Banking and public policy: too big to fail.
Kaufman, George G.
I. INTRODUCTION
I have devoted much of my professional career to the study of
banking (in the broadest sense to include all channels of financial
intermediation operating either in the sunlight or in the shadows), its
management, and its interaction with public policy. On the whole, it has
been a wonderful and exciting journey. Banking and finance are at the
very heart of most industrial economies. As has been vividly reinforced
in recent years, what happens in the financial sector may affect not
only the remainder of the financial sector but also the real economy,
particularly on the downside, and vice versa. What happens in the real
sector feeds back on the financial sector.
But, at times, I feel that economists know only little, if any,
more about banking and its relationship with the rest of the economy
than we did some 50 years earlier. Financial crises have neither been
reduced in either magnitude or frequency, no less disappeared (Reinhart
and Rogoff 2009). Indeed, in some countries, they have become more
frequent and deeper. The recent financial crisis from 2007 to 2010 in
the United States and many, but not all, industrial countries, commonly
now referred to as the great financial crisis (GFC), may well be the
most serious and damaging in U.S. history. It has been a rough and
costly ride. This should have humbled most of us.
In this article, I describe what I believe to be one of the, if not
the, major public policy issues in banking today--"too big to
fail" (TBTF). Although most ideas are taken from my earlier papers,
all are not mine. I have borrowed freely and shamelessly from my
colleagues. If nothing else, correctly conducted plagiarism can be
efficient.
As noted, banking and finance are important in nearly all
economies. For the United States, income created by the financial sector
accounts for about 8% of GDR Not only are banking and finance important
in most countries, but, at least until the GFC, the sector was growing
rapidly (Artill, Hou, and Sarkar 2014). This had important collateral
benefits and costs. A number of studies have reported that the broader,
deeper, and more liquid the financial system is, the greater is the
growth rate in real aggregate income in that country (Barth, Caprio, and
Levine 2012; Caprio 2013). Some more recent studies, however, found that
these results may be sensitive to a number of factors, including the
time period examined and the state of a country's economic
development (Gambacorta, Yang, and Tsatsaronis 2014; Levine, Loayza, and
Beck 2000). Losses in aggregate income from financial problems and
crises in any country may be greater than, equal to, or less than the
gains in income from greater and more efficient financial activities
both before and after the crises. Which it is determines the societal
contribution of the financial sector and the success or failure of our
policies. Moreover, as observed in recent years, abrupt changes in the
health of the financial sector have important societal (income and
wealth distribution) and macroeconomic implications. That is, not only
aggregate wealth but also the distribution of wealth is importantly
affected by banking and financial behavior.
TBTF goes under many different names, such as
* Too big to liquidate;
* Too complex to liquidate;
* Too big to manage;
* Too complex to manage;
* Too big to prosecute; and
* Too big to jail.
Thus, the term means different things to different people. But, by
any name, it suggests that the big are getting special treatment that
the small are not. Other than those who benefit directly, for reasons
discussed later, few like the concept and what it represents and there
have been many attempts to kill it. But, like vampires and Moby Dick,
TBTF refuses to stay dead for very long and returns to haunt our
existence. As a result, TBTF has become one of the most important public
policy issues affecting banking and financial markets today. Indeed, the
issue has migrated beyond economics and finance to religion. The
Financial Times of June 18, 2014, reported that the Archbishop of
Canterbury has warned that banks are still "too big to fail"
(Arnold 2014). Apparently, large banks should repent for the sin of
largeness!
In theory, a bank fails and is legally closed (its charter revoked)
when the value of its liabilities exceeds that of its assets, so that
its net worth is negative. The financial stake of the bank's equity
shareholders is wiped out and the unsecured creditors, who have not
managed to run, share in the remaining losses according to their legal
priority. But, in practice, some troubled big banks or other large
financial firms may not be failed and closed when they become insolvent
as would other banks or other financial firms. They might be permitted
to continue to operate by their regulators or the government, their
creditors would not suffer losses and not flee the institution, and
their shareholders' stake possibly not wiped out totally.
