Within U.S. trade and the long shadow of the American secession.
Felbermayr, Gabriel ; Groschl, Jasmin
I. INTRODUCTION
One hundred fifty years after Confederate troops attacked Fort
Sumter in South Carolina, a recent U.S.-wide survey by the Pew Research
Center summarizes the findings as: "The Civil War at 150: Still
Relevant, Still Divisive." (1) The poll reports that 56% of
Americans believe that the Civil War is still relevant to politics and
public life today. And that 4 in 10 Southerners sympathize with the
Confederacy. But does the long defunct border between the Confederation
and the Union still affect economic relations between U.S. states that
belonged to different alliances today? Is the former border still
relevant, still divisive, for economic transactions? This paper sheds
light on this question using bilateral trade flows between states.
The Civil War has cost 620,000 American lives, more than any other
military conflict. Goldin and Lewis (1975) document that it has retarded
the economic development of the whole nation and of the South in
particular. And, as the Pew poll shows, the nation is still divided
along the lines of the former alliances over whether the war was fought
over moral issues--slavery--or over economic policy. Yet, long before
the war, the Southern and the Northern economies differed: The South was
dominated by large-scale plantations of cotton, tobacco, rice, and
sugar, whose profitability relied on forced labor. It exported crops to
Europe and imported manufacturing goods from there. The North, dominated
by smaller land-holdings, was rapidly urbanizing; slavery was
practically abolished north of the Mason-Dixon Line by 1820. (2) Its
infant manufacturing industries were protected by import tariffs against
European competition.
The North-South divide is very visible in contemporaneous
state-level data. On average, the South is still poorer, more rural,
more agricultural, less educated, more religious, and has different
political views. The economic gap may have narrowed (Mitchener and
McLean 1999), in particular after the end of segregation in the 1960s.
But, political disagreement, in particular on the role of federal
government, continues to beset the country. A special sense of Southern
identity continues to mark a cultural divide within the United States.
This paper contributes to a growing literature on the long shadow
of history for economic transactions (Falck et al. 2010; Head, Mayer,
and Ries 2010; Nitsch and Wolf forthcoming). It shows that the former
border still constitutes a discontinuity in the economic geography of
the United States. The modern literature has identified cultural
differences across countries as impediments of international trade, but
typically not within the same country. Estimates of various border
effects abound in the literature and there are well-tested empirical
methods to measure their trade-inhibiting force. The more challenging
question in this paper is: Can the estimated border effect be
interpreted as a genuine Union-versus-Confederation effect?
We proceed in three steps. First, employing an OLS approach with
state fixed effects for bilateral trade between states, we find a
robust, statistically significant, and economically meaningful
trade-inhibiting effect of the former border. In the preferred 1993
data, on average, the historical border reduces trade between states of
the former Confederation or Union by about 13% to 14%. In comparison,
the Canada--U.S. border restricts trade by 155% to 165% (Anderson and
Van Wincoop 2003). Nitsch and Wolf (forthcoming) find that the former
border between East and West Germany restricts trade by about 26% to 30%
in 2004. Running a million placebos, we show that no other border
between random groups of (old) U.S. states yields a stronger
trade-reducing effect.
The result is robust to employing alternative methodologies (in
particular a Poisson model), using different waves of the Commodity Flow
Survey (CFS) (1997, 2002, 2007), drawing on sectoral rather than
aggregate bilateral trade data, measuring transportation costs
differently (travel time instead of sheer geographical distance), or
allowing for more flexibility by using distance intervals as in Eaton
and Kortum (2002) instead of a log-linear distance measure. Including
the rest of the world, or different treatment of states, whose
allegiance to either the Union or the Confederation is historically not
obvious, does not change the results. The estimated border effect
represents an ad valorem tariff equivalent of about 2% to 7%.
Interestingly, the effect is stronger (and more robust) in the food,
manufacturing, and chemicals sectors than in mining, which is
characterized by a completely standardized good, or machinery, where the
pattern of specialization across North and South is very strong.
In a second step, we add a large array of contemporaneous variables
to the original model to account for observable differences between the
South and the North. The controls are meant to capture migrant, ethnic,
or religious networks. While these variables matter empirically, they do
not reduce the estimated border effect. We account for cultural
differences expressed by different colonial relations across states, and
for different patterns of urbanization. We include variables that relate
to the institutional setup of states, or that measure differences in the
judicial system. We control for differences in endowment proportions, or
for differences in the structure of the states' economies. Finally,
we add demographic factors and test the Linder hypothesis. Most of these
controls have some explanatory power, but they do not undo the border
effect. The estimate falls from 13% to 11%. This finding survives the
same battery of robustness checks applied to the parsimonious model.
Third, we acknowledge that the North-South border, marked by the
Secession, is likely not to be exogenous. Engerman and Sokoloff (2000,
2005) suggest that it is related to endowment differences between
Northern and Southern states in cropland, or in the size and structure
of agricultural production. The emergence of the border may have to do
with historical ethnic patterns, historical educational achievements of
the population, or institutional differences as captured by the
historical incidence of malaria as in Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson
(2002). Finally, and most importantly, it may result from the incidence
of slavery. Not all of these variables matter empirically for
contemporaneous trade patterns, but they cannot easily be excluded from
the explanation of contemporaneous bilateral trade on conceptual
grounds. Including them into the gravity equation does not undo the
"Secession effect." Quite to the opposite, the estimated
effect actually increases. Finally, we extend the analysis to Western
states, but keep the same coding of the border. Thus, we add pairs of
states which have been completely unaffected by the Secession. Then, the
border dummy essentially captures whether two states have been on
opposing sides of the Civil War rather than belonging to the North or
the South. We continue to find a border effect (7% to 19%), which can
now be attributed more plausibly to the Secession.
The literature offers explanations of border effects in terms of
"political barriers," "arte-fact," and
"fundamentals." The first should be largely absent in an
integrated economy such as the United States. The second relates to
difficulties in separating the impact of border-related trade barriers
from the impact of geographical distance (Head and Mayer 2002) or to
problems of statistical aggregation (Hillberry and Hummels 2008). We
deal with these issues by using alternative measures of trade costs and
by a large number of placebo exercises. We view our results as
consistent with the "fundamentals" approach: historical events
have shaped cultural determinants of trade which still matter today.
Our results show that the United States is not a single market,
even 150 years after the Civil War. The historical conflict still is
divisive today. This is an important lesson for the European integration
process, which is more complex due to the lack of a common language, a
common legal/judicial system, common regulatory framework, and--most
important in our context--the fact that the last huge conflict is not
150 but only 67 years away. Hence, one should not be too optimistic in
assessing the economic effects of political union. From a welfare
perspective, our results allow two interpretations. First, it could be
that the Secession has had lasting effects on trade costs. By shaping
the distribution of (railway) infrastructure or business networks
(production clusters), and more generally, by affecting bilateral trust,
South-North trade frictions are still higher than intra-group frictions.
To the extent that our estimates measure this, it signals a long-lasting
welfare loss due to the Secession. Second, it could be that the
Secession had lasting effects on preferences. The trade embargo during
the war could have led to persistent preferences for local goods due to
habit formation. In that case, a welfare interpretation of our findings
is more problematic, in particular quantitatively. However, if the
divergence of preferences was indeed caused by the war, depending on the
precise characterization of preferences, the estimate can still be
interpreted as an indication of welfare losses.
The literature on border effects was pioneered by McCallum (1995),
who finds that trade volumes between Canadian provinces were about 22
times larger than those between Canada and the United States in 1988.
Subsequent research shows that states usually trade 5 to 20 times more
domestically than internationally. (3) Few studies have moved from
simply exploring border barriers to investigating and explaining
potential causes. Wei (1996) and Hillberry (1999) do not find that
tariffs, quotas, exchange rate variability, transaction costs, and
regulatory differences can explain the border effect. Recent studies
illustrate that the impact of borders also extends to the sub-national
level, implying that additional reasons for high local trade levels must
exist. Examples are Wolf (1997, 2000), Hillberry and Hummels (2003),
Combes, Lafourcade, and Mayer (2005), Buch and Toubal (2009), and Nitsch
and Wolf (forthcoming).
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section II
provides details of the empirical strategy. Section III describes the
benchmark results, placebo estimations, and a sensitivity analysis.
Section IV uses a large array of contemporaneous controls to address a
potential omitted variables problem. Section V attempts to explain the
"Secession effect" by historical variables and by adding
Western states to the analysis. The last section concludes.
II. EMPIRICAL STATEGY AND DATA
A. Empirical Strategy
Our empirical strategy follows Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003),
henceforth AvW, and the subsequent research. Based on a multi-country
framework of the Krugman (1980) constant elasticity of substitution
(CES) model with iceberg trade costs, the literature stresses that the
consistent estimation of bilateral barriers requires to take
multilateral trade resistance into account.
Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003) show that the CES demand system
with symmetric trade costs can be written as
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
and [z.sub.ij] [equivalent to] [x.sub.ij] /([Y.sub.i][Y.sub.j]) is
the value of bilateral exports [x.sub.ij] between state i and state j
relative to the product of the states' gross domestic products
(GDPs), [Y.sub.i] and [Y.sub.j]. [[beta].sub.0] is a constant across
state pairs, [[beta].sub.1] = -[alpha]([sigma] - 1) and [[beta].sub.2] =
-[rho]([[sigma] - 1]), where [sigma] > 1 is the elasticity of
substitution. [Border.sub.ij] = (1 - [[delta].sub.ij]) represents the
historical border line between Union and Confederate states, which takes
a value of unity if states in the pair historically belonged to opposing
alliances and zero otherwise, ln [Dist.sub.ij] is the log of
geographical distance between states. [X.sub.iy] denotes a vector of
additional controls, and the multilateral resistance terms are defined
as [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] where
[[theta].sub.k] is the share of income of state k in world income. In
our exercise, we substitute multilateral resistance terms with state
fixed effects and switch y on and off and work with various vectors
[X.sub.ij]. [[epsilon].sub.ij] is the standard error term.
The complication with estimating that model is that the
multilateral resistance terms In [P.sub.i.sup.1-[sigma]] and In
[P.sup.1-[sigma].sub.j] depend on estimates of [[??].sub.1] and
[[??].sub.2] in a nonlinear fashion. We follow a large strand of
literature (Anderson and Van Wincoop 2003; Feenstra 2004; Hummels 1999;
Redding and Venables 2004) and apply origin and destination fixed
effects in an ordinary least squares (OLS) gravity regression. The fixed
effects capture all time-invariant origin and destination specific
determinants, such as multilateral resistance terms, but also
geographical characteristics and historical or cultural facts. The model
deploying state fixed-effects accounts for any state-level unobserved
heterogeneity. We proxy trade costs by geographical distance, adjacency,
and the historical border between the former alliances of states in the
Union and the Confederacy.
