Dubious and dubiouser: contingent valuation and the time of day.
Dickinson, David L. ; Whitehead, John C.
I. INTRODUCTION
The contingent valuation method (CVM) is a stated preference
approach to the valuation of public goods (Carson 2012a, 2012b).
Preferences are "stated" in the sense that survey respondents
are asked hypothetical behavior questions that can be used to reveal
their home-grown valuations. The CVM may be useful for estimating
benefits and costs involving changes in unpriced, nonmarket goods and
services for which no revealed preference data exist. Economists
traditionally assume that tastes are constant (Stigler and Becker 1977).
While many models in economics allow for preference changes, CVM
researchers typically either (implicitly) assume stable and unchanging
preferences over the course of a day, or they simply ignore how
time-of-day may impact willingness to pay. The issue of time-of-day
effects on CVM data is the focus of this article.
The Exxon Valdez oil spill focused attention on the CVM and the
1990s was an active period of research that became known as the
"CVM debate" (Portney 1994). The high point of the CVM debate
may have been Diamond and Hausman's (1994) declaration that they
prefer no (willingness to pay) number to some number (developed using
the CVM) for policy analysis. During the most recent decade, those
interested in CVM research were able to go about their business without
much grief from the rest of the economics profession. But now the recent
BP Deepwater Horizon oil spill has reawakened the CVM debate within the
economics profession (Kling, Phaneuf, and Zhao 2012). The highlight of
this reawakening may be Hausman's (2012) declaration that his
opinion has gone from "dubious to hopeless" about the ability
of the CVM to provide any useful information. (1)
While researchers have considered issues related to time in
contingent valuation (e.g., Propper 1990; Whittington et al. 1992;
Whitehead and Hoban 1999; Berrens et al. 2002), Diamond and Hausman
(1994) and Hausman (2012) will not even give the CVM "the time of
day." Therefore, not totally inexplicably, we consider time-of-day
effects by requiring survey respondents to answer a willingness to pay
question over the entire 24-hour cycle. A guiding principle, consistent
with the work of the CVM critics, is that a hypothetical valuation
question, especially one used for major policy issues and natural
resource damage assessments, should pass the most important theoretical
validity test no matter what time of day the survey is administered.
II. THEORY
As the CVM is based on responses to hypothetical valuation
questions there have been concerns about the validity of value
estimates. Validity is the extent to which a valuation method generates
a measure that is unbiased. Theoretical validity is the extent to which
a valuation measure changes in response to the changes in conditions
under which it is evaluated. Evidence from previous research suggests
that willingness to pay estimates may be theoretically valid in certain
situations (Carson 2012a, 2012b).
To develop the most basic test of the theoretical validity of the
CVM, consider indirect utility, v(p,q,y), where p is a vector of market
prices, q is an unpriced public good, and y is income. Willingness to
pay for a change in the public good, q >q, can be defined implicitly
as v(p, q',y- WTP) = v(p, q, y). Next, consider a dichotomous
choice valuation question where respondents are asked whether they would
be willing to pay a randomly assigned fee, A, for the change in the
public good. The respondent must compare utilities in two situations,
with the change in the public good and fee and without: v(p,q',y -
A) >/< v (p,q,y). Rearranging terms, the difference in utility
caused by the proposal is a function of the assigned fee, [DELTA]v =
v(p,q',y - A) - v(p,q,y) >/< 0. When survey respondents are
faced with a referendum vote the probability that they will vote for the
proposal is the probability that the change in utility is greater than
zero, Pr(for) = Pr[[DELTA] v(A)>0]. The probability that a respondent
is willing to pay the fee is decreasing in the fee as [partial
derivative][DELTA]v/[partial derivative]A < 0.
A. Data
Our data are from an online survey. Names from campus email lists
were randomly assigned to a 1-hour response window and subjects were
allowed to start and complete the survey once within the assigned
response window on Tuesday, Wednesday, or Thursday of the survey week
(Dickinson and McElroy 2010). All 24 hours of the day were utilized, and
there was an equal chance that any given subject might be assigned to
any of the 1-hour response windows. Recruitment emails highlighted the
incentives, the survey link, and the randomly assigned time response
window. (2) For this article, we focus on subject responses to the
following CVM referendum question:
The Renewable Energy Initiative (REI; http://www.rei.appstate.edu)
was created by motivated students in an attempt to reduce ASU's
carbon footprint. The REI is charged with bringing renewable energy
projects to the campus of Appalachian State. Each semester, every
student at ASU pays $5 from their student fees into a fund controlled by
the REI. One project that the REI is currently considering is the
purchase of a medium scale wind turbine. ASU has offered land behind the
Broyhill Inn for installation. However, funds for purchase, installation
and operation of the wind turbine are unavailable. It is estimated that
an additional $A from each ASU student each year would be needed for the
purchase, installation and operation of the wind turbine. If this issue
was presented as a referendum during the next student election, would
you vote for or against the increase in student fees?
