A few goodmen: surname-sharing economist coauthors.
Goodman, Allen C. ; Goodman, Joshua ; Goodman, Lucas 等
I. THE PHENOMENON OF COAUTHORSHIP
The phenomenon of coauthorship in the economics profession has been
widely explored. Card and DellaVigna (2013), for example, document the
fact that the number of authors per economics paper has been steadily
growing over time. In the early 1970s, three-fourths of economics
articles were single-authored. That fraction dropped to less than
one-fourth by 2012. Recent research also points to the importance of how
one chooses one's coauthors. Einav and Yariv (2006) explore
"alphabetical discrimination," the fact that economists with
earlier surname initials have greater career success, and argue that
this phenomenon is not observed in academic fields where the order of
coauthorship is not determined alphabetically. This suggests that, all
else equal, a given economist should choose coauthors whose last names
fall later in the alphabet than his or her own name. (1,2) Freeman and
Huang (2014) document the tendency of academics to coauthor with others
of a similar ethnic background and argue that the homogeneity among
coauthors leads to lower quality papers. We leave it to the reader to
determine whether this paper is consistent with that finding.
II. PRIOR LITERATURE BY SURNAME-SHARING COAUTHORS
Relatively little attention has, however, been paid to the
phenomenon of coauthors sharing surnames. The phenomenon is rare but not
vanishingly so, for two reasons. First, finding a coauthor within
one's own household or extended family likely has lower costs than
finding coauthors elsewhere. Hamermesh and Oster (2002) noted that
rapidly improving communications technology has lowered the cost of
coauthoring with distant researchers, rendering this fact less relevant.
They also point out, however, that researchers seem to choose coauthors
in part for their consumption value and not just their productivity. In
short, family members may want to coauthor simply because they enjoy
working together more than with non-family members.
Second, surname sharing among economists is common. To show this,
we used the raw data from Card and DellaVigna (2013), which covers all
publications from 1970 to 2012 in the American Economic Review,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Journal of Political Economy,
Econometrica, and the Review of Economic Studies. (3) We identify nearly
9,000 unique economists, of whom 45% share a surname with at least one
other economist in the data. Within that group, 43% share a surname with
only one other economist, 17% share a surname with two other economists,
and 10% share a surname with more than 10 other economists. The five
most common surnames are Smith (35), Lee (30), Brown (24), Chen (22),
and Miller (21). As a result, many surname-sharing collaborations are at
least theoretically possible.
Systematically searching for evidence of such collaborations is
quite challenging, given that no common search engine allows one to
specify such a search. Entering "Smith and Smith" into Google
Scholar, for example, simply yields results for articles authored by a
single Smith, and wildcards are of no additional help. We were thus
aided greatly by the data from Card and DellaVigna (2013), which does
allow such searching. Within the more than 13,000 papers contained in
that data are 33 papers written by 28 unique pairs of surname-sharing
coauthors, with no examples of surname sharing by more than two
coauthors. (4) We then supplemented these examples through the less
rigorous methodological approach of introspection, asking around, and
scanning www.econjobrumors.com threads concerning "famous
couples." (5)
We ultimately found four types of relationships generating surname
sharing. The first and most common type of such coauthorship is by
married economists with the same surname. Prominent examples of this
include Romer and Romer (2013) on monetary policy, Reinhart and Reinhart
(2010) on macroeconomic crises, Summers and Summers (1989) on financial
markets, Ostrom and Ostrom (1999) on public goods, Ramey and Ramey
(2010) on parental time allocation, Ellison and Ellison (2009) on
internet-based price elasticities, and Friedman and Friedman (1980) on
personal choice.
The second type of such papers are those authored by economist
siblings. Examples of this type include Kehoe and Kehoe (1995) on
general equilibrium models, Dal Bo and Dal Bo (2011) on social conflict,
Ulph and Ulph (2013) on climate change policy, Ahlin and Ahlin (2013) on
product differentiation, and Pope and Pope (2009) on college sports. All
these examples involve pairs of brothers. We have found only one example
of brother-sister coauthorship, Sexton and Sexton (2014) on conspicuous
conservation, the authors of which are twins. Our research uncovered no
pairs of sister coauthors, pointing to a substantial gap in the
literature.