Alternatively, select insolvent large firms, mostly, but not exclusively
(think General Motors and Chrysler) large financials may be failed but
subject to a resolution process that differs from the resolution process
usually applied to other insolvent firms in the same industry (e.g.,
federal bankruptcy code [FBC]) with respect to loss allocation.
The government has enacted special TBTF resolution regimes for
select firms, for example, a systemic risk exemption (SRE) or override
to least cost resolution (LCR), the usual failure resolution process for
chartered banks in the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement
Act (FDICIA) of 1991, and the Orderly Liquidation Authority (OLA) in
place of bankruptcy for large bank holding companies and large non-bank
financial companies in the recently enacted Dodd-Frank Act Wall Street
Reform and Consumer Protection Act (DFA) of 2010. In TBTF resolutions,
the firm is failed but some or all creditors and other in-the-money
stakeholders may receive more than they would under the usual (no-TBTF)
resolution process, which is likely to impose losses. Loss allocation is
not determined by the usual rules. The difference between the amount
paid to creditors at resolution and the corresponding lesser pro-rata
recovery amount received is the loss--"protection" or
"bail-out"--funded by a third party, for example, the
government.
Why is there a perceived need for TBTF resolutions? In the
resolution of most insolvent firms, losses are spread pro-rata over all
creditor claims of the same legal priority. But there is fear in some
quarters that losses to some or all uninsured and unsecured creditors at
large financial institutions will generate unacceptable large adverse
externalities (collateral damage) to financial and economic stability.
These firms, and banks in particular, are structured in ways that make
them provide critical/essential services to the economy that likely
would be discontinued or continued on a smaller scale if the firm became
insolvent and was resolved the usual way with losses to
depositors/creditors. This is because
* Bank deposits collectively comprise the largest share of the
country's money supply and are the primary medium of exchange;
* Bank deposits represent a significant portion of the
public's most liquid assets;
* Bank deposits are held in a wide range of amounts, including very
small amounts by a large proportion of the population, including
households of limited financial means and expertise;
* Banks are major providers of credit to households, business
firms, and governments;
* Banks have a large proportion of their liabilities in very
short-term debt that is shorter in maturity on average than their assets
and that can easily be withdrawn or not renewed (run);
* Banks operate much of the payments system;
* Some individual banks are large relative to GDP, and individual
bank asset size and market concentration have increased greatly through
time;
* Banks are closely interconnected with each other through
interbank deposits, loans, and derivative transactions;
* Dealer banks are particularly closely interconnected with large
financial institutions;
* Bank assets are widely perceived to be less transparent than
assets of most nonbank firms;
* Large banks tend to have complex organizational structures and
operate cross-border both nationally and internationally and are thus
subject to different legal and regulatory jurisdictions; and
* Ownership and location of bank assets can be transferred quickly
and at low costs (Bliss and Kaufman 2011).
The view that banks are "special" was clearly summarized
recently by William Dudley, the President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York, as follows:
... the root cause of "too big to fail" is the fact that
in our financial system as it exists today, the failure of large complex
financial firms generate large, undesirable externalities. These include
disruption of the stability of the financial system and its ability to
provide credit and other essential financial services to households and
businesses. When this happens, not only is the financial sector
disrupted, but its troubles cascade over into the real economy. (Dudley
2012, 1)
II. TREATMENT OF TROUBLED LARGE BANKS
If large banks experience difficulties and threaten to become
insolvent, regulators (the government) have two options to avoid or
limit the feared collateral damage. First, they could prevent the
failure and the accompanying losses to depositors/creditors and possibly
also on a more limited scale to shareholders. The firms are rescued and
continue to live. Second, they could permit the firms to fail, but
protect the creditors either partially or totally. That is, the firm and
shareholders die, but all creditors need not.