* For
* Against
* Don 7 know
* I need more information
The student fee, $A = 4, 8, 16, 24, 40, or 56, was randomly
assigned across survey treatments. (3)
A total of 683 subjects completed the survey, with an average 28.5
responses per each 1 -hour time slot of the day. We discard 92
respondents who completed the survey at a time other than their assigned
time and 67 nonstudents who would not be bound by the payment vehicle.
We use a final data set of 524 subjects. (4) Fifty-seven percent of the
sample is female, which is similar to the population of students at our
institution (55% female). The average age is 24 (range 18-47) years.
Sixty-one percent of respondents voted for the increase in student fees.
A total of 11% voted against, 5% did not know, and 23% needed more
information. The average student fee is $27.
Time of day is split into four blocks associated with higher versus
lower alertness ratings as established in the literature (Dickinson and
McElroy 2010). We call these four time blocks as night, morning,
afternoon, and evening. Night is between 12:00 am and 6:00 a.m., morning
is between 6 a.m. and 12p.m.. afternoon is between 12 p.m. and6 p.m.,
and evening is between 6 p.m. and 12 p.m. Twenty-four percent of the
sample took the survey during the night (n= 128), 23% in the morning (n
= 119), 30% in the afternoon (n = 155), and 23% in the evening (n =
122).
III. RESULTS
Considering first the frequency of votes in the student referendum,
responses from the night time block were 63% "for" at $4 and
61% "for" at a fee of $56 (Table 1). The "for" votes
are highest at fees of $8 and $16 and lowest at fees of $24 and $40. The
chi-square statistic indicates that variation in "for" votes
is not statistically different across student fees. Results are more
typical during the morning time block: all seven respondents vote for
the proposal at the $4 fee and only 42% vote yes at the $56 fee, but the
chi-square statistic only reveals price variation is statistically
significant at the p =. 11 level. The afternoon and evening votes reveal
statistically significant variation in the "for" votes at the
p~.05 level in the predicted direction. The CVM passes this key validity
test only in the afternoon and evening time blocks.
We next estimate the determinants of "for" votes and
willingness to pay using the censored logistic regression model (Cameron
1988). During morning, afternoon, and evening time blocks, students vote
rationally with "for" votes declining as the student fee rises
(Table 2). The model chisquare statistic is significant in the morning,
afternoon, and evening time block models but is not statistically
significant in the night-time model. During the night time, students are
completely insensitive to the student fee, at least in the standard way
of thinking; the student fee has no statistically significant effect on
"for" votes. (5,6)
Willingness to pay for the renewable energy proposal is $52 during
the night time, $38 in the morning, $39 in the afternoon, and $23 in the
evening. (7) Given the width of the confidence intervals the willingness
to pay estimates are not significantly different from each other.
However, the point estimate of the night-time willingness to pay is
economically different from the other time periods. For example, with
17,000 students at Appalachian State University, the aggregate
willingness to pay during the night time is $884,000 compared to
$391,000 during the evening. Nighttime contingent valuation may lead to
too many environmental policy proposals passing the benefit cost test.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
In this article, we find that survey respondents do not pass a key
validity test during the time of day when most experience the deep
circadian trough of sleepiness (i.e., night). Interpreting our results
in the least charitable way calls into question the validity of the CVM.
Hausman (2012), in the context of another test of validity (i.e., scope)
suggests that "as contingent valuation surveys are typically
pretested, the survey design can be manipulated to ensure that at least
minimal scope effects are present." The same can be said for price
effects. Perhaps CVM surveys have been manipulated so that survey
respondents participate during times of the day, such as morning,
afternoon, and evening, when at least minimal price effects are present.
These results have implications for contingent valuation survey
research. Mail, in-person, and phone are the traditional survey modes.
Of these, in-person and phone surveys are typically conducted during
morning, afternoon, and evening hours. But mail survey respondents are
able to complete the questionnaire at any time. Therefore, mail survey
respondents could have been answering questions during the night for
decades! More recently, online surveys have become ubiquitous.
Researchers should implore mail and internet survey respondents with
explicit warnings to complete the survey during the morning, afternoon,
and evening hours. Given the ability to time stamp survey taking with
online survey administration, at the least, time-of-day effects should
be routinely reported by CVM researchers. Diligent referees should
require such reporting or just assume the worst from the data.
