首页    期刊浏览 2025年04月20日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Wages, employment, and statistical discrimination: evidence from the laboratory.
  • 作者:Dickinson, David L. ; Oaxaca, Ronald L.
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2014
  • 期号:October
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:While taste-based discrimination (Becker 1957) is driven by prejudice, research on statistical discrimination attempts to explain differential treatment of individuals unrelated to prejudice. In essence, statistical discrimination results when the actual or assumed statistical properties of a group are applied to anyone belonging to that group. Differential treatment based on lower average outcomes of one's group (e.g., minorities, females) was considered a starting point for modeling of statistical discrimination (see Phelps 1972). However, labor market researchers then considered that statistical discrimination could result from measures other than the average outcomes of one's group (see Aigner and Cain 1977; Lundberg and Startz 1983). Theoretical models have explored various reasons why statistical discrimination might arise in varied contexts. Most notable are the models based on differential screening or communication costs (Cornell and Welch 1996; Lang 1986), noisier productivity signals (see discussion in Aigner and Cain 1977), or incomplete information (Lundberg and Startz 1983). (1)
  • 关键词:Employers;Employment discrimination;Labor market;Unemployment

Wages, employment, and statistical discrimination: evidence from the laboratory.


Dickinson, David L. ; Oaxaca, Ronald L.


I. INTRODUCTION

While taste-based discrimination (Becker 1957) is driven by prejudice, research on statistical discrimination attempts to explain differential treatment of individuals unrelated to prejudice. In essence, statistical discrimination results when the actual or assumed statistical properties of a group are applied to anyone belonging to that group. Differential treatment based on lower average outcomes of one's group (e.g., minorities, females) was considered a starting point for modeling of statistical discrimination (see Phelps 1972). However, labor market researchers then considered that statistical discrimination could result from measures other than the average outcomes of one's group (see Aigner and Cain 1977; Lundberg and Startz 1983). Theoretical models have explored various reasons why statistical discrimination might arise in varied contexts. Most notable are the models based on differential screening or communication costs (Cornell and Welch 1996; Lang 1986), noisier productivity signals (see discussion in Aigner and Cain 1977), or incomplete information (Lundberg and Startz 1983). (1)

Field studies, some of which involve experimental manipulations, have uncovered evidence of statistical discrimination in mortgage lending (Ladd 1998), auto sales (Ayers and Siegelman 1995; Goldberg 1996; Harless and Hoffer 2002), sports card price negotiations (List 2004), law enforcement decisions (Applebaum 1996), exam grading (Hanna and Linden 2012), taxi fare negotiations (Castillo et al. 2013), and vehicle repair estimates (Gneezy and List 2006). In labor markets, some discrimination may be due to factors other than productivity characteristics (Neumark 1999), but the evidence for statistical discrimination based on race has been elusive (see Altonji and Pierret 2001). Identifying statistical discrimination from field data is complicated by the fact that it may arise as first-moment or second-moment statistical discrimination, and they are difficult to disentangle empirically.

More controlled laboratory studies have also examined statistical discrimination (Anderson and Haupert 1999; Castillo and Petrie 2010; Davis 1987; Dickinson and Oaxaca 2009; Fershtman and Gneezy 2001; Masclet, Peterle, and Larribeau 2012). (2) Findings from these laboratory studies indicate that statistical discrimination may result from aversion to risk, mistaken stereotypes, biased probability assessments, or incomplete information. The benefit of the laboratory approach is our ability to control and cleanly identify the source of the discrimination, if it exists.

Whether taste-based or statistical, discrimination is most always measured along a single dimension, such as vehicle pricing, labor market wages, group choice, or job assignments. (3) However, in many instances multiple avenues for discrimination exist simultaneously and to focus on only one may produce a systematically biased view of the prevalence of statistically based discrimination. (4) In this paper, we examine statistical discrimination in a controlled experimental environment. Statistical discrimination in our study can only be based on productivity-distribution risk attached to worker groups. We not only cleanly separate taste-based from statistical discrimination, but we also cleanly isolate second-moment statistical discrimination in a way not possible from field data. Building on Dickinson and Oaxaca (2009), our key contribution is to examine an environment in which discrimination may be exercised simultaneously along the dimensions of both wages and employment rates. This more closely approximates the field environments we hope to study, where discrimination may exist in terms of labor market wages and/or hiring practices, auto sales prices and/or sales rates, mortgage rates and/or home sales.

As in Dickinson and Oaxaca (2009), subjects negotiate in a simulated labor market where worker subjects are given an induced common-knowledge productivity distribution. In the present design, our environment allows workers of distinct productivity-distribution groups to compete against each other in negotiating with employers for a wage contract. The environment is designed such that there is equilibrium unemployment, allowing us to compare both wage and unemployment rates of workers belonging to distinct productivity-distribution groups. Additionally, these data allow us to examine the bias in discrimination estimates that would exist if we only had data on one dimension or the other from our experimental market (i.e., only hiring data or only wage data).

Our results indicate that, while higher variance in a worker's productivity decreases the negotiated wage, there is evidence that experimental employers substitute hiring choice and wage contracts. More specifically, workers with higher productivity variance are more likely to be hired, but they receive lower wages. An alternative measure of productivity risk (i.e., the distributional support) significantly decreases the likelihood of being employed while not significantly impacting the wage if hired. (5) These results are intriguing and highly relevant to naturally occurring labor markets where hiring and pay decisions are often made over potential workers from heterogeneous statistical worker groups. Our evidence that experimental employers practice statistical wage discrimination and statistical employment reverse-discrimination indicates that a focus on wages alone may overestimate the real incidence of statistical discrimination.

II. EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN

The experimental environment is an oral double-auction market, with employer and worker subjects negotiating wage contracts in an open pit. There is no central auctioneer, and no actual labor task is involved. Rather, we use the context of a labor market so that it would be easier for subjects to comprehend the trading environment. We replicate the methods of Dickinson and Oaxaca (2009) to the extent possible, which facilitates comparison of our results. The design is a context-specific use of classic market experiment techniques discussed in Smith (1982). That is, supply and demand are induced upon subjects, and all decisions have monetary consequence. See Appendix SI, Supporting Information, for experiment instructions.

Each experimental session consists of 15 subjects. Five of these subjects are randomly assigned to be "employer" subjects, and the rest are assigned as "worker" subjects. A worker can sell at most one unit of labor, and an employer can hire only one unit of labor, during each round of the experiment. Workers have an induced reservation wage of $0.80, such that they are guaranteed this payment for a round in which they are not employed and this reservation wage is private information to workers. The expected productivity of a unit of labor to the employer is 3 units of output, which sell for a normalized $ 1.00 per unit (the price per unit of output is private employer information). Thus, expected revenue to an employer from hiring a unit of labor is $3.00. Profits to a worker subject are either the reservation wage, [W.sub.R], or the negotiated wage, W, which we did not bound so that workers enjoying utility from making a contract may choose to negotiate W < [W.sub.R]. Employer profits are the realized productivity of the worker (times output price $1.00) minus the negotiated wage. The thicker supply side of the market guarantees equilibrium unemployment of five workers (50% unemployment) per round. (6) Figure 1 shows the simulated labor market for each round of the experiment.

An experiment session consists of four treatments of four decision rounds each, for a total of 16 decision rounds per experimental session. The labor pool in each treatment consists of workers belonging to one of two distinct worker productivity types. A worker's type or "group" for a given round is identified by an ID badge worn by the subject. At the outset of an experimental session workers are assigned to a productivity distribution through random allocation of the 10 ID badges, that is, 5 ID badges for each productivity-distribution group. For subsequent treatments in an experimental session, each group cohort is randomly assigned to one of two groups corresponding to the particular treatment. This procedure is much simpler to implement but may potentially retain negotiating power asymmetries across the two competing worker groups. In the conduct of the experiment, there was never any evidence of group "bonding" or group consciousness. As will be seen below, worker and worker-employer pair random effects were taken account of in the econometric analysis of the experimental results. (7)

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The design choice to randomly assign workers to productivity-distribution groups implies that workers are effectively identical within these groups. This reflects our focus on the employers' wage and hiring choices. As such, actual worker subjects may not seem necessary in our experiments, but we choose to not mechanize the worker choice in order to maintain the labor negotiations context of our experiments. Additionally, the market exchange environment leverages the well-documented power of the double-auction institution to produce the competitively predicted wage outcomes. This allows one to attribute outcome differences across worker groups to the productivity group differences with minimal concern that bargaining heterogeneity is driving the results.

We used a total of six different worker productivity distributions in all. The productivity-distribution information of each worker group is shown in Table 1. As in Dickinson and Oaxaca (2009), the worker productivity distributions are intended to explore three distinct measures of "risk": the distributional variance, the support of the distribution, and the probability that earnings will be less than mean earnings ($3.00) for an employer. (8) As can be seen in Table 1, hiring a worker identified as belonging to Group 1 guarantees the employer a certain productivity of 3 units of output. Hiring a worker from any of the other groups involves risk of some sort. Upon hiring a worker from a risky productivity-distribution group, a random draw from the appropriate productivity distribution determines the worker productivity to the employer for that round. Productivity draws are independent each and every round, such that employers are aware that negotiating a wage contract with the same subject in two distinct rounds or with any subject from the same productivity group as in a previous round may not lead to the same productivity outcome. We do not include any risk or loss aversion instrument in our design, and so heterogeneity in either of these individual preference dimensions may add noise to our data that will be dealt with in the econometric analysis.

As noted above, employer choice involves two dimensions: hiring workers from one group or the other and the choice of wage. With six distinct worker productivity groups, there are 15 possible binary group comparisons. An experiment session, however, involves only four treatments, and so we select treatments so that each session involves one treatment that pairs the certain productivity group, GI, with one of the other groups, and then three treatments with labor pools comprised of (G2,G5), (G2.G6), and (G3,G4) productivity group pairings (treatments randomly ordered within a session). The (G2,G5) pairing captures the risk associated with the probability of earnings less than mean earning, and the (G2,G6) pairing captures the risk associated with changing the support by extending the maximum outcome to 5 versus 4. In the case of the (G3,G4) pairing, the variance is higher for G4 but the support is missing outcomes 2 and 4 which are symmetric around the distribution mean of 3. The distributional information in Table 1 highlights how these binary comparisons vary the risk measures. Table 2 shows the productivity comparisons used in each of the five experimental sessions we ran, and the location of any particular treatment within the set of four treatments was varied across sessions. Because each subject was administered four of the many possible treatment pairings (see Table 2), our design is a mixed design with both within- and between-subjects components.

III. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

In our environment, employers make a simultaneous choice of employment and wage rate. Thus, a simple choice framework for employers would be a traditional model of choice where employer utility, U, is a function of expected profits, [pi], and employment risk (i.e., productivity risk), r. U = U([pi],r), where [U.sub.[pi]]' > 0, [U.sub.r]' < 0, [U.sub.[pi]]" < 0, [U.sub.r]" > 0. Because expected productivity is fixed across all worker groups, [pi] varies inversely with the wage rate. Assuming employers are risk averse, we borrow from optimal portfolio theory of Markowitz (1952) and formulate an employer's utility maximization decision. (9) As seen in Section IV (Table 3), our data indicate that expected profits are higher (i.e., wages lower) for the risky productivity groups relative to certain productivity. Thus, the labor market "portfolio" constraint describing combinations of expected profits and productivity risk available to employers appears as the upward sloping line in Figure 2, as one would expect.

In this framework, employers with a higher marginal disutility of productivity risk (bold indifference curves in Figure 2) will choose to hire workers from groups considered a lower productivity risk, paying them higher wages (resulting in lower expected profits, it). Conversely, employers with lower marginal disutility of risk (dashed indifference curves) will hire from riskier worker groups and face higher expected profits. We reiterate here that higher expected profits are not due to higher levels of average productivity--average worker productivity is constant in our experimental design--but rather due to lower market wages for the same level of average productivity. The risk-reward trade-off is at the core of this framework.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

This framework assumes a continuous risk choice dimension, but our experimental framework has employers choosing between hiring a worker from one group or another. Within this framework, choices of workers from one group or the other will generate the employment rates in our data. An underlying assumption is that there is a market wage for each worker group and employers take that wage as given. Although this is not true in our two-sided auction market, the simplification captures the idea that both empirical employment and wage models should be the functions of worker groups as well as the variables capturing the particular worker group pairing facing the employer in a given choice round. For example, consider two worker groups, [G.sub.x] and [G.sub.y]. A worker from [G.sub.x] will be hired over [G.sub.y] if the hire offers the employer higher utility. So an employment indicator for the worker from [G.sub.x], can be defined as [E.sub.Gx] = 1[U([[pi].sub.Gx], [r.sub.Gx]) - U([pi][G.sub.y], [r.sub.Gy]) > 0]. Such a framework is basically a random utility model that lends itself to probit estimation techniques with regressors that capture the relevant worker group information. In Figure 3 we see that the employer with indifference curves as shown would prefer hiring a [G.sub.y] worker over a [G.sub.x] worker, but would employ a [G.sub.z] worker over a [G.sub.y] worker. The probability of employment for a worker from a given group depends on the alternative available to the employer.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

It is clear from this framework that one can view the hiring and wage choices of employers in a general way that focuses on risk and compensating differentials. While it is true that our experiments can therefore apply to risky choice in general, in many instances such a risky choice decision is cast as a simple individual choice task. This would be more applicable to choice over risky assets in a portfolio choice problem, but the two-sided negotiations context we employ has greater external validity for labor markets. It is also worth highlighting that the few studies examining a dual-dimension of discrimination possible do so only empirically, without offering a theoretical basis. In some instances, econometric modeling choices may even constrain coefficients on wage and employment outcomes to imply discrimination on both dimensions (see our comments in Section IV on the Tobit model). A framework that suggests employers might substitute wages for employment risk is novel for labor markets, and gives us reason to suggest caution regarding empirical strategies for labor market discrimination studies that address employment and wages simultaneously.

IV. RESULTS

We consider a series of random effects models for wage and unemployment rate determination. For wage determination, we estimate wage equations based on contract pair (employer-worker) random effects, based on employer random effects, and based on worker random effects. (10) In any given experimental session there were 5 employers, 10 workers, 4 treatments, and 4 rounds per treatment. With a total of 5 sessions, we therefore have 25 employers and 50 worker subjects in the data set. In our design, 5 of the 10 workers are unemployed each round. Thus, our data include 400 total wage contracts and consequently 400 observations for contract pair random effects and 400 observations for employer random effects. On the other hand, there are a total of 800 observations for work random effects.

In the case of contract pairs, there were 161 distinct employer-worker pairings. The random effects wage determination model corresponding to contract pair random effects is an unbalanced design and is parsimoniously specified by

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

where {ij} denotes each unique employer(i)-worker(j) contract pair, [G.sub.jt] is a vector of dummy variables for the group association of the jth worker, [T.sub.t] is a vector of dummy variables for the treatments (corresponding to which two worker groups are competing for wage contracts), [R.sub.t] is a vector of dummy variables corresponding to the four rounds per treatment, [C.sub.{ij}t] is a vector of dummy variables for employer-worker gender pairings, the [beta]'s are conforming parameter vectors, [u.sub.{ij}] is a normally distributed mean zero, constant variance contract pair random effect, and [[epsilon].sub.{ij}t] is a normally distributed mean zero, constant variance idiosyncratic error term.

When considering employer random effects, we have a balanced design. The wage determination model in this case is specified as

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

where variables are defined as above (i indexes employers, j indexes workers).