In a rescue, firms are rescued from insolvency through the
injection of sufficient explicit or implicit capital by the government
to maintain or restore positive net worth. Injection of explicit capital
generally takes the form of preferred stock and of implicit capital in
the form of guarantees of depositor and creditor claims. No losses
accrue to any party but shareholders. Senior management may or may not
be changed, and essential services are maintained. Old
shareholders' interests are partially or totally wiped out, for
example, the TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program) in the United States
in 2008 and the RFC (Reconstruction Finance Corporation) in the United
States in 1933. A more descriptive and accurate name for firms that are
likely to be rescued than TBTF is too big to not rescue (TBTNR).
At times, it is necessary to protect fully only some but not all
creditors or all creditors only partially to restrict the collateral
damage to amounts the economy may be expected to absorb without serious
damage. In this case, the troubled firm may not be rescued but failed by
the regulators, particularly if the resolution regime gives the
regulators the authority to select the creditors to be protected against
loss and by how much. At times, the FDIC failed a bank, but fully
protected all depositors, and other unsecured creditors explicitly
insured or not. If some depositors or creditors will not be protected,
some market discipline is maintained and a failure resolution may be
preferred to a rescue. But this process requires an appropriate
resolution regime. As the firm is failed, it was never strictly speaking
TBTF. If the bank is failed and, because of fear of excessive collateral
damage, all depositors and creditors are fully protected, the bank may
be TBTNR but not TBTF. It is ironic that the term TBTF was first applied
to the Continental Illinois National Bank in Chicago, the seventh
largest bank in the country at the time, which was failed by the
regulators in 1984. The shareholders were effectively wiped out.
There appears to be considerable confusion between rescues and
failure resolution. For example, the multinational Financial Stability
Board recently stated that
The "too-big-to-fail" (TBTF) problem arises when the
threatened failure of a SIFI leaves public authorities with no option
but to bail it out using public funds to avoid financial instability and
economic damage.... The SIFI framework sets out recommendations for
improving the authorities' ability to resolve such institutions in
an orderly manner, without exposing tea-payers to loss, while
maintaining continuity of their vital economic functions. This may
require changes to resolution regimes. (Financial Stability Board,
September 2, 2013, 27, emphasis added)
Likewise, a recent academic paper argues that
The too-big-to-fail (TBTF) doctrine postulates that the government
will not allow large financial institutions to fail if their failure
would cause significant disruption to the financial system and economic
activity. It is commonly claimed that, because of the TBTF doctrine,
large financial institutions and their investors expect the government
to back the debts of these institutions should they encounter financial
difficulty. (Acharya, Auginer, and Warburton 2014, 1, emphasis added)
In both statements, the first sentence describes a rescue and the
second sentence a failure resolution, but the two are not related.
Changing the resolution regime, as many reform proposals do, does not
affect the rescue process, only the resolution process. The remainder of
the article discusses only the resolution of failed or dead firms. For
banks, their death is officially recognized when their charter is
revoked. Resolution is frequently confused with rescue in which the firm
is not failed but survives, though under modified ownership and
management. In the recent crisis years, rescues greatly outnumbered
failure resolutions for comparable troubled firms.
III. COST OF TBTF POLICIES
As noted, TBTF resolution regimes are designed to protect some or
all explicitly uninsured and unsecured depositors/creditors. Unless
offset by ex post correctly computed premiums, the direct cost of the
protection is shifted from the depositors/creditors to third parties
that are likely to be more broadly based and dispersed and therefore
often less able to lobby against this shift, for example, government
(taxpayers) and/or private parties (other banks). In addition, there are
indirect costs that do not appear until later. Underpriced insurance
encourages depositors/creditors to reduce their due diligence and
monitoring of their banks and accept a lower deposit rate than if there
was no protection. As is well recognized, banks respond to the reduced
monitoring and lower cost of funds by increasing their risk exposures.