In this paper, we also use the Poisson pseudo maximum likelihood
(PPML) method with state fixed effects suggested by Santos Silva and
Tenreyro (2006). The PPML approach has important advantages when trade
flows are measured with error. Then, heteroskedastic residuals do not
only lead to inefficiency of the log-linear estimator, but also cause
inconsistency. This is because of Jensen's inequality which says
that the expected value of the logarithm of a random variable is
different from the logarithm of its expected value. This suggests that
E(ln [z.sub.ij]) not only depends on the mean of [z.sub.ij], but also on
higher moments of the distribution. Heteroskedasticity in the residuals,
which at first glance only affects efficiency of the estimator, feeds
back into the conditional mean of the dependent variable, which, in
general, violates the zero conditional mean assumption on the error term
needed to guarantee consistency.
For robustness reasons, we also estimate the nonlinear least
squares (NLS) model suggested by Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003) to
identify the border effect. (4) Finally, we implement the idea of Baier
and Bergstrand (2009) to linearize the model with the help of a
first-order expansion of the multilateral resistance terms and estimate
by OLS.
B. Data Sources
For within--and cross-state trade flows, we focus on bilateral
export data from the 1993, 1997, 2002, and 2007 CFS collected by the
Bureau of Transportation Statistics. The CFS tracks shipments in net
selling values in millions of dollars. The CFS covers 200,000 (100,000;
50,000; 100,000) representative U.S. firms for 1993 (1997; 2002; 2007).
The literature is concerned about the low number of firms surveyed in
the waves after 1993, see Erlbaum, Holguin-Veras, and Hancock (2006).
For this reason, existing studies have usually focused on the 1993 wave
which represents about 25% of registered U.S. firms; we follow in this
tradition. GDP by state stems from the Regional Economic Accounts,
provided by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. Bilateral distance is
calculated as the great circle distance between state capitals.
Our primary sample consists of 28 U.S. states divided into two
groups that originate from the split caused by the Secession (Figure 1).
The South comprises 11 states, while the North consists of 17 states, as
listed in Table 1. Five states (Delaware, Kentucky, Maryland, Missouri,
and West Virginia) are excluded from the benchmark sample since soldiers
from these states fought on both sides of the Civil War and the
allegiance to either group of states is unclear. Still today, these five
states do not belong to the (fuzzily defined) "deep South."
(5) Somewhat abusing terminology, we call these five states border
states. We conduct sensitivity analysis with respect to the choice of
excluding those states. (6)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Table A1 in the Appendix shows averages and standard deviations
(for the year 1993) of the variables used in this study. Southern states
have on average substantially larger shares of Afro-Americans (22.9% vs.
7.4%); the share of Christians is higher while the share of Jewish
citizens is smaller (0.8% vs. 2.1%). The percentage share of urban
population is lower in the South than in the North (65.7% vs. 72.9%).
Historically (as of 1860), average farm sizes were substantially larger
in the South than in the North; this gap has closed since then. The same
is true for educational outcomes (illiteracy and average schooling). The
GDP per capita average across the South is about 12% lower than the
average across the North. The most dramatic differences in 1993 data
pertain to institutional variables: The North is much more unionized
than the South. All Northern states had a minimum wage while only 45.5%
of the Southern states had one. In the 1992 presidential election, 64%
of Southern states voted Republican while only 12% of Northern states
did. (7)
Figure 2 plots cumulative distribution functions (CDFs) of
bilateral trade flows scaled by both states' GDPs. (8) For all
years, the cumulative distribution function for North-South flows lies
to the left of flows within the North or the South. Interestingly,
South-South flows stochastically dominate North-North flows. In 1993,
where data quality is best, the median flow is about 30% larger within
the South than across South and North. This is of course a rough
exercise as it does not control for other variables, such as distance,
but it gives a first visual sense of how big the border effect is.
III. THE EFFECT OF THE FORMER UNION-CONFEDERATION BORDER
A. Benchmark Results
Estimating Equation (1) allows to assess the average impact of the
border on cross-border North-South trade flows relative to within-region
flows. Table 2 provides our benchmark results for the year of 1993. In
line with the gravity literature, the estimated elasticity of distance
is very close to -1 and highly significant at the 1% level. In our
sample, and in accordance with the literature, adjacency increases
bilateral trade. Due to the omission of border states from our baseline
estimations, adjacency correlates negatively with the border. If
adjacency increases trade, its omission would bias the border effect
away from zero. In column (1), we estimate the model using origin and
destination fixed effects, which account for all unobserved importer and
exporter characteristics. Our model explains 84% of the variation in
trade patterns. Under fixed effects, cross-border trade is on average
12.8% ([e.sup.-0137] - 1) smaller than within region trade. Hence, the
border equals a tariff of 2% to 7%, depending on the choice of
elasticity of substitution. (9) Compared to international border
effects, this is a substantial amount for a sub-national barrier caused
by an event more than a century ago. Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003)
find that cross-border trade for the Canada-U.S. case is about 80.8%
lower than within trade. (10) This amounts to a tariff equivalent of 20%
to 128%. Results by Nitsch and Wolf (forthcoming) suggest that the
former East-West border within Germany reduces cross-border trade by
about 20.5% relative to within-region trade. (11)
In column (2), we use two indicator variables to measure
within-group trade relative to cross-border trade separately for the
North and the South. We find that trade within the South is 1.66 times
larger than cross-border trade with the North in 1993.
Counter-intuitively, the North trades 1.26 times less within the region
than across the border. This is puzzling, but fits the evidence
displayed in Figure 2. Next, we estimate a PPML approach with state
fixed effects suggested by Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006). Column (3)
shows that the border estimate remains very close compared to the OLS
fixed-effects estimation. The border impeding trade effect between the
North and the South persists with a magnitude of 14%.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Importantly, the puzzle on North-North trade is not robust. The
negative effect turns positive but insignificant when estimating the
model using PPML, while results on other variables remain very much the
same; see column (4). PPML can account for zeros in the trade data (16
observations in our data set). However, the main difference to OLS lies
in the fact that it obtains consistent estimates even in the presence of
measurement error causing heteroskedasticity. Therefore, we interpret
the puzzling finding in column (2) as an artifact. (12)
In column (5), we estimate a "multicountry" model. We
consider trade between U.S. states, between 20 OECD countries (13) and
exports from individual U.S. states to OECD countries (14) into the PPML
fixed-effects model of column (3). We use OECD trade, distance, and
GDP' data provided by AvW and U.S. state exports to OECD countries
from Robert Feenstra's webpage. (15) Column (5) reports that the
distance parameter remains relatively close to -1, while the border
reduces North-South trade within the United States by 13.4%. Sample size
increases to 1,764 observations, while the explanation power of our
model increases only slightly.
In the final step we explore the CFS data in more detail, as
disaggregated trade flows at the two-digit commodity level are
available. This is in the spirit of Hillberry (1999), who estimated
commodity specific border effects for products traded between Canada and
the United States in 1993. We pool over all commodities available in the
specific year. As commodities are subject to varying transportation
costs, we include Origin x Commodity and Destination x Commodity fixed
effects following Chen (2004). For 1993, results for the pooled
commodity fixed-effects estimation are depicted in Table 2, column (6).
We find that the border reduces North-South trade by 7.7%.
Estimates of the Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003) NLS model indicate
that the border reduces trade flows between the North and the South by
about 19.6% in 1993. When we estimate the model by including MR terms
into the gravity estimation as suggested by Baier and Bergstrand (2009),
we find that the adjusted explanation power of the estimation slightly
falls to 67%, while the border estimate remains very close compared to
the fixed-effects estimation. The impeding trade effect of the border
between the North and the South remains at 12%. (16)
B. Placebo Estimations
Is there something special about trade across the former
Union-Confederation border as opposed to trade across other hypothetical
borders? To deal with this question, we randomly assign 11 out of the 28
"old" U.S. states to a hypothetical "South" and the
remainder to a hypothetical "North." (17) Based on regression
(1) of Table 2, we run a million placebo regressions. We find a negative
and significant (at the 10% level) border effect in 7% of the cases. In
12 cases, the border effect is slightly larger than the 12.8% found in
our benchmark case. The largest effect we find is 1.2 percentage points
larger than our original effect, but the standard error is so large that
one cannot reject the hypothesis that the effect is identical to the
12.8 benchmark result. In all 12 cases, the "South" consists
predominantly of New England and the Great Lakes States.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 3 compares the hypothetical South to the "true"
sample by counting the number of misallocated states (put into the
"wrong" group). Diagram (a) depicts that all samples, where
one state was misallocated, yield a negative and statistically
significant border effect. If two states are misallocated that share
drops to about 58%; if more than five states are put into the
"wrong" group the share falls below 10%. Diagram (b) displays
the absolute value of the average border effect found in different
subsamples. If one state is allocated to the "wrong" group,
the average border effect is about 0.11 (as compared to 0.14 in the
"correct" grouping). The average effect falls quickly as more
states are misallocated and is below 0.01 if five or more states are
exchanged.
In further placebo exercises, we investigate border effects between
coastal and interior states as well as between Eastern and Western
states in the whole United States. We do not find a border effect
between coastal and interior states. There is no border effect either at
a hypothetical East-West border (approximately drawn at the 90[grados]
longitude line). Differences between these states can be explained by
our contemporaneous controls. (18) To provide further falsification
tests, we consider regions where states are clustered together and split
the 28-state sample into Eastern and Western states. We find no
significant border effect. (19) Further, we arbitrarily break North and
South into two regions (Northeast-Midwest; Southeast-Southwest) each. We
find no evidence of a border effect within the subregions. (20)
C. Sensitivity Analysis
Table 3 summarizes border effect estimates obtained from using the
1997, 2002, or 2007 waves of the CFS rather than the more reliable 1993
data. Across the OLS fixed-effects model, the PPML fixed-effects
approach, and the commodity-level regression, we find negative border
effects that are all highly statistically significant. Interestingly,
there is no evidence that the border effect shrinks over time.
Comparison across time is hindered by different sampling across waves.
The former border reduces trade by between 7% and 16%, with the average
effect clustering around at about 12%.
The use of geographical distance as a measure of transportation
costs has been criticized by Head and Mayer (2002). Since 71% to 75% of
shipments in the United States are transported by truck (Department of
Transportation), we use actual travel time from Google maps as an
alternative measure of transportation costs. Ozimek and Miles (2011)
provide a tool to retrieve these data. We find that the use of travel
time reduces the estimated border effect in the preferred 1993 sample
from 10% to 7%, thereby confirming the hypothesis that geographical
distance slightly inflates the estimated border effects. However, across
waves, the effect remains negative and statistically significant. (21)
As it is important to measure distance correctly, we allow for
further flexibility and use distance intervals as in Eaton and Kortum
(2002) instead of a log-linear distance measure. We therefore create
five distance intervals (in kilometers) including distances as: [0,250),
[250,500), [500,1000), [1000,2000), and [2000,max] and include dummies
thereof into the regression. We find border effects to be slightly more
trade impeding compared to when using the log-linear distance measure
and still highly significant for all years. (22) Interestingly, we find
a similar distance ranking as in Eaton and Kortum (2002) for U.S.
states. Distance intervals that capture relatively close state pairs
have a smaller negative effect on trade than pairs that are further
apart relative to the closest distance interval [0,250). From this we
conclude that our border results are not qualitatively affected by the
distance measure.