At the risk of encouraging more contingent valuation research,
these results suggest future investigation in the area of sleep and
contingent valuation. In our survey, the subjects were not forced to
respond during the night if that was their assigned time slot. So, our
sample includes some self-selection. (8) Presumably those subjects who
are less bothered by the prospect of survey-taking during the night are
the ones in the sample. This likely reflects the natural mix of
individuals who may be awake during the night: some who are awake by
voluntary choice (e.g., students who study rather than sleep, the
undead, etc.), and others awake for less than completely voluntary
reasons (new parents, procrastinating students, the authors as we try to
revise this article before it is considered a new submission). Future
time of day and CVM research should consider these selection effects.
The night-time bias we find may be a more general reflection of CVM
response patterns when cognitive resources are depleted. In other words,
when cognitive resources are depleted for any reason, perhaps then CVM
responses are insensitive to prices, the scope of the good and
willingness to accept diverges from willingness to pay. Future research
should explore whether there is cause for concern in CVM studies that
might include other forms of cognitively depleted respondents in their
data. Examples might include subjects who are multitasking during survey
response (thus, cognitive resources are being diverted by other tasks),
or whether it has been several hours since the last meal suggesting low
blood sugar and limited glucose availability to fuel brain function.
Evaluating the validity of CVM response data just got a lot more
complicated.
Finally, time-of-day effects should also be explored in other areas
of economic research. For example, night-time laboratory and field
experiments might also lead to questions about their validity, and
time-of-day effects may be important in studies of subjective
well-being. Survey respondents may be willing to take a survey during
the night time but they may not be at all happy about it. While this
research may raise other concerns or ideas for future research, further
mention is beyond the scope of this article. In other words, we have
decided to just sleep on it.
ABBREVIATIONS
CVM: Contingent Valuation Method
REI: Renewable Energy Initiative
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12161
REFERENCES
Berrens, R. P., H. Jenkins-Smith, A. K. Bohara, and C. L. Silva.
"Further Investigation of Voluntary Contribution Contingent
Valuation: Fair Share, Time of Contribution, and Respondent
Uncertainty." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
44(1), 2002, 144-68.
Cameron, T. A. "A New Paradigm for Valuing Non-market Goods
Using Referendum Data: Maximum Likelihood Estimation by Censored
Logistic Regression." Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 15(3), 1988, 355-79.
--. "Interval Estimates of Non-market Resource Values from
Referendum Contingent Valuation Surveys." Land Economics, 67(4),
1991, 413-21.
Carson, R. T. Contingent Valuation: A Comprehensive Bibliography
and History. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2012a.
--. "Contingent Valuation: A Practical Alternative When Prices
Aren't Available." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(4),
2012b, 27-42.
Diamond, P. A., and J. A. Hausman. "Contingent Valuation: Is
Some Number Better Than No Number?" Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 8(4), 1994, 45-64.
Dickinson. D. L., and T. McElroy. "Rationality Around the
Clock: Sleep and Time-of-Day Effects on Guessing Game Responses."
Economics Letters, 108(2), 2010, 245-48.
Haab, T. C., M. G. Interis, D. R. Petrolia, and J. C. Whitehead.
"From Hopeless to Curious? Thoughts on Hausman's 'Dubious
to Hopeless' Critique of Contingent Valuation." Applied
Economic Policy and Perspectives, 35(4), 2013,593-612.
Hausman, J. "Contingent Valuation: From Dubious to
Hopeless." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(4), 2012, 43-56.
Kling, C. L., D. J. Phaneuf, and J. Zhao. "From Exxon to BP:
Has Some Number Become Better Than No Number?" Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 26(4), 2012, 3-26.
Portney, P. R. "The Contingent Valuation Debate: Why
Economists Should Care." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(4),
1994, 3-17.
Propper, C. "Contingent Valuation of Time Spent on NHS Waiting
Lists." The Economic Journal, 100(400), 1990. 193-99.
Stigler, G. J., and G. S. Becker. "De Gustibus Non Est
Disputandum." American Economic Review, 67, 1977, 76-90.
Whitehead, J. C., and T. J. Hoban. "Testing for Temporal
Reliability in Contingent Valuation with Time for Changes in Factors
Affecting Demand." Land Economics, 3, 1999, 453-65.
Whittington, D., V. K. Smith, A. Okorafor, A. Okore, J. L. Liu, and
A. McPhail. "Giving Respondents Time to Think in Contingent
Valuation Studies: A Developing Country Application." Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 22(3), 1992, 205-25.
(1.) See Haab et al. (2013) for a cromulent reply to Hausman
(2012).
(2.) A random prize drawing of $100 ($300 for midnight to 8 a.m.
time slots) was used as an incentive for completing the survey within
the assigned response window. The initial recruitment e-mail highlighted
that one survey question, unrelated to the CVM question, would also
offer the chance to win an additional $50. Responses to that
incentivized question were analyzed by Dickinson and McElroy (2010).