The resulting bank losses will only become visible later. Likewise, the
lower cost of funds gives TBTF banks a competitive advantage over
non-TBTF (smaller) banks, whose deposits are not expected to be
protected and must offer a higher unsubsidized deposit rate. (1) The
resulting allocation of both financial and real resources is likely to
be inefficient. Because these effects do not occur immediately but
through time, the costs of TBTF promise to also increase through time.
Lastly, because all banks do not serve the same markets, they are
likely to have different legislators "guarding" their
well-being. These guardians may be expected to insure that troubled
banks in their "protection domains" receive the same benefits
as other banks in other domains, even if they are smaller in size than
the other banks. As a result, ceteris paribus, the number of assumed
TBTF banks may be expected to increase through time with an accompanying
increase in societal costs, as occurred between 1984 and 1991. But the
higher the visible costs, the greater is the likely opposition to a
continuation of TBTF resolutions.
IV. BENEFITS OF TBTF POLICIES
Deposits in a failed bank to be protected under TBTF resolution may
be expected to be those for which the societal benefits estimated by the
regulators exceed the estimated societal costs. The largest benefit is
likely to be the estimated reduction in collateral damage from what
would have occurred if the protection had not been provided. A review of
past TBTF resolutions, however, shows that these benefits have not been
quantified very rigorously. Rather, they are sized by subjective broad
generalizations. For example, the decision to protect all depositors and
creditors of the Continental Illinois National Bank in Chicago when it
failed in 1984 was justified by the regulators as follows. C.T. Conover,
who was the Comptroller of the Currency at the time of the failure,
testified before Congress at the time that
Had the Continental failed and been treated in a way in which
depositors and creditors were not made whole, we could very well have
seen a national, if not an international, financial crisis, the
dimensions of which were difficult to imagine. None of us wanted to find
out. (Conover 1984, 288)
Maybe they did not want to experience the actual crisis, but they
should at least have tried to estimate the damage. John La Ware, a
Governor of the Federal Reserve System, later testified before Congress
that
The only analogy that I can think of for the failure of a major
international institution of great size is a meltdown of a nuclear
generating plant like Chernobyl. (LaWare 1991, 34)
It would have been highly unlikely that any estimated costs of
providing the protection would have exceeded the estimated benefits of
"saving the world" and protection not provided. As Federal
Reserve Governor Daniel Tarullo observed
... No matter what its general economic policy principles, a
government faced with the possibility of a cascading financial crisis
that can bring down its national economy tends to err on the side of
intervention. (Tarullo 2009, 2)
Moreover, the benefits are recognized immediately and decline
through time, while the recognized immediate costs are small but
increase through time. Today triumphs over tomorrow! This is a classic
time inconsistency problem in economics. Thus, TBTF resolutions were
applied to large banks far more often than not. (2)
But, through time, the regulators' estimates of such large
benefits raised doubts, were increasingly questioned, lost considerable
credibility, and were implicitly downsized. At the same time, the
increasingly large delayed costs became more visible. The effective
benefit-cost ratio declined through time after the TBTF resolution was
applied. At the time of a failure, benefits tend to be overestimated and
costs underestimated and the greater the crisis, the larger the
perceived collateral damage and the greater the overestimate of the
benefits of protection.
Another benefit of TBTF resolutions accrues to the regulators.
Recognizing a bank insolvency and failing the bank is politically
unpopular and depicts regulators in a bad light. They are charged to
keep banks safe and open and are evaluated by doing so. By hiding losses
and keeping insolvent banks open and operating, TBTF provides political
cover for regulators from public criticism, at least in the short run.
Likewise, as failing a bank reduces the popularity of regulators among
bankers, not failing a bank or delaying the decision does not
necessarily reduce the likelihood of the regulator being able to use the
revolving door in the future to gain employment with a bank at
considerably higher compensation.