To make sure that our treatment of border states (i.e., states
whose allegiance was unclear and that are therefore excluded from our
benchmark sample), does not bias our results, we assign them
alternatively to the South or to the North. The border states were slave
states, but officially never seceded, so it is counterfactual to include
them into the South. We find that the assignment of those border states
does not matter qualitatively for our findings. Estimated effects are
slightly lower than when border states are excluded altogether. (23)
California, Oregon, and Nevada fought on the side of the Union and may
thus be included in the sample on the side of the North, even though
they were separated from the other states by a large distance and the
territories that did not yet belong to the United States. Results do not
change qualitatively if we include the three states in the North. The
inclusion of the three states rather increases the border effect, which
turns out to reduce North-South trade by 17% under OLS fixed-effects and
18% under PPML fixed effects. (24) In addition, the Northern states
trade more with another under the OLS fixed-effects approach if we
include the three states in the North. (25)
D. Estimates by Sector
Finally, we also run regressions sector-by-sector. Table 4 provides
summary results, suppressing other coefficients except the one on the
border dummy. (26) The estimated border effect is [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], confounding the elasticity of
substitution and the trade-cost increasing effect of the border. It is
therefore not surprising that the low-[sigma] agricultural sector
features a high but only moderately robust estimate, while the
low-[sigma] mining sector does not display a border effect (except in
1997). No border effect exists in the machinery sector, neither. This is
presumably due to North-South differences in comparative advantage that
the simple model does not capture. The border effect is most pronounced
in the chemical and manufacturing sectors, where the degree of product
differentiation is high (hence, [sigma] low).
One may conjecture that the Secession has continuing negative
effects on the level of trust between market participants. It may also
have affected the strength of preferences for local products. Both
mechanisms should have no bearing on standardized (homogeneous) goods
whose quality can easily be verified and where idiosyncratic features of
demand should not matter (e.g., steel). It is therefore comforting that
the border effect is largest in sectors with typically strongly
differentiated output. The finding therefore supports the view that the
former border reflects a cultural divide.
IV. ACCOUNTING FOR OBSERVED CONTEMPORANEOUS HETEROGENEITY
A. Benchmark Results
In this section, we investigate whether observable characteristics
of state pairs bias the estimated coefficient. We include a large number
of contemporaneous determinants of trade that are discussed in the
empirical literature stepwise into the regression. If the variables are
not bilateral in nature, we bilateralize them by either taking the
absolute difference of variables in state i and state j, denoted by the
operator [DELTA], or by using the product of variables in state i and
state j, denoted by the operator x. The product of variables relates to
network effects between pairs, while the [DELTA] operator focuses on the
difference between state pairs. (27) Table 5 reports results for our
benchmark year 1993. All estimations include origin and destination
fixed effects.
Column (1) of Table 5 depicts the benchmark result including
geographical variables with a border effect of 13%. In column (2), we
account for the impact of ethnic, religious, or cultural networks
(Combes, Lafourcade, and Mayer 2005; Rauch 1999; Rauch and Trindade
2002) and migration within the United States (Helliwell 1997; Head and
Ries 1998; Millimet and Osang 2007). The literature reasons that common
culture and tastes increase trade flows as they facilitate contracts and
instill trust; they also make it more likely that states produce and
consume similar goods. Migration and networks might bias the border
effect estimate upwards as they increase trade but are negatively
associated with the border. To test the impact of networks we include
(1) cross-state migration stocks of people residing in one state but
were born in another taken from the American Community Survey Decennial
Census; (2) the product of the share of Afro-Americans in total state
population from the Population Estimates Program; (3) the product of the
Jewish population in total state population from the American Jewish
Yearbook; and (4) self-reported affinity to Christianity, other
religious groups, or no religion from the American Religious
Identification Survey 2008 Report, into the estimation. We find that
migration networks, high shares of Afro-Americans, of population shares
affiliated to Buddhism, Hinduism, or Islam, and of people not
self-identifying with any religious group spur trade flows. A 1%
increase in the bilateral migration stock indicates an increase in trade
by 13% in column (2). (28) If we include network controls, the border
still turns out to reduce bilateral trade by 11.3%. In addition, common
colonial heritage, also included in column (2), may have lasting effects
on bilateral trade. (29) We construct an indicator variable that takes
value one if a pair of states had a common colonizer (Britain, France,
or Spain) and zero otherwise. We find that a common colonial past
increases bilateral trade by about 22%. Yet, while most of those network
variables matter statistically, they reduce the estimated border effect
only slightly.
Column (3) examines the impact of labor market and political
institutions. We control for labor market institutions by including
dissimilarities in union membership and density from Hirsch, Macpherson,
and Vroman (2001), as well as a dummy for the existence of minimum wage
legislation provided by the U.S. Department of Labor. In theory,
differences in labor market institutions could increase bilateral trade,
because differential legislation acts as a source of comparative
advantage as in Cunat and Melitz (2012). In our analysis, we find that
institutional differences tend to reduce trade (albeit statistical
precision of estimates is nonexistent). This may signal that
institutional differences are caused by some deeper differences in
cultural norms and that the latter discourage trade by more. Column (3)
also controls for differences in the political alignment in the 1992
presidential election (Clinton against Bush sen.) and whether states
elect or appoint the judiciary. Voting behavior has no statistically
measurable effect on trade, while the difference in judiciary
appointment procedure turns out to depress bilateral trade flows. The
estimated border effect, however, remains virtually unchanged.
In column (4), we include controls for the difference in relative
factor endowments of states, thereby accounting for the Heckscher-Ohlin
trade theory. Omitting differences in factor proportions might lead to
an upward bias of the border coefficient, as differences in factor
proportions should increase trade flows and appear to be more pronounced
when the border is present. To measure contemporaneous differences in
relative factor proportions and human capital accumulation, we include
the absolute difference in (1) capital-labor shares from Turner, Tamura,
and Mulholland (2008); (2) shares of high and low skilled in the
population (30); (3) average years of schooling for the population over
25 from Turner et al. (2007); (4) cropland from the National Resource
Inventory Summary Report; (5) average farm size from the Census of
Agriculture; (6) agricultural relative to total output; and (7)
manufacturing relative to total output from the Bureau of Economic
Analysis. As in other gravity exercises, classical Heckscher-Ohlin
variables do not show up statistically significant, though both the
variables on the difference in the capital-labor ratio and the
difference in relative skill endowment bear the right sign. Differences
in the availability of cropland reduce bilateral trade. Contemporaneous
differences in factor endowments do not capture the border, which still
reduces North-South trade by 10.3%.
Column (5) includes demographic variables such as the difference in
contemporaneous population and population density from the Population
Estimates Program, as well as fertility rates from the Vital Statistics
of the United States. Common demographic features across states may
suggest common preferences, so that bilateral trade is larger for such
states. The estimated parameters, however, are insignificant throughout.
The border effect remains negative and significant.
Finally, following the literature on the Linder effect, we include
the difference in the log of per capita income as in Thursby and Thursby
(1987), Bergstrand (1989), and Hallak (2010). The hypothesis is that
states with dissimilar GDP per capita should have differing preference
structures and, hence, trade less. Since the border correlates
negatively with GDP per capita in the data, omitting the Linder term may
bias the border effect away from zero. This is, however, not what we
find. In column (6), we find no support for the Linder hypothesis; the
estimated border effect does not move. We have also experimented with
direct measures of inequality (Gini coefficients), but without success.
Column (6) represents our most comprehensive and preferred model.
The border effect is about 11.2%. It explains 87% of the variation in
bilateral trade flows, 67% of which are attributable to included
variables and controls. (31)
B. Sensitivity Analysis
Table 6 summarizes sensitivity results pertaining to the
comprehensive model in column (6) of Table 5. (32) Panel A deploys the
OLS fixed-effects approach. Our baseline border effect of -0.119 is
reported in column (A1). We find a negative and significant border
effect for 1993 and 2002, while the effect for 1997 and 2007 are
insignificant. Results based on the CFS from 1997 onwards suffer from
the fact that the number of firms surveyed is only around 25% of those
surveyed in 1993. In Panel B, we turn to the PPML model that includes
fixed effects. The border barrier turns out to be strong only in 1993.
If we use the pooled commodity fixed effects setup with
ImporterxCommodity and Destination x Commodity fixed effects following
Chen (2004) in Panel C, we find a strong trade impeding effect for all
years (except for 2002). Overall, we can conclude that the findings on
the border effect compare well to our earlier results. The border
reduces cross-border trade by 7% to 21%, depending on the year and the
specification. (33)
V. ACCOUNTING FOR HISTORICAL DETERMINANTS
A. Benchmark Results
The economic literature on the emergence of armed conflicts depicts
that strong bilateral trade links decrease the probability that two
countries go to war, while multilateral openness increases the odds of
conflict (Martin and Thoenig 2008). If determinants of bilateral trade
are persistent over time, the border could not be considered exogenous
in the statistical sense. Historical bilateral trade data are, however,
not available. But, one can include historical variables that may,
through their impact on historical trade patterns, affect the
probability of conflict (and thus the incidence of the border).
Moreover, Eichengreen and Irwin (1998) suggest that history might affect
contemporaneous trade flows through persistent effects on institutions.
According to Engerman and Sokoloff (2000, 2005), dissimilarities in
agricultural land use, driven by soil endowments and climate, led to the
South adopting slavery and, more broadly, to the emergence of
conflicting economic interests between the North and the South, and
ultimately, to the Secession. The different economic models may have
long-lasting effects on inequality within states, which may, in turn, be
relevant for today's level of economic transactions (Linder
effect). It may also have persistent effects on institutions, which
affect contemporaneous bilateral trade. The historical settlement
structure may have induced networks along cultural lines that survived
over time. (34) Absolute differences in historical variables are
positively correlated to the border, so that their omission may bias the
estimated border effect away from zero.
To account for these possibilities, Table 7 includes historical
differences in (1) cropland; (2) average farms size; (3) population
density; and (4) illiteracy rates of the non-slave population. (35) In
columns (1) to (3), we find that none of these variables matter
statistically, except for historical farm size differences which are
significant at the 5% level. Including farm size increases rather than
decreases the border coefficient to -0.234. This is surprising as
historical farm size differences correlate positively with the border.
One would expect the legacy of slavery to partly capture the border
barrier in column (4). However, we find that differences in slave shares
in 1860 exert no impact on bilateral trade patterns and do not explain
away the border barrier. (36) Interestingly, the inclusion of the
absolute difference in shares of free blacks in 1860 exerts a positive
and significant effect on contemporaneous trade in column (7).
