首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月08日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The labor market in the art sector of Baroque Rome.
  • 作者:Etro, Federico ; Marchesi, Silvia ; Pagani, Laura
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2015
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 关键词:Artists;Arts;Labor market;Wage gap

The labor market in the art sector of Baroque Rome.


Etro, Federico ; Marchesi, Silvia ; Pagani, Laura 等


"Caravaggio said that it takes as much manufacture to do a good painting of flowers as of human figures." Vincenzo Giustiniani, Letter on painting (1620-1630)

I. INTRODUCTION

A wide literature in cultural economics, surveyed by Ashenfelter and Graddy (2003), has analyzed the pricing of art through hedonic regressions based on auction data. This analysis is focused on secondary markets and sheds light on the determinants of art value, the life cycle of painters (Galenson and Weinberg 2000), or the sources of artistic success (Hellmanzik 2010). (1) Similar techniques can be applied to historical primary markets to shed light on the determinants of the earnings of the artists and of the characteristics of their commissions. Only recently, however, art historical studies have put together wide datasets on prices of the artistic commissions during the Renaissance and the Baroque age (see De Marchi and Van Miegroet 2006; O'Malley 2005; Spear and Sohm 2010) and economic investigations are now possible. (2) In this article, we analyze the seventeenth-century market for painters based in Rome through a unique dataset on paintings of the Baroque age, which allows us to focus on the (occupational) choice of the artistic genre by painters and on equilibrium pricing across art sectors.

The most impressive and rapid phenomenon of the seventeenth-century art industry has been the innovative form of artistic differentiation that led to the mass production of new genres of paintings. Besides traditional figurative paintings, mainly on religious, mythological, and historical subjects, and besides portraits, the new genres of the Baroque art market included what were considered "minor genres" such as still lifes (reproducing animals, fruits, flowers, and lifeless objects), landscapes (reproducing the countryside or the urban environment), so-called genre paintings (reproducing daily life scenes), and battles (reproducing fights without necessarily a specific historical content). Each genre represented a specific sector of production (with limited substitutability between genres on the demand side), and painters either specialized in one or few genres or they could switch between them according to market opportunities.

The prestige of the genres was rigorously ranked in the artistic culture of the time, and the most dignified and worthy subjects were those depicting creative compositions of idealized human figures, as in religious and mythological paintings. Behind these, a relative preference was reserved for landscape paintings, which had to represent idealized views of the world. Compositions of the daily aspects of reality, the so-called genre paintings, were at a lower level in the ranking of the art commissioners, while the least worthy genres were those imitating reality without idealization like portraits and, at the lowest level, still lifes. (3) Such a ranking of preferences for the genres was well understood between art collectors, art critics, and artists, and later codified by the art academies. A preliminary view of the data on primary sales of paintings suggests that this hierarchy was also associated with a clear ranking of payments among the different genres. Price differentials between them were sizable: the average prices in Roman silver scudi were, respectively, 17 scudi for still lifes, 25 for genre paintings, 39 for portraits, 66 for landscapes, and 240 for all the figurative paintings (with further differences between subcategories). Paintings of different genres obviously differed in many respects (e.g., size, technique, support, and destination) and price differentials did not necessarily reflect differences in the effective compensation of the painters. However, as long as the market was competitive and painters could freely choose whether to specialize in one genre 3 or switch between genres to exploit profitable opportunities, we can hardly imagine that systematic compensation differentials could persists between artistic sectors. In other words, in equilibrium, painters and paintings should have been allocated between different commissions to the point of equalizing the marginal return of each genre.

The main objective is to test this hypothesis of price equalization between artistic sectors. To do so, we adopt a labor market framework in which painters can be thought as workers, patrons can be thought as employers, and genres can be interpreted as distinct artistic sectors. Rather than wages (e.g., annual or hourly wages, as in the standard labor market literature) the data report the price of each single item (painting) produced by each artist. In labor economic terms, we would define the compensation for each painting (i.e., the painting price) as a compensation at a piece rate rather than at a time rate. If artists' mobility between artistic fields (genres) was free, we expect that, after controlling for demand and supply side features, any price differential between paintings of different genres should disappear.

A similar hypothesis has been largely investigated in the literature on interindustry wage differentials. The first strand of studies on this topic (Dickens and Katz 1987; Gibbons and Katz 1992; Kruger and Summers 1988; Murphy and Topel 1987) found that substantial wage differentials across sectors (and firms) exist that cannot be explained by observable worker or firm characteristics. Accordingly, standard competitive theories of the labor market could hardly rationalize this evidence (4): one would need to complement them taking into account compensating wage differentials or market frictions associated with efficiency wages (informational frictions) or imperfect mobility of workers (search frictions). Still, common to all of these early studies is the lack of appropriate data to control properly for unobservable characteristics of workers and firms. In other words, the main empirical problems in explaining wage differentials typically relied on the difficulty of obtaining detailed matched employer-employee datasets about a competitive labor market and observing the same worker employed in multiple sectors and in different firms (without selection on workers switching jobs).

More recently, the emergence of new datasets linking employers and employees has made this possible. The seminal work of Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) (5) has readdressed the topic of wage differentials by using unique longitudinal-matched employer-employee data of French workers and firms: given the matched nature of their panel, they can control simultaneously for workers and firms' fixed effects, and they find that most of the interindustry wage differential is explained by worker effects. Since then, the availability of new data matching workers to their employers fostered interest for this topic. (6) The basic message of this literature is that unobserved worker and firm characteristics matter a lot for wage determination but, although the inclusion of individual and employer heterogeneity considerably reduces interindustry differentials, significant differences in wage levels across sectors persist.

The empirical analysis follows the spirit of this literature looking at a unique dataset on painters active in Rome in the seventeenth century, put together by the art historian Richard Spear and administered by the Getty Research Institute (see Spear and Sohm 2010). The dataset provides a lot of information on the observable features of the commissions, of the paintings, and of the painters. (7) Most of all, the dataset is a matched employer-employee (patron-painter) dataset and hence it allows us to analyze the interindustry (genre) price differential exploring the role of worker (artist) and firm (patron) heterogeneity in the determination of painters' compensation.

The advantage of analyzing a primary artistic market through a matched employer-employee dataset is that we can observe workers (painters) that are constantly switching between sectors (genre of paintings) and between employers (patrons). Moreover, as differences in the artistic ability (talent) were painter-specific and quintessentially unobservable (i.e., nonmeasurable), we fully capture them through artists' fixed effects. Most importantly, unlike in the standard literature in labor economics, in which each firm could be classified into a single industry only, the data allow us to identify sectors and patrons dis-jointly. Indeed in modern labor markets evidence of interindustry wage differentials could depend, for example, on firm heterogeneity as firms cannot switch across industries. On the contrary, in the obtained data each patron could commission paintings belonging to different genres (or sectors) and so we are able to control for patron fixed effects. The main contribution is then related to the specific features of the data that allow us to estimate the intersectoral compensation differentials using a matched employer-employee while controlling simultaneously for both workers' and firms' heterogeneity. (8)

The main result we obtain is that, after controlling for observable characteristics of both paintings and artists and for both artists' and patrons' fixed effects, all the price differentials between genres disappear or become insignificant, which suggests that the labor market for painters must have been rather competitive and allocated artists between genres to the point of equalizing the marginal returns of the different artistic sectors. This is remarkable since we find one of the earliest microeconometric examples of a competitive mechanism at work in a labor market of very high skilled workers producing highly differentiated goods; previous findings of wage equalization in the literature were based on data on highly interchangeable blue- and white-collar workers producing similar goods and services. Moreover, the results are reinforced by the fact that we analyze a market populated by a small number of agents on both sides of the market, while the empirical literature on industry wage differential is generally based on administrative data with thousands of observations. (9)

While arbitrage appears to hold between genres and also between geographical destinations, we find some evidence of residual price differentials at the employer level, which we mainly explain in terms of incentive mechanisms to induce effort in the production of artistic quality and compensating wage differentials. Interesting results are related to the moral hazard problem emerging in contractual relations for figurative paintings in which effort of painters and final quality of paintings were not contractable ex ante or verifiable ex post. First, in the case of religious, mythological, and historical paintings, we show that patrons and artists adopted a typical solution pointed out in the literature on principal-agent contracts: prices were made conditional on measurable features of the paintings which were positively correlated with effort and quality (Holmstrom and Milgrom 1991), one of which was the number of human figures per square meter in the composition. Second, we find a price premium for altarpieces destined to public display as in private chapels (within public churches), which we interpret as evidence of a signaling mechanism in the commissions by private patrons of artworks that were visible by the entire community (Nelson and Zeckhauser 2008; Spence 1973).

We find residual price premia paid by foreign kings and foreign families, such as the Medici from Florence and the Gonzaga from Mantua. Following the decomposition of variance in Gruetter and Lalive (2009), we show evidence of negative covariance between artist and patron effects, and on this basis, we argue that the most convincing explanation for this is related to compensating wage differentials rather than efficiency wages. We emphasize that the best paid artists (for works of similar objective characteristics and destination) included famous masters such as Maratta, Pietro da Cortona, Guido Reni, Caravaggio, Vouet, Lorrain, and Poussin. Finally, the rewards of the painters were increasing with age, consistently with the importance of on-the-job experience in the artistic market, possibly due to the development of experimental innovations (Galenson 2006).

This article is organized as follows. Section II describes product differentiation in the market for paintings and the economic hypotheses to be tested. Section III illustrates the dataset. Section IV describes the empirical strategy and the results, and performs some robustness checks. Finally, Section V concludes.

II. PRICE EQUALIZATION BETWEEN GENRES OF PAINTINGS

Most paintings during the Renaissance were of figurative subject, mainly religious or mythological, but also allegorical, literary, or strictly historical (including battles drawn from a real or invented context), and we define these as figurative paintings. Since the end of the sixteenth century, however, the raising demand of private buyers belonging to the high and middle classes (and the influence of Nordic art) led to the development of new artistic subjects, usually regarded as minor genres, such as still lifes, landscapes, and so-called genre paintings (depicting ordinary daily life). These minor genres flourished during the Baroque age of the seventeenth century.

On the demand side, the substitutability between genres was limited because of the different decorative roles that the different genres had in private homes and churches (e.g., portraits had a different purpose than landscapes within a private building, and only religious paintings could be destined to churches). On the supply side, painters were usually engaged in all genres during their career (think of Caravaggio, Annibale Carracci, or Salvator Rosa to cite some famous eclectic artists), but often they favored one or two genres more than the others in their commissions.

While nowadays we are not used to artistic hierarchies based on paintings' subject, in the seventeenth century the prestige of the different artistic genres was clearly ranked. The least worthy subjects were still lifes, imitating inanimate reality without idealization (Spear and Sohm 2010, 91). The position of portraits in this hierarchy was variable, but often at a low level for the alleged absence of creativity in works aimed at merely copying real human figures. Genre paintings were equally penalized by the lack of decorum and idealization, and the typical focus on the worst aspects of life, which was considered vile by contemporary artists and critics (Spear and Sohm 2010, 94). Landscapes and (even more) battles were more valuable than these genres because of their idealized depictions. The most dignified and worthy subjects were those depicting creative compositions of ideal human figures (Spear and Sohm 2010, 91), like historical paintings, and, most of all, religious and mythological paintings. There is wide documentary evidence that such a ranking of preferences (and willingness to pay on the demand side) was well understood between art critics, art collectors, artists, and intellectuals. (10) Later in the century, it was even codified by the art academies. (11)

The basic training in different genres and techniques was more or less common to most artists. Therefore, as long as the market was competitive and the alternative artistic genres were open to the entry of new painters, we can hardly imagine that systematic differences in prices could persist over time between different genres. Painters of different talent could perfectly choose to be active in different sectors, but if a given painter could earn more by switching between genres, this would happen whenever a painting in another genre could provide a higher compensation. (12) The only differences consistent with a competitive mechanism could be motivated by compensating differentials, which at the time were associated with the social connections that a certain patron could provide to the painter (providing new and certain commissions in the future). But beyond exceptional circumstances, a standard arbitrage argument suggests that, after controlling for observable characteristics of the paintings such as size, technique, or support, and unobservable characteristics of painters and commissioners, any price differential between paintings of different genres should disappear. (13)

A. Price Determinants: The Supply Side

To test the hypothesis of price equalization between genres, we need to identify the main supply and demand factors that may have affected prices in the market for paintings of Baroque Rome. On the supply side, the price of paintings depends first of all on the talent and the reputation of the painter, which is obviously painter-specific: the reservation price of painters was clearly increasing in their innate ability, for instance because better painters had more outside options. Moreover, the ability to produce high quality could change with the experience of each painter: the latter may reflect an age/earning profile dependent on reputational effects emerging with the activity in the profession (in a Mincerian tradition) or on actual improvements, that is artistic innovations perceived and priced by the market, that require a certain experience (Galenson 2006; Galenson and Weinberg 2000).

Other sources of price differential that derive from the supply side are painting-specific. The most important and measurable feature is the size of paintings, which reflects the cost of production and captures many things such as the complexity of the conception as well as the need of assistants, possibly increasing less than proportionally with dimension because of scale economies. With regard to figurative paintings, also the number of figures depicted could have been increasing the cost of production and therefore the price; however, once controlling for size, it is not clear if this was still true. Another factor is the originality of the work: even if the concept of autography was quite different from our modern understanding (plagiarism was not a legal issue), copies, often performed by minor painters, implied less work because they did not require a preliminary creative activity.

The technique adopted could substantially affect costs of production and prices: compared with oil paintings, frescoes required a complex preparation (think of ceilings and cupolas, or even large walls) but also a rapid execution, which could have an ambiguous impact on costs. (14) Beyond the different costs of production, frescoes (which were common mainly for figurative paintings and landscapes) provided a different esthetic perception (and commitment due to the fixed position) within churches and private residences and, therefore, they could command different prices. Whether frescoes were paid more or less than oil paintings remains an open question to be settled at the empirical level. Finally, in case of oil paintings, the support could also affect prices: most oil paintings were executed on canvas, but few others of small size were executed on copper support or other smooth material (commonly, still lifes and landscapes).

B. Price Determinants: The Demand Side

If we move to analyze the demand side, we expect that different patrons could have different willingness to pay. The dataset is rich in information that is useful to identify the patrons (mainly churches or noble and rich families), the geographical destination of the commission (Rome, a minor destination in the countryside, a medium city, or a place outside Italy), the purpose of their commissions (a private collection and residence, a religious institution, or a private chapel within a church), and its kind (for a single or multiple paintings). This allows us also to check for various motivations behind price differentials generated by different willingness to pay by different patrons.

In the literature on wage differentials at the firm level (i.e., employer size-wage effect), there are many explanations on the possible sources of such differences (e.g., Brown and Medoff 1989; Manning 2003). The theory of the labor market emphasizing institutions argues that differences in unionization explain wage differences across firms (e.g., Booth 1995). However, unionization was absent in our market. (15) Equilibrium search theory rationalizes wage differentials across firms for homogeneous workers due to search frictions (e.g., Postel-Vinay and Robin 2002; van den Berg and Ridder 1998), which are, however, hard to apply in a context populated by very high-skilled workers producing highly differentiated goods. (16) Thus, compensating wage differentials, in competitive markets, and rent-sharing theories or efficiency wage considerations, in noncompetitive markets, remain the two most likely explanations for price differentials.

The first explanation is due to different non-monetary rewards (on compensating wage differentials, see Hwang, Reed, and Hubbard 1992; Rosen 1986). If painters had more to gain from commissions from well-connected Roman families able to guarantee future commissions or network with other patrons and less to gain from occasional and riskier commissions from foreign families, they could be indifferent between lower prices for the first kind of commissions and the second one. Thus, it is likely to expect negative covariance between artist and patron effects. Indeed, better artists looked for safer patrons that paid less for a typical income effect on the supply side (as in labor markets where high-wage earners purchase safer jobs). (17)

Other sources of price differentials rely on market frictions due to imperfect observability of workers' effort and noncontractability (ex ante) of paintings' quality. Theories of efficiency wages provide a variety of explanations for differential compensations. On one side, as the reservation price of painters was increasing in their ability, patrons could pay more to attract the best painters (Weiss 1980). On the other side, we may expect that the most susceptible-to-quality patrons were more prone to provide monetary incentives to induce effort of the painters, and these were ready to exert higher effort to avoid the risk of working for ordinary patrons (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984) or to be paid as painters of lower quality. For both motivations, it is then likely to expect positive covariance between artist and patron effects. This is obvious in models of pure asymmetric information where higher wages are used to select more productive workers. More productive workers find it more convenient to choose high wage-high effort contracts relative to low wage-low effort contracts, and the first kind of contracts are offered exactly to screen the best workers and increase their effort.

As we could expect from basic contract theory, a variety of additional incentive mechanisms could emerge in the artist-patron relationship in case of figurative paintings, for which contractual agreements were mostly established ex ante and were subject to moral hazard. (18) We emphasize one aspect related to signaling and one related to optimal principal-agent contracts. First, as pointed out by Nelson and Zeckhauser (2008), commissions of altarpieces and frescoes for private chapels within public churches were visible to the entire contemporary audience, and could guarantee high visibility for their patrons in front of the fellow citizens, of the political and ecclesiastic power (and even of God) and signal what at the time was called "magnificence." In this sense, we can test a signaling mechanism a la Spence (1973) for artistic commissions: commissioners were ready to invest more in order to obtain higher-quality works when a mechanism of signaling of "magnificence" was active; therefore, we expect higher prices for paintings addressed to private chapels as compared with common religious commissions and especially with other private commissions that were not destined to public display (such as private palaces and private collections).

Second, we look at the optimal patron-artist contracts from the perspective of principal-agent theory. As reputational constraints and efficiency wages did not perfectly align the incentives of patrons and artists, there was room for further contractual solutions to the moral hazard problem. In line with the "informativeness principle" (see Holmstrom and Milgrom 1991), it is reasonable to believe that the optimal patron-artist contracts had to be based, explicitly or implicitly, on any verifiable and measurable feature of the painting that was correlated with effort and quality. The number of figures could be taken as a proxy for effort and quality for two main reasons. First of all, the variety and complexity of the composition of human figures invented by the artist had a positive, although partial, correlation with quality, and could be summarized exactly by the number of figures. For instance, we know that pricing by number of figures became a typical procedure during the early 600s for leading painters such as Guercino, Domenichino, and Guido Reni. (19) Second, the same hierarchy of genres could provide a link between number of figures and perceived quality: a higher number of human figures was increasing on average the space destined in the painting to subjects of higher perceived value (the human figures) and reducing the space available for subjects of lower quality (background landscapes or decorative still lifes). (20)

Taking all this in consideration, we can reformulate the hypothesis of price equalization between genres in a more appropriate way. Price equalization should hold, after controlling for observable and unobservable characteristics of paintings, artists, and patrons, between still lifes, genre paintings, landscapes, portraits, and all the figurative paintings with a small number of human figures, allowing for increasing price premia when the figurative paintings contained a higher number of figures. (21)

Finally, we also test whether arbitrage was taking place not only between genres but also between big cities and the countryside. More specifically, we expect that prices for paintings destined to big and rich cities (where wealthy demand was) should not be significantly different from prices of paintings destined to small towns and villages in the countryside, otherwise profitable opportunities for provincial painters would have been unexploited. However, notice that this goes against the common perception at the time, for which Rome was the best paying market (Spear and Sohm 2010). (22)

III. DATA

In this section, we provide an accurate description of the dataset and of the variables we consider as price determinants in the empirical analysis, and we show some descriptive statistics.

A. Description of the Dataset

The empirical analysis is based on a unique dataset established at the Getty Research Institute (the Payments to Artists Database, hereafter PAD) which documents payments directly made to artists for the primary market in seventeenth-century Rome (Spear and Sohm 2010). (23) The dataset contains approximately a thousand records of payments to artists and provides a lot of precious information regarding paintings' and painters' characteristics. To the aim of our analysis, the most valuable characteristic of the PAD is that it is a matched employer-employee (patron-painter) dataset. The source of the information includes original contracts between artists and patrons (typically for the altarpieces), records of the buyers themselves (typically for the minor genres, which were not contracted in detail), evidence from contemporary writers, archives, and inventories. The survival of all this information for these painters and patrons through centuries is random, but it is quite reasonable that most of the information found by art historians actually concerns well-known painters dealing with famous and wealthy patrons. Therefore, we need to be aware that this selection excludes from the analysis the lower end of the art market, which was populated by largely undistinguished craftsmen supplying low-quality products without any formal agreement with the buyers. However, such selection allows us to focus on the upper end of the art market where in general the most famous painters were directly competing with each other. (24)

In PAD, the information of a typical "arrangement" between the artist and the patron concerns the record's number, the artist's name, the title, the subject, the object, the dimension, the number of figures, the patron's name, the payment date, the price paid, and the destination (both the original and the current one). Finally, the records often contain interesting notes providing further details on the contract, when available. Table 1 describes the structure of the typical arrangement in PAD.

The original records in the dataset could refer either to a single or to a multiple commission (i.e., more than one painting for the same artist-patron contract). When multiple commissions are taken into account, the total number of single observations increases to about a thousand and five hundred observations. Whether a painting belongs to a single or to a multiple commission is generally explicitly indicated in its title. Knowing the number of paintings for each commission enables us to control for a possible discount premium. The painting's title also reports whether each painting represents a copy rather than an original work.

The painting's price is the dependent variable of the econometric analysis. The given value is the amount paid to the artist in silver scudi romani; in some cases, prices were converted from another currency (such as doubloons, gold scudi, livres tournois, Spanish real, and pound sterling). (25) In the rare cases in which prices do not represent an original payment to an artist, they are identified as evaluation prices or sale prices. In these cases, however, prices are restricted to the years when the artist was selling his works because they are probably more representative of the original sale prices. (26)

In PAD, the "subject" is identified as: sacred, mythological, allegorical, history, heraldic, literary, battle, landscape, architectural, portrait, genre, still life, or animals. In order to obtain variables with an easier interpretation and to link them with the traditional artistic subject classification, we aggregated more homogeneous genres among themselves. As a result, we obtained the following classification: (1) Sacred, (2) Myth (mythological and allegory), (3) History (history, literary, and heraldic), (4) Battle, (5) Landscape (landscape and architectural), (6) Portrait, (7) Genre, and (8) Still life (still life and animal). We defined the first four groups as belonging to the "figurative" genre, as they involved traditional compositions of idealized human figures, but we will also report the distinction in the four subgroups in the regressions. The number of figures is also given for these figurative paintings: the full-figure equivalent is reported as a specific number only when the number of figures is lower than five, whereas full-figure equivalents are more generally designated "5-10" when they vary between five and ten and "crowd" when they are greater than ten or impossible to count. (27)

In the dataset, the "object" refers to both the technique and the support used by the artist. The former includes drawings, etching, fresco, mosaic, oil, tapestry, tempera, watercolor; and the latter includes canvas, panel, mirror, copper, lapis, slate, stucco, and touchstone. The object also indicates whether a painting was "Easel," which is used to designate what might also be called a gallery picture and which could be taken as an indirect information for its small size when effective size is missing in the dataset. To guarantee a basic homogeneity in the objects under investigation, we dropped the observations when the object referred to drawings, mosaics, tapestries, and watercolors. We do have a few observations for oil paintings with a support different from canvas and characterized by a smooth and compact surface (mostly copper, but also mirror, lapis, wood panel, and others). As a control for the paintings's features, we included dummies for oil paintings not on canvas and for frescoes. The dimension has been converted in square meters. In some cases, the available information is only about one side of the paintings and some other times only the information "small," "medium," "large" or only the size of the frame are given. In all these circumstances, an appropriate estimate was made (sometimes considering the distribution of size of comparable subjects in the sample).

The artist's name could either be the name of a single artist or of more artists, that we considered as copainters. The artist's name allows us to control for his talent (by including artist fixed effects) and also to discriminate among painters according to their origin (local or immigrant). (28) Moreover, as the payment date is reported in the dataset, by looking at the painters' biographies we derived the age of the painters at the time in which the artwork was made.

As demand factors are concerned, in most cases we have information on the patron's name, which indicates the person or the institution that commissioned the painting. Patrons could be churches, other religious institutions (e.g., confraternity or religious orders), the Vatican church of St. Peter or private patrons. These latter were generally noble families residing in Rome, as in the case of the Barberini or the Orsini family, or in other Italian towns, as for the Gonzaga family in Mantua or the Medici family in Florence. Sometimes even the Popes active during the century directly commissioned paintings. Demand for paintings originated also from foreign patrons, both nobles and kings such as Charles I of England or Louis XIV of France. Finally, paintings were occasionally bought by rich dealers, as Mattia Capocaccia, one of the rare traders in paintings, and Fabrizio Valguamera, apparently trader of (stolen) jewels. (29)

The "destination" in the dataset indicates both the city and the specific location the artwork was addressed to. The majority of paintings was commissioned for the city of Rome. However, the dataset contains many paintings for other important Italian towns, such as Bologna, Florence, Mantua, or Naples, for minor provincial centers, such as Caprarola or Frascati, and also for foreign European destinations, such as London, Madrid, or Paris. The variable destination allows us also to distinguish between religious and secular locations. Within religious locations, we are able to discriminate between the case in which the painting was placed in a family chapel inside a church or in a public space within the church. Secular locations can be private palaces or private collections. Therefore, the demand side can be controlled by patron fixed effects and by looking both at the city where the painting was addressed to and at the place where the painting was planned to be positioned. This last variable is likely to be related to the willingness to pay of the patrons. Table A1 contains the details of the definitions and sources of the variables included in the regressions.

B. Descriptive Statistics of the Dataset

The payment date in PAD is recorded between 1576 and 1711. In our analysis, however, we slightly reduced the available observations, focusing only on the period from 1600 to 1700, for artistic homogeneity (this is commonly studied as the Baroque century in art history) and also for monetary reasons: the real value of the silver scudo is known to have been remarkably stable during that period (see Spear and Sohm 2010), which allows us to focus on the nominal prices in silver coins without loss of generality. The following descriptive analysis is based on the observations remaining after filtering data from missing values (remaining with 1,133 observations). The distribution by genre is shown in Table 2. Notice that the sacred subjects make the largest share of the market. Altogether figurative paintings (i.e. sacred, battle, historical, and mythological subjects) represent about 60% of the sample. Around 20% are landscapes, whereas portraits and still fifes cover 9% of the sample each. The associated positive correlation between the production of paintings per genre and the average prices per genre is broadly in line with an adjustment mechanism: in sectors where the willingness to pay was higher, more paintings were produced to equalize prices compared with sectors where the willingness to pay was lower.

The average price of paintings is 144 scudi, although prices exhibit a large variation, ranging between 1 scudo romano for some still fifes and portraits to the 14,000 scudi of the huge fresco by Gaulli "Triumph of the Name of Jesus" located in the main Roman church of the Jesuits. In spite of few observations with prices above 1,000 scudi, 90% of the paintings are priced less than 300 scudi, while the median value is 48. There are some noticeable differences between the average prices by genre. The highest values are observed for figurative paintings with historical and sacred subjects at the top followed by mythological and allegorical subjects, and by battles at the bottom. Landscapes follow next, while portrait, genre paintings, and still lifes are the least priced.

The range of variation by dimension is large, with very small paintings measuring less than 0.5 nr up to the majestic "Glorification of the Reign of Pope Urban VIII," a 363 [m.sup.2] ceiling fresco by Pietro da Cortona located in Barberini Palace in Rome. However, apart from few very large paintings, the average dimension is slightly more than 5 [m.sup.2] while the median is just 2 [m.sup.2]. Considering genres, the data show that the average dimension is between 1 and 2 [m.sup.2] for all nonfigurative paintings. The average dimension is instead more than 8 [m.sup.2] in the case of figurative paintings. (30)

Turning to patrons, Popes accounted for about 5% of the whole demand, while around 8% came from religious institutions (excluding St. Peter's church that alone covers 3.3% of the sample). The paintings were demanded mainly for private locations, particularly private collections (62%). Around one quarter of the paintings in the sample was instead addressed to churches, in same cases sponsored by private families for their own chapels inside public churches (6.7%). Demand originated mainly from Rome, but also from other important Italian towns (16%) and minor centers in the Italian countryside (8%), with large price differentials for different destinations; about 6% of the paintings were exported outside Italy.

IV. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY AND RESULTS

We estimate a semi-linear price equation where the natural logarithm of price is regressed on a set of dummy variables for genres and on a set of other explanatory variables. Moreover, the PAD has a matched nature as it relates artist and patron information. This allows us to estimate the price equation including both painter and patron fixed effects and hence to evaluate the extent to which price heterogeneity is related to unobservable characteristics among painters (artist effect) or among patrons (patron effect). Indeed, unobservable ability is in general a crucial factor of wage determination. This is all the more so in the labor market for artists, where the esthetic value of the artwork, mainly dependent on painter's talent, is one of the key determinant of its price.

To include both artists' and patrons' fixed effects, we removed from the sample all the artists and patrons with a single observation, reducing the number of observations from 1,133 to 1,061. The sample then comprises a maximum of 1,061 paintings for 87 artists and 50 patrons (which reduces in number depending on the explanatory variables we include due to missing values). We should add that the panel of artists and patrons (panel over paintings, not over time for our purposes) is strongly unbalanced as it includes artists with a minimum of 2 observations and a maximum of 43 observations (Poussin), and patrons with a minimum of 2 to a maximum of 115 observations (the Chigi family).

We follow the procedure by Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) to analyze the compensation of the painters. (31) Specifically, we estimate the (log) price of paintings commissioned to an artist i by a patron j using ordinary least squares (OLS). We include a set of explanatory variables (i.e., paintings' and artists' characteristics) and both artist and patron fixed effects. The price equation we estimate is the following:

[P.sub.in] - [alpha] + [X.sub.in][beta] + [[theta].sub.i] + [[psi].su.j((i,n)] + [[chi].sub.k(j(i,n))] + [[epsilon].sub.in]

with E[[[epsilon].sub.in] [??] i, n,j(i, n), [X.sub.in]] = 0, (32) where pin is the logarithm of the price paid to an artist i for a painting n, [alpha] is a constant, [X.sub.in] denotes the observable painting-varying exogenous characteristics of both artists and of paintings (per artist) with coefficient [beta], [[theta].sub.i], is the pure artist effect, [[psi].sub.j(i,n)] is the pure patron effect for the patron j(i, n) that has commissioned the painting n to the artist i, [[chi].sub.k(j(i,n))] is the effect of the genre k(j(i,n))--which is related to the painting n that is commissioned to an artist i by a patron j, and [[epsilon].sub.in] is the statistical residual. (33)

We interpret this price equation as a wage equation in which [p.sub.in] is the compensation of a worker i for a painting n, which is regressed on a set of observable characteristics of the painting and of the workers (experience and origin), on the identity of the individual and on the identity of the employer. The genre to which each painting belongs could also be interpreted as the industry to which each artist belongs. This enables us to interpret mobility of artists across artistic sectors as interindustry workers' mobility and prices differentials across genres as interindustry wage (compensation) differentials. One important difference, however, is that while each firm could be classified into a single industry, here each patron could commission paintings belonging to different genres.

A. Main Results

The results are summarized in Table 3. In the first column, we start by estimating a baseline price equation where the natural logarithm of price is regressed on dummies for genres to highlight the unconditional price differential between them. As already shown by descriptive evidence, a sharp ranking of prices can be detected, with still fifes (the reference category) at the bottom, followed in increasing order by portraits and genre paintings, and by landscapes and battles. Figurative paintings are the best paid artworks, with sacred and mythological subjects with a large number of human figures at the top. We also performed pairwise t test on the equality of coefficients between still fifes, portraits, genre paintings, landscapes, and figurative paintings, and we found that they were all statistically different from each other with the only exception of the coefficients of genre paintings and portraits. This result is in fine with the traditional hierarchy of genres (and with the anecdotal evidence according to which the relative position of portraits in this hierarchy was variable). (34) Overall, differences in genre and number of figures appear to explain only 45% of price variability.

The descriptive analysis has shown a large variation of paintings' size by subject. More specifically, figurative paintings have a higher average dimension than other subject paintings. Related studies on the value of old master paintings in the rest of Italy show that dimension was a crucial determinant of prices (see Etro and Pagani 2012). Hence, we first want to observe whether the price differential between genres persists after controlling for paintings' dimension. The second column shows that indeed it does, confirming the price differential between genres per square meter, although the relative price premium diminishes for figurative paintings with a large number of figures.

As the following step, in the third column, we control for the full set of paintings' characteristics. Results show that the price differential still exists, although it is reduced: paintings with the same objective characteristics are differently paid depending on the subject they represent. Prices decrease with the number of commissioned paintings and in the case of oil paintings that are not painted on canvases, even though only at the 10% level of significance; the coefficients for the dummies for copies and frescoes are negative as well. To control for demand effects, in this specification we also include the geographical destination for which the painting was demanded and the location where it was planned to be positioned. Quite interestingly, and in fine with the common perception at the time, paintings addressed abroad were the best paid, about 200% more than the reference destination, which is Rome, whereas paintings commissioned for the countryside were paid about 50% less. As the location destination is concerned, we can detect a clear ranking where commissions for private chapels were by far the best paid, those for churches were "intermediate," and those for private palaces and private collections (the reference category) were at the bottom. Finally, in this specification, we introduce two macroeconomic explanatory variables. The first is the time trend in paintings' prices, which emphasizes a negative but extremely small trend. The second is a dummy for the decade following the plague of 1656, which is meant to capture the effect of the main aggregate shock that may have affected demand (but also supply) during the century: the effect is not significant. Both these controls will be omitted in the following specifications, because the year of execution comoves with the age of the artists and because of the irrelevance of the aggregate shock. (35)

We then add in the fourth column the artists' observable characteristics, including the age of the artists and a dummy for immigrant painters. The price of paintings increases with artist's age by around 2% per year, in line with that found by Etro and Pagani (2012) for Venetian paintings in the same period. (36) Concerning the provenance of the painters, notice that foreign painters were mainly specialized in minor genres, which were less paid in absolute terms. However, when controlling for genres, we do not find any evidence of price differentials between Italian and immigrant painters. (37)

In the fifth column, we enrich the specification by simply adding patron fixed effects to control for unobservable heterogeneity on the demand side. Results show that the price differential between genres still persists, although it is slightly reduced: each patron did pay on average much more for a figurative painting compared with another painting of the same size and characteristics but of a different genre, exactly because the willingness to pay for different genres was variable according to the hierarchy of preferences for different genres in the Baroque age. Notice, however, that after controlling for patron fixed effects the coefficients of the geographical destinations become nonsignificant at conventional levels, suggesting the existence of an arbitrage mechanism between destinations with different demand--as already pointed out in Etro and Pagani (2012) for the Venetian market.

Including only artist fixed effects, in the sixth column, strongly reduces the price differentials between genres and those coefficients became almost all insignificant, with the exception of all the coefficients on figurative paintings. We should emphasize that the value of the (non-adjusted) R-squared is higher in this specification, which contains only artist fixed effects (i.e., 0.79) with respect to the previous one where we included only patron fixed effects (0.76).

Estimation results of the full model of the price equation are presented in the last column of Table 3. This specification includes both patrons' and artists' fixed effect (i.e., their unobservable characteristics to control for individual talent). The price differential between still lifes and all the other genres finally disappears: ceteris paribus, a still life was not paid differently from a portrait, a genre painting, a landscape, or a figurative painting (with less than five figures) by the same painter. Moreover, notice that also any price differential between figurative paintings (namely of historical, mythological, and sacred subject) with a similar number of figures disappears. This is true for all the three groups of figurative paintings, that is with less than five figures, with five to ten figures and with a crowd or more than ten figures (which includes also all the battles). Therefore, the main hypothesis is fully confirmed: the artistic sector choice of painters led to the equalization of prices. In a sense, if figurative paintings were paid more in absolute terms, it was mainly because better painters were engaged on average in figurative paintings, and these better painters were paid more also when they were engaged in other genres. However, minor painters could not switch from still lifes to figurative paintings to earn extra profits because they would have been paid less than other painters, exactly enough to make them indifferent between genres. Which is exactly what a competitive labor market would have predicted. (38) Notice that a similar result concerns geographical destinations, whose coefficients are nonsignificant: arbitrage appears to take place both across sectors (genres) and between commissions from major destinations and the countryside.

In Table 4, we report the contributions of artists (fixed effects), patrons, genres (including figuratives with less than five figures, that are comparable with the other genres), and other observable characteristics to explain the variance of logprices (as in Gruetter and Lalive 2009) after estimation of the full specification in the last column of Table 3. Pure price differentials between genres provide a negligible contribution to explain overall price variability (2.52%), whereas all the observable characteristics together explain around 43% of it, and artist and patron effects together explain more than 41%, with a larger role for artists than patrons. These results appear in line with those of Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) and the subsequent literature, which shows that most of the interindustry wage differentials can be explained by variation in unobservable characteristics, mainly of the workers.

At this stage of the analysis, we can comment also on the other final estimation results. Starting from the effect of paintings' characteristics, we confirm previous results regarding the positive link between size and price, with a return above 3% for an additional square meter beyond the average size; moreover, we find evidence of decreasing returns given the negative and significant coefficient of the squared term. The price premium for figurative paintings with a large number of human figures remains positive and it is statistically significant: plus 150% for figurative paintings with five to ten figures and plus 220% for those with more than ten figures. (39) This is consistent with the hypothesis that quantifiable aspects of paintings as the number of figures depicted were agreed (in preliminary drawings or verbal communications, as we know it happened for Guercino, Guido Reni, and others) also with the purpose of insuring a certain effort and quality, a sort of incentive mechanism to limit moral hazard in line with standard principal-agent theory (Holmstrom and Milgrom 1991). (40)

The dummy on frescoes is negative and significant: this suggests that the rapid technique of frescoes, often executed by high-quality painters, was compensated with a lower payment per square meter. Nevertheless, in the absence of further information on the time of execution of frescoes, as compared with oil paintings, we cannot draw definitive conclusions on the existence of price differentials between the two techniques. The coefficients for copies and for paintings not on canvas are negative and significant in specifications not controlling for artists' characteristics, while in the full specification they remain negative but they turn insignificant. Therefore, copies (or replicas of existing paintings) and paintings on copper and other unusual supports were not paid less, but they were simply carried out by worse painters: again, there was nothing to gain in specializing in copies or in paintings on a different support, otherwise a profitable opportunity would have emerged. Finally, the negative coefficient of the variable describing the number of paintings in the multiple commissions highlights the existence of a quantity discount of around 5% for each additional painting.

On the demand side, interesting results concern the impact of the place where the artwork was addressed to. As a matter of fact, the same patron could have different willingness to pay depending on the place where the painting was planned to be positioned. For instance, patrons often commissioned paintings for their private chapels within public churches. Nelson and Zeckhauser (2008) have suggested that higher investments for these commissions could be motivated to induce higher quality and signal more magnificence in front of the contemporaries. The estimates largely confirm this hypothesis: the very high and significant coefficient for the commissions for private chapels implies that they were on average better paid than paintings for private collections (the excluded category) and private palaces (however, the coefficient of private chapel is higher but not significantly different from that of other religious destinations).

B. Artist and Patron Effects

Let us consider the role of painters' and patrons' characteristics in our full specification. The price of paintings increases with artist's age by around 2% per year, which may be related to the importance of on-the-job experience in terms of experimental innovativeness (Galenson 2006; Galenson and Weinberg 2000). Due to the unbalanced nature of the panel, in Table 3, we report only the coefficients of the artists with at least eight observations, because for too few observations it would be difficult to comment on the values of their coefficients. In order to facilitate interpretation, we follow the technique used by Kruger and Summers (1988) to compute industry wage differentials with the method of correction proposed by Haisken-DeNew and Schmidt (1997) to compute the exact standard errors of coefficients, and we express results as deviation from an artist-share weighted mean. The coefficients on the artist dummy variables then show the artist effect with respect to the sample average. Results show that some of the most famous painters of the time were the best paid: first of all the main masters of the typical Baroque art such as Guido Reni, Pietro da Cortona, and Carlo Maratta (in ascending order), often engaged in figurative paintings, but also painters who were repeatedly active in multiple genres such as Caravaggio, who was actually responsible for the introduction of genre paintings and still lifes in Italian art, or the French painter Simon Vouet. Among the best paid painters, we also find two other French painters, Nicolas Poussin and Claude Lorrain, who were mainly engaged in landscapes.

Let us move to the patrons. As expected, patrons' characteristics also affect prices. As we did for the artists, in Table 3 we report the coefficients of the patrons with at least eight observations in the estimation sample, relative to the average patron. We see that paintings commissioned by the Vatican St. Peter's church, by foreign kings, and by selected wealthy and powerful families outside Rome, such as the Medici from Florence and the Gonzaga from Mantua were paid more than average. Instead, some established families based in Rome such as the Orsini and the Sacchetti paid less than average (also Barberini, Borghese, and the Popes have negative, although not significant at conventional levels, coefficients). Interpreting these results from a labor market perspective, however, is not immediate.

As we argued before, one possibility is that the labor market was not competitive and frictions due to imperfect observability of quality and effort led to efficiency wage mechanisms aimed at selecting quality (Weiss 1980) or inducing effort (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984). These mechanisms would imply a positive covariance between artist and patron effects as in this case patrons should pay more to select higher-quality painters or to induce higher effort. On the contrary, compensating wage differentials are consistent with a competitive labor market. Working for some specific patrons provided artists with alternative types of compensation: examples were the opportunity to access prestigious networks that provided repeated commissions and so to see an increase in their future earning profile or at least to reduce their risk in the process of gaining new commissions. This would generate lower prices for well-connected Roman families and higher prices for foreign families, and also a negative covariance between artist and patron effects: better painters should prefer the safer commissions. (41)

In Table 4, we look at the decomposition of the variance of prices, as performed by Gruetter and Lalive (2009). The variance-covariance matrix shows the determinants of the contribution of different effects in explaining price variability. For instance, most of the contribution of the artists derives from the variability between artists, but also from the fact that better paid artists were engaged in commissions with observable characteristics that were better paid, such as larger paintings for private chapels. If we look at the contribution of patrons, we notice a high variability in their payments and again a positive covariance with the observable characteristics: patrons that paid more also asked more valuable characteristics, as it should be intuitive.

More important is to analyze the covariance between patron and artist effects. Specifically, we find evidence of a negative covariance of artists and patron effects, which is consistent with the hypothesis of compensating wage differentials but not with efficiency wages. Moreover, a closer look at the difference between the single coefficients of Roman-based patrons with respect to non-Roman ones provide us with further evidence in favor of the hypothesis of compensating wage differentials consistently with a competitive labor market. (42)

C. Robustness Checks

We performed a number of robustness checks on the basic empirical analysis; the main two will be discussed in this section. (43) Ideally, one would have liked to observe a dataset in which all patrons demand paintings of all genres to each artist, which is clearly impossible within a limited historical sample as ours. However, it is interesting to check whether price equalization holds where the artists or the patrons are indeed diversifying their supply or their demand. In the first column of Table 5, we present the results of a regression in which we limited the data to the paintings of the "switchers," that is, the painters that in the dataset have paintings in more than one genre. The main assumption underlying our result is that the painters could switch their activity between different genres to exploit any profitable opportunities, which implies that such opportunities should disappear in equilibrium: an immediate implication of this is that price equalization should strictly hold for all the painters that do diversify within the dataset. The results presented in Table 5 on the switchers reinforce the main conclusion regarding the validity of the hypothesis of price equalization between genres. (44)

In the second column of Table 5, we present the results of a regression in which we limited the data to observations referring to patrons that demanded paintings of different genres. After this selection, the number of observations is largely reduced, but the main results are confirmed. This check can provide additional insights on the competition mechanism at work: we find again that there are no price differentials between genres, suggesting the existence of competition between artists also within commissions from specific patrons.

Finally, we estimate the model including match-specific fixed effects to control for unobserved characteristics of the artist-patron match, such as relative bargaining power. Woodcock (2011) presents direct evidence of the importance of matching in wage determination in modern labor markets. Fie finds that match effects, which have been ignored in previous works, are an important determinant of earnings dispersion, and concludes that specifications that omit match effects substantially overestimate the returns to experience, attribute too much variation to personal heterogeneity, and underestimate the extent to which good workers sort into employment at good firms. In the dataset, we can identify match effects only for observations referring to artists and patrons with more than a single transaction and with relationships with, respectively, more than one patron and more than one artist, because otherwise the match fixed effects could not be identified. We are able to identify 64 matches between a corresponding number of artists and patrons, amounting to 249 observations. Although we cannot include match effects for all the sample's observations, we replicate estimates inserting match-specific fixed effects in the equation to be estimated; results are largely unchanged and they confirm the main conclusion regarding price equalization (see column 3 of Table 5).

V. CONCLUSIONS

We have analyzed the labor market in the Baroque Roman art sector using a unique matched painter-patron panel dataset on commissions for still lifes, landscapes, portraits, genre paintings, battles, and sacred, mythological, and historical paintings. In line with the traditional hierarchy of genres, the price differential between them was high and significant. Adopting a labor economics perspective, we are able to analyze the intergenre compensation differentials and, differently from a standard matched employer-employee approach, we control for both the role of individual and employer heterogeneity in the determination of artists' compensation.

We find that most of the intergenre price differential is explained by the variation in average individual heterogeneity across sectors (genres). This suggests that the labor market for painters was rather competitive and allocated artists between artistic genres to the point of equalizing the marginal return of different genres. For each painter, every commission from a patron for a still life, a portrait, a genre painting, a landscape, or a comparable figurative painting was equally profitable at the margin. This reflected an efficient equilibrium of occupational choice and, incidentally, made it possible for the new artistic genres to develop and flourish in this and the following centuries. While we find evidence of arbitrage between genres and also between geographical destinations, we show some evidence of residual price differentials at the employer level, which we mainly explain in terips of incentive mechanisms to induce effort in the production of artistic quality and compensating wage differentials in competitive markets.

Additional data on other paintings, patrons, and artists may allow one to improve the main empirical analysis, to check how the artist fixed effects evolve with the sales price of previous works and with the sponsorship of nobles, to check for the relevance of network relations between artists and patrons and may also allow one to make further progress in the identification of demand and supply of art. Finally, in a Schumpeterian perspective, it would be interesting to investigate whether different compensations affected artistic innovations in certain locations or certain periods of art history: it was not by chance that artistic innovation flourished first in the wealthiest cities characterized by more developed free market economies, as was Rome during the seventeenth century.

ABBREVIATIONS

OLS: Ordinary Least Squares

PAD: Payments to Artists Database

doi: 10.1111/ecin.12115

Online Early publication June 25, 2014
APPENDIX

TABLE A1
Variables Definitions

Variables                          Definition

Variables of Interest:
Genre and Number of Figures
Still lifes                        Dummy = 1 for a still life
Landscapes                         Dummy = 1 for a landscape
Genre paintings                    Dummy = 1 for a genre
Portraits                          Dummy = 1 for a portrait
Figurative paintings (1-4 fig)     Dummy = 1 for a "figurative
                                     painting'' (i.e., Sacred or
                                     History or Myth) with 1 to 4 fig.
Sacred (1-4 figures)               Interaction Sacred * Figurative (1
                                     to 4 figures)
Historical & Literary (1-4 fig)    Interaction History * Figurative
                                     (1 to 4 figures)
Mythological & Allegory (1-4       Interaction Myth * Figurative (1
  fig)                             to 4 figures)
Figurative paintings (5-10 fig)    Dummy = 1 for a "figurative
                                     painting" (i.e., Sacred/History/
                                     Myth) with 5 to 10 fig.
Sacred (5-10 fig)                  Interaction Sacred * Figurative (5
                                     to 10 figures)
Historical & Literary (5-10 fig)   Interaction History * Figurative
                                     (5 to 10 figures)
Mythological & Allegory (5-10      Interaction Myth * Figurative (5
 fig)                                to 10 figures)
Figurative paintings (>10 fig)     Dummy = 1 for a "figurative
                                     painting" (i.e., Sacred/History/
                                     Myth) with > 10 fig.
Sacred (>10 fig)                   Interaction Sacred * Figurative
                                     (>10 figures)
Historical & Literary (> 10 fig)   Interaction History * Figurative
                                     (>10 figures)
Mythological & Allegory (> 10      Interaction Myth * Figurative (>
  fig)                               10 figures)
Battles                            Interaction Battle* Figurative (>
                                     10 figures)
Control Variables:
Paintings' characteristics
Size (square meters)               Size in square meters
Size (square meters) squared       Size in square meters squared
Number of commissioned             Number of paintings for single and
  paintings                          multiple commission
Copy from original                 Dummy = 1 for a copy form original
Not on canvas                      Dummy = 1 for paintings on a
                                     support different form canvas
                                     (e.g., copper, etc.)
Fresco                             Dummy = 1 for frescoes
City destinations
Rome                               Dummy = 1 for destination to Rome
Minor destinations                 Dummy = 1 for destination to minor
                                     Italian town (see below)
Medium destinations                Dummy = 1 for destination to major
                                     Italian town (see below)
Exports                            Dummy = 1 for foreign destination
                                     (see below)
Location destinations
Private palace                     Dummy = 1 for destination to
                                     private palace
Private collection                 Dummy = 1 for destination to
                                     private collection
Private chapel                     Dummy = 1 for destination to
                                     private palace
Church and other religious         Dummy = 1 for destination to
  buildings                          church and other rel. buildings
Patrons' fixed effects
Private patrons                    Dummy = 1 when patrons are private
                                     families with at least 2
                                     observations in the sample (see
                                     below)
Churches                           Dummy = 1 when the patrons are
                                     urban churches
City of Rome                       Dummy = 1 when the patron is the
                                     City of Rome
Foreign nobles                     Dummy = 1 when the patron is a
                                     foreign noble
Kings' commission                  Dummy = 1 when the patron is a
                                     king
Other religious institutions       Dummy = 1 for other religious
                                     commissions
Pope's commission                  Dummy = 1 when the patron is a
                                     Pope
Vatican                            Dummy = 1 when the patron is the
                                     Vatican
Vatican St. Peters                 Dummy = 1 when the patron is the
                                     Vatican St. Peter
Artists' characteristics and
  fixed effects
Artists                            Dummy = 1 for artists with at least
                                     2 observations (see below)
Age of artist                      Difference between payment date
                                     and year of birth
Immigrant                          Dummy = 1 for artists coming from
                                   outside Italy
Other
Time trend                         Payment date
Plague                             Dummy = 1 for the period 1656 1665
                                     (aggregate demand shocks)

Artists                           Private Patrons   Destinations

Abbatini        Manfredi          Aldobrandini      Minor:
Alberti         Maratti           A1 temps          Ariccia
Arpino          Maratti & Onofri  i Altieri         Bagnaia
Baderni         Mattia            Barberini         Bassano di Sutri
Baglione        Mei               Borghese          Bassano Romano
Belloni         Miel              Bornia            Caprarola
Bonzi           Mola              Borromeo          Castel Gandolfo
Both            Morandi           Brancallero       Castel San Pietro
Brandi          Nuzzi             Campello          Catania
Bril            Pace              Capocaccia        Cesena
Brueghel        Passerotti        Cardelli          Fano
Camassei        Pellegrini        Cerasi            Fara
Caravaggio      Perfetta          Chigi             Foligno
Caroselli       Pomarancio        Colonna           Frascati
Carracci        Porpora           Correggio         Lanuvio
Cerquozzi       Poussin           Corsini           San Quirico d'Orcia
Cerrini         G. Preti          de Rossi          Spoleto
Chiari          M. Preti          Farnese           Tivoli
Ciampelli       Reni              Filomarino
Cigoli          G. Romanelli      Furgotto          Medium:
Codazzi         U. Romanelli      Giustiniani       Arezzo
Courtois        Rondoni           Gonzaga           Ferrara
Cozza           Rosa              Guicciardini      Florence
Cresti          Sacchi            Mattei            Mantua
Cortona         Salini            Mazarin           Messina
V. de Boulogne  Saracen i         Medici            Milan
Domenichino     Sassoferrato      Orsini            Naples
Dughet          G. Stanchi        Pamphilj          Palermo
Elsheimer       N. Stanchi        Peretti Montalto  Perugia
Ferri           Stella            Pointel           Pistoia
F. Napoletano   Stom              Riviera           Siena
Galli           Swanevelt         Roscioli          Venice
Gaulli          Tanari            Rospigliosi
A. Gentileschi  Tassi             Ruffo             Exports:
G. Gimignani    Tempesta          Sacchetti         Antwerp
L. Gimignani    Tomasini          Santacroce        Austria
Gramatica       Trevisani         Santori           Dalmazia
Grimaldi        Turchi            Savoia            London
Honthorst       Vajani            Sfondrato         Madrid
Jannetti        F. Vanni          Spada             Paris
Laer            R. Vanni          Valguarnera       Rouen
Lanfranco       Viola                               Switzerland
Leoni           Vouet
Lorrain

TABLE A2
Artist Specialization by Genre

                 Number of Genres

                  1     2     3    Total

No. of artist    50    20     9       79
of which:
  Still life      9     1     2       12
  Genre           3     1     4        8
  Landscape       9     3     6       18
  Portrait        0    10     4       14
  Figurative     29    19     8       56
% observations   52    29    19      100


REFERENCES

Abowd. J. M.. F. Kramarz, and D. N. Margolis. "High Wage Workers and High Wage Firms." Econometrica, 67(2), 1999. 251-333.

Abowd, J. M., F. Kramarz, D. N. Margolis, and K. R. Troske. "The Relative Importance of Employer and Employee Effects on Compensation: A Comparison of France and the United States." Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 15, 2001, 419-36.

Abowd, J. M., F. Kramarz, P. Lengermann, K. L. McKinney, and S. Roux. "Persistent Inter-industry Wage Differences: Rent Sharing and Opportunity Costs." IZA Journal of Labor Economics, 1(7), 2012.

Abowd, J., F. Kramarz, and S. Woodcock. "Econometric Analyses of Linked Employer-Employee Data," in The Econometrics of Panel Data, edited by L. Matyas and P. Sevestre. Berlin: Springer Netherlands, 2008, 727-60.

Ackerberg, D. A., and M. Botticini. "Endogenous Matching and the Empirical Determinants of Contract Form." Journal of Political Economy, 110(3), 2002, 564-92.

Ashenfelter, O., and K. Graddy. "Auctions and the Price of Art." Journal of Economic Literature, 41. 2003, 763-86.

Bertrand, M., C. Goldin, and L. F. Katz. "Dynamics of the Gender Gap for Young Professionals in the Corporate and Financial Sectors." American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 2010, 228-52.

Booth, A. The Economics of Trade Unions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995.

Brown, C., and J. Medoff. "The Employer Size-Wage Effect." Journal of Political Economy, 97(5), 1989, 1027-59.

Card, D., J. Heining, and P. Kline. "Workplace Heterogeneity and the Rise of West German Wage Inequality." NBER Working Paper No. 18522, 2012.

De Marchi, N., and H. Van Miegroet, ed. Mapping Markets for Paintings in Europe 1450-1750. Turnhout, Belgium: Brepols, 2006.

Dickens, W. T., and L. F. Katz. "Inter-Industry Wage Differences and Industry Characteristics," in Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Markets, edited by K. Lang and J. S. Leonard. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987.

Eeckhout, J., and P. Kircher. "Identifying Sorting-In Theory." Review of Economic Studies, 78(3). 2011, 872-906.

Enggass, R., and J. Brown. Italian and Spanish Art, 16001750: Sources and Documents. Evanston, IL: Northwestern University Press, 1970.

Etro, F. The Economics of Renaissance. Mimeo, Ca' Foscari University, 2013.

Etro, F., and L. Pagani. "The Market for Paintings in Italy during the Seventeenth Century." Journal of Economic History, 72(2), 2012, 423-47.

--. "The Market for Paintings in the Venetian Republic from Renaissance to Rococo." Journal of Cultural Economics, 37(4), 2013, 391-415.

Etro, F., and E. Stepanova. "The Market for Paintings in the Netherlands during the Seventeenth Century." Working Paper No. 16, University of Venice, Ca' Foscari, Department of Economics, 2013.

Galenson, D. Old Masters and Young Geniuses: The Two Life Cycles of Artistic Creativity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006.

Galenson, D., and B. A. Weinberg. "Age and the Quality of Work: The Case of Modern American Painters." Journal of Political Economy, 108(4), 2000, 761-77.

Gibbons, R., and L. Katz. "Does Unmeasured Ability Explain Inter-Industry Wage Differentials?" Review of Economic Studies, 59, 1992, 515-35.

Goux, D., and E. Maurin. "Persistence of Interindustry Wage Differentials: A Reexamination Using Matched Worker-Firm Panel Data." Journal of Labor Economics, 17(3), 1999, 492-533.

Graddy, K. "Taste Endures! The Rankings of Roger de Piles ([dagger] 1709) and Three Centures of Art Prices." Journal of Economic History, 73(3), 2013, 766-91.

Gruetter, M., and R. Lalive. "The Importance of Firms in Wage Determination." Labour Economics, 16(2), 2009, 149-60.

Haisken-De New. J. P., and C. M. Schmidt. "Interindustry and Interregion Differentials: Mechanics and Interpretation." Review of Economics and Statistics, 79, 1997, 516-21.

Haskell. F. Patrons and Painters: Art and Society in Baroque Italy. New York: Alfred N. Knopf, 1982.

Hellmanzik, C. "Location Matters: Estimating Cluster Premiums for Prominent Modern Artists." European Economic Review, 54, 2010, 199-218.

Holmstrom. B., and P. Milgrom. "Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and lob Design." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1, 1991, 24-52.

Hwang, H.-S., W. R. Reed, and C. Hubbard. "Compensating Wage Differentials and Unobserved Productivity." Journal of Political Economy, 100(4), 1992, 835-58.

Kruger, A. B., and L. H. Summers. "Efficiency Wages and the Inter-Industry Wage Structure." Econometrica, 56(2), 1988, 259-93.

Manning, A. Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003.

Montias, J. Art at Auction in 17th Century Amsterdam. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 2002.

Murphy, K. M., and R. H. Topel. "Unemployment, Risk, and Earnings: Testing for Equalizing Wage Differences in the Labor Markets," in Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Markets, edited by K. Lang and J. S. Leonard. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987.

Nelson, J. K., and R. J. Zeckhauser. The Patron's Payoff. Conspicuous Commission in Italian Renaissance Art. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008.

O'Malley, M. The Business of Art. Contracts and the Commissioning Process in Renaissance Italy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2005.

Postel-Vinay, F., and J.-M. Robin. "Equilibrium Wage Dispersion with Worker and Employer Heterogeneity." Econometrica, 70(6). 2002, 2295-350.

Rosen, S. "The Theory of Equalizing Differences," in Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 1, edited by O. C. Ashenfelter and R. Layard. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1986, 641-92.

Shapiro, C., and J. Stiglitz. "Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device." American Economic Review, 74, 1984, 433-44.

Spear, R., and P. Sohm. Painting for Profit. The Economic Lives of Seventeenth-Century Italian Painters. New Haven, CT; London: Yale University Press, 2010.

Spence, M. "Job Market Signaling." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 1973, 355-74.

van den Berg, G. J., and G. Ridder. "An Empirical Equilibrium Search Model of the Labor Market." Econometrica, 66(5), 1998, 1183-221.

Weiss, A. M. "Job Queues and Layoffs in Labor Markets with Flexible Wages." Journal of Political Economy, 88(3), 1980, 526-38.

Woodcock, S. "Wage Differentials in the Presence of Unobserved Worker, Firm, and Match Heterogeneity." Labour Economics, 15(4), 2008, 771-93.

--. Match Effect. Mimeo, Simon Fraser University, 2011.

(1.) For analysis of the secondary market in historical periods see Montias (2002) and Etro and Stepanova (2013), who focus on the Dutch auctions of the seventeenth century.

(2.) Etro (2013) analyzes data from the Italian Renaissance market. Etro and Pagani (2012, 2013) have mainly analyzed the Venetian market of altarpieces. For a classic work on Baroque patrons see Haskell (1982).

(3.) See Spear and Sohm (2010, 91).

(4.) Which is true also in the case of highly skilled workers such as the painters of the dataset (e.g., see Bertrand et al. 2010).

(5.) See also Goux and Maurin (1999) and more recently Gruetter and Lalive (2009) and Woodcock (2008) for related analysis.

(6.) For instance, after decomposing wage rates into a worker effect and a firm effect, Abowd et al. (2001) and Abowd et al. (2012) compute the share of interindustry wage differences attributable to worker and to firm effect in France and the United States. The second work relates the part arising from individual heterogeneity to the worker's opportunity wage rate and the part arising from employer heterogeneity to product market quasi-rents and relative bargaining power. Moreover, different modeling techniques have been developed to address the econometric challenges related to longitudinal matched employer-employee data (see the survey in Abowd, Kramarz, and Woodcock 2008). Recently, Card, Heining, and Kline (2012) have used the methodology to investigate the evolution of wage inequality.

(7.) We know the age at which painters executed the works: since they received a similar general training before becoming independent masters, but kept training and improving their ability and reputation with time, on-the-job experience is the main observable characteristic of the painters that we use.

(8.) In labor terms, sector or industry is a characteristic of the firm, thus the definition of the pure industry effect (for example in Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis 1999) is simply the correct aggregation of the pure firm effect within the industry. This is not the case in our context.

(9.) Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) study a longitudinal sample of the French labor market with over one million workers from more than five-hundred thousand employing firms.

(10.) Vincenzo Giustiniani (1564-1637), a famous art collector, in a letter distinguished 12 "categories, concerning both the methods of painting and the rankings of painters" with a clear hierarchy (see Enggass and Brown 1970). The worst three categories, or " methods" concerned copies. At a higher level of Giustinani's ranking were portraits and still lifes. At an even higher level, he placed different kinds of landscape paintings. The best categories were about figurative paintings, including battles and, a step above, historical subjects divided into subcategories differentiated only from a stylistic point of view. Similar views were expressed by other experts in the following decades.

(11.) The hierarchy of genres became a source of intellectual debate in the European art academies. A shared view was later codified in a famous lecture given by the art critic Andre Felibien at the French Academy (Conferences de l'Academic Royale de Peinture et de Sculpture pendant l'annee 1667). His influential hierarchy of the genres, ranked still lifes in the lowest position and figurative paintings at the highest level. For an economic analysis of ancient art critique, see Graddy (2013).

(12.) In a Schumpeterian perspective, the same innovation of new genres in the Baroque period can be justified by the new economic compensation that minor genres started to deliver to the painters. See Etro and Pagani (2013) on Schumpeterian patterns in the Venetian art market.

(13.) Notice that we are not claiming that each artist was equally good in each genre, because clearly there could be different talents and skills in different genres (and specialization could induce improvements in a single genre and not in the others). The hypothesis is that if artists could switch between genres, they would do it whenever painting a different genre could provide a higher payment. Therefore, any equilibrium would allocate works (and workers) between genres to the point of equalizing prices.

(14.) As Spear and Sohm (2010) notice, "more data are required before it can be said if it definitely was cheaper to paint in fresco than oil, not only because there were so many variables in the quality and quantities of pigments used in different jobs, but also because a fresco painter might or might not have been responsible for the cost of preparing a wall, or an oil painter for buying his canvases and stretcher. I suspect that generally fresco was the cheaper medium by measure, but even so that does not take into account the overhead of hiring more assistants for elaborate projects" (56-57).

(15.) More specifically, the painters did belong to a guild, but this was not able to affect prices in any effective way (Spear and Sohm 2010).

(16.) Bargaining power on the product market and the rents stemming from it cannot be a source of price differentials at the patron level, because in our context the workers (artists) produce a consumption good for the final consumers and they are not hired as inputs in the production of goods to be sold on another market.

(17.) See the discussion in Gruetter and Lalive (2009).

(18.) For an interesting analysis of contractual relations in premodern time, see Ackerberg and Botticini (2002).

(19.) Guercino claimed to commit to a fixed price of 100 scudi per full-length figure (50 for half-length figure, 25 for heads); however, this could be part of a sophisticated bargaining technique because deviations from this "commitment" were the rule rather than the exception. In a letter of 1628, Guido Reni argued that the low-level painters could not obtain more than 2 or 3 scudi for large life-size figures and ordinary painters could ask at most 15 scudi per figure, while an extraordinary painter like himself could name his own price on the basis of the quality of his work independently from size and number of figures (Spear and Sohm 2010).

(20.) Moreover, painters were often focusing their own effort on human figures and especially on difficult parts as the heads, delegating less relevant parts (including background decorations, landscapes, and still lifes) to their own assistants. Accordingly, a higher number of figures was a proxy for a wider direct intervention of the master painters in the overall execution, and consequently for higher quality.

(21.) To be as conservative as possible, we define figurative paintings with a small number of figures as those with at most four human figures. This is particularly conservative for our purposes because portraits depicted almost always a single human figure.

(22.) In 1625, Fra Atanasio, an art dealer who was negotiating an altarpiece by Giovanni Battista Crespi called Cerano in Milan, told the patron that the painter would have probably accepted 250 scudi, but also that if Cerano were to go to Rome he would be paid double because, he added, Rome is "where you go to get rich" (Spear and Sohm 2010, 233).

(23.) The original dataset is available online at: http://www.getty.edu/research/tools/provenance/payments_to_artists/index.html.

(24.) The dataset presents quite a few missing values, which in fact markedly reduced the total number of available observations. More specifically, we decided to delete all the records containing simultaneous missing information on the subject (or genre), title, and dimension. However, in order to obtain a number of observations as large as possible we decided to make a few guesses regarding the missing values of a given variable, provided that all the other crucial information was certain. All these guesses are described more precisely in a Data Appendix available on request.

(25.) Notice that some payments were made in kind (with wine, wheat, cheese, diamonds, even flowers, and marzipan): however, their equivalent cash value is cited in the documents and reported in PAD.

(26.) As all artists in PAD (with the notable exception of Artemisia Gentileschi) are male, we will use the male pronoun throughout all this work.

(27.) In PAD, data were assembled with the method for figure counting used by the Deputies of the Cappella del Tesoro di San Gennaro in Naples in the 1630s. Other than counting what obviously were full or half figures, they counted a certain number of putti as the equivalent of a full figure.

(28.) Rome attracted many foreign painters, mainly Dutch and Flemish (e.g.. Both, Bril, Brueghel, and Honthorst present in the dataset) or French (such as Lorrain, Dughet, and Poussin), who were often focused on the minor genres: mainly still lifes and genre paintings for the Dutch and the Flemish, and landscapes for the French.

(29.) Only in the case of Capocaccia, eight prices derive from a resale (to the Cardinal Francesco Maidalchini); therefore, they should be interpreted as an (upperbound to the) estimate of the original prices.

(30.) When considering figurative paintings, an important attribute to consider is the number of figures depicted. The largest share of paintings (almost 50%) have a low number of figures (from 1 to 4), around one-third have an intermediate value (between 5 and 10) while only 17% of figurative paintings contain more than 10 figures.

(31.) Notice that Eeckhout and Kircher (2011) have recently criticized the procedure by Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) to measure sorting between employers and workers, showing that in general matching models the direction of sorting depends on the cross derivative of the production function with respect to both firms and workers, whose sign is ambiguous. In our market, the production function (of quality of the paintings) depends only on the workers (the artists) and not on the employers (the patrons); therefore, this theoretical critique does not apply.

(32.) This assumption is usually problematic in modern labor markets, because it requires exogenous mobility between jobs. When voluntary, a transition to a new job is rare and aimed at increasing the wage, and therefore it can be systematically biased by endogenous factors. This is probably not the case in our market, where painters were constantly switching from a job (and a patron) to another.

(33.) After obtaining the least square parameter estimates [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] we can determine the importance of different factors in price determination with the procedure of Gruetter and Lalive (2009). Using the following decomposition of the variance of the logarithm of the price:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

we can express the importance of each factor as the ratio between the covariance of its contribution with the price and the overall variance. In particular, the importance of the artists effects is:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

and the same for the other components. Notice that cov [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] implies positive sorting of artists across patrons effects, and cov ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]) implies negative sorting. Results are presented in Table 4.

(34.) See Spear and Sohm (2010). Incidentally, this result is also consistent with the descriptive evidence reported in Table 2, where slightly increasing the number of observations is enough to invert the rank between genre and portrait with respect to the one emerging from the baseline regression. Notice that historical subjects and battles appear to be less paid than other figurative subjects, at least in compositions with a large number of figures. Also this is in line with the hierarchy of genres, because idealized subjects (as religious and mythological subjects) were better considered than realistic (historical) ones.

(35.) Controlling for age, the time trend becomes indeed irrelevant. And the main results remain the same if we replace age with the year of execution in the full specification. We have also used 10 or 20 years dummy variables to control for time effects and the results are unchanged.

(36.) We also included age squared among the regressors but its coefficient is very small and highly insignificant.

(37.) Results will not be displayed in the full specification due to collinearity with the artists' fixed effects.

(38.) Table A2 shows that the number of actual " switchers" in the sample is considerable and corresponds to 37% of all the artists in the estimated sample (and to about half of the number of observations because they have more paintings in the dataset on average). Of course, most of the artists may have been engaged in multiple genres even if this is not reported in the limited sample.

(39.) We remark that the price premium for figurative paintings with a small number of figures would have not only been statistically insignificant, but also economically insignificant, had we limited the category to a lower number of figures (up to two or three). We are grateful to Deirdre McCloskey for discussion on this point.

(40.) This hypothesis needs further verification. The price premium for number of figures is confirmed in a dataset with only figurative paintings. Most important, it disappears for the subset of figurative paintings whose price was estimated ex post. This may confirm that a price premium emerges only in ex ante contracts as a partial solution to the moral hazard problem. We are grateful to Paul Milgrom and Julio Rotemberg for lively discussions on this point.

(41.) A negative covariance between artist and patron effects could also be simply explained by different bargaining power in noncompetitive markets. However, a difference in the (negative) signs of the well-connected Roman patrons (who were in fact able to guarantee access to networks and to repeated commissions), with respect to the (positive) signs of the non-Roman ones, would make compensating wage differentials a most convincing explanation. A related point is that the observed cross-patrons price differentials may reflect unobserved characteristics of the artist-patron match indicating relative bargaining power. In the next section, we replicate estimation including match-specific fixed effects.

(42.) Extremely rich and powerful foreign patrons, as foreign kings, the Medici, and the Gonzaga did have to pay a lot to obtain works from artists active in Rome, but rarely from the very top ones. Instead, some important families such as Orsini and Sacchetti managed to purchase repeatedly from top painters at good prices. Remarkably, the only art dealer in the dataset, Capocaccia, has a negative coefficient: probably it was for his services to the painters as a distributor of paintings across Roman families that he managed to obtain good deals from the best painters. Only the exceptional prices for the decoration of St. Peter's church do not appear in line with the hypothesis of compensating wage differentials, but this case is unique under many dimensions.

(43.) In unreported regressions, we also excluded outliers (in particular, paintings with extremely high price or size), frescoes and paintings on a different support than the most common canvas, we extended the dataset to the period 1576-1711, and we controlled for the evolution of the artist fixed effects with age and for an alternative specification of paintings' size. These additional results confirm the main results and are available on request.

(44.) It is important to remark that we know from art historical sources that almost all the painters in the dataset did paint commissions from most genres (although these are not documented in the dataset).

FEDERICO ETRO, SILVIA MARCHESI and LAURA PAGANI *

* We would like to thank Lorenzo Cappellari and Barbara Petrongolo for their insightful and constructive comments and suggestions. We also thank Orley Ashenfelter, Karol Jan Borowiecki, Emilio Colombo, Tiziana Cuccia, Maria De Paola, Giulio Fella, Davide Fiaschi, James Fleckman, Francis Kramarz, Emanuela Marrocu, Ulisse Mangialaio, Deirdre McCloskey, Paul Milgrom, John O'Hagan, Alessia Paccagnini, Mario Padula, Valeria Pinchera, Julio Rotemberg, Andrei Shleifer, and Richard Spear. Finally, we thank participants at the XXVIII Italian Conference of Labor Economics (Rome, 2013), the European Association of Labor Economist (Torino, 2013), the VI European Workshop on Applied Cultural Economics (Ljublijana, 2013), the III Workshop on Institutions, Individual Behavior and Economic Outcomes (Argentiera, 2012), and at the 53 SIE Annual Meeting (Matera, 2012), and seminar participants at the Copenhagen Business School, LSE, University of Pisa, Queen Mary University of London, the University of Milano Bicocca (CISEPS), the University of Southern Denmark, and the University of Venice for useful comments.

Etro: Professor, Department of Economics, University of Venice, Ca' Foscari, 30121 Venezia, Italy. Phone +39 041 234 9172, Fax +39 041 234 9176, E-mail federico.etro@ unive.it

Marchesi: Professor, Department of Economics, Management and Statistics, University of Milan, Bicocca, 20126 Milano, Italy. Phone +39 02 64483057, Fax +39 02 64483085, E-mail silvia.marchesi@unimib.it

Pagani: Professor, Department of Economics, Management and Statistics, University of Milan, Bicocca, 20126 Milano, Italy. Phone +39 02 64483060, Fax +39 02 64483085, E-mail laura.pagani@unimib.it
TABLE 1
Typical Record in PAD

PI Record            P-268
Artist name          CARAVAGGIO,
                       MICHELANGELO MERISI
                       DA (Italian)
Title                Supper at Emmaus
Subject              Sacred
Object type          Oil (Easel)
Dimensions           141 x 196 cm
Figures              4 half lengths
Patron name          Mattei, Ciriaco
Payment date         1601
Price paid           150 scudi
City (destination)   Rome, Mattei collection
Present location     London, National Gallery

Note: PI, provenance index.

TABLE 2
Descriptive Statistics of the Original Dataset (1,133 observations)

Genre distribution (%)

Still                    Portrait       Genre          Landscape
9                           9             3               21

Average price by genre (in scudi romani)

Still                   Portrait        Genre          Landscape
17                         39             25              66

Average size by genre (in square meters)

Still                   Portrait        Genre          Landscape
1.1                        1.9           1.4              1.9

Number of figures distribution (%)                   Medium (5-10)
Low (1-4)
49                                                        33

Object type distribution (%)

Not on canvas support                                   Fresco
6                                                          7

Patrons (%)

Other religious            King     Foreign noble      St. Peter
0.7                         1             2               3.3

Location destination (%)

Private chapel                      Private palace
6.7                                       12

City destination (%)

Foreign                                  Rome
6                                         70

Average price by destination (in scudi romani)

Foreign                                  Rome
238                                      146

Genre distribution (%)

Still                   Battle    Myth          Sacred         History
9                         3        7              45              3

Average price by genre (in scudi romani)

Still                   Battle    Myth          Sacred         History
17                        73      202            242             262

Average size by genre (in square meters)

Still                   Battle    Myth          Sacred         History
1.1                      1.5      15.3           7.3            11.5

Number of figures distribution (%)           High (crowd)
Low (1-4)
49                                                17

Object type distribution (%)

Not on canvas support                            Copy
6                                                 3

Patrons (%)

Other religious          Pope    Church    Private families
0.7                       5        7              81

Location destination (%)

Private chapel          Church            Private collection
6.7                       19                      62

City destination (%)

Foreign                 Medium                  Minor
6                         16                      8

Average price by destination (in scudi romani)

Foreign                 Medium                  Minor
238                      137                     127

TABLE 3
Log Price Determination

                                               Baseline
                                Baseline      With Size
                                   (1)           (2)

Still life (omitted)
Portrait                         0.667 ***     0.627 ***
                                (0.156)       (0.154)
Genre                            0.686 ***     0.681 ***
                                (0.216)       (0.211)
Landscape                        1.411 ***     1.361 ***
                                (0.147)       (0.146)
Figurative (<5 fig)              1 946         1.809 ***
                                (0.147)       (0.150)
Sacred < 5 (omitted)
History < 5                     -0.048         0.037
                                (0.123)       (0.125)
Myth < 5                        -0.256        -0.237
                                (0.168)       (0.162)
Figurative (5-10 fig)            2.897 ***     2.535 ***
                                (0.162)       (0.163)
Sacred 5-10 (omitted)
History 5-10                    -0.684 ***    -0.423 *
                                (0.232)       (0.238)
Myth 5-10                       -0.241        -0.039
                                (0.467)       (0.441)
Figurative (>10 fig)             3.671 ***     2.780 ***
                                (0.219)       (0.210)
Sacred > 10 (omitted)
History > 10                    -1.651 ***    -0.948 ***
                                (0.375)       (0.335)
Myth >10                        -0.088        -0.494 *
                                (0.351)       (0.296)
Battle >10                      -2.354 ***    -1.484 ***
                                (0.355)       (0.340)
Size                                           0.052 ***
                                              (0.009)
Size^2                                        -0.0001 ***
                                              (0.000)
# commissions

Copy

Not on canvas

Fresco

Private chapel

Church and other rel

Private palace

Private collection (omitted)
Minor destinations

Medium destinations

Exports

Rome (omitted)
Age of artist

Immigrant

Trend

Plague

Constant                         2.161 ***     2.103 ***
                                (0.118)       (0.116)
Artist fixed effects                No            No
Patron fixed effects                No            No
Observations                       762           726
[R.sup.2]                        0.447         0.507

Artists with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Arpino                           0.169
                                (0.291)
Baglione                        -0.015
                                (0.350)
Belloni                         -0.941 ***
                                (0.330)
Both                             0.346
                                (0.311)
Bril                            -0.592 *
                                (0.336)
Camassei                        -0.052
                                (0.343)
Caravaggio                       0.793 **
                                (0.336)
Cerquozzi                        0.004
                                (0.431)
Courtois                        -0.709 **
                                (0.340)
Cortona                          0.861 ***
                                (0.221)
V. de Boulogne                   0.423
                                (0.315)
Domenichino                      0.094
                                (0.190)
Dughet                          -0.532
                                (0.328)
Ferri                            0.245
                                (0.207)
Gaulli                           0.212
                                (0.242)
Gimignani                       -0.314 *
                                (0.175)
Grimaldi                         0.261
                                (0.323)
Jannetti                        -2.052 ***
                                (0.495)
Lanfranco                        0.475 **
                                (0.215)

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Aldobrandini                    -0.294
                                (0.314)
Altemps                         -0.381
                                (0.540)
Barberini                       -0.111
                                (0.118)
Borghese                         0.027
                                (0.236)

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Capocaccia                      -0.840 **
                                (0.338)
Chigi                            0.082
                                (0.146)
Church                           0.067
                                (0.180)
Colonna                          0.033
                                (0.238)
Filomarino                      -1.566 ***
                                (0.395)
Foreign nobles                   0.226
                                (0.226)
Gonzaga                          1.678 **
                                (0.704)
King                             1.405
                                (0.401)

                                  Paintings           Artist
                               Characteristics    Characteristics
                                     (3)                (4)

Still life (omitted)
Portrait                         0.508 ***           0.705 ***
                                (0.134)             (0.137)
Genre                            0.521 ***           0.433 *
                                (0.200)             (0.230)
Landscape                        1.081 ***           1 073
                                (0.132)             (0.148)
Figurative (<5 fig)              1 315               1 414
                                (0.148)             (0.145)
Sacred < 5 (omitted)
History < 5                      0.044              -0.031
                                (0.220)             (0.240)
Myth < 5                         0.033              -0.022
                                (0.192)             (0.189)
Figurative (5-10 fig)            1.768 ***           1.814 ***
                                (0.157)             (0.157)
Sacred 5-10 (omitted)
History 5-10                    -0.116              -0.013
                                (0.266)             (0.216)
Myth 5-10                        0.011              -0.011
                                (0.393)             (0.369)
Figurative (>10 fig)             2.030 ***           2.280 ***
                                (0.222)             (0.218)
Sacred > 10 (omitted)
History >10                     -0.185              -0.333
                                (0.284)             (0.317)
Myth >10                         0.316               0.080
                                (0.302)             (0.295)
Battle >10                      -0.895 ***          -1.134 ***
                                (0.337)             (0.334)
Size                             0.048 ***           0.044 ***
                                (0.009)             (0.009)
Size^2                          -0.0001 ***         -0.0001 ***
                                (0.000)             (0.000)
# commissions                   -0.037 ***          -0.049 ***
                                (0.009)             (0.009)
Copy                            -0.597 ***          -0.843 ***
                                (0.220)             (0.265)
Not on canvas                   -0.282 *            -0.311 **
                                (0.154)             (0.149)
Fresco                          -0.641 ***          -0.535 ***
                                (0.187)             (0.197)
Private chapel                   1.031 ***           1.186 ***
                                (0.134)             (0.130)
Church and other rel             0.902 ***           0.901 ***
                                (0.130)             (0.127)
Private palace                   0.633 ***           0.786 ***
                                (0.146)             (0.151)
Private collection (omitted)
Minor destinations              -0.706 ***          -0.651 ***
                                (0.155)             (0.152)
Medium destinations              0.505 ***           0.475 ***
                                (0.108)             (0.110)
Exports                          1.111 ***           0.801 ***
                                (0.156)             (0.167)
Rome (omitted)
Age of artist                                        0.021 ***
                                                    (0.003)
Immigrant                                           -0.050
                                                    (0.105)
Trend                           -0.006 ***
                                (0.002)
Plague                           0.153
                                (0.106)
Constant                        12.411 ***           1.354 ***
                                (2.717)             (0.184)
Artist fixed effects                No                  No
Patron fixed effects                No                  No
Observations                       716                 716
[R.sup.2]                        0.634               0.652

Artists with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Arpino                                            Leoni
Baglione                                          Lorrain
Belloni                                           Maratti
Both                                              Mei
Bril                                              Morandi
Camassei                                          F. Napoletano
Caravaggio                                        Nuzzi
Cerquozzi                                         Pace
Courtois                                          Poussin
Cortona                                           Mattia Preti
V. de Boulogne                                    Reni
Domenichino                                       G. Romanelli
Dughet                                            Rosa
Ferri                                             G. Sacchi
Gaulli                                            Salini
Gimignani                                         Stanchi
Grimaldi                                          Tempesta
Jannetti                                          Vouet
Lanfranco

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Aldobrandini                                      Mattei
Altemps                                           Mazarin
Barberini                                         Medici
Borghese                                          Orsini

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Capocaccia                                        Peretti montalto
Chigi                                             Pointel
Church                                            Pope
Colonna                                           Roscioli
Filomarino                                        Ruffo
Foreign nobles                                    Sacchetti
Gonzaga                                           Vatican St. Peter
King                                              Valguarnera

                                   Only            Only
                                 Patron FE       Artist FE
                                    (5)             (6)

Still life (omitted)
Portrait                         0.596 ***      -0.263
                                (0.153)         (0.371)
Genre                            0.437 **        0.031
                                (0.220)         (0.390)
Landscape                        0.864 ***       0.239
                                (0.180)         (0.398)
Figurative (<5 fig)              1.268 ***       0.604 *
                                (0.172)         (0.344)
Sacred < 5 (omitted)
History < 5                      0.019          -0.223
                                (0.186)         (0.292)
Myth < 5                         0.072           0.014
                                (0.195)         (0.201)
Figurative (5-10 fig)            1.636 ***       1.051 ***
                                (0.177)         (0.347)
Sacred 5-10 (omitted)
History 5-10                     0.009          -0.067
                                (0.226)         (0.177)
Myth 5-10                       -0.243           0.001
                                (0.282)         (0.297)
Figurative (>10 fig)             1.858 ***       1.450 ***
                                (0.230)         (0.387)
Sacred > 10 (omitted)
History >10                     -0.175          -0.170
                                (0.243)         (0.437)
Myth >10                         0.380           0.181
                                (0.334)         (0.361)
Battle >10                      -0.941 ***      -0.197
                                (0.252)         (0.363)
Size                             0.034 ***       0.038 ***
                                (0.007)         (0.010)
Size^2                          -0.00007 ***    -0.00008 ***
                                (0.000)         (0.000)
# commissions                   -0.099 ***      -0.014
                                (0.019)         (0.011)
Copy                            -0.996 ***      -0.013
                                (0.225)         (0.275)
Not on canvas                   -0.435 ***      -0.217
                                (0.153)         (0.196)
Fresco                          -0.472 **       -0.463 **
                                (0.204)         (0.225)
Private chapel                   0.797 ***       0 772
                                (0.240)         (0.155)
Church and other rel             0.514 ***       0.891 ***
                                (0.159)         (0.133)
Private palace                   0.287           0.595 ***
                                (0.183)         (0.147)
Private collection (omitted)
Minor destinations              -0.105          -0.267
                                (0.220)         (0.173)
Medium destinations              0.215           0.312 ***
                                (0.208)         (0.117)
Exports                          0.328           0.498 **
                                (0.271)         (0.211)
Rome (omitted)
Age of artist                    0.018 ***       0.017 ***
                                (0.003)         (0.005)
Immigrant                        0.117
                                (0.118)
Trend

Plague

Constant                         1.136 ***       0.066
                                (0.258)         (0.168)
Artist fixed effects                No             Yes
Patron fixed effects               Yes              No
Observations                       716             716
[R.sup.2]                        0.758           0.794

Artists with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Arpino
Baglione
Belloni
Both
Bril
Camassei
Caravaggio
Cerquozzi
Courtois
Cortona
V. de Boulogne
Domenichino
Dughet
Ferri
Gaulli
Gimignani
Grimaldi
Jannetti
Lanfranco

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Aldobrandini
Altemps
Barberini
Borghese

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Capocaccia
Chigi
Church
Colonna
Filomarino
Foreign nobles
Gonzaga
King

                                 Patron &
                                 Artist FE
                                    (7)

Still life (omitted)
Portrait                        -0.349
                                (0.398)
Genre                           -0.030
                                (0.406)
Landscape                        0.308
                                (0.441)
Figurative (<5 fig)              0.534
                                (0.370)
Sacred < 5 (omitted)
History < 5                      0.003
                                (0.266)
Myth < 5                         0.100
                                (0.205)
Figurative (5-10 fig)            0.912 **
                                (0.372)
Sacred 5-10 (omitted)
History 5-10                     0.004
                                (0.205)
Myth 5-10                       -0.354
                                (0.286)
Figurative (>10 fig)             1 183
                                (0.422)
Sacred > 10 (omitted)
History >10                     -0.000
                                (0.538)
Myth >10                         0.413
                                (0.358)
Battle >10                      -0.282
                                (0.337)
Size                             0.032 ***
                                (0.010)
Size^2                          -0.00007 ***
                                (0.000)
# commissions                   -0.049 **
                                (0.024)
Copy                            -0.177
                                (0.221)
Not on canvas                   -0.280
                                (0.204)
Fresco                          -0.396 **
                                (0.193)
Private chapel                   0.686 **
                                (0.302)
Church and other rel             0.645 ***
                                (0.153)
Private palace                   0.557 ***
                                (0.174)
Private collection (omitted)
Minor destinations               0.109
                                (0.209)
Medium destinations              0.023
                                (0.165)
Exports                          0.286
                                (0.218)
Rome (omitted)
Age of artist                    0.018 ***
                                (0.005)
Immigrant

Trend

Plague

Constant                       - 1.742
                                (0.614)
Artist fixed effects               Yes
Patron fixed effects               Yes
Observations                       716
[R.sup.2]                        0.848

Artists with at Least Eight Observations in

Arpino                           0.931
                                (0.568)
Baglione                         0.839 ***
                                (0.252)
Belloni                          1.072 ***
                                (0.198)
Both                             0.327
                                (0.203)
Bril                            -0.017
                                (0.226)
Camassei                         0.014
                                (0.306)
Caravaggio                      -0 721
                                (0.270)
Cerquozzi                       -0.409
                                (0.393)
Courtois                         0.673 **
                                (0.293)
Cortona                          0.264
                                (0.365)
V. de Boulogne                   0.652 **
                                (0.256)
Domenichino                      0.362
                                (0.222)
Dughet                           0.654
                                (0.413)
Ferri                            0.561 **
                                (0.218)
Gaulli                          -1.384 ***
                                (0.473)
Gimignani                        0.157
                                (0.407)
Grimaldi                        -0.565 *
                                (0.312)
Jannetti                         0.868 **
                                (0.402)
Lanfranco

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Aldobrandini                    -0.203
                                (0.341)
Altemps                         -0.632 **
                                (0.307)
Barberini                        0.868 ***
                                (0.252)
Borghese                        -1.388 ***
                                (0.335)

Patrons with at Least Eight Observations in the Estimated Sample

Capocaccia                       0.239
                                (0.232)
Chigi                           -0.381
                                (0.399)
Church                          -0.178
                                (0.175)
Colonna                         -0.599 ***
                                (0.203)
Filomarino                       0.097
                                (0.253)
Foreign nobles                  -2.098 ***
                                (0.373)
Gonzaga                          0.815 ***
                                (0.202)
King                            -0.020
                                (0.320)

Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. Coefficients represent
deviations from artist-share weighted mean. Specification as in
column 7 of Table 3. FE, fixed effects.

*** p < .01, ** p < .05, * p < .1.

TABLE 4
The Components of Paintings' Prices

                                Total         Observable      Artist
                             Contribution   Characteristics   Effect

Observable characteristics       43.41           33.76          6.41
  of which genre effect           2.52             --             --
Artist effect                    24.20            6.41         23.34
Patron effect                    17.16            3.23         -5.54
Error term                       15.22            0.00          0.00
Total contribution              100.00           43.41         24.20

                             Patron   Error
                             Effect   Term

Observable characteristics    3.23     0.00
  of which genre effect         --       --
Artist effect                -5.54     0.00
Patron effect                19.47     0.00
Error term                    0.00    15.22
Total contribution           17.16    15.22

Note: Specification as in column 7 of Table 3.

TABLE 5

Robustness Checks
                        Only Multi-   Only Multi-      Match-
                           Genre         Genre        Specific
                          Artist        Patrons     Fixed Effects

Still life (omitted)
Portrait                 -0.100         0.192        -0.587
                         (0.454)       (0.487)       (0.498)
Genre                     0.266         0.199        -0.090
                         (0.456)       (0.328)       (0.298)
Landscape                 0.536         0.59          0.283
                         (0.492)       (0.451)       (0.523)
Figurative (<5 fig)       0.647         0.496         0.501
                         (0.455)       (0.449)       (0.456)
Sacred <5 (omitted)
History <5               -0.512        -0.022         0.094
                         (0.448)       (0.393)       (0.207)
Myth <5                   0.225         0.357         0.222
                         (0.321)       (0.223)       (0.199)
Figurative (5-10 fig)     1.259 ***     1.142 **      0.911 **
                         (0.478)       (0.525)       (0.452)
Sacred 5-10 (omitted)
History 5-10              0.093         0.359         0.32
                         (0.339)       (0.357)       (0.233)
Myth 5-10                -0.562        -0.113        -0.454
                         (0.460)       (0.469)       (0.318)
Figurative (>10 fig)      1.330 **      1.236 **      1.130 **
                         (0.538)       (0.481)       (0.475)
Sacred >10 (omitted)
History >10              -0.122        -1.098 **      0.036
                         (0.767)       (0.486)       (0.651)
Myth >10                  0.66          0.174         0.655 *
                         (0.443)       (0.501)       (0.342)
Battle >10               -0.616         - 1.014      -0.188
                         (0.484)       (0.368)       (0.330)
Constant                  0.485         - 1          -2.190 ***
                         (0.819)       (0.658)       (0.782)
Observations            343           160           716
[R.sup.2]                 0.849         0.901         0.894

Notes: Robust standard error in parentheses. Specification as
in column 7 of Table 3 including match-specific fixed effects.

*** p <.01, **p < .05, * p <.1.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有