V. ALTERNATIVE TBTF RESOLUTION REGIMES
TBTF resolution regimes differ according to the type and amount of
depositor/creditor claims protected. On the one extreme, no accounts are
protected. This may be termed a no-TBTF resolution. On the other
extreme, all depositor/creditor claims are protected. This may be termed
a 100%-TBTF resolution. But, depending on the benefit-cost trade off,
regulators may wish to protect some but not all depositor/creditor
claims, for example, demand deposits but not time deposits. Demand
deposits may be viewed as a more important part of the payments system
than are time deposits and losses to them may do more economic damage
than do equivalent losses to time deposits. Protecting some but not all
claims in a failure resolution may be viewed as a hybrid TBTF
resolution. Thus, TBTF resolutions are not only black and white but come
in different shades of gray.
Hybrid resolutions are frequently misclassified as no-TBTF
resolutions. For example, ex-Congressman Barney Frank, the former
Chairman of the House Banking Committee and the coauthor of the
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act that, among
other things, was intended "to end too big to fail," has
argued that in a no-TBTF (no protection) resolution
... shareholders are wiped out, the CEO is fired, and the
institution no longer exists, and the regulators may, at that point, the
FDIC, pay off some debts if it is necessary to prevent a downward
spiral, but any penny paid out must be recouped from the large financial
institutions. (Frank 2011, emphasis added).
As some creditor claims are protected, I consider this is a
hybrid-TBTF resolution, not a no-TBTF resolution. However, Frank appears
to assume that because protecting these claims avoids a damaging
downward spiral in the economy, the protection is a necessity, not
arbitrary.
Likewise, Fed Governor Daniel Tarullo, who is in charge of bank
supervision and regulation at the Board, has argued that
A fourth reform, intended to ensure that no firm is too big to
fail, was the creation by Dodd-Frank of orderly liquidation authority.
Under this authority, the FDIC can impose losses on a failed
institution's shareholders and creditors ... while avoiding runs by
short-term counterparties.... [F]or the resolution mechanism to be
credible ex-ante and effective ex-post, the capital and liability
structure of major firms must be able to absorb losses without either
threatening short-term funding liabilities or necessitating injections
of capital from the government. (Tarullo 2012, 2, emphasis added)
But the only way short-term counterparties will not run when the
solvency of a bank is in doubt is if they were expected to be protected.
Again, this represents a hybrid TBTF resolution, not a no-TBTF. Tarullo
is also confusing a no-TBTF resolution with a hybrid resolution, in
which stability in short-term claims is given great weight and viewed as
a necessity. Thus, no-TBTF resolutions are not defined equally by
everyone.
Moreover, differences in definition of TBTF resolutions also arise
depending on who finances any protection provided. Some argue that
protection is TBTF only if it is financed by the government. But Peter
Wallison, a frequent commentator on financial issues, argues that
... the source of funds for a bailout is not the real issue. The
possibility of a creditor bailout creates moral hazard, no matter where
the bailout funds originate. and it is moral hazard that provides the
largest batiks or other large financial firms with competitive
advantages. (Wallison 2012, emphasis added)
Thus, as long as any funds are shifted from third parties to
depositors/creditors to compensate them for losses, even only if private
sources and not the government is the provider, the resolutions are
effectively considered TBTF resolutions.
Differences in definition generate confusion as to who is being
protected by TBTF, by whom, and for what reason. As different observers
may see different parties as being protected for the same named TBTF
resolution, the task of reaching agreement on how to modify or end TBTF
altogether becomes more difficult and awaits greater clarity and
agreement in definitions.
VI. WILL DFA KILL TBTF?
A primary objective of the DFA is to kill TBTF. But past experience
suggests that like vampires, even if killed, TBTF may not stay dead for
very long unless killed with a wooden stake or equivalent (depending on
the story) stabbed through the heart. Does DFA give the regulators the
right cross and can the regulators find TBTF's heart to succeed?