In addition, similarities in culture due to similar settlement
structures in U.S. states before the war could have induced social and
business networks that have survived over time and still affect trade.
We therefore include the product in the shares of French, Spanish,
Irish, British, and German settlers in 1860. While Spanish, German, or
British heritage has no particular impact on trade, Irish heritage
decreases bilateral trade significantly in column (5). States with a
large share of French settlers trade more amongst each other.
According to Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2002), historical
climatic differences measured by the incidence of malaria, may have
affected the characteristics and quality of institutions. In the present
case, it is conceivable that the high risk of malaria in the South has
led to the acceptance of slavery by the local elite and may therefore
constitute a deep reason for the conflict. It may also affect
contemporaneous trade flows through its lasting effect on institutions.
So, we include the malaria risk index in 1860 from Hong (2007). We find
neither a significant effect on trade nor does historical climate
explain away the border. In the last column, we include all historical
controls simultaneously in our model. All in all, we find that the
border reduces trade by 22%, even when we include variables capturing
the historical determinants of the Secession. (37)
B. Including the West
From the previous analysis, one cannot conclude that the Secession
has caused the observed border effect in contemporaneous trade data.
Including historical variables that relate to the deep reasons for the
Civil War goes some way in dealing with reverse causation. However, it
fails to account for unobserved shocks that both make the odds for
Secession and today's bilateral trade flows larger. Unfortunately,
no instrument is ready-to-use in an IV approach.
One way to nudge the analysis closer to identifying a causal effect
consists in separating the whole of the United States--including the
West--into states that underwent a treatment by the Secession and states
that were not affected by these historical events. We separate the
states into three groups--the North, the South, and the West--still
excluding border states, the District of Columbia, Alaska, and Hawaii.
(38) The border dummy is unity for states that found themselves on
opposite sides of the Civil War and zero for all other pairs of states.
Adding the West adds a control set of state pairs that are characterized
by their absence of a past shaped by the Civil War.
Table 8 reports the results. All models include additional
contemporaneous controls. (39) In columns (1), (3), and (5), we find for
the OLS fixed effects, the PPML fixed effects, and the pooled commodity
fixed-effects regression a significant trade impeding effect of the
Secession treatment. The effect ranges between 7% and 19%. In addition,
we again find in column (2) that the South trades more amongst each
other while the effect on the North is negative, but turns insignificant
when we control for heteroskedasticity in the PPML fixed-effects
approach in column (4). There seems not to be any particular trade
effect within Western states. (40)
When we estimate border effects for a sample of South and West
states (41) and a separate sample of North and West states, (42) we see
no border effect. In some cases, we even find a positive and significant
coefficient such that Southern and Western states trade more rather than
less with another.
VI. CIVIL WAR AT 150: STILL RELEVANT, STILL DIVISIVE
The former border between the Union and the Confederation is still
relevant today: The defunct border represents a trade barrier that
lowers trade between U.S. states by on average 7% to 22%. In a million
placebo estimations, we find supportive evidence that the magnitude of
this border effect is unique. The result is robust to using alternative
waves of the CFS, to different econometric methods, or to the inclusion
of Western states or the rest of the world. It cannot be substantially
attenuated, let alone eliminated, by adding a vast array of
contemporaneous and historical variables that correlate both with the
border dummy and, potentially, also with bilateral trade.
The great Mississippi novelist and poet William Faulkner famously
writes "The past is never dead. It's not even past"
("Requiem for a Nun," 1951). This holds true for the Secession
that tore the United States apart 150 years ago, even when the judgment
is based on bilateral trade data and econometric analysis: Trade between
the former Confederation and the former Union is about 13% smaller on
average than within the alliance. Several additional results stand out:
First, the effect of the long defunct border on today's trade is
not attributable to the legacy of slavery alone. It becomes weaker if
not the Secession but the status of slave states is the criterion for
belonging to one of the two groups. Second, the border effect is not
merely a North-South effect. When the border is redefined to reflect
whether two states have been on opposing sides in the Civil War, it
remains significantly negative. Third, the trade inhibiting force of the
former border has to do with the degree of differentiation of products:
the higher, the stronger. This suggests that the channel through which
the border still matters may be through cultural affinity or trust.
Our results imply that one cannot view the United States as a
single market. The effect of the former Union-Confederation border
persists after 150 years. The finding suggests that one should not be
overly optimistic as to other regional integration projects. This
applies most notably to Europe, where the last major war ended only 67
years ago and the history of conflict is much longer and bloodier.
Moreover, in contrast to the United States there is no pre-war history
of integration, and other frictions related to languages, legal systems
etc. are plentiful.
In terms of welfare, our results imply that trade disruptions in
the past can still constitute barriers today. By distorting the flow of
trade away from the structure that would have obtained without the
Secession, they present continuing welfare losses. So, by its long-run
effects on economic integration armed conflicts may cast a very long
shadow on the welfare of future generations.
ABBREVIATIONS
CDFs: Cumulative Distribution Functions
CES: Constant Elasticity of Substitution
CFS: Commodity Flow Surveys
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
MR: Multilateral Resistance
NLS: Nonlinear Least Squares
OECD: Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
PPML: Poisson Pseudo Maximum Likelihood
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00510.x
Online Early publication January 10, 2013
APPENDIX
TABLE A1
Summary Statistics by State, 1993
Unit of Observation: State Level
Sample North (N = 17) South (N = 11)
Variable M SD M SD
Black Share 7.412 5.519 22.855 7.871
Jewish Share 2.105 2.339 0.809 1.285
Christian Share 86.882 3.059 91.636 3.139
Other Religion Share 3.235 2.278 1.727 1.272
No Religion Share 7.647 1.998 5.000 1.673
Urban Share 72.853 16.095 65.655 12.098
In 1860 Cropland 15.038 1.045 15.228 0.806
In 1860 Farm Size 4.785 0.184 5.940 0.291
In 1860 Population Density 3.338 1.384 2.454 0.929
In 1860 Illiteracy Rates 1.604 0.415 2.683 0.303
1860 Slave Share 0.000 0.001 39.700 11.369
1860 Free Black Share 1.018 0.999 1.170 1.326
1860 French Share 0.302 0.202 0.254 0.619
1860 Spanish Share 0.004 0.005 0.032 0.076
1860 Irish Share 6.890 4.303 0.918 1.057
1860 German Share 4.772 4.244 0.886 1.271
1860 British Share 4.250 2.216 0.306 0.204
1860 Malaria Risk 0.126 0.073 0.351 0.057
In Capital-Labor Ratio 11.610 0.261 11.520 0.227
In High-Low Skilled Ratio 0.264 0.316 -0.256 0.256
In Average Schooling 2.579 0.023 2.538 0.023
In Cropland 7.821 2.223 8.574 0.656
In Farm Size 5.309 0.570 5.574 0.424
In Agri. / Tot. Output -4.515 0.687 -4.159 0.427
In Manuf. / Tot. Output -1.615 0.250 -1.661 0.364
In Population 15.237 1.009 15.534 0.624
In Population Density 5.175 1.145 4.602 0.485
In Fertility 4.127 0.071 4.184 0.065
In Income Per Capita 10.129 0.129 10.011 0.115
Union Membership 18.106 5.470 8.436 2.826
Union Density 19.812 5.218 10.382 3.009
Minimum Wage 1.000 0.000 0.455 0.522
Republican 0.118 0.332 0.636 0.505
Judiciary Election 1.824 0.883 1.182 0.405
Unit of Observation: State Level
Sample
Variable Description
Black Share Share (%) of blacks in population.
Jewish Share Share (%) of Jewish in population.
Christian Share Share (%) of Christian in population.
Other Religion Share Share (%) of people with other religion.
No Religion Share Share (%) of people with no religion.
Urban Share Share (%) of urban population.
In 1860 Cropland 1860 cropland in 1,000 acres.
In 1860 Farm Size 1860 average farm size in acres.
In 1860 Population Density 1860 population by square km.
In 1860 Illiteracy Rates 1860 share of non-slave illiterate.
1860 Slave Share 1860 slaves in population.
1860 Free Black Share 1860 free blacks in population.
1860 French Share 1860 French in population.
1860 Spanish Share 1860 Spanish in population.
1860 Irish Share 1860 Irish in population.
1860 German Share 1860 German in population.
1860 British Share 1860 (American) British in population.
1860 Malaria Risk 1860 Malaria risk index.
In Capital-Labor Ratio Capital relative to labor.
In High-Low Skilled Ratio Bachelor to high school, age [greater
than or equal to] 25.
In Average Schooling Years of schooling.
In Cropland Cropland in 1,000 acres.
In Farm Size Average farm size in acres.
In Agri. / Tot. Output Agri. over total output, mio US $.
In Manuf. / Tot. Output Manuf. over total output, mio US $.
In Population Total population in thousands.
In Population Density Population by square km.
In Fertility Live births per 1,000 women, age 15-44.
In Income Per Capita Total GDP per capita.
Union Membership Percentage of union membership.
Union Density Percentage of union density.
Minimum Wage 1 if state has minimum wage, 0 else.
Republican 1 if republ., 1992 pres. election. 0
else.
Judiciary Election 1 if judiciary is elected. 0 else.
Notes: Data sources as in Table A2 (Appendix).