(3.) Referendum valuation questions are increasing in incentive
compatibility with their consequentiality (Carson, 2012a, 2012b).
Questions are consequential if the survey respondent cares about the
proposal and feels that it might influence policy. The hypothetical
referendum has some degree of consequentiality given that the Broyhill
Wind Turbine was a real proposal at the time of the survey.
(4.) All of the data in this study are available on request from
the authors. Unlike Bigfoot sightings, we have proof that the data for
this study are real and not made up. Our interpretations may be more
suspect, but the design and data are real.
(5.) While based on the sleep literature our choice of time blocks
is somewhat ad hoc. Note that we obtain similar results for the group of
respondents who took the survey between 1 a.m. and 5 a.m. Including
respondents at 11 p.m. or 7 a.m. causes the price coefficient to be
marginally significant (p =. 10). We should also note that gender, age,
and a variable to capture the previous (self-reported) night sleep
quantity of the subjects were all statistically insignificant (results
available on request). This leaves us with the remaining result: CVM
responses do NOT go bump in the night!
(6.) As pointed out by a colleague, given that our subjects are
college students, the night-time sample results could be affected by
alcohol consumption. This concern is mitigated somewhat by our design
choice to not include traditional party nights in the 72-hour data
collection period (well, that is unless one considers Thirsty Thursday a
party night).
(7.) Willingness to pay is the ratio of the constant and the
coefficient on the fee amount. Standard errors for willingness to pay
are estimated using the Wald method (Cameron 1991).
(8.) By this we mean that not all subjects recruited from e-mail
lists chose to participate. As noted before, if a subject was assigned a
particular response time slot but completed the survey during some other
time, then we discard the data from that subject.
DAVID L. DICKINSON and JOHN C. WHITEHEAD *
* The authors thank Appalachian State University for funding and
Todd Cherry, Tim Haab, Matt Interis. two journal referees, and Yoram
Bauman for many helpful comments. While funding from a major oil company
has not been received by the authors, on this or any past project,
readers still should not take this article too seriously. While the
empirical results could be developed into a reasonably serious paper,
the authors could only be motivated to write it for yucks and grins.
After comments from reviewers such as "I don't think this is
humorous" and "I didn't laugh or would I expect others
to," we have reconsidered our informal description of this as a
"funny paper." In defense of our initial stance, however, we
did survey some colleagues and got a strange look or two.
Dickinson: Department of Economics, Appalachian State University,
Boone, NC 28607. Phone 828-262-7652, Fax 828-262-6105, E-mail
dickinsondl@appstate.edu
Whitehead: Department of Economics, Appalachian State University,
Boone, NC 28607. Phone 828-262-6121, Fax 828-262-6105, E-mail
whiteheadjc@appstate.edu
TABLE 1
Frequency of "for" Votes
Night (12 Morning (6 Afternoon Evening (6
a.m. to 6 a.m to 12 (12 p.m. to p.m. to 12
a.m.) p.m.) 6 p.m.) a.m.)
Fee For Total For Total For Total For Total
4 5 8 7 7 13 15 6 10
8 23 33 20 34 27 41 18 25
16 9 12 6 8 5 9 2 4
24 14 30 17 32 20 34 15 38
40 9 22 6 12 10 26 10 22
56 14 23 11 26 14 30 6 23
Total 74 128 67 119 89 155 57 122
[chi square] 7.63 (.18) 9.05 11.72 11.89
(p = .11) (p = .04) (p = .04)
TABLE 2
Logistic Regression
Dependent Variable: Vote ("for" Votes = 1)
Night Morning
(12 a.m. to 6 a.m.) (6 a.m. to 12 p.m.)
Estimate SE Estimate
Intercept 0.646 ** 0.325 0.828 **
Fee -0.012 0.010 -0.022 **
Model [chi square] 1.53 4.61 **
(2 df)
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.009 0.028
WTP 52.05 ** 25.07 38.42 ***
Cases 128 119
Afternoon
(12 p.m. to 6 p.m.)
SE Estimate SE
Intercept 0.334 0.970*** 0.296
Fee 0.011 -0.025 *** 0.009
Model [chi square] 8.03 ***
(2 df)
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.038
WTP 10.31 38.66*** 7.84
Cases 155
Evening
(6 a.m. to 12 p.m.)
Estimate SE
Intercept 0.732** 0.351
Fee -0.032*** 0.011
Model [chi square] 8.79 **
(2 df)
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.052
WTP 23.13*** 6.07
Cases 122
Note: ***, **, and * indicates significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%
level, respectively.