Financial restraints and private investment: evidence from a nonstationary panel.
Costantini, Mauro ; Demetriades, Panicos O. ; James, Gregory A. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
In the early 1970s, McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) put forward the
idea that financial repression--that is, government-imposed controls on
lending and deposit rates, capital controls, and directed credit--had a
negative impact on investment and growth by suppressing domestic saving
and distorting the allocation of credit. Although their views were
vigorously challenged by a range of critics, (1) their main policy
recommendation for financial liberalization gained momentum among policy
makers in both developing and developed countries. As a result, the last
40 years have witnessed a gradual removal of financial restraints
worldwide with increased movement of capital around the globe. (2)
Both these developments are likely to influence the behavior of
private investment. Increased international capital flows are likely to
result in a relaxation of borrowing constraints for many firms, leading
to credit expansion. (3) Under fully liberalized conditions the price of
credit for many, if not all, firms will rise, making their investment
plans more sensitive to the price of credit and no longer sensitive to
the availability of credit. Under partial liberalization or continued
financial repression, however, some firms may continue to have access to
subsidized credit while others may have access to more expensive
international loans. Does the retention of financial restraints under
these circumstances deter or promote investment? In other words, once a
country moves away from complete financial repression--where the only
source of credit for private investment is the domestic banking
system--can the provision of cheaper, albeit rationed, domestic credit
help stimulate private investment? This is the question we address in
this article. To do so, we employ a theoretical model of investment
which assumes that firms have access to quantity-constrained domestic
loans that are cheaper than those they can obtain from international
capital markets. (4) This accommodates the idea that increased
international capital flows might have relaxed borrowing constraints for
many firms while, at the same time, some firms may have continued to
benefit from access to cheaper policy loans. We operationalize the model
in a multicountry setting and derive five variants of a private
investment equation including a baseline neoclassical model without
financial restraints. To estimate the investment equations, we employ
recently developed nonstationary panel methodologies that allow for
cross-sectional dependence across countries. The presence of dependence
across countries is a plausible hypothesis in a world characterized by
growing real and financial interlinkages, which we test by appropriate
econometric procedures.
Our sample includes 20 developing countries over the period
1972-2000. The econometric analysis consists of three steps. First, unit
root tests for cross-sectionally dependent panels are applied. Second,
the existence of a cointegrating relationship among the variables is
investigated, fully allowing for cross-section dependence. Third, the
fully modified ordinary least squares (FMOLS) estimator developed by Bai
and Kao (2006) is used to estimate the investment equations. We contrast
our results with those obtained using the pooled FMOLS estimator of
Pedroni (2000), which assumes cross-sectional independence.
Our findings confirm the importance of taking into account
cross-country dependence. We find that when we allow for cross-sectional
dependence, investment displays more sensitivity to world capital market
conditions and exchange rate uncertainty. Perhaps more surprisingly, we
find that "repressing" domestic real interest rates resulted
in higher levels of private investment than those that would have been
obtained under more "liberalized" conditions. This finding,
which contrasts sharply with the McKinnon-Shaw prediction, complements a
growing literature on the possible negative effects of financial
liberalization on the channels of economic growth. Stiglitz (1994)
provides a unifying theoretical rationale for such effects, drawing on
information asymmetries in financial markets which provide scope for
meaningful government interventions. Singh (1997), drawing on Keynes
(1936) and a large body of empirical evidence, emphasizes the negative
effects that emanate from stock market volatility. Demetriades and
Luintel (2001) provide evidence of positive effects of financial
restraints on South Korea's financial development, reflecting lack
of competition in the banking system. More recently, Andrianova,
Demetriades, and Shortland (2008, 2010) provide evidence suggesting that
bank privatization--one of the main pillars of financial
liberalization--has been negatively associated with both financial
development and growth, reflecting poor regulation. Last but not least,
recent work by Ang (2011) suggests that financial liberalization had a
negative effect on technological deepening by distorting the allocation
of human capital.
The article is organized as follows. Section II describes the
modeling framework. Section III discusses econometric methodology and
empirical results. Section IV summarizes and concludes.
II. THE MODELING FRAMEWORK
A. Theoretical Underpinnings
The dynamic investment equations estimated in this article are
based on the theoretical model put forward by Demetriades and Devereux
(2000), henceforth D&D. D&D use a microeconomic model of a
representative firm's investment decision under financial
restraints as their starting point. The model suggests a structural
relationship between the optimal capital stock and the
"modified" cost of capital, which is then used to derive a
long-run theory-consistent aggregate investment equation that takes into
account the presence of financial restraints. The rest of this section
provides a brief outline of the D&D approach.