TABLE A2
Summary Statistics and Data Sources, 1993
Unit of Observation: Pairs of States
Full North-South
Sample (N = 756) (N = 374)
Variable M SD M SD
In [z.sub.ij] -16.257 0.863 -16.590 0.637
[z.sub.ij] 1.31e-07 1.64e-07 7.36e-08 5.15e-08
[Border.sub.ij] 0.495 0.500 1.000 0.000
In [Disti.sub.ij] 6.854 0.663 7.139 0.411
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.112 0.316 0.000 0.000
In Migration
[Stock.sub.ij] 9.722 1.528 9.482 1.525
x Black [Share.sub.ij] 178.111 203.585 169.404 140.489
x Jewish [Share.sub.ij] 2.393 5.376 1.702 4.218
x Christian
[Share.sub.ij] 7876.034 465.705 7961.583 376.909
x Other Religion
[Sharer.sub.ij] 1.081 0.993 1.039 0.886
x No Religion
[Share.sub.ij] 43.471 20.768 38.235 15.907
x Urban [Share.sub.ij] 0.490 0.144 0.478 0.134
[Colonizer.sub.ij] 0.540 0.499 0.524 0.500
[DELTA] In 1860
[Cropland.sub.ij] 1.062 0.816 1.025 0.778
[DELTA] In 1860 Farm
[Size.sub.ij] 0.698 0.525 1.155 0.331
[DELTA] In 1860
Population
[Density.sub.ij] 1.429 1.120 1.492 1.069
[DELTA] In 1860
Illiteracy
[Rates.sub.ij] 6.462 5.127 9.901 4.663
x 1860 Slave
[Share.sub.ij] 21.596 20.239 39.700 10.854
x 1860 Free Black
[Share.sub.ij] 1.200 1.029 1.215 1.043
x 1860 French
[Share.sub.ij] 0.07-1 0.167 0.077 0.218
x 1860 Spanish
[Share.sub.ij] 0.0001 0.001 0.000 0.000
x 1860 Irish
[Share.sub.ij] 19.925 32.596 6.326 8.991
x 1860 German
[Share.sub.ij] 9.995 20.730 4.226 8.473
x 1860 British
[Share.sub.ij] 7.052 11.245 1.302 1.140
[DELTA] 1860 Malaria
[Risk.sub.ij] 0.151 0.105 0.225 0.089
[DELTA] In
Capital-Labor
[Ratio.sub.ij] 0.281 0.211 0.276 0.208
[DELTA] In High-Low 0.454 0.308 0.565 0.324
Skilled
[Ratio.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Average
[Schooling.sub.ij] 0.036 0.025 0.045 0.027
[DELTA] In 1.959 1.619 1.924 1.383
[Cropland.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Farm 0.580 0.465 0.567 0.467
[Size.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Agricultural
To Total
[Output.sub.ij] 0.711 0.503 0.709 0.486
[DELTA] In
Manufacturing To
Total [Output.sub.ij] 0.329 0.254 0.338 0.259
[DELTA] In
[Population.sub.ij] 1.000 0.735 0.953 0.703
[DELTA] In Population
[Density.sub.ij] 1.109 0.814 1.090 0.769
[DELTA] In
[Fertility.sub.ij] 0.081 0.065 0.084 0.070
[DELTA] In Income Per 0.150 0.118 0.159 0.128
[Capita.su8b.ij]
[DELTA] Union
[Membership.sub.ij] 7.627 5.431 9.939 5.497
[DELTA] Union
[Density.sub.ij] 7.434 5.267 9.668 5.420
[DELTA] Minimum
[Wage.sub.ij] 0.087 0.124 0.081 0.105
[DELTA]
[Republican.sub.ij] 0.452 0.498 0.604 0.490
Judiciary
[Election.sub.ij] 0.426 0.495 0.428 0.495
Sample
Variable Data Source
In [z.sub.ij] Commodity Flow Survey; Bureau of
Economic Analysis.
[z.sub.ij] Commodity Flow Survey.
[Border.sub.ij] Own calculations.
In [Disti.sub.ij] Anderson and van Wincoop (2003).
[Adjacency.sub.ij] Own calculations.
In Migration
[Stock.sub.ij] American Community Survey.
x Black [Share.sub.ij] Population Estimates Program.
x Jewish [Share.sub.ij] The American Jewish Yearbook.
x Christian
[Share.sub.ij] ARIS 2008 Report.
x Other Religion
[Sharer.sub.ij] ARIS 2008 Report.
x No Religion
[Share.sub.ij] ARIS 2008 Report.
x Urban [Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing.
[Colonizer.sub.ij] Own calculations.
[DELTA] In 1860
[Cropland.sub.ij] Census of Agriculture 1860.
[DELTA] In 1860 Farm
[Size.sub.ij] Census of Agriculture 1860.
[DELTA] In 1860
Population
[Density.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
[DELTA] In 1860
Illiteracy
[Rates.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
x 1860 Slave
[Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
x 1860 Free Black
[Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
x 1860 French
[Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
x 1860 Spanish
[Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
x 1860 Irish
[Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
x 1860 German
[Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
x 1860 British
[Share.sub.ij] Census of Population and Housing 1860.
[DELTA] 1860 Malaria
[Risk.sub.ij] Hong (2007).
[DELTA] In
Capital-Labor
[Ratio.sub.ij] Turner et al. (2008).
[DELTA] In High-Low Census of Population; American
Skilled Community Survey.
[Ratio.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Average
[Schooling.sub.ij] Turner et al. (2007).
[DELTA] In National Resource Inventory Summary
[Cropland.sub.ij] Report.
[DELTA] In Farm Census of Agriculture.
[Size.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Agricultural
To Total
[Output.sub.ij] Bureau of Economic Analysis.
[DELTA] In
Manufacturing To
Total [Output.sub.ij] Bureau of Economic Analysis.
[DELTA] In
[Population.sub.ij] Population Estimates Program.
[DELTA] In Population
[Density.sub.ij] Population Estimates Program.
[DELTA] In
[Fertility.sub.ij] Vital Statistics of the United States.
[DELTA] In Income Per Bureau of Economic Analysis; Population
[Capita.su8b.ij] Estimates Program.
[DELTA] Union
[Membership.sub.ij] Hirsch et al. (2001).
[DELTA] Union
[Density.sub.ij] Hirsch et al. (2001).
[DELTA] Minimum
[Wage.sub.ij] US Department of Labor.
[DELTA]
[Republican.sub.ij] The American Presidency Project.
Judiciary
[Election.sub.ij] Own calculations.
Notes: Data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis stem from the
Regional Economic Accounts. Contemporaneous variables if not stated
otherwise. The operator A denotes the absolute difference of
variables between state i and state j. The operator x denotes the
product of variables in state i and state j. In [z.sub.ij] has 740
observations for the full sample and 364 for the North-South sample.
TABLE A3
1993 Standard Transportation Commodity Codes (STCC)
Commodity Meaning Agriculture
1 Farm products x
8 Forest products x
9 Fresh fish or other marine products x
10 Metallic ores
11 Coal
13 Crude petroleum, natural gas. gasoline
14 Non-metallic minerals
19 Ordinance or accessories
20 Food or kindred products x
21 Tobacco products, excluding insecticides x
22 Textile mill products
23 Apparel or other finished textile products
24 Lumber or wood products. excluding furniture
25 Furniture or fixtures
26 Pulp, Paper, allied products
27 Printed matter
28 Chemicals or allied products
29 Petroleum or coal products
30 Rubber or miscellaneous plastics products
31 Leather or leather products
32 Clay, concrete, glass, stone products
33 Primary metal products
34 Fabricated metal products
35 Machinery, excluding electrical
36 Electrical machinery, equipment, supplies
37 Transportation equipment
38 Instruments, photographic and optical goods
39 Miscellaneous products of manufacturing
40 Waste or scrap materials
41 Miscellaneous freight shipments
99 LTL-general cargo
Commodity Mining Chemical Machinery Manufacturing
1
8
9
10
11 x
13 x
14 x
19 x
20
21
22 x
23 x
24 x
25 x
26 x
27 x
28 x
29 x
30 x
31 x
32 x
33 x
34 x
35
36 x
37 x
38 x
39 x
40 x
41
99
TABLE A4
1997, 2002, 2007 Standard Classification of Transported Goods (SCTG)
Commodity Meaning
1 Live animals and live fish
2 Cereal grains
3 Other agricultural products
4 Animal feed and products of animal
origin, n.e.c.
5 Meat. fish, seafood. and preparations
6 Milled grain products, bakery products
7 Other prepared foodstuffs, fats, oils
8 Alcoholic beverages
9 Tobacco products
10 Monumental or building stone
11 Natural sands
12 Gravel and crushed stone
13 Nonmetallic minerals n.e.c.
14 Metallic ores and concentrates
15 Coal
17 Gasoline and aviation turbine fuel
18 Fuel oils
19 Coal and petroleum products, n.e.c.
20 Basic chemicals
21 pharmaceutical products
22 Fertilizers
23 Chemical products and preparations, n.e.c.
24 Plastics and rubber
25 Logs and other wood in the rough
26 Wood products
27 Pulp, newsprint. paper, and paperboard
28 Paper or paperboard articles
29 Printed products
30 Textiles, leather, articles of textiles or leather
31 Nonmetallic mineral products
32 Base metal in primary or semifinished forms
33 Articles of base metal
34 Machinery
35 Electronic and office equipment and components
36 Motorized and other vehicles (including parts)
37 Transportation equipment, n.e.c.
38 Precision instruments and apparatus
39 Furniture, mattresses and supports, lamps
40 Miscellaneous manufactured products
41 Waste and scrap
43 Mixed freight
Commodity Agriculture Mining Chemical Machinery Manufacturing
1 x
2 x
3 x
4 x
5 x
6 x
7 x
8 x
9 x
10 x
11 x
12 x
13 x
14 x
15 x
17 x
18 x
19 x
20 x
21 x
22 x
23 x
24 x
25 x
26 x
27 x
28 x
29 x
30 x
31 x
32 x
33 x
34 x
35 x
36 x
37 x
38 x
39 x
40 x
41
43
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson. "Reversal of
Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World
Income Distribution." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 2002,
1231-94.
Anderson, J., and E. Van Wincoop. "Gravity with Gravitas: A
Solution to the Border Puzzle." American Economic Review, 93(1),
2003, 170.
Baier, S., and J. Bergstrand. "Bonus vetus OLS: A Simple
Method for Approximating International Trade-Cost Effects Using the
Gravity Equation." Journal of International Economics, 77(1), 2009,
77-85.
Bergstrand, J. "The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic
Competition, and the Factor-Proportions Theory in International
Trade." Review of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 1989, 143-53.
Broda, C., J. Greenfield, and D. Weinstein. "From Groundnuts
to Globalization: A Structural Estimate of Trade and Growth."
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 12512, 2006.
Buch, C., and F. Toubal. "Openness and Growth: The Long Shadow
of the Berlin Wall." Journal of Macroeconomics, 31(3), 2009,
409-22.
Chen, N. "Intra-National Versus International Trade in the
European Union: Why Do National Borders Matter?" Journal of
International Economics, 63(1), 2004, 93-118.
Combes, P., M. Lafourcade, and T. Mayer. "The Trade-Creating
Effects of Business and Social Networks: Evidence from France."
Journal of International Economics, 66(1), 2005, 1-29.
Cunat, A., and M. Melitz. "Volatility, Labor Market
Flexibility, and the Pattern of Comparative Advantage." Journal of
the European Economic Association, 10(2), 2012, 225-54.
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum. "Technology, Geography, and
Trade." Econometrica, 70(5), 2002, 1741-79.
Eichengreen, B., and D. Irwin. "The Role of History in
Bilateral Trade Flows," in The Regionalization of the World
Economy, edited by J. Frankel. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1998.
Engerman, S., and K. Sokoloff. "History Lessons: Institutions,
Factors Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World."
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 2000, 217-32.
--. "Colonialism, Inequality, and Long-Run Paths of
Development." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
No. 11057, 2005.
Erlbaum, N., J. Holguin-Veras, and K. Hancock. "Some
Suggestions for Improving CFS Data Products." Transportation
Research Circular No. E-C088, 2006.
Falck, O., S. Heblich, A. Lameli, and J. Suedekum. "Dialects,
Cultural Identity, and Economic Exchange." IZA Working Paper No.
4743, 2010.
Feenstra, R. Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2004.
Galor, O., O. Moav, and D. Vollrath. "Inequality in
Landownership, the Emergence of Human-Capital Promoting Institutions,
and the Great Divergence." Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 2009,
143-79.