Since in any given period, half of the workers will be unemployed, we model the wage determination process for workers as a balanced design random effects Tobit:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

Here, [X.sub.jt] is a vector of worker personal characteristics corresponding to gender, minority status, and citizenship. (11) From the estimated Tobit model, we can examine unemployment rates. Specifically, we back out the probability of being employed

P (Employed = 1) = [PHI](I/[sigma])

where [PHI] is the standard normal cumulative distribution function, [sigma] is the standard deviation of worker wages, and / is the index function defined earlier by

I = [[beta].sub.0] + G[[beta].sub.G] + T[[beta].sub.T] + R[[beta].sub.R] + X[[beta].sub.X].

Considering the wage effect coefficients of the random effects models for contract pairs and employers, all worker groups with some productivity risk exhibited negative wage effects compared with Group G1 with the certain productivity outcome (see Table 4). These negative wage effects were statistically significant in two cases, Groups G3 and G4. When considering the random effects Tobit model for workers, we find that relative to G1 all of the other groups exhibit consistently negative wage effects. These were statistically significant in two cases, Groups G2 and G5.

Table 5 reports the estimated treatment effects for isolated productivity risk variables: variance, support, and probability of productivity less than the mean. With respect to the contract pairs and employer random effects model, the results suggest that higher variances are associated with statistically significantly lower wage contracts. The G4-G3 treatment shows that higher variance and two omitted outcomes symmetric around the mean productivity outcome depress wage contracts. The G4-G5 comparison is not a treatment but is rather a cross-subject design to estimate the wage-contract effects of the higher variance associated with G4 and the same two omitted outcomes. The estimated impact on wage contracts is even greater than the G4-G3 treatment. The only difference in these two variance/support comparisons is that the difference in variances for G4-G5 is nearly twice as large as that of the G4-G3 treatment. This would suggest that the variance effect is the driver of the wage contract effects. Indeed the statistically significant negative G3-G5 cross-subject estimate in Table 5 is exactly the difference between G4-G5 and G4-G3. As the supports are identical, this effect is solely the result of the variance difference between G3 and G5. At the same time, there were no statistically significant wage contract effects of productivity distribution support or the probability of productivity less than the mean. On the other hand, the random effects Tobit model for workers shows no statistically significant coefficients associated with membership in higher variance groups or in groups with a higher probability of generating productivity less than the mean. Yet, there is a statistically significant negative coefficient for membership in groups with a higher support range.

We use the estimated probabilities of employment from the Tobit model evaluated at the overall sample mean to estimate the marginal effects of our risk measures on the probability of employment. We find no statistically significant employment effect of the higher variance with symmetrically omitted outcomes of G4 against G3 but we do find statistically significant positive employment effects of the higher variances of G3 and G4 against G5. We find no statistically significant employment effect from a higher probability of drawing productivity less than the mean.

As already pointed out, while all three of the variance-related treatments had statistically significant negative impacts on wage contracts in the contract pairs and employer RE models, they had no direct wage impacts when taking account of worker random effects. Interestingly, two of the variance treatments (G4 vs. G5 and G3 vs. G5) had positive effects on employment. These positive employment effects were accompanied by negative wage contract effects for employers. The variance/support treatment for G4 vs. G3 had no statistically significant employment effect to offset the employer/contract pair negative wage contract effect. In the case of the higher support range treatment, there was no contract pair/employer wage contract effect, but there was a negative wage and employment impact when taking account of worker random effects. When considering the probability of productivity draws less than the mean, we find no evidence of wage or employment effects.

The contract pair and employer-based random effects estimations look at the data from the employer perspective, without considering the unemployment risk as is the case when looking at the worker random effects Tobit estimations. If we consider the workers' perspective, the expected wage is determined according to

[W.sup.e] = E(W|X) = (W|W > 0) x ([pi]),

where [W.sup.e] is the worker's expected wage, W | W > 0 is the wage conditional upon being employed, and [pi] is the probability of being employed. This expected wage is simply a weighted average of W = 0 when unemployed and W > 0 when employed. The change in the expected wage associated with group "k" compared with group "j" can be calculated as follows:

[DELTA] [W.sup.e.sub.kj] = [W.sup.e.sub.k] - [W.sup.e.sub.j].

In the case of a Tobit model, the marginal effects of continuous variables are constrained to have the same sign for the conditional mean wage effects and the employment effects. This correspondence would generally carry over when looking at the marginal effects of binary variables. Thus, we use the Tobit model to estimate employment effects, but focus on the random effects wage equations for estimated wage effects as these are not constrained by the Tobit model to have the same sign as the employment effects. (12)

Column 6 of Table 5 (Wage Effect | X) reports the expected wage effects using the predicted wages and probabilities evaluated at overall sample means. Three of the risk treatments show a negative effect on mean expected wages but only the negative support treatment effect is statistically significant. In the case of employer and contract pair random effects, the support treatment does not produce a statistically significant wage effect. With the exception of the G4-G3 comparison, the variance treatments show statistically significant positive effects on worker average wages (including 0 wages when unemployed). These same variance treatment comparisons show negative and statistically significant wage effects for employer and contract pair random effects. Thus, the expected or "average" wage results seem to conflict with the contract wage effects of the variance treatments when considering employer and contract pair random effects. It is clear that the employment probability effects are driving these results.