The main assumption of D&D is that the official banking system
is unable to satisfy the entire demand for investible funds because of
the presence of an interest rate ceiling, which restricts the supply of
funds h la McKinnon-Shaw (see also Fry 1994). The model departs from the
McKinnon-Shaw tradition, however, in that it assumes the existence of an
"alternative" financial market in which firms can borrow
freely, albeit at an interest rate that is higher than the official
lending rate. Their interpretation of the alternative market is that it
is the world capital market although it could also be interpreted as the
unofficial credit market, or "curb," market (see Taylor 1983
and Van Wijnebergen 1983). There are theoretical and empirical reasons
for us preferring the first interpretation to the second, not least the
stylized facts relating to the increased international capital flows
alluded to in the introduction. Thus, we assume that firms have access
to two types of borrowing: domestic bank borrowing and international
loans. Rationing of domestic loans to different firms is assumed to
depend on the availability of collateral, which is related to the
firm's capital stock.
The representative firm is assumed to maximize the wealth of its
shareholders given by the present discounted value of dividends
([D.sub.t]). The nominal discount rate used in determining the present
value is the one which is obtained in the world capital market, denoted
as [i.sup.*.sub.t], because this is the rate at which shareholders are
assumed to be able to borrow or lend as much as they wish. (5) Note that
the firm takes both the domestic lending rate it and the world interest
rate [i.sup.*.sub.t] as determined exogenously in the appropriate
market. Moreover, the firm is assumed to be able to raise finance only
through borrowing or retained earnings.
Formally, the optimization problem can be stated as:
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [[beta].sub.s] = [[PI].sup.s.sub.l=t+1][(1 +
[i.sup.*.sub.l-1]).sup.-1], subject to the following constraints:
(2) [D.sub.t] = [q.sub.t][Y.sub.t] - [p.sub.t][I.sub.t] + [B.sub.t]
- (l + [i.sub.t])[B.sub.t-1] + [A.sub.t] - (1 +
[i.sup.*.sub.t])[A.sub.t-1],
(3) [K.sub.t] = (1 - [delta])[K.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t],
(4) [B.sub.t] [less than or equal to] [x.sub.t][p.sub.t][K.sub.t],
where [E.sub.t]{.} is the expectations operator, [q.sub.t][Y.sub.t]
represents current revenue, [q.sub.t] is the price of output in period t
and [Y.sub.t] is output, and the latter is a function of the capital
stock at the beginning of the period, [Y.sub.t] = f([K.sub.t-1]). (6)
The value of current investment is represented by [p.sub.t][I.sub.t],
where [p.sub.t] is the current price of capital goods and [I.sub.t] is
the quantity of investment made during period t. New issues of one
period debt from the domestic and international market are denoted as
[B.sub.t] - [B.sub.t-1] and [i.sup.*.sub.t] - [A.sub.t-1], respectively,
whereas [i.sub.t] [B.sub.t-1] and [i.sup.*.sub.t] [A.sub.t-1] are
nominal interest payments to the domestic and international capital
market, respectively. (7) The exponential rate of depreciation of
capital is assumed constant at [delta].
The first two constraints are standard in models of firm
investment. The first constraint is the flow of funds identity for the
firm and the second constraint is the equation of motion of the capital
stock. The third constraint is specific to D&D; it constrains the
supply of domestic bank loans in the domestic market to be a proportion,
[x.sub.t], of the value of the firm's capital stock. The capital
stock, therefore, represents collateral; banks are willing to lend more
to large firms than to small firms. (8) Taking first-order conditions
together yields
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
This states that, in equilibrium, the expected marginal revenue product of capital is equal to a modified cost of capital. The modified
cost of capital consists of: the financial cost at the rate in the
international market [i.sup.*.sub.t] [p.sub.t]; plus the cost of the
fall in the value of the asset [delta][E.sub.t][P.sub.t+1]; minus the
expected capital gain term, [E.sub.t][p.sub.t+1] - [p.sub.t]; plus the
final term which reflects the reduction in the standard cost of capital
relative to the international capital market. This final term shows the
cheaper source of finance which is available at rate it but acknowledges
that only a proportion [x.sub.t] can be financed in this way.
