Expenditure Survey, 1971-72. Karachi.
[13.] Pakistan. Directorate General of Energy Resources. Energy
Year Book, 1981. Islamabad.
[14.] Pakistan. Energy Resources Cell. Energy Data Book, 1979.
Islamabad.
[15.] Parikh, J. K. Energy Systems and Development: Constraints,
Demand and Supply of Energy for Developing Regions. Delhi: Oxford
University Press. 1980.
[16.] Pindyck, R. S. The Structure of World Energy Demand.
Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press. 1979.
[17.] Riaz, T. "A Long-Range Energy Sector Plan for
Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review. Autumn 1981.
[18.] Taylor, Lester. "The Demand for Electricity: A
Survey". The Bell Journal of Economics. Spring 1975.
[19.] Word Bank. Pakistan: Issues and Options in the Energy Sector.
Report No. 2953-Pak. Washington, D.C. 1980.
(1) The capacity of appliances are usually measured in KWH. Here we
have converted one KWH into one Tone of Equivalent (TOE) by dividing the
former with a factor of 4200 [14].
(2) Small Roman letters stand for logarithms of economic variables.
The logarithm specification yields better results in terms of the
significance of the estimated parameters. It has the added advantage
that the coefficients are interpreted as demand elasticities [8].
(3) See Appendix A.
(4) See Appendix B.
(5) The overall climate of the Indus basin of Pakistan, in which
the largest urban centres are located, is hot (arid) and even humid for
about 8 to 9 months in the year.
MAHMOOD IQBAL, The author is a Ph.D. candidate in Economics at
Simon Fraser University, Canada. This study was initiated when the
author was a Visiting Economist at the Applied Economics Research
Centre, University of Karachi, Pakistan. He is deeply indebted to
Professor Mahmood H. Khan for giving valuable suggestions and improving
the style of the paper. He is grateful to Dr. T. M. Heaps for his
detailed comments. The author alone is responsible for any errors or
omissions.
Table 1
Regression Results of Demand for Fuel in Pakistan
(1959-60 to 1980-81)
Regres-
sion
Equation Intercept Income
I. Gas: OLS 1 -5.457 2.601
(1.184) (3.772)
Electricity : OLS 2 -17.253 2.379
(3.713) (3.419)
: GLS 3 -10.650 2.007
(4.537) (5.581)
II. Gas: OLS 4 -7.848 2.749
(1.819) (3.959)
Electricity : OLS 5 -23.555 2.946
(4.028) (4.659)
: GLS 6 -10.887 1.988
(4.657) (5.557)
III. Gas plus
Electricity : OLS 7 -27.508 2.690
(5.098) (3.327)
: GLS 8 -19.302 2.041
(5.070) (3.523)
IV. Gas plus
Electricity : OLS 9 -18.347 2.729
(2.208) (3.419)
: GLS 10 -17.709 2.024
(4.285) (3.597)
Average
Price of Gas
Price of Price of and Elec-
Gas Electricity tricity
I. Gas: OLS -1.151 -0.324 --
(4.757) (1.308)
Electricity : OLS -0.937 0.246 --
(3.840) (0.985)
: GLS 0.113 -0.126 --
(1.050) (1.321)
II. Gas: OLS -1.303 -- --
(6.025)
Electricity : OLS -- -0.216 --
(0.735)
: GLS -- -0.087 --
(0.961)
III. Gas plus
Electricity : OLS -1.135 0.069 --
(4.001) (0.239)
: GLS -0.053 -0.156 --
(0.274) (0.889)
IV. Gas plus
Electricity : OLS -- -- -1.083
(3.267)
: GLS -- -- -0.216
(1.690)
Tempera-
ture Trend D-W [R.sup.2]
I. Gas: OLS -0.392 1.029 1.71 0.99
(0.786) (9.807)
Electricity : OLS 0.308 0.136 0.89 0.97
(0.612) (1.290)
: GLS 0.216 0.296 2.53 0.72
(2.572) (3.240) [??] = 0.26
II. Gas: OLS 0.424 1.066 1.61 0.99
(0.834) (10.312)
Electricity : OLS 1.183 -0.032 0.68 0.94
(1.959) (0.251)
: GLS 0.188 0.281 2.40 0.72
(2.304) (3.309) [??] = 0.20
III. Gas plus
Electricity : OLS 0.304 1.157 0.97 0.97
(0.520) (1.278)
: GLS 0.210 0.309 2.22 0.59
(1.327) (2.716) [??] = 0.11
IV. Gas plus
Electricity : OLS 0.634 0.039 0.70 0.96
(0.980) (0.303)
: GLS 0.201 0.306 2.21 0.58
(1.320) (2.630) [??] = 0.10
Note: Figures in parentheses are t-statistics.
Table 2
Long Run and Short-Run Income and Price Elasticities
Natural Gas plus
Natural Gas Electricity Electricity
Income:
Long Run 2.74 2.94 2.77
Short Run 0.77 0.85 0.73
Price:
Long Run -1.30 -0.22 -1.08
Short Run -0.36 -0.06 -0.29
Sources: Table 1.
Appendices A and B.