Our findings suggest that the variance treatments depress wage contracts for employers and contract pairs, but raise the probability of a worker being employed in two of the three variance treatments (see far-right column of Table 5). These wage contract effects are consistent with the theoretical framework outlined earlier, which stressed the risk-reward trade-off to an employer of wages and productivity risk of hiring certain workers. Regarding overall risk effects, the positive employment effects of two of the variance treatments in the worker RE Tobit model generate positive estimated effects on mean wages and conditional mean wages. While in some sense overcorrecting our worker RE Tobit results demonstrate that the effects of risk on wage contracts alone do not reveal the full extent of statistical discrimination. Certainly, the negative risk effects of productivity variance on employer contract wages overstate the extent of statistical discrimination because the same measure of risk increases the probability of employment. In the case of the support treatment, the lack of wage contract effects actually understates the extent of statistical discrimination because the negative employment effects reduce the expected wages of these workers. The probability of productivity draws less than the mean had little effect on wage contracts, conditional wages, employment probabilities, and expected wages.

Among the control variables in our models, the round/period effects were never statistically significant. In the contract pairs and employer RE models (relative to contracts between male employers and male workers), the presence of a female in the contract is associated with higher wage contracts. The highest contract is associated with female employers and female workers (C_ff in Table 4), followed by contracts with male employers and female workers (C_mf), and finally by contracts between female employers and male workers (C_fm). However, the estimated wage contract effect for C_fm is not statistically different from a male employer/male worker contract. In the RE Tobit wage model for workers, we controlled for gender, minority status, and noncitizen. For the most part these variables were not statistically significant though minority status exhibited a marginally significant negative effect on wages and because of the restrictions imposed by a Tobit model, a small negative effect on the probability of employment. We should highlight that the race and gender variables are used only as controls and cannot be used to identify taste-based discrimination in our study, as these variables may correlate with other relevant variables.

Given that the subject workers assume a relatively passive role compared with the subject employers, columns 2 and 3 of Table 5 provide our best estimates of the wage contract effects of our risk measures, while column 6 provides the sole estimates of the employment effects of the risk measures. With this in mind, a main result of this paper is that our estimations suggest that belonging to a risky productivity group has a negative effect on wage contracts while it may yet have a positive effect on the probability of being employed. Thus, our laboratory evidence suggests that employers may view hiring choices and wage contracts as substitute goods. That is, a higher productivity variance increases the likelihood that one will be employed, but conditional on employment there is a lower wage contract. Reverse statistical discrimination in hiring choices is perhaps used by employers to help leverage wage negotiations (i.e., those high-variance workers willing to accept lower wages increase their likelihood of being employed). It would therefore be an incomplete view of statistical discrimination if one were to focus simply on wage effects among the employed. In some cases, doing so in our data would upwardly bias one's estimate of the negative effects of productivity variance in the labor pool because it would fail to take into account any increased probability of employment. In other cases, there can be a downward bias in the estimate of statistical discrimination, such as when we find no significant wage effect among employed workers, but a decreased likelihood of employment.

V. DISCUSSION

Our previous work (Dickinson and Oaxaca 2009) found a significant effect of loss probabilities on depressing wage contracts, a result we do not replicate in these data. However, the availability of more than one way to statistically discriminate in the present experiments implies the results we report here are not directly comparable to our previous research. The present experiments generate a richer data set for exploring how worker productivity risk impacts the dual choice faced by employers. The result is that this current work is more externally valid and applicable to field labor markets.

Our data are consistent with employers exercising trade-offs between hiring choices and wage contracts in an environment where competing heterogeneous workers have identical expected labor productivity but differ with respect to the riskiness of their labor productivity. We implement a design where there is equilibrium unemployment such that employers may simply choose to not hire workers from less-preferred worker groups. For worker groups with a higher variance of labor productivity, we estimate lower wages from the contract-pair and employer random effects models, but we also find that these same workers often face an increased probability of being employed. Thus, our data overall show statistically based discrimination in wages but reverse statistical discrimination in hiring choices.

The offsetting wage and employment effects we find imply that expected wages of the worker may actually be higher as a result of belonging to a high risk worker pool, when defining risk as a higher variance of labor productivity. However, we also isolate an alternative measure of risk, the support of the productivity distribution, and find that typical wage estimates may underestimate statistical discrimination as a result of that alternative risk measure. As a result, we cannot make a general claim as to the direction of the likely bias in typical wage discrimination estimates, but it is clear that ignoring hiring choices in one's analysis can generate significant wage effect biases. These results make the case for considering employment, wages, and earnings in empirical research as a way to more fully assess whether discrimination has any net impact on labor market outcomes. In doing so, we suggest caution in interpreting earnings data because, although they capture the impact of wages joint with employment, earnings are also a function of worker preferences as well.

Although there exists a body of literature on statistical discrimination, researchers have yet to examine environments where "statistical" discrimination may be exercised on multiple dimensions. Our contribution is that we study such an environment in a controlled laboratory setting. This research highlights, however, that multiple avenues for potential discrimination do not necessarily imply discrimination on multiple fronts. Indeed, evidence suggests that individuals may discriminate along one dimension but simultaneously reverse-discriminate along the other. This may be more likely with statistical discrimination than with taste-based discrimination, as Aeberhardt et al. (2010) find evidence for taste-based discrimination in both employment and wages, although there is insufficient research to make this claim.