Equation (5) holds for every firm in the economy in the
steady-state. D&D show that the same relationship will be observed
in the economy as a whole providing that certain aggregation conditions
are satisfied and that firm-specific shocks to the proportion of a
firm's capital stock financed out of bank loans cancel out across
firms. The steady-state relationship can be embedded in a dynamic model
that explains aggregate behavior by assuming that investment is driven
by the difference between the actual marginal product of capital and its
equilibrium level based on (5). Additional dynamics would be generated
by time lags in decision-making, ordering, delivery, installation of new
capital, and so on. The dynamic investment equation corresponding to (5)
is then given by
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The term [Y.sub.t]/[K.sub.t-1] is interpreted as a proxy for the
marginal product of capital and the modified cost of capital is split
into two components: the real interest rate in the world capital market
and the term capturing financial restraints.
As we expect investment to depend on the difference between the
marginal product and the modified cost of capital, the theoretical model
predicts that [b.sub.2] should be positive and [b.sub.3] should be
negative. The fourth term is present only under financial restraints. A
positive [b.sub.4] would provide support for the hypothesis that the
existence of an alternative market for credit outweighs the credit
rationing effect described by McKinnon-Shaw. In such a case, increasing
the level of the interest rate ceiling in the domestic market would
serve to increase the overall cost of capital (which corresponds to
Figure 1 in D&D). On the other hand, a negative [b.sub.4] would
suggest that the existence of the alternative market is not sufficient
to outweigh the McKinnon Shaw effect, that is, higher domestic interest
will have a positive effect on investment on balance. In this case, the
supply of domestic financial savings is elastic with respect to the
domestic interest rate so that an increase in the domestic interest rate
has a relatively large effect on the domestic supply of investable funds
(this corresponds to Figure 2 in D&D).
B. Operationalizing the Model in a Multicountry Analysis
There are three variables in Equation (6) that are not directly
observed and require modeling assumptions to be made to operationalize
the model in a multicountry empirical analysis: the capital stock, the
world capital market interest rate, and the financial restraints dummy.
The construction of the first is based on the perpetual inventory method
given by expression (3). (9) The interest rate [i.sup.*] used here is
the U.S. lending rate. Given the sample of countries we are using, we
believe that the U.S. rate is the most appropriate rate to approximate
the cost of loans from the world market. The expected inflation series
are in turn proxied by the current inflation rate prevailing in each
country. The financial restraints dummy is based on the nominal interest
rate differential [i.sup.*] - i. In the theoretical model, the supply of
bank loans becomes rationed only if [i.sup.*] exceeds i. This suggests
that an observation could be considered as being under conditions of
"financial restraints" if [i.sup.*] - i > 0. Five variants
of Equation (6) are estimated to allow some flexibility in the way that
financial restraints are defined and to capture the possible effects of
exchange rate risk. (10)
The first model is a "Neo-Classical" investment
equation--denoted as NC--which corresponds to a world without financial
restraints ([b.sub.j4] = 0):
(7a) [I.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt-1] = [b.sub.j0] +
[b.sub.j1]([I.sub.jt-1]/[K.sub.jt-2]) +
[b.sub.j2]([Y.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt-1) + [b.sub.j3][r.sup.*.sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.jt],
where the subscript j refers to country j and the error term is
IID(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.j]) across time but may be correlated across
countries as a result of common real or financial shocks.
The second model--denoted as [FR.sup.A]--tests the financial
restraints hypothesis assuming that all the countries always operate
under conditions of financial restraints:
(7b) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The third model--denoted as [FR.sup.D]--also accommodates the
possible effect of financial restraint but the financial restraints term
is now interacted with [D.sub.jt], a dummy variable that equals 1 when
an observation is considered as being under condition of financial
restraints (as defined above) and 0 otherwise:
(7c) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The fourth model--denoted as [FR.sup.A] (unrestricted)
"unbundles" the financial restraints term into its two
components, the real interest rate differential and the inflation rate
differential:
(7d) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The fifth model--denoted as FR-ER--introduces a measure of exchange
rate uncertainty to capture the risk associated with international
borrowing by domestic firms, which may have a negative effect on
investment:
(7e) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [SDEX.sub.jt] is the 3-year moving average of the standard
deviation of the domestic exchange rate vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar.