That would depend. Arguments can be made on either side.
Two arguments suggest that TBTF may be killed for good. In its
Title 2, DFA establishes the OLA to resolve the failure of select
troubled large bank holding companies and nonbank financial firms, whose
resolution by the FBC would threaten financial stability. DFA gives the
FDIC, as receiver, the ability to protect some uninsured and unsecured
claimants, but only if doing so would reduce the resolution cost to the
FDIC. However, the earlier enacted FDICIA permits the FDIC to also
protect claims at chartered banks if doing so reduces the adverse
effects on financial stability. OLA does not permit this. Thus, OLA
provides one less rationale for providing protection to large nonbank
financial firms and limits the potential loss to the FDIC. More
importantly, OLA permits regulators to close (place in receivership)
covered firms sooner than under the FBC. The regulators can do so when
they perceive a threat of default by the firm rather than waiting for an
actual default. The faster a closure, the smaller are any losses likely
to be and the less reluctant would regulators be to close the firm.
On the other hand, it should not be very difficult for regulators
to argue that by reducing potential financial instability through
providing additional protection, the cost to the FDIC of resolving a
firm is lowered. Thus, they are likely to do so and effectively apply a
TBTF resolution. Likewise, the DFA does not increase the incentives of
regulators to not only "talk-the-talk" but also to
"walk-the-walk" in implementing sanctions and denying
protection and TBTF resolution to covered institutions. Thus, there is
little to lessen the severe principal-agent problem between taxpayers
and the regulators that contributed significantly to the recent and also
earlier banking crises. Regulators did not have the political will to
take strong unpopular actions that could reduce the cost of resolutions.
It is the lack of political will by regulators, not the lack of
appropriate regulations, that makes killing TBTF difficult and permits
its resurrection when killed (Kaufman and Malliaris 2010). Prompt
corrective action and LCR provisions in FDICIA look better on paper than
in action. Lastly, in crises, regardless of the letter or spirit of the
law, policy-makers are likely to act to minimize their own short-term
costs. Short-term survival is key. Ad-hocery is likely to triumph! TBTF
by any name will survive.
VII. HOW DOES DFA AFFECT RESCUES (TBTNR)?
In 2008, rescues were used in large volume to provide assistance to
many financial institutions through both direct Treasury funding and a
broadened Federal Reserve discount window (Section 13(3) lending)
(Garcia, forthcoming). Title 11 of DFA restricts the Fed's use of
its discount window to provide emergency only through broadly based
programs rather than directing the aid to individual institutions. It
must also receive prior approval from the Secretary of the Treasury for
such assistance. Again, the regulators' will to accept these
restrictions during a future crisis may be questioned. Lastly, the DFA
requires large complex and systemically important institutions to
develop a road map or "living will" that shows how the
institution is internally organized and how, if it became insolvent, it
could be resolved efficiently. This plan must be approved by the
regulators. If accurate, this knowledge should make both rescues and
failure resolutions more efficient. But the criticisms by the regulators
of the first round of wills submitted by the largest banks suggest that
there may be a long and slow learning process (Board of Governors 2014).
VIII. WHY REVIEW THE PAST TO DEVELOP REFORMS FOR THE FUTURE
Every crisis brings forth calls for reforms. But, it must be
remembered the "reforms" are only changes that one likes.
Changes that one does not like are "deforms." To design reform
solutions correctly, one need first to correctly identify the
problems(s). Getting it right requires knowing what went wrong.
The Spanish-American philosopher George Santayana (1863-1952)
warned us that "those who cannot remember the past are condemned to
repeat it." This is an optimistic and hopeful view. It suggests
that while the past was not always optimum, the future could be made
better. What is required to develop the right reforms is to study and
learn from history. But what do those policymakers who do remember
history do? Unfortunately, I believe more pessimistically that those who
can remember the past are condemned to agonize first and then to repeat
it.