A practical implication of this research is to say it would be incorrect to assume that sufficiently risk-averse employers will statistically discriminate across all dimensions. Rather, we suggest that employers may value the trade-off between wages and employment similar to how one balances risk and reward in other contexts. Our results also have important implications for our estimates of the extent of statistical discrimination, and highlight the likely bias that exists in such estimates when data analysis only examines one possible dimension for discrimination. We focus on non-prejudiced based discrimination, but this is likely an important message for all types of discrimination research.

doi: 10.1111/ecin. 12103

Online Early publication May 28, 2014

SUPPORTING INFORMATION

Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online version of this article:

Appendix S1. Experiment Instructions.

REFERENCES

Aeberhardt, R., D. Fougere, J. Pouget, and R. Rathelot. "Wages and Employment of French Workers with African Origin." Journal of Population Economics, 23, 2010, 881-905.

Aigner. D. J., and G. G. Cain. "Statistical Theories of Discrimination in Labor Markets." Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 30, 1977, 175-87.

Altonji, J. G., and C. R. Pierret. "Employer Learning and Statistical Discrimination." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 2001, 175-87.

Anderson, D. M., and M. J. Haupert. "Employment and Statistical Discrimination: A Hands-On Experiment." Journal of Economics, 25, 1999, 85-102.

Applebaum, A. I. "Racial Generalization, Police Discretion and Bayesian Contractualism, " in Handled with Discretion, edited by J. Kleinig. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, 1996.

Ayers, I., and P. Siegelman. "Race and Gender Discrimination in Bargaining for a New Car." The American Economic Review, 85, 1995, 304-21.

Becker, G. S. The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1957.

Castillo, M., and R. Petrie. "Discrimination in the Lab: Does Information Trump Appearance?" Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 2010, 50-59.

Castillo, M., R. Petrie, M. Torero, and L. Vesterlund. "Gender Differences in Bargaining Outcomes: A Field Experiment on Discrimination. " Journal of Public Economics, 99, 2013, 35-48.

Charles, K. K., and J. Guryan. "Prejudice and Wages: An Empirical Assessment of Becker's The Economics of Discrimination. " Journal of Political Economy, 116(5), 2008, 773-809.

Cornell, B., and I. Welch. "Culture, Information, and Screening Discrimination. " Journal of Political Economy, 104, 1996, 542-71.

Davis, D. D. "Maximal Quality Selection and Discrimination in Employment." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 8, 1987, 97-112.

Dickinson, D. L., and R. L. Oaxaca. "Statistical Discrimination in Labor Markets: An Experimental Analysis." Southern Economic Journal, 76(1), 2009, 16-31.

Fershtman, C., and U. Gneezy. "Discrimination in a Segmented Society: An Experimental Approach." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 2001, 351-77.

Gneezy, U., and J. A. List. "Are the Physically Disabled Discriminated Against in Product Markets?" Unpublished Paper, University of Chicago, 2006.

Goldberg, P. K. "Dealer Price Discrimination in New Car Purchases: Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey." Journal of Political Economy, 104, 1996, 622-34.

Groothuis. P. A., and J. R. Hill. "Pay Discrimination, Exit Discrimination or Both? Another Look at an Old Issue Using NBA Data." Journal of Sports Economics, 14, 2013, 171-85.

Hanna, R. N., and L. L. Linden. "Discrimination in Grading." American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(4), 2012, 146-68.

Harless, D. W., and G. E. Hoffer. "Do Women Pay More for New Vehicles? Evidence from Transaction Price Data." American Economic Review, 92, 2002, 270-79.

Heckman, J. J. "Detecting Discrimination." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(2), 1998, 101-16.

Ladd, H. F. "Evidence on Discrimination in Mortgage Lending." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(2), 1998, 41-62.

Lang. K. "A Language Theory of Discrimination." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 1986, 363-81.

Lazear, E. P. "Hiring Risky Workers, " in Internal Labour Markets, Incentives and Employment, edited by I. Ohashi and T. Tachibanaki. New York; London: St. Martin's Press; Macmillan Press, 1998, 143-58.

List, J. A. "The Nature and Extent of Discrimination in the Marketplace: Evidence from the Field." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 2004, 49-89.

Lundberg, S. J., and R. Startz. "Private Discrimination and Social Intervention in Competitive Labor Markets." American Economic Review, 73, 1983, 340-47.

Markowitz, H. "Portfolio Selection." Journal of Finance, 7(1), 1952, 77-91.

Masclet, D., E. Peterle, and S. Larribeau. "The Role of Information in Deterring Discrimination: A New Experimental Evidence of Statistical Discrimination." CREM Working Paper 2012-38, 2012.

Neumark, D. "Wage Differential by Race and Sex: The Roles of Taste Discrimination and Labor Market Information." Industrial Relations, 38, 1999, 414-15.

Phelps, E. S. "The Statistical Theory of Racism and Sexism." American Economic Review, 62, 1972, 659-61.

Rodin, M., and G. Ozcan. "Is It How You Look or Speak That Matters? An Experimental Study Exploring the Mechanisms of Ethnic Discrimination." SULCIS Working Paper 2011-3, 2011.

Smith, V. L. "Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science." American Economic Review, 72, 1982, 923-55.

(1.) Charles and Guryan (2008) conducted an empirical study with data on community-level prejudice from the 1972-2004 waves of the General Social Survey. They conclude that prejudice-based discrimination accounts for only one-quarter of the black-white wage gap. Other mechanisms suggested as the source of the remaining wage gap include statistical discrimination.