III. ECONOMETRIC METHODOLOGY AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The empirical analysis consists of three steps. In the first step,
we test for nonstationarity in the data using the testing procedures
developed by Bai and Ng (2004), labelled by them as panel analysis of
non-stationarity in idiosyncratic and common components (PANIC). The
basic idea consists of modeling the panel series as the sum of a set of
common factors and idiosyncratic components. Both the factors and the
idiosyncratic components can be I(l) or stationary, so that dependence
can be modeled not only through the disturbance terms but also through
the common factors. Bai and Ng propose to test the factors and the
idiosyncratic components separately. This feature makes it possible to
ascertain if nonstationarity comes from a pervasive or an idiosyncratic
source. (11) In the second step, we investigate the existence of a
cointegrating relationship for all the models. To this end, the panel
procedure recently developed by Gengenbach, Palm, and Urbain (2006) is
applied.
1. A preliminary PANIC analysis on each variable [X.sub.i,t] and
[Y.sub.i,t] to extract common factors is conducted. Tests for unit roots
are performed on both the common factors and the idiosyncratic
components using the Bai and Ng (2004) procedure.
2. (a) If I(1) common factors and I(0) idiosyncratic components are
detected, then a situation of cross-member cointegration is found and
consequently the nonstationarity in the panel is entirely because of a
reduced number of common stochastic trends. Cointegration between
[Y.sub.i,t] and [X.sub.i,t] can only occur if the common factors for
[Y.sub.i,t] cointegrate with those of [X.sub.i,t]. The null of no
cointegration between the estimated factors can be tested using the
Johansen (1988) trace test as suggested by Gengenbach, Palm, and Urbain
(2006).
2. (b) If I(1) common factors and I(1) idiosyncratic components are
detected, then defactored series are used. In particular, [Y.sub.i,t]
and [X.sub.i,t] are defactored separately. Testing for no cointegration
between the defactored data can be conducted using standard panel tests
for no cointegration such as those of Pedroni (1999, 2004).
Cointegration between [Y.sub.i,t] and [X.sub.i,t] is found only when the
tests for both the common factors and the idiosyncratic components
reject the null of no cointegration. (12)
In the third step, we estimate the long-run relationship among the
variables of interest in the five models under consideration using the
continuous-update fully modified (CUP-FM) estimator developed by Bai and
Kao (2006). These authors discuss the limiting distributions of various
panel OLS and FM estimators and argue for the use of CUP-FM estimators.
(13)
Our panel data set contains 20 countries over the period 1972-2000.
The countries were chosen because of data availability. A detailed
description of the countries involved, measurement of variables, and
data sources is given in the Appendix. To support the cross-sectional
dependence hypothesis, the cross-section dependence (CD) test developed
by Pesaran (2004) is applied to our data. The test proposed is:
(8) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
denote the sample estimate of the pair-wise correlation of the
residuals [e.sub.it] from the regression of any variable of interest on
an intercept, a linear trend and a lagged dependent variable for each
country i. CD test results are reported in Table 1. Clear evidence of
cross-sectional dependence is found because the null hypothesis of no
cross-correlation is strongly rejected.
Table 2 reports the results of the Bai and Ng (2004), Pesaran
(2007), and Moon and Perron (2004) panel unit root tests. The
cross-sectionally augmented Im-Pesaran-Shin (CIPS) test of Pesaran
(2007) and the [t.sup.*.sub.a] and [t.sup.*.sub.b] of Moon and Perron
(2004) are included in the analysis because they have greater power than
the Bai and Ng test in small samples. (14) In applying the Bai and Ng
procedure to test for unit roots, we consider the common factors and the
idiosyncratic components separately. The number of common factors is
determined using the IC2 criterion developed by Bai and Ng (2002), and
one common factor is selected. (15) Where there is only one common
factor, Bai and Ng (2004) suggest using a standard Augmented
Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test to test stationarity (16):
(9) [DELTA][[??].sub.t] = c + [[delta].sub.0] [[??].sub.t-1] +
[[delta].sub.1] [DELTA][F.sub.t-1] + ... + [[delta].sub.p]
[[??].sub.t-p] + [v.sub.t]
where [F.sub.t] indicates an r x 1 vector of common factors. The
ADF tests results for the extracted common factor provide evidence of a
unit root in all the variables. To test the stationarity of the
idiosyncratic component, Bai and Ng (2004) propose pooling individual
ADF t-statistics with de-factored estimated components [e.sub.it] in the
model with no deterministic trend
(10) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The pooled tests are based on Fisher-type statistics defined as in
Maddala and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001). Let [P.sup.c.sub.[??]](i) be the
p value of the ADF t-statistics for the i-th cross-section unit,
[ADF.sup.c.sub.[??]](i), then the standardized Choi-type statistics is:
(11) [Z.sup.c.sub.[??]] = [-2 [n.summation over (i=1)] log
[P.sup.c.sub.[??]](i) - 2N] / [square root of (4N)].