IX. CONCLUSION
Technically, TBTF describes a resolution regime in which some or
all depositor/creditor claimants of failed large firms, mostly banks and
nonbank financial firms, are partially or totally protected against loss
from insolvency (negative net worth) by the government in order to
reduce collateral damage to other firms and the economy from increased
financial instability. But TBTF can incur significant societal costs.
Reducing the probability and magnitude of loss to these claimants
permits large firms to obtain funding at lower cost. This both
incentizes the affected banks to increase their risk exposures and gives
them a competitive advantage over smaller no-TBTF banks. The benefits of
reducing collateral damage tend to be perceived to be large at the time
of a crisis and decrease over time thereafter. But the regulators'
estimates of the collateral damage caused by not providing protections
are generally highly subjective and not rigorously developed. They tend
to overstate the actual reduction in collateral losses from the
protection. The costs, on the other hand, are small at first, but
increase over time. This results in a strong bias toward providing
protection in a TBTF resolution.
But resolutions need not only protect either all claimants or no
claimants. Some resolutions may protect only accounts for which the
benefits are perceived to exceed the cost but not others for which the
benefits are smaller and the costs higher. These may be classified as
hybrid-TBTF resolutions. Hybrids are often misclassified. Hybrids in
which accounts are protected, because the benefits are perceived to be
much greater than the costs, are not infrequently classified incorrectly
as no-TBTF institutions. Likewise, protecting some accounts that are
perceived to provide critical services is frequently not considered a
TBTF resolution. Thus, there is a disagreement about the definition of
TBTF. One person's TBTF resolution may be another's no-TBTF
resolution. It may be possible to "kill" TBTF by defining it
away.
The article also differentiates between resolutions and rescues. In
rescues, the firm is not killed. Equity support is provided by the
government generally in exchange for an ownership stake and managerial
control. As the firm is kept solvent, all depositors/creditors are fully
protected. In failure resolutions, net worth is negative. The firm is
killed. But some or all depositors/creditors are not. They may be
partially or fully protected by the government (FDIC) in order to limit
collateral damage. If perceived to be so protected, the firm while alive
may obtain funding at lower cost, both giving it a competitive advantage
over smaller firms that are not expected to be protected and incentizing
it to increase its risk exposure. The benefits of being classified as
TBTF tend to be seen first and the costs only later. Moreover,
regulators tend to overestimate the benefits and underestimate the
costs, particularly in crisis periods. This results in greater and more
frequent use of TBTF resolutions. But as costs increase and become more
visible, opposition has increased and the continuation of TBTF
resolutions has become a major public policy issue. But TBTF has been
difficult to kill for good, despite numerous attempts to do so. Like
vampires, it is likely to haunt us for years to come.
ABBREVIATIONS
DFA: Dodd-Frank Act Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act
FBC: Federal Bankruptcy Code
FDICIA: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act
GAO: Government Accountability Office
GFC: Great Financial Crisis
LCR: Least Cost Resolution
OLA: Orderly Liquidation Authority
RFC: Reconstruction Finance Corporation
SRE: Systemic Risk Exemption
TARP: Troubled Asset Relief Program
TBTF: Too Big to Fail
TBTNR: Too Big to Not Rescue
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12169
REFERENCES
Acharya, V., D. Anginer, and A. J. Warburton. "The End of
Market Discipline?" Working Paper, Stern School of Business, New
York University, June 2014.
Arnold, M. "Archbishop of Canterbury Warns Banks Are Still
'Too Big to Fail'." Financial Times, June 18, 2014.
Artill, S., D. Hou, and A. Sarkar. "Components of U.S.
Financial Sector Growth, 1950-2013." Economic Policy Review
(Federal Reserve Bank of New York), March 2014.
Barth, J. R., G. Caprio Jr., and R. Levine. Rethinking Bank
Regulation. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2006.
--. Guardians of Finance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2012.