Goldin, C., and F. Lewis. "The Economic Cost of the American
Civil War: Estimates and Implications." Journal of Economic
History, 35(2), 1975, 299-326.
Hallak, J. "A Product-Quality View of the Linder
Hypothesis." Review of Economics and Statistics, 92(3), 2010,
453-66.
Head, K., and T. Mayer. "Illusory Border Effects: Distance
Mismeasurement Inflates Estimates of Home Bias in Trade." CEPII
Working Paper No. 2002-01, 2002.
Head, K., T. Mayer, and J. Ries. "The Erosion of Colonial
Trade Linkages alter Independence." Journal of International
Economics, 81 (1), 2010, 1-14.
Head, K., and J. Ries. "Immigration and Trade Creation:
Econometric Evidence from Canada." Canadian Journal of Economics,
13(1), 1998, 47-62.
Helliwell, J. "National Borders, Trade and Migration."
Pacific Economic Review, 2(3), 1997, 165-85.
--. How Much Do National Borders Matter? Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press, 1998.
--. "Measuring the Width of National Borders." Review of
International Economics, 10(3), 2002, 517-24.
Hillberry, R. "Explaining the Border Effect: What Can We Learn
from Disaggregated Commodity Flow Data." Indiana University
Graduate Student Economics Working Paper No. 9802, 1999.
--. "Aggregation Bias, Compositional Change, and the Border
Effect." Canadian Journal of Economics, 35(3), 2002, 517-30.
Hillberry, R., and D. Hummels. "lntranational Home Bias: Some
Explanations." Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 2003,
1089-92.
--. "Trade Responses to Geographic Frictions: A Decomposition
Using Micro-Data." European Economic Review, 52(3), 2008, 527-50.
Hirsch, B., D. Macpherson, and W. Vroman. "Estimates of Union
Density, by State." Monthly Labor Review, 124(7), 2001, 51-55.
Hong, S. "The Burden of Early Exposure to Malaria in the
United States, 1850-1860: Malnutrition and Immune Disorders."
Journal of Economic History, 67(04), 2007, 1001-35.
Hummels, D. "Toward a Geography of Trade Costs." GTAP
Working Paper No. 17, 1999.
Krugman, P. "Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the
Pattern of Trade." American Economic Review, 70(5), 1980, 950-59.
Martin, M. T. P., and M. Thoenig. "Make Trade Not War?"
Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 2008, 865 -900.
McCallum, J. "National Borders Matter: Canada-US Regional
Trade Patterns." American Economic Review, 85(3), 1995, 615-23.
Millimet, D., and T. Osang. "Do State Borders Matter for US
Intranational Trade? The Role of History and Internal Migration."
Canadian Journal of Economics, 40(1), 2007, 93-126.
Mitchener, K., and I. McLean. "US Regional Growth and
Convergence, 1880-1980." Journal of Economic History, 59(4), 1999,
1016-42.
Nitsch, V. "National Borders and International Trade: Evidence
from the European Union." Canadian Journal of Economics, 33(4),
2000, 1091-105.
Nitsch, V., and N. Wolf. Forthcoming. "Tear Down This Wall: On
the Persistence of Borders in Trade." Canadian Journal of
Economics.
Nunn, N. "The Importance of History for Economic
Development." Annual Review of Economics, 1, 2009, 65-92.
Ozimek, A., and D. Miles. "Stata Utilities for Geocoding and
Generating Travel Time and Travel Distance Information." Stata
Journal, 11(1), 2011, 106-19.
Parsley, D., and S. Wei. "Explaining the Border Effect: The
Role of Exchange Rate Variability, Shipping Costs, and Geography."
Journal of International Economics, 55(1), 2001, 87-105.
Rauch, J. "Networks versus Markets in International
Trade." Journal of International Economics, 48(1), 1999, 7-35.
Rauch, J., and V. Trindade. "Ethnic Chinese Networks in
International Trade." Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(1),
2002, 116-30.
Redding, S., and A. Venables. "Economic Geography and
International Inequality." Journal of International Economics,
62(1), 2004, 53-82.
Reed, J., and D. Reed. 1001 Things Everyone Should Know About the
South. New York: Doubleday, 1997.
Santos Silva, J., and S. Tenreyro. "The Log of Gravity."
Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 2006, 641-58.
Silverman, B. Density Estimation for Statistics and Data Analysis.
London: Chapman & Hall, 1992.
Thursby, J., and M. Thursby. "Bilateral Trade Flows, the
Linder Hypothesis, and Exchange Risk." Review of Economics and
Statistics, 69(3), 1987, 488-95.
Turner, C., R. Tamura, and S. Mulholland. "How Important Are
Human Capital, Physical Capital and Total Factor Productivity for
Determining State Economic Growth in the United States: 1840-2000?"
MPRA Paper No. 32846, 2008.
Turner, C., R. Tamura, S. Mulholland, and S. Baier. "Education
and Income of the States of the United States: 1840-2000." Journal
of Economic Growth, 12(2), 2007, 101-58.
Wei, S. "Intra-National versus International Trade: How
Stubborn Are Nations in Global Integration?" National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper No. 5531, 1996.
Wolf, H. "Patterns of Intra-and Inter-State Trade."
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5939, 1997.
--. "Intranational Home Bias in Trade." Review of
Economics and Statistics, 82(4), 2000, 555-63.
SUPPORTING INFORMATION
Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online
version of this article:
TABLE S1. Cross Correlations of [Border.sub.ij] with all other
Variables, 1993
TABLE S2. Alternative Methods: AvW and OLS with MR Terms
TABLE S3. Placebo Coast-Interior and East-West, 1993
TABLE S4. Robustness: In-Sample Eastern-Western States
TABLE S5. Robustness: Subsamples
TABLE S6. Sensitivity Analysis Various Years
TABLE S7. Alternative Distance Measure (fixed-effects estimation)
TABLE S8. Sensitivity Analysis: Allocation of Border States, 1993
TABLE S9. Additionally Including California, Oregon and Nevada,
1993
TABLE S10. Sectoral Regressions (fixed-effects estimation)
TABLE S11. Additional Controls, Alternative Samples and Models:
Summary Results
TABLE S12. Sectoral Regressions Including Controls (fixed-effects
estimation)
TABLE S13. Additionally Including the West: Sensitivity
TABLE S14. Robustness: Alternative Samples Including the South-West
TABLE S15. Robustness: Alternative Samples Including the North-West
GABRIEL FELBERMAYR and JASMIN GROSCHL *
* We thank the editor, Cedric Tille, and two anonymous referees for
excellent comments and suggestions. We are also grateful to Mario Larch,
Doug Nelson, Katheryn Russ and to seminar participants at the ETSG
meeting in Copenhagen, 2011, the Munich-Tuebingen International
Economics Workshop in Munich, 2011 and the Royal Economic Society
meeting in Cambridge, 2012. We thank the Leibniz Gemeinschaft (WGL) for
financial support under project Pact 2009 Globalisierungsnetzwerk.
Felbermayr: Ifo-Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the
University of Munich, Poschingerstr. 5, 81679 Munich, Germany; CESifo
& GEP. Phone +49 (0)89 9224 1428, Fax +49 (0)89 985369, E-mail
felbermayr@ifo.de
Groschl: Ifo-Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the
University of Munich, Poschingerstr. 5, 81679 Munich, Germany. Phone +49
(0)89 9224 1317, Fax +49 (0)89 985369, E-mail groeschl@ifo.de
(1.) Pew Research Centre for the People and the Press, "Civil
War at 150: Still Relevant, Still Divisive," April 8, 2011;
available at http://pewresearch.org/pubs/1958/.
(2.) The Mason-Dixon Line settled a conflict between British
Colonies and set the common borders of Pennsylvania, Maryland, Delaware,
and West Virginia.
(3.) Helliwell (1997, 1998, 2002); Wei (1996); Hillberry (1999,
2002); Woff (1997, 2000); Nitsch (2000); Parsley and Wei (2001);
Hillberry and Hummels (2003); Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003); Chen
(2004); Feenstra (2004); Combes, Lafourcade, and Mayer (2005); Millimet
and Osang (2007); Baier and Bergstrand (2009); Buch and Toubal (2009);
Nitsch and Wolf (forthcoming) to name only a few.
(4.) Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003) propose to estimate their
gravity model by means of an iterative procedure that minimizes the sum
of squared residuals, while simultaneously obtaining values for the
multilateral resistance terms.
(5.) Reed and Reed (1997) define the "deep South" as an
area roughly coextensive with the old cotton belt from eastern North
Carolina through South Carolina west into East Texas, with extensions
north and south along the Mississippi.
(6.) Note that California, Oregon, and Nevada were officially part
of the Union but played no particular role in the Civil War. So, we
exclude them from our benchmark sample, but include them in our
robustness check in Table S9 in the Supporting Information.
(7.) North-South differences are also clearly visible when looking
at pairs of states. Table A2 in the Appendix differentiates between the
sample of all pairs (N = 756) and the sample of cross-border pairs
(states from different sides of the historical border; N = 374).
(8.) We have estimated Epanechnikov Kernel density functions, with
the width of the density window around each point set to the
"optimal" level; see Silverman (1992). Optimal bandwidths are
approximately 0.17, 0.25, and 0.32 for North-South, North-North and
South-South flows, respectively.
(9.) Broda, Greenfield, and Weinstein (2006) estimate elasticities
of substitution with a median of 3.8 and a mean of 12.1. The elasticity
of substitution they estimate for the United States is 2.4. We follow
the recent literature and calculate tariff equivalents according to a
range of the elasticity of substitution between 3 and 10.
(10.) Table 2 in AvW, two-country model: [e.sup-1.65-]- 1.
(11.) Table 2a in Nitsch and Wolf (forthcoming), pooled OLS in
2004: [e.sup.-0.229] - 1.
(12.) The puzzle also vanishes when counting the border states into
the South (Table S8, Supporting Information) or when including
California, Oregon, and Nevada into the Union (Table S9, Supporting
Information).
(13.) These include Canada, Australia, Japan, New Zealand, Austria,
Belgium-Luxembourg, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland,
Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and
the United Kingdom.
(14.) We focus on exports from U.S. states to the OECD as import
data of individual U.S. states from OECD states (and vice versa) are not
available.
(15.) http://cid.econ.ucdavis.edu/
(16.) Detailed results are found in Table S2 (Supporting
Information).
(17.) The number of potential "South" subsamples and
hence of state groups is huge: 21,474,180. Estimating all possible
border effects between these groups of states is computationally
extremely costly. A single regression takes about 1 second. Computation
time then amounts to 249 days.
(18.) Detailed results are found in Table S3 (Supporting
Information).
(19.) Detailed results are found in Table S4 (Supporting
Information).
(20.) Detailed results are found in Table S5 (Supporting
Information).
(21.) The 1997 wave is an exception. Detailed results are found in
Table S7 (Panel A) (Supporting Information).
(22.) Detailed results are found in Table S7 (Panel B) (Supporting
Information).
(23.) Detailed results are found in Table S8 (Supporting
Information).