The previous statistic converges for (N, T [right arrow]
[infinity]) to a standard normal distribution. In our analysis, we use
the Fisher-type statistic defined as in Choi (2001). The pooled p value
inverse normal tests do not reject the null hypothesis of a unit root
for all the variables, providing strong evidence of nonstationarity.
Similarly, the results obtained with the tests developed by Pesaran
(2007) and Moon and Perron (2004), which are more powerful in small
samples, show that the null hypothesis of a unit root cannot be rejected
for all the variables.
As the panel no cointegration hypothesis can be rejected only if
the tests for both the common factors and the idiosyncratic components
reject the null of no cointegration (see Gengenbach, Palm, and Urbain
2006, 698-99), we apply the panel cointegration tests proposed by
Pedroni (1999, 2004) to the defactored data and the Johansen (1988)
trace test to the common factor components. The results are reported in
Table 3. For the panel tests, we use two statistics proposed by Pedroni
(1999, 2004). The first statistic is a panel version of a nonparametric
statistic that is analogous to the familiar Phillips and Perron
[rho]-statistic, [Z.sub.[rho]]. The second is a parametric statistic,
which is analogous to the familiar ADF t-statistic, [Z.sub.t]. These
tests assume the null hypothesis of no cointegration against the
alternative that all units (countries) share a common cointegrating
vector. The results of these tests provide evidence of a common
cointegrating vector for the whole panel. With regard to the common
factor components, a cointegrating relationship is found with the
Johansen (1998) trace test in all the models.
Having found evidence of cointegration in each of the models, we
first estimate these models using the FMOLS estimator proposed by
Pedroni (2004) under the assumption of cross-sectional independence.
Table 4 reports the estimation results. The term proxying the marginal
product of capital ([b.sub.2]) is always positive and strongly
significant, as predicted by the theory. The coefficient of the world
interest rate ([b.sub.3]) is negative and significant in all the models,
which is consistent with the interpretation that the world interest rate
captures an important component of the cost of capital, irrespective of the extent to which the models incorporate financial restraints. The
coefficients on the various financial restraints terms where they appear
are positive but rarely significant. In Model [FR.sup.A], which contains
the unbundled financial restraints term that is not interacted with the
dummy variable, [b.sub.4] is positive and highly insignificant. In Model
[FR.sup.D], where the unbundled term is interacted with the dummy aimed
at capturing the presence of financial restraints, [[??].sub.4] is again
positive and of a similar magnitude as in Model [FR.sup.A] and remains
highly insignificant. In Model [FR.sup.A] (unrestricted), which
unbundles the financial restraints term, the real interest rate
component [[??].sub.4], which captures the real interest rate
differential is positive and insignificant. Interestingly, the inflation
rate component [b.sub.5] is positive and significant at the 5% level.
Its sign suggests that a low domestic inflation rate relative to the
world inflation rate has a positive effect on domestic investment (this
effect varies with the volume of domestic lending relative to the
capital stock). Conversely, when domestic inflation exceeds world
inflation, domestic investment decreases (this effect also varies with
the volume of loans relative to the capital stock). This is broadly in
line with the traditional McKinnon-Shaw effect which suggests that high
inflation has a negative effect on investment because it depresses the
supply of investable funds. However, the mechanism here is a different
one. The inflation component of the financial restraints term captures
the part of the low-nominal interest rate that is because of low
inflation. If domestic inflation is lower than world inflation, domestic
nominal interest rates are low relative to the world capital market and
this reduces the cost of capital associated with domestic loans. Model
FR-ER, which includes the two exchange rate uncertainty variables,
suggests that both terms capturing exchange rate uncertainty are
negative as expected, although only one of the two--[[??].sub.5]--is
significant at the 5% level while the other one--[b.sub.6]--is
insignificant. Thus, there is some evidence that exchange rate
uncertainty depresses domestic investment.