Bliss, R. R., and G. G. Kaufman. "Resolving Insolvent Large
Complex Financial Institutions: A Better Way." The Banking Law
Journal, 128(4), 2011, 339-63.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and FDIC.
"Agencies Provide Feedback on Second Round Resolution Plans of
'First-Wave' Filers." Joint Press Release, Washington,
DC, August 5, 2014.
Caprio, G., Jr. "Financial Regulation after the Crisis."
Special Paper 226, Financial Markets Group, London School of Economics.
November 2013.
Conover, C. T. "Testimony." Inquiry into the Continental
Illinois Corp. and Continental Illinois National Bank: Hearing before
the Subcommittee on Financial Institutions Supervision, Regulation, and
Insurance of Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs. 98-111.
U.S. House of Representatives, 98th Congress, 2nd Session, September
18-19 and October 4, 1984.
Dudley, W. "Solving the Too Big to Fail Problem." Speech,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York, November 12, 2012.
Financial Stability Board. Report: Progress and Next Steps towards
Ending "Too-Big-to-Fail" (TBTF), September 2, 2013.
Frank, B. "Testimony." Subcommittee on Financial
Institutions and Consumer Credit, U.S. House of Representatives (No.
122-37), Washington, DC, June 14, 2011.
Gambacorta, L., J. Yang, and K. Tsatsaronis. "Financial
Structure and Growth." BIS Quarterly Review, March 2014,21-35.
Garcia, G. G. H. "The U.S. Financial Crisis and the Great
Recession--Counting the Costs," in The Great Financial Crisis: A
Retrospective, edited by James Barth and George G. Kaufman. Singapore:
World Scientific and Now Publishers, forthcoming.
Kaufman, G. G., and A. G. Malliaris "The Financial Crisis of
2007-2009: Missing Financial Regulations or Absentee Regulators,"
in Lessons from the Financial Crisis, edited by R. W. Kolb. Hoboken, NJ:
John Wiley & Sons, 2010, 337-44.
LaWare, J. "Testimony." Economic Implications of the
"Too-Big-to-Fail" Policy: Hearing before the Subcommittee on
Economic Stabilization of Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban
Affairs. U.S. House of Representatives, 102nd Congress, 1st Session, May
9, 1991.
Levine, R., N. Loayza, and T. Beck. "Financial Intermediation
and Growth: Causality and Causes." Journal of Monetary Economics,
46(1), 2000, 31-77.
Reinhart, C. M., and K. S. Rogoff. This Time Is Different.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.
Strahan, P. "Too Big to Fail: Causes, Consequences, and Policy
Responses." Annual Review of Financial Economics, 5, 2013, 43-61.
Tarullo, D. "Confronting Too Big to Fail." Speech, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC, October 21,
2009.
--. "Regulatory Reform since the Financial Crisis."
Speech, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington,
DC, May 2, 2012.
U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO). "Large Bank
Holding Companies: Expectations of Government Support." GAO-14-621.
GAO, Washington, DC, July 2014.
Wallison, P. "Too Big to Ignore: The Future of Bailouts and
Dodd-Frank after the 2012 Election (Policy Studies)." American
Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC, October 24, 2012.
(1.) A recent study by the Government Accountability Office (GAO)
found that large bank holding companies had a funding advantage over
smaller bank holding companies during the financial crisis, but the
advantage appears to have disappeared afterwards (U.S. Government
Accountability Office 2014).
(2.) A good review of TBTF appears in Strahan (2013).
GEORGE G. KAUFMAN, This article is a revised version of ray
presidential address to the Western Economic Association in Denver,
Colorado, on June 29, 2014.
Kaufman: John Smith Professor of Finance and Economics, Department
of Finance, Loyola University Chicago, Chicago, IL 60611. Phone
312-915-7075, Fax 312-915-8508, E-mail gkaufma@luc.edu; Consultant,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago, IL