(24.) The increase in the border effect when the three
"disconnected" states are included supports the view that the
border effect is really about a "genuine"
Union-versus-Confederation effect.
(25.) Detailed results are found in Table S9 (Supporting
Information).
(26.) Detailed results are found in Table S10 (Supporting
Information).
(27.) We tried a range of other variables and combinations, as well
as network and difference variables separately and combinations thereof.
The results are robust to these modifications.
(28.) A similar effect has been identified by Combes, Lafourcade,
and Mayer (2005) for trade within France.
(29.) See, for instance, Head, Mayer, and Ries (2010).
(30.) We measure high skilled by a Bachelor's degree or above
and low skilled by a High School degree or below. Data stem from the
Census of Population and the American Community Survey.
(31.) A model that explains bilateral trade solely using importer
and exporter fixed effects can only explain 20% of the variation in the
dependent variable.
(32.) Details are relegated to Table S11 (Supporting Information).
(33.) When we work with sectoral data and include the additional
controls, results suggest that the trade impeding effect is mainly
caused by barriers to manufacturing products in all years. Compared to
our earlier results, the border effect is negative but less robust for
agriculture and chemicals--except for 2002 and 2007. Mining and
machinery products again depict in most cases an indistinguishable
coefficient from zero. Table S12 (Supporting Information) reports
detailed results.
(34.) The analysis relates to the literature on the long-term
impact of factor endowments and institutions (Acemoglu, Johnson, and
Robinson 2002; Galor, Moav, and Vollrath 2009; Nunn 2009).
(35.) Additionally, all models include our additional
contemporaneous controls from Table 5 column (6) and importer as well as
exporter fixed effects.
(36.) If we use the difference in the share of slaves in 1840, when
there were still slaves also living in the North, we still find robust
results on the border effect but an insignificant coefficient close to
zero for the slave share. In column (7), the effect of differences in
1840 slaves is still zero, while the effects of all other historical
controls prevail. The border effect remains negative and significant on
the 1% level.
(37.) We have also experimented with direct measures for the
historical transportation system (differences or networks of railroad
miles per 100 square miles of land area after the Civil War in 1870).
The result is robust to the inclusion of the historical transportation
system.
(38.) West includes all U.S. states that were not assigned to the
North, the South, or the border states in Table 1, excluding the
District of Columbia, Alaska, and Hawaii.
(39.) Historical controls are not available for most of the Western
states before the war, as these were only Territories in 1860.
(40.) Results are similar for the other years and can be found in
Table S13 (Supporting Information).
(41.) Detailed results are found in Table S14 (Supporting
Information).
(42.) Detailed results are found in Table S15 (Supporting
Information).
TABLE 1
Sample
Excluded/
North = Union South = Confederacy Border States
Connecticut Alabama Delaware
Illinois Arkansas Kentucky
Indiana Florida Maryland
Iowa Georgia Missouri
Kansas Louisiana West Virginia
Maine Mississippi
Massachusetts North Carolina California
Michigan South Carolina Nevada
Minnesota Tennessee Oregon
New Hampshire Texas
New Jersey Virginia
New York
Ohio
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
Vermont
Wisconsin
TABLE 2
Basic Border Effect Results
Dependent Variable: In bilateral exports between i and j relative to
states' GDPs
Year of Data: 1993
Data: Aggregated
OLS FE
Specification: (1) (2)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.137 ***
(0.03)
North-North [dummy.sub.ij] -0.230 **
(0.09)
South-South [dummy.sub.ij] 0.504 ***
(0.10)
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.919 *** -0.919 ***
(0.03) (0.03)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.434 *** 0.434 ***
(0.06) (0.06)
Fixed effects
Importer YES YES
Exporter YES YES
Importer x Commodity -- --
Exporter x Commodity -- --
Observations 740 740
Adjusted/pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.841 0.841
Year of Data: 1993
Data: Aggregated
PPML FE
Specification: (3) (4)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.152 ***
(0.03)
North-North [dummy.sub.ij] 0.063
(0.08)
South-South [dummy.sub.ij] 0.241
(0.09)
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.953 *** -0.953 ***
(0.03) (0.03)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.426 *** 0.426 ***
(0.05) (0.05)
Fixed effects
Importer YES YES
Exporter YES YES
Importer x Commodity -- --
Exporter x Commodity -- --
Observations 756 756
Adjusted/pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.030 0.030
Year of Data: 1993
Data: Aggregated Commodity
PPML Multi Chen (2004) FE
Specification: (5) (6)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.144 *** -0.080 ***
(0.04) (0.02)
North-North [dummy.sub.ij]
South-South [dummy.sub.ij]
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.828 *** -0.670 ***
(0.03) (0.02)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.629 *** 0.492
(0.05) (0.04)
Fixed effects
Importer YES --
Exporter YES --
Importer x Commodity -- YES
Exporter x Commodity -- YES
Observations 1,764 12.271
Adjusted/pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.060 0.601
Notes: Constant and fixed effects not reported. Robust standard errors
reported in parentheses. States in sample as in Table 1. District of
Columbia is excluded. In column (5), we adapt a multi-country PPML
fixed-effects approach, respectively, and add exports of individual
U.S. states to 20 OECD countries and between OECD trade.
*** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level; *
significant at the 10% level.
TABLE 3
Sensitivity Across Different Survey Waves
Dependent Variable: In bilateral exports between i and
j relative to states' GDPs
Data: Aggregated Commodity
OLS PPML FE Chen
Specification: FE FE (2004)
Panel A: 1997
(A1) (A2) (A3)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.070 ** -0.096 *** -0.132 ***
(0.03) (0.03) (0.02)
Observations 738 756 10,342
Adjusted/pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.821 0.030 0.795
Panel B: 2002
(B1) (132) (133)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.120 *** -0.141 *** -0.177 ***
(0.03) (0.04) (0.02)
Observations 711 756 6,979
Adjusted/pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.816 0.030 0.767
Panel C: 2007
(C1) (C2) (C3)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.110 *** -0.143 *** -0.172 ***
(0.03) (0.04) (0.02)
Observations 740 756 11,834
Adjusted/pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.847 0.030 0.763
Notes: Constant, fixed effects, effects on log distance and
adjacency are not reported. Robust standard errors reported
in parentheses. Table S8 (Supporting Information) contains
full results. Column (3) includes Importer x Commodity and
Exporter x Commodity fixed effects following Chen (2004).
States in sample as in Table 1. District of Columbia is
excluded.
*** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5%
level; * significant at the 10% level.
TABLE 4
Sectoral Results (Fixed-Effects Estimation)
Dependent Variable: In bilateral exports between i and j relative to
states' GDPs
Sector Agriculture Mining Chemical
Panel A: 1993
(A1) (A2) (A3)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.254 *** -0.052 -0.236 ***
(0.08) (0.26) (0.07)
Observations 4,585 1,156 2,940
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.659 0.611 0.545
Panel B: 1997
(B1) (B2) (B3)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.133 -0.453 ** -0.065
(0.08) (0.18) (0.06)
Observations 5.210 2,403 3,075
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.720 0.658 0.688
Panel C: 2002
(C1) (C2) (C3)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.158 -0.123 -0.150 *
(0.10) (0.36) (0.08)
Observations 4,190 1,377 2.680
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.679 0.623 0.659
Panel D: 2007
(D1) (D2) (D3)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.242 *** 0.007 -0.287 ***
(0.07) (0.17) (0.06)
Observations 3,910 1,679 2,976
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.752 0.674 0.715
Sector Machinery Manufacturing
Panel A: 1993
(A4) (A5)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.036 -0.051
(0.07) (0.05)
Observations 4,140 11,484
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.565 0.684
Panel B: 1997
(B4) (B5)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.078 -0.181 ***
(0.05) (0.04)
Observations 3,315 7,340
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.681 0.752
Panel C: 2002
(C4) (C5)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.037 -0.246 ***
(0.07) (0.06)
Observations 3,065 6,800
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.618 0.722
Panel D: 2007
(D4) (D5)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.016 -0.238 ***
(0.07) (0.04)
Observations 3,332 7,156
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.614 0.766
Notes: Importer and exporter fixed effects included in all
regressions. Constant, fixed effects and effects on log distance and
adjacency not reported. Robust standard errors reported in
parentheses. Table S 10 (Supporting Information) contains full
results. Commodities pooled into sectors as listed in Tables A3 and A4
in the Appendix. States in sample as in Table 1. District of Columbia
excluded.
*** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level; *
significant at the 10% level.