However, one may argue that the assumption of cross-sectional
independence is unrealistic in a world characterized by growing real and
financial interlinkages. To check for cross-sectional dependence in the
estimates, we compute the long-run cross-sectional correlation matrix of
the residuals obtained for each model. (17) The results show that the
correlations for model NC lie between 0.25 and 0.89, with an overall
average of 0.47, for model [FR.sup.A] between 0.23 and 0.90, with an
overall average of 0.46, for model [FR.sup.D] between 0.23 and 0.88,
with an overall average of 0.48, for model [FR.sup.A] (unrestricted)
between 0.24 and 0.89, with an overall average of 0.53, and for model
FR-ER between 0.24 and 0.88, with an overall average of 0.51. Overall,
these results clearly show that the cross-sectional independence
assumption is violated for all the models. As evidence of
cross-sectional dependence is found, we use the CUPFM estimator of Bai
and Kao (2006), which allows for cross-sectional dependence through
common factors. Table 5 reports the estimation results. Allowing for
cross-country effects impacts on both the magnitude and significance of
various coefficients and alters the economic interpretation of some of
the results. The term proxying the marginal product of capital
([b.sub.2]) is once again always positive and strongly significant, but
its coefficient is much larger compared to the estimates obtained
assuming cross-sectional independence. The coefficient of the world
interest rate ([b.sub.3]) remains negative and significant in all the
models, but once again the estimated coefficients are much
larger--hovering around -0.25 compared to -0.08 in Table 4--suggesting
that domestic investment appears to be much more responsive to world
capital markets if one allows for cross-country effects. Remarkably, all
the financial restraints terms remain positive but are now statistically
significant at the 5% level, which now suggests that financial
restraints do play an important role in determining investment. In Model
[FR.sup.A], the unbundled financial restraints term--[b.sub.4]--is
positive and significant with a coefficient that has more or less the
same size as the one on the world interest rate. The positive
coefficient suggests that depressing the domestic interest rate through
financial restraints results in additional domestic investment, in
contrast to the McKinnon-Shaw prediction. In Model [FR.sup.D], which
interacts the financial restraints term with the financial restraints
dummy, the coefficient on financial restraints ([[??].sub.4]) is more
than twice the size of the world interest rate coefficient. This
suggests that countries in which financial restraints were present are,
in fact, the ones that may have benefited from low domestic interest
rates. Model [FR.sup.D] (unrestricted), which unbundles the interest
rate differential into its two components does, however, provide some
comfort to supporters of the McKinonn-Shaw hypothesis in that it
continues to show, as in Table 4, the positive effects of low inflation
on investment. Nevertheless, the effect of the real interest rate
differential is now positive and significant at the 5% level, suggesting
that depressing the real interest rate to below world levels has a
positive effect on domestic investment. The positive effect of low
inflation--or negative effect of high inflation--suggests that to some
extent McKinnon and Shaw are fight to emphasize the damage caused by
high inflation. However, in our case this is not so much because of the
reduced supply of funds but rather because of the higher cost of
capital, because high inflation--in the absence of interest rate
ceilings that were common before our sample period and were emphasized
by McKinnon and Shaw--normally results in higher nominal interest rates.
On balance, as is shown in Model [FR.sup.D], the aggregate effect of
financial restraints on domestic investment is positive, although the
effect of the inflation rate seems to be broadly along the lines
suggested by McKinnon-Shaw.
The results also suggest that exchange rate uncertainty is an even
more important determinant of investment if one takes into account
cross-country effects. Both terms capturing exchange rate uncertainty
([[??].sub.5] and [b.sub.6]) are now significant at the 5% level and
their coefficients are more than twice the absolute size compared to
those reported in Table 4.
IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
This article employs recently developed panel data methods to
estimate a model of private investment under financial restraints for 20
developing countries using annual data for 1972-2000. Unit root tests
for cross-sectionally dependent panels show that the variables are
nonstationary. The application of panel cointegration methods reveals a
long-run relationship among the variables. The nature of this
relationship varies depending on whether we take into account
cross-country effects. When we allow for cross-sectional dependence,
investment displays more sensitivity to world capital market conditions
and exchange rate uncertainty. A perhaps even more surprising result is
the finding that financial restraints appear to have had a positive
overall effect on domestic investment, in contrast to the McKinnon--Shaw
prediction. On the other hand, our findings relating to the impact of
inflation on investment accord well with the McKinnon--Shaw
hypothesis--regardless of whether allowance is made for cross-sectional
dependence. An applied econometrician who does not allow for
cross-sectional dependence when estimating investment equations across a
panel of countries may therefore find more support for the McKinnon-Shaw
hypothesis than is warranted by the data.