(2.) Another paper, Rodin and Ozcan (2011), finds evidence of discrimination in a laboratory experiment in Sweden. Subjects not perceived as stereotypically Swedish are rated as worse performers, which could be consistent with either taste-based or statistical discrimination. Providing information on performance outcomes does not explain or eliminate the negative beliefs regarding subjects with foreign-accented speech, which suggests taste-based discrimination.

(3.) Two exceptions we are aware of both focus on taste-based discrimination. Groothuis and Hill (2013) examine the effect that exit discrimination may have in biasing wage equations using professional basketball player data. They fail to find evidence of discrimination using 1990-2008 data, but note that residual methods of identifying discrimination are prone to pitfalls. Aeberhardt et al. (2010) find evidence for taste-based discrimination in at both the hiring stage as well as in wage data of French workers with African origins. Their study is based on a typical assumption that unexplained residual differences in the data imply discrimination.

(4.) Heckman (1998) notes that differential outcomes clearly need not imply discrimination, but it is also true that the absence of differentials need not imply the absence of discrimination. For example, estimates of labor market discrimination would be biased downwards if females or minority workers were discriminated against in hiring, and yet discrimination estimates were based solely on wage data. Those employers most averse to the statistical characteristics attached to certain workers do not hire those workers, and the remaining employers require a lesser wage discount to employ workers from the female or minority group. One might plausibly argue, however, that employers averse to minority or female workers (on statistical grounds) might choose to hire these workers if the market wage discount is large enough and employers view hiring choice and wage payments as substitutes. Thus, the direction of bias is not so clear.

(5.) In total, we examine three distinct measures of productivity risk that can be identified through our experimental treatments: productivity variance, the support of the productivity distribution, and the probability of worker productivity being less than the group average. Each of these ways to think of risk has a basis in the literature (see Dickinson and Oaxaca 2009).

(6.) Of course, we assume that all workers not employed were actually attempting to secure a wage contract, which is reasonable given that worker subjects were not allowed to simply disengage themselves completely from the pit negotiations. Of course, some subjects tried harder than others, but this is a feature of real world job search as well.

(7.) In addition to answering all subject questions prior to beginning the experiment rounds, any misunderstanding on the part of subjects regarding the differences in productivity distribution groups were quickly resolved due to the spirited and open nature of the double auction exchange environment coupled with real monetary incentives.

(8.) This measure of risk may be thought of as similar to studying loss aversion. If expected (average) profits are considered the reference point of the employer, then earnings less than mean earnings in a decision round would be a type of loss. Actual negative earnings were not possible, however. Also, though workers typically received wages well below the marginal revenue product generated to the employer, this maximum retail price was private employer information. Workers only knew that they would earn either their negotiated wage, or a reservation wage of $.80 if not employed.

(9.) In some instances employers may value productivity variance for the upside option value when low productivity workers can be terminated (see Lazear 1998). However, our environment does not allow for this given that each wage contract is a one-period contract independently drawn from the relevant productivity distribution.

(10.) For the wage determination models, we reject ordinary least squares in favor of random effects in all cases.

(11.) Our overall sample was 33% female, 40% minority, and 11% non-U.S. citizen. Regarding the subsample of worker subjects the values are 36% female, 38% minority, and 12% non-U.S. citizen.

(12.) We considered the possibility of estimating a traditional two-stage Heckit model as an alternative. However, it is difficult to find plausible exclusion restriction for the wage equations in our case. Moreover, the addition of the inverse mills ratio in the panel data setting would not yield consistent estimators. Although we did estimate a random effects probit model for employment, which yielded virtually identical results to our reported Tobit results, the addition of the wage information using the Tobit model produces a more efficient estimator for our employment probability parameters.

DAVID L. DICKINSON and RONALD L. OAXACA *

* The authors thank Tim Perri and Pete Groothuis, seminar participants at Appalachian State University, and participants at the 2013 WEAI Pacific Rim meetings in Tokyo for valuable comments on the paper.

Dickinson: Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC 28608. Phone 828-262-7652, Fax 828-262-6105, E-mail dickinsondl@appstate.edu

Oaxaca: Department of Economics, University of Arizona and IZA, Tucson, AZ 85721. Phone 520-621-4135, Fax 520-621-8450, E-mail rlo@email.arizone.edu
TABLE 1
Experiment Treatment Design

Worker      Productivity
Group (G)   (Probability)             Mean        Variance

G1          3 (1.00)                    3            0
G2          1,2,3,4,5                   3            1
              (,1,.1,.6,.1,.1)
G3          1,2,3,4,5                   3            2
              (.2,.2,.2,.2,.2)
G4          1,3,5 (.4,.2,.4)            3           3.2
G5          1,2,3,4,5                   3            1
              (.01,.39,
              .27,.25,.08)
G6          1,2,3,4                     3            1
              (.15,.05,.45,.35)

                                   Likelihood
                                       of
Worker         Distribution       Productivity
Group (G)         Support            < Mean

G1                   3                  0
G2               1,2,3,4.5             0.2

G3               1,2,3,4,5             0.4

G4                 1,3,5               0.4
G5               1,2,3.4,5             0.4

G6                1,2,3,4              0.2

TABLE 2 Pairings Used in Each Session
                                           Session Number
                      Treatment
                   Pairings (T) of     1   2   3   4   5
                   Worker Groups (G)

Risky choice       T1 = G2 and G5      X   X   X   X   X
options that       T2 = G2 and G6      X   X   X   X   X
identify unique    T3 = G3 and G4      X   X   X   X   X
risk factor

Certain versus     T4 = G1 and G2      X
risky choice       T5 = G1 and G3              X
employer           T6= G1 and G4                       X
options            T7= G1 and G5                   X
                   T8= G1 and G6           X
                   Total treatments    4   4   4   4   4

Note: The ordering of treatments was varied across sessions.