TABLE 5
Contemporaneous Controls, 1993 (Fixed-Effects Estimation)
Dependent Variable: In bilateral exports between i and j relative to
states' GDPs
(1) (2)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.137 *** -0.120 ***
(0.03) (0.03)
Geographical controls
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.919 *** -0.631 ***
(0.03) (0.04)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.434 *** 0.356 ***
(0.06) (0.05)
Network controls
In Migration [Stock.sub.ij] 0.129 ***
(0.03)
x Black [Share.sub.ij] 0.001 ***
(0.00)
x Jewish Share.sub.ij] -0.005
(0.00)
x Christian [Share.sub.ij] 0.002
(0.00)
x Other Religion [Share.sub.ij] 0.062 **
(0.03)
x No Religion [Share.sub.ij] 0.007
(0.00)
x Urban [Share.sub.ij] 3.494 ***
(0.77)
Common [colonizer.sub.ij] 0.198 ***
(0.04)
Labor market/political institutions
[DELTA] Union [membership.sub.ij]
[DELTA] Union [density.sub.ij]
[DELTA] Minimum [wage.sub.ij]
[DELTA] [Republican.sub.ij]
Judiciary [election.sub.ij]
Heckscher-Ohlin controls
[DELTA] In Capital-labor [ratio.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In High-low skilled [ratio.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Average [schooling.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In [Cropland.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Farm [size.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Agricultural to total
[output.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Manufacturing to total
[output.sub.ij]
Demography
[DELTA] In [Population.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Population [density.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In [Fertility.sub.ij]
Linder hypothesis
[DELTA] In Income per [Capita.sub.ij]
Observations 740 740
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.841 0.865
(3) (4)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.1 17 *** -0.109 ***
(0.04) (0.04)
Geographical controls
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.633 *** -0.627 ***
(0.04) (0.05)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.352 *** 0.380 ***
(0.05) (0.05)
Network controls
In Migration [Stock.sub.ij] 0.125 *** 0.089 **
(0.03) (0.03)
x Black [Share.sub.ij] 0.001 *** 0.001 ***
(0.00) (0.00)
x Jewish Share.sub.ij] -0.004 -0.003
(0.00) (0.00)
x Christian [Share.sub.ij] 0.002 0.002
(0.00) (0.00)
x Other Religion [Share.sub.ij] 0.064 ** 0.067 **
(0.03) (0.03)
x No Religion [Share.sub.ij] 0.006 0.007
(0.00) (0.00)
x Urban [Share.sub.ij] 3.425 *** 3.675 ***
(0.81) (0.92)
Common [colonizer.sub.ij] 0.202 *** 0.173 ***
(0.04) (0.04)
Labor market/political institutions
[DELTA] Union [membership.sub.ij] -0.003 -0.013
(0.02) (0.02)
[DELTA] Union [density.sub.ij] 0.003 0.013
(0.02) (0.02)
[DELTA] Minimum [wage.sub.ij] -0.177 -0.207
(0.15) (0.15)
[DELTA] [Republican.sub.ij] -0.001 -0.003
(0.03) (0.03)
Judiciary [election.sub.ij] -0.074 ** -0.073 **
(0.03) (0.03)
Heckscher-Ohlin controls
[DELTA] In Capital-labor [ratio.sub.ij] 0.024
(0.16)
[DELTA] In High-low skilled [ratio.sub.ij] 0.076
(0.09)
[DELTA] In Average [schooling.sub.ij] -1.404
(1.13)
[DELTA] In [Cropland.sub.ij] -0.053 ***
(0.02)
[DELTA] In Farm [size.sub.ij] 0.021
(0.05)
[DELTA] In Agricultural to total 0.066
[output.sub.ij] (0.04)
[DELTA] In Manufacturing to total -0.102
[output.sub.ij] (0.11)
Demography
[DELTA] In [Population.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In Population [density.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In [Fertility.sub.ij]
Linder hypothesis
[DELTA] In Income per [Capita.sub.ij]
Observations 740 740
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.866 0.868
(5) (6)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.120 *** -0.119 ***
(0.04) (0.04)
Geographical controls
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.611 *** -0.612 ***
(0.05) (0.05)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.397 *** 0.399 ***
(0.05) (0.05)
Network controls
In Migration [Stock.sub.ij] 0.088 ** 0.086 **
(0.03) (0.03)
x Black [Share.sub.ij] 0.001 *** 0.001 ***
(0.00) (0.00)
x Jewish Share.sub.ij] -0.002 -0.002
(0.00) (0.00)
x Christian [Share.sub.ij] 0.002 * 0.002
(0.00) (0.00)
x Other Religion [Share.sub.ij] 0.055 * 0.056 *
(0.03) (0.03)
x No Religion [Share.sub.ij] 0.005 0.005
(0.00) (0.00)
x Urban [Share.sub.ij] 3.648 *** 3.651 ***
(1.13) (1.13)
Common [colonizer.sub.ij] 0.168 *** 0.169 ***
(0.04) (0.04)
Labor market/political institutions
[DELTA] Union [membership.sub.ij] -0.016 -0.017
(0.02) (0.02)
[DELTA] Union [density.sub.ij] 0.016 0.017
(0.02) (0.02)
[DELTA] Minimum [wage.sub.ij] -0.167 -0.168
(0.15) (0.15)
[DELTA] [Republican.sub.ij] -0.002 -0.002
(0.03) (0.03)
Judiciary [election.sub.ij] -0.072 ** -0.072 **
(0.03) (0.03)
Heckscher-Ohlin controls
[DELTA] In Capital-labor [ratio.sub.ij] 0.022 0.000
(0.16) (0.20)
[DELTA] In High-low skilled [ratio.sub.ij] 0.079 0.080
(0.09) (0.09)
[DELTA] In Average [schooling.sub.ij] -1.473 -1.584
(1.15) (1.27)
[DELTA] In [Cropland.sub.ij] -0.052 *** -0.052 ***
(0.02) (0.02)
[DELTA] In Farm [size.sub.ij] 0.010 0.007
(0.07) (0.07)
[DELTA] In Agricultural to total 0.038 0.038
[output.sub.ij] (0.04) (0.04)
[DELTA] In Manufacturing to total -0.075 -0.064
[output.sub.ij] (0.11) (0.12)
Demography
[DELTA] In [Population.sub.ij] -0.018 -0.019
(0.03) (0.03)
[DELTA] In Population [density.sub.ij] 0.029 0.030
(0.04) (0.04)
[DELTA] In [Fertility.sub.ij] -0.675 -0.658
(0.41) (0.41)
Linder hypothesis
[DELTA] In Income per [Capita.sub.ij] 0.069
(0.29)
Observations 740 740
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.869 0.868
Notes: Importer and exporter fixed effects included in all
regressions. Constant and fixed effects not reported. Robust standard
errors reported in parentheses. The operator [delta] denotes the
absolute difference of variables in state i and state j. The operator
x denotes the product of variables in state i and state j.
*** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level; *
significant at the 10% level.
TABLE 6
Controls, Alternative Samples, and Models: Summary Results
Dependent Variable: In bilateral exports between i and j relative to
states' GDPs
Year of Data: 1993 1997 2002 2007
Panel A: OLS FE
(A1) (A2) (A3) (A4)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.119 *** -0.039 -0.119 * 0.016
(0.04) (0.05) (0.06) (0.06)
Observations 740 738 711 740
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.868 0.854 0.844 0.874
Panel B: PPML FE
(BI) (B2) (B3) (B4)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.133 *** -0.027 -0.019 0.115
(0.05) (0.05) (0.07) (0.07)
Observations 756 756 756 756
Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.028 0.028 0.033 0.031
Panel C: Pooled commodity FE (Chen 2004)
(C1) (C2) (C3) (C4)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.234 *** -0.101 *** -0.050 -0.076 **
(0.04) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04)
Observations 12.271 10,342 6.979 11.834
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.611 0.805 0.775 0.773
Notes: Constant, fixed effects, and controls not reported. Robust
standard errors reported in parentheses. All models include variables
of column (6) in Table 5 as additional controls. Full results are
reported in Table S11 (Supporting Information).
*** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level:
* significant at the 10% level.
TABLE 7
Contemporaneous and Historical Controls, 1993
(Fixed-Effects Estimation)
Dependent Variable: In bilateral exports between i and j relative to
states' GDPs
(1) (2) (3)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.234 *** -0.121 *** -0.129 **
(0.07) (0.04) (0.06)
Controls as of Table 5 YES YES YES
column (6) included
Historical controls
[DELTA] In 1860 -0.027
[Cropland.sub.ij] (0.02)
[DELTA] In 1860 Farm 0.160 **
[size.sub.ij] (0.08)
[DELTA] In 1860 Population 0.032
[density.sub.ij] (0.02)
[DELTA] In 1860 Illiteracy 0.001
[rates.sub.ij] (0.00)
[DELTA] 1860 Slave
[share.sub.ij]
[DELTA] 1860 Free Black
[Share.sub.ij]
x 1860 French [Share.sub.ij]
x 1860 Spanish [Share.sub.ij]
x 1860 Irish [Share.sub.ij]
x 1860 German [Share.sub.ij]
x 1860 British [Share.sub.ij]
[DELTA] 1860
[Malaria Risk.sub.ij]
Observations 740 740 740
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.869 0.869 0.868
(4) (5)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.177 ** -0.118 ***
(0.08) (0.04)
Controls as of Table 5 YES YES
column (6) included
Historical controls
[DELTA] In 1860
[Cropland.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In 1860 Farm
[size.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In 1860 Population
[density.sub.ij]
[DELTA] In 1860 Illiteracy
[rates.sub.ij]
[DELTA] 1860 Slave 0.002
[share.sub.ij] (0.00)
[DELTA] 1860 Free Black 0.030
[Share.sub.ij] (0.02)
x 1860 French [Share.sub.ij] 0.492 ***
(0.16)
x 1860 Spanish [Share.sub.ij] 2.462
(16.94)
x 1860 Irish [Share.sub.ij] -0.002 **
(0.00)
x 1860 German [Share.sub.ij] 0.001
(0.00)
x 1860 British [Share.sub.ij] 0.002
(0.00)
[DELTA] 1860
Malaria [Risk.sub.ij]
Observations 740 740
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.869 0.873
(6) (7)
Border [dummy.sub.ij[ -0.141 *** -0.251 **
(0.04) (0.10)
Controls as of Table 5 YES YES
column (6) included
Historical controls
[DELTA] In 1860 -0.035 *
[Cropland.sub.ij] (0.02)
[DELTA] In 1860 Farm 0.100
[size.sub.ij] (0.09)
[DELTA] In 1860 Population 0.028
[density.sub.ij] (0.02)
[DELTA] In 1860 Illiteracy 0.006
[rates.sub.ij] (0.01)
[DELTA] 1860 Slave 0.000
[share.sub.ij] (0.00)
[DELTA] 1860 [Free Black 0.035 *
Share.sub.ij] (0.02)
x 1860 French [Share.sub.ij] 0.474 ***
(0.17)
x 1860 Spanish [Share.sub.ij] 0.085
(17.74)
x 1860 Irish [Share.sub.ij] -0.002 **
(0.00)
x 1860 German [Share.sub.ij] 0.001
(0.00)
x 1860 British [Share.sub.ij] 0.003
(0.00)
[DELTA] 1860 0.345 0.255
Malaria [Risk.sub.ij] (0.25) (0.29)
Observations 740 740
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.869 0.873
Notes: Importer and exporter fixed effects included in all
regressions. All models include variables as of column (6), Table 5
as additional controls. Constant, fixed effects, and contemporaneous
controls not reported. Robust standard errors reported in
parentheses. The operator [DELTA] denotes the absolute difference of
variables in state i and state j. The operator x denotes the
product of variables in state i and state i.
*** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level;
* significant at the 10%n level.
TABLE 8
Additionally Including the West, 1993
Dependent Variable: In bilateral exports between i
and j relative to states' GDPs
Data Aggregated
OLS FE
Specification: (1) (2)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.068 *
(0.04)
South-South [dummy.sub.ij] 0.235 ***
(0.07)
North-North [dummy.sub.ij] -2.665 **
(1.24)
West-West [dummy.sub.ij] -0.039
(0.09)
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.421 *** -0.422 ***
(0.05) (0.05)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.463 *** 0.458 ***
(0.07) (0.07)
Additional controls YES YES
Observations 1,696 1,696
Adjusted/Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.808 0.808
Data Aggregated Commodity
PPML FE Chen (2004) FE
Specification: (3) (4) (5)
Border [dummy.sub.ij] -0.090 * -0.213
(0.05) (0.03)
South-South [dummy.sub.ij] 0.267 ***
(0.09)
North-North [dummy.sub.ij] -0.307
(0.30)
West-West [dummy.sub.ij] -0.084
(0.11)
In [Distance.sub.ij] -0.275 *** -0.282 *** -0.238 ***
(0.06) (0.05) (0.03)
[Adjacency.sub.ij] 0.338 *** 0.326 *** 0.475 ***
(0.06) (0.06) (0.04)
Additional controls YES YES YES
Observations 1,806 1,806 23,400
Adjusted/Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.039 0.039 0.567
Notes: Constant, fixed effects, and controls not reported. Robust
standard errors reported in parentheses. All models include variables
as of column (6), Table 5 available for all U.S. states as additional
controls.
*** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level;
* significant at the 10% level.