The third type, parent-child coauthorship, is rarer, perhaps
because of the disincentives for young researchers to have senior
coauthors who will receive the bulk of the credit for the research. We
have found only three examples so far. (6) The first, Levy and Levy
(1982), is a finance paper written by a father and son. The second, Van
Praag and Van Praag (2008), is an exploration of the phenomenon of
alphabetical discrimination by a father and a daughter for whom the
issue is quite salient in all researches but the paper in question. The
third, Tremblay, Tremblay, and Tremblay (2011), was written by two
parents and their son studying a Cournot-Bertrand model of competition.
We know of only one example of grandparent-grandchild coauthorship,
Modigliani and Modigliani (1997) on risk-adjusted performance. More such
collaborations should be possible, suggesting another front on which
progress can be made.
The fourth and rarest type of surname-sharing coauthorship involves
unrelated individuals who happen to be on the same campus. We have found
only two such examples. (7) Rosen and Rosen (1980) on federal taxes and
home ownership was written by two unrelated faculty members at
Princeton. Chen and Chen (2011) on social identity was written by a
University of Michigan faculty member and his then doctoral student.
III. OUR CONTRIBUTION
Our contribution to this literature is twofold. First, we believe
this paper is the first written by four economists who share a surname.
(8) All the aforementioned examples have only two coauthors, except for
Tremblay, Tremblay, and Tremblay (2011) which has three. The one example
we have uncovered of a published economics paper with four
surname-sharing coauthors is Skarbek, Skarbek, Skarbek, and Skarbek
(2012) written by two brothers and their two wives. We argue, however,
that this research does not diminish our contribution, for two reasons.
First, though David and Emily Skarbek are husband and wife economists,
Brian and Erin Skarbek are husband and wife attorneys. As such, the
paper has only two economist coauthors. Second, when that research
project began, both women still had their maiden names. The fourway
name-sharing arose only because of two marriages and the resulting name
changes that occurred during a lengthy publication process. (9) We
therefore suspect that the shared surnames may be endogenous to the
publication process itself.
Our second, and related, contribution is that the four coauthors of
this paper are unrelated by marriage, blood, or current campus. This
paper arose when two of us (Sarena and Joshua) who had overlapped in
graduate school and were often mistaken for siblings or spouses were
connected by a mutual friend to one of her graduate students (Lucas). We
then identified a fourth coauthor (Allen) through a search of the AEA
website. None of us has ever been or is currently married to any of the
other of us. Nor to our knowledge are we siblings, parents, children,
cousins, or any other sort of familial relation. It is, of course,
theoretically possible that we share a Goodman-surnamed ancestor in some
prior generation, but we have no empirical evidence that this is true.
(10) The fact that all four of us specialize in applied public economics
(broadly defined) is an additional, aesthetically pleasing coincidence.
IV. CONCLUSION
This paper is the first coauthored by four nonrelated
surname-sharing economists. Our main contribution is showing that such a
collaboration is feasible. We also note that, for papers with more than
two coauthors, surname-sharing eliminates the "et al." penalty
documented by Simcoe and Waguespack (2011). Though the many expected
citations to this paper will refer to it as Goodman et al. (2015), such
citations will provide equal amounts of publicity to all of us
coauthors.
Future breakthroughs on this topic should be possible. We believe
much could be learned if only economists John Turner (University of
Georgia), Lesley Turner (University of Maryland), Nicholas Turner (U.S.
Treasury Department), and Sarah Turner (University of Virginia) would
find a way to work together. Substantial progress might also come from
collaboration between Janet Smith (Claremont McKenna College), Jeffrey
Smith (University of Michigan), Jeremy Smith (University of Warwick),
and Jonathan Smith (College Board), whose work could explore the impact
of both surname-sharing and first initial-sharing. Finally, we encourage
cousins Erzo F.P. Luttmer (Dartmouth College), and Erzo G.J. Luttmer
(University of Minnesota) to consider collaborating for reasons too
obvious to state. (11) This area seems ripe for exploration.
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12167
REFERENCES
Ahlin, C., and P. Ahlin. "Product Differentiation under
Congestion: Hotelling Was Right." Economic Inquiry, 51(3). 2013,
1750-63.