Therefore, our findings show the importance of cross-country
effects in estimating investment models. In addition, they suggest that
countries that managed to suppress domestic real interest rates without
generating high inflation enjoyed higher levels of private investment
than those that would have been obtained under liberalized conditions.
There is, of course, a limit to the extent that real interest rates can
be depressed by applying nominal interest rate ceilings without
resorting to inflationary policies, When low real interest rates are the
result of high inflation, private investment it seems does not appear to
increase. Thus, while mild financial repression can stimulate private
investment, severe repression through high inflation may well have the
opposite effect.
Our findings highlight two new avenues for further research. First,
they suggest that cross-country studies of private investment and
possibly other macroeconomic aggregates need to take into account
cross-country effects. Second, they suggest that it may be fruitful to
reexamine the effects of financial repression on other key macroeconomic
aggregates using the kind of techniques we have used in this article.
ABBREVIATIONS
ADF: Augmented Dickey Fuller
AIC: Akaike Information Criterion
BIC: Bayesian Information Criterion
CD: Cross-Section Dependence
CIPS: Cross-Sectionally Augmented Im-Pesaran-Shin
CUP-FM: Continuous-Update Fully Modified
D&D: Demetriades and Devereux (2000)
FMOLS: Fully Modified Ordinary Least Squares
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
PANIC: Panel Analysis of Non-stationarity in Idiosyncratic and
Common Components
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2011.00424.x
APPENDIX A: DESCRIPTION AND SOURCES OF DATA
I is private fixed capital formation; K is private capital stock; Y
is real gross domestic product (GDP); [r.sup.*] is U.S. real lending
rate; [i.sup.*] is U.S. nominal lending rate; r is domestic real lending
rate; i is domestic nominal lending rate; B is claims on private sector
by deposit money banks and other financial institutions; [[pi].sup.*] is
the U.S. inflation rate (computed using the GDP deflator); [pi] is the
domestic inflation rate (computed using the GDP deflator); SDEX is the
3-year moving average of the standard deviation of the domestic exchange
rate vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar. The data is from the World Bank
Development Indicators (2008). Data on private investment is from
Everhart and Sumlinski (2001).
APPENDIX B: LIST OF COUNTRIES
The panel comprises Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, Costa Rica, Cote
d'Ivoire, Dominican Republic, Egypt, El Salvador, Guatemala, India,
Kenya, Malawi, Mexico, Morocco, Paraguay, Philippines, Thailand,
Trinidad and Tobago, Uruguay, and Venezuela.
APPENDIX C: MONTE CARLO SIMULATION RESULTS
TABLE A1
Size and Size-Adjusted Power Comparisons of Panel Unit Root Tests
N = 20 Size
T = 30 CIPS [t.sup.*.sub.a] [t.sup.*.sub.b]
0.047 0.051 0.039
N = 20 Size
T = 30 [MATHEMATICAL [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII] IN ASCII]
0.038 0.045
N = 20 Power
T = 30 CIPS [t.sup.*.sub.a] [t.sup.*.sub.b]
0.520 0.922 0.789
N = 20 Power
T = 30 [MATHEMATICAL [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII] IN ASCII]
0.130 0.270
Notes: The following DGP was considered: [y.sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.i0]
+ [z.sup.0.sub.it], [z.sub.it] = [[rho].sub.i][z.sup.0.sub.it-1] +
[tau] [[summation].sup.K.sub.i=1] [[beta].sub.ij][f.sub.it] with
([f.sub.it], [[epsilon].sub.it], [[alpha].sub.it]) -i.i.dN(0,
[I.sub.3]), [tau] = 1, where the common factors and the idiosyncratic
components are assumed to be of the same importance (see Gutierrez
2006), [[beta].sub.ij] -U[-1,4], K = 1, [[rho].sub.i] = 1, and
[[rho].sub.i] -[0.9, 1] for the size and the size-adjusted power. The
results were obtained using 1000 replications.
REFERENCES
Abiad, A., and A. Mody. "Financial Reform: What Shakes It?
What Shapes It?" American Economic Review, 95, 2005, 66-88.
Andrianova, S., P. O. Demetriades, and A. Shortland.
"