TABLE 3
Summary Wage and Employment Data
(Averaged across All Treatments and Sessions)

Worker      Wage   minWage   maxWage   Employment
Group (G)                                 Rate

G1          1.41     .79      10.00       .55
G2          1.08     .50      2.80        .46
G3          1.18     .75      2.50        .49
G4          1.07     .75      2.50        .52
G5          0.99     .50      3.00        .47
G6          0.99     .65      1.80        .56

TABLE 4
Group Wage Effects

                        Random
                     Effects (MLE)         Effects (MLE)
                      Wage Effect           Wage Effect
                      Coefficients          Coefficients
Variables          (Standard Errors)     (Standard Errors)

Constant           1.022 *** (0.212)     1.023 *** (0.208)
G2                   -0.086 (0.190)        -0.079 (0.187)
G3                 -0.699 *** (0.219)    -0.788 *** (0.220)
G4                 -0.929 *** (0.220)    -1.020 *** (0.220)
G5                   -0.084 (0.211)        -0.101 (0.205)
G6                   -0.186 (0.209)        -0.143 (0.198)
T2                   0.091 (0.129)         0.058 (0.130)
T3                 0.775 *** (0.297)     0.878 *** (0.296)
T4                  -0.003 (-0.199)         0.010(0.199)
T5                  0.688 ** (0.279)     0.708 *** (0.272)
T6                 1.452 *** (0.279)     1.548 *** (0.276)
11                   -0.177 (0.212)        -0.151 (0.216)
T8                   -0.069 (0.212)        0.051 (0.213)
C_ff               0.527 *** (0.164)     0.388 *** (0.135)
C_mf                0.269 ** (0.109)     0.267 *** (0.083)
C_fm                 0.138 (0.126)         0.178 (0.114)
Female                     --                    --
Minority                   --                    --
Noncitizen                 --                    --
Log Likelihood          -395.975              -398.730
N                         400                   400

                     Effects (MLE)
                      Wage Effect
                      Coefficients
Variables          (Standard Errors)

Constant            0.561 * (0.325)
G2                  -0.486 * (0.283)
G3                   -0.333 (0.337)
G4                   -0.336(0.335)
G5                  -0.514 * (0.312)
G6                   -0.149 (0.308)
T2                   -0.165 (0.191)
T3                   -0.135 (0.450)
T4                   -0.256 (0.297)
T5                   -0.096 (0.417)
T6                   0.287 (0.405)
11                   -0.323 (0.300)
T8                   -0.456 (0.315)
C_ff                       --
C_mf                       --
C_fm                       --
Female               0.166 (0.148)
Minority            -0.268 * (0.156)
Noncitizen           0.027 (0.234)
Log Likelihood          -936.843
N                         800

Note: Round dummies-suppressed for space-were
all statistically insignificant.

*, **, *** indicate significance at the .10, .05, and .01 levels,
respectively, for the two-tailed test.

TABLE 5
Employment Models Risk Effect Identification
(Binary Groups Comparisons)

                            Contract
                            Pair Random
             Groups         Effects

                            (MLE) Wage
Risk         [G.sub.x]-     Effect
Measure      [G.sub.y]      Coefficients

Variance/    G4-G3          -0.230 ** (0.126)
  Support
Variance/    G4-G5          -0.846 *** (0.301)
  Support
Variance     G3-G5          -0616 ** (0.309)
Support      G2-G6          0.100 (0.125)
Prod < avg   G5-G2          0.002 (0.124)
Log-L                       -395.975
N                           400
                  Employer
                   Random
                  Effects

                 (MLE) Wage       (MLE) Wage
Risk               Effect         Effect
Measure         Coefficients      Coefficients

Variance/    -0.232 ** (0.126)    -0.003 (0.194)
  Support
Variance/    -0.919 *** (0.301)   0.179 (0.450)
  Support
Variance     -0.684 ** (0.301)    0.181 (0.465)
Support      0.065 (0.127)        -0.337 * (0.189)
Prod < avg   -0.022 (0.126)       -0.037 (0.187)
Log-L        -398.730             -936.843
N            400                  800

                      Worker Random Effects Tobit

                                      Risk Effect on
                                  Employment Probability
                                    (Marginal Effects)
                                  [psi] ([x.sup.'][beta]/
                                  [[sigma]).sub.Gx=1] -
Risk          Wage Effect | X     [psi] ([x.sup.'][beta]/
Measure          (At Sample        [[sigma]).sub.[Gy=1]]
                   Means)            (At Sample Means)

Variance/    -0.001 (0.014)       -0.001 (0.009)
  Support
Variance/    0.087 *** (0.033)    0.058 *** (0.022)
  Support
Variance     0.088 *** (0.035)    0.059 *** (0.023)
Support      -0.176 *** (0.033)   -0.109 *** (0.016)
Prod < avg   -0.013 (0.021)       -0.009 (0.016)
Log-L        --                   --
N            800                  800

*, **, *** indicate significance at the .10, .05,
and .01 levels, respectively, for the two-tailed test.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有