Card, D., and S. DellaVigna. "Nine Facts about Top Journals in
Economics." Journal of Economic Literature, 51(1), 2013, 144-61.
Chen. R., and Y. Chen. "The Potential of Social Identity for
Equilibrium Selection." American Economic Review, 101(6),
2011,2562-89.
Dal Bo, E., and P. Dal Bo. "Workers, Warriors, and Criminals:
Social Conflict in General Equilibrium." Journal of the European
Economic Association, 9(4), 2011, 646-77.
Einav, L., and L. Yariv. "What's in a Surname? The
Effects of Surname Initials on Academic Success." Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 20(1), 2006, 175-87.
Ellison, G., and S. F. Ellison. "Search, Obfuscation, and
Price Elasticities on the Internet." Econometrica, 77(2), 2009,
427-52.
Engers, M., J. S. Gans, S. Grant, and S. P. King.
"First-Author Conditions." Journal of Political Economy,
107(4), 1999, 859-83.
Freeman, R., and W. Huang. "Collaborating with People like Me:
Ethnic Co-authorship within the US." Working Paper No. 19905,
National Bureau of Economic Research, 2014.
Friedman, M., and R. Friedman. Free to Choose: A Personal
Statement. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1980.
Goodman, A. C., and J. L. Goodman, Jr. "The Co-Op
Discount." Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics. 14(1-2),
1997, 223-33.
Gordon, R., and G. B. Dahl. "Views among Economists:
Professional Consensus or Point-Counterpoint?" American Economic
Review, 103(3), 2013, 629-35.
Hamermesh, D. S., and S. M. Oster. "Tools or Toys? The Impact
of High Technology on Scholarly Productivity." Economic Inquiry,
40(4), 2002, 539-55.
Kehoe, P. J., and T. J. Kehoe. "A Primer on Static Applied
General Equilibrium Models," in Modeling North American Economic
Integration, Vol. 31, edited by P. J. Kehoe and T. J. Kehoe. Boston:
Kluwer Academic, 1995, 1-31.
Levy, H., and A. Levy. "Stochastic Dominance and the
Investment Horizon with Riskless Assets." Review of Economic
Studies, 49(3), 1982, 427-38.
McNollgast. "Positive and Normative Models of Procedural
Rights: An Integrative Approach to Administrative Procedures."
Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 6, 1990, 307-32.
Modigliani, F., and L. Modigliani. "Risk-Adjusted
Performance." Journal of Portfolio Management, 23(2), 1997, 45-54.
Ostrom, V., and E. Ostrom. "Public Goods and Public
Choices," in Polycentricity and Local Public Economies. Readings
from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, edited by M.
McGinnis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1999, 75-105.
Pope, D., and J. Pope. "The Impact of College Sports Success
on the Quantity and Quality of Student Applications." Southern
Economic Journal, 75(3), 2009, 750-80.
Ramey, G., and V. A. Ramey. "The Rug Rat Race." Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 2010, 129-76.
Reinhart, C., and V. Reinhart. "After the Fall." Working
Paper No. 16334, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2010.
Reinhart, C., V. Reinhart, and K. Rogoff. "Debt Overhangs:
Past and Present." Working Paper No. 18015, National Bureau of
Economic Research, 2012.
Romer, C., and D. Romer. "The Most Dangerous Idea in Federal
Reserve History: Monetary Policy Doesn't Matter." American
Economic Review, 103(3), 2013, 55-60.
Rosen, H. S., and K. T. Rosen. "Federal Taxes and
Homeownership: Evidence from Time Series." Journal of Political
Economy, 88(1), 1980, 59-75.
Sexton, S. E., and A. L. Sexton. "Conspicuous Conservation:
The Prius Halo and Willingness to Pay for Environmental Bona
Fides." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 67(3),
2014, 303-17.
Simcoe, T. S., and D. M. Waguespack. "Status, Quality, and
Attention: What's in a (Missing) Name?" Management Science,
57(2), 2011, 274-90.
Skarbek, D., E. Skarbek, B. Skarbek, and E. Skarbek.
"Sweatshops, Opportunity Costs, and Non-Monetary Compensation:
Evidence from El Salvador." American Journal of Economics and
Sociology, 71(3), 2012, 539-61.
Stinebrickner, R., and T. Stinebrickner. "A Major in Science?
Initial Beliefs and Final Outcomes for College Major and Dropout."
Review of Economic Studies, 81 (1), 2014, 426-72.
Summers, L., and V. Summers. "When Financial Markets Work Too
Well: A Cautious Case for a Securities Transactions Tax." Journal
of Financial Services Research, 3(2-3), 1989, 261-86.
Tremblay, C. H., M. J. Tremblay, and V. J. Tremblay. "A
General Cournot-Bertrand Model with Homogeneous Goods." Theoretical
Economics Letters, 1, 2011, 38-40.
Ulph, A., and D. Ulph. "Optimal Climate Change Policies When
Governments Cannot Commit." Environmental and Resource Economics,
56(2), 2013, 161-76.
Van Praag, C. M., and B. M. Van Praag. "The Benefits of Being
Economics Professor A (rather than Z)." Economica, 75(300), 2008,
782-96.
(1.) Engerset al. (1999) show that alphabetical ordering by surname
is actually an equilibrium in a market where participants are interested
in evaluating the relative contribution of coauthors. That this paper
uses first names to order coauthors suggests the stability of that
equilibrium.
(2.) McNollgast (1990) avoids this ordering challenge by collapsing
all coauthors' surnames into a single surname. For details, see
web.stanford.edu/group/mcnollgast/cgi-bin/ wordpress/mcnollgast/.
(3.) We thank Stefano DellaVigna and David Card for sharing this
data, without which much of this analysis would have been impossible.
(4.) For purposes of this paper, we focus on research whose
coauthors all share a surname. This excludes examples such as Reinhart.
Reinhart, and Rogoff (2012), whose inclusion of Ken Rogoff as coauthor
was disqualifying. We also dismissed intriguing but ultimately
irrelevant research such as Gordon and Dahl (2013), in which one
coauthor's surname is the other's first name.
(5.) We encourage readers to send us further examples by leaving
comments at scholar.harvard.edu/joshua
goodman/blog/surname-sharing-coauthors.
(6.) We exclude Stinebrickner and Stinebrickner (2014) because,
though son Todd is an economist, father Ralph is a computer scientist by
training.
(7.) One of us once coauthored a paper with an unrelated John
Goodman, Jr., but the generational suffix renders this research
irrelevant to the current study. See Goodman and Goodman Jr. (1997).
(8.) We feel fortunate that Todd, Ralph, Lori, Diana, and Monica
Stinebrickner have yet to post or publish their working paper
"Inter-family coordination in the collection of a detailed
longitudinal survey: evidence from the collection of the Berea Panel
Study".
(9.) David Skarbek graciously shared these facts via personal
correspondence.
(10.) None of us is sufficiently interested in exploring this fact
to spend money on DNA-testing services.
(11.) An exhaustive list of such potential collaborations can be
found at ideas.repec.org/homonyms.html. We thank Christian Zimmermann
for pointing this out.
ALLEN C. GOODMAN, JOSHUA GOODMAN, LUCAS GOODMAN and SARENA GOODMAN
*
* For invaluable research assistance, we thank Napat Jatusripitak
and Carlos Paez, even though their surnames are quite different from
ours. Susannah Tobin, no relation to James, thought up the title. We
thank Yoram Bauman and four anonymous referees for valuable feedback. We
received no support for this research from any source. The analysis and
conclusions set forth are those of the authors and do not indicate
concurrence by other members of the research staff or the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve. Any errors are Goodman's.
Goodman, A.: Department of Economics, Wayne State University,
Huntington Woods, MI 48070. Phone 313577-3235, Fax 313-577-9564, E-mail
allen.goodman @wayne.edu
Goodman, J.: Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University,
Cambridge, MA 02138. Phone 617-496-9720, E-mail joshua_goodman @hks.
harvard.edu
Goodman. L.: Department of Economics, University of Maryland,
College Park, MD 20742. Phone 206-9190469, E-mail goodman@econ.umd.edu
Goodman, S.: Division of Research and Statistics, Consumer Finance
Section, Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Washington, DC 20551. Phone
202-973-6961, Fax 516702-4053, E-mail sarena.f.goodman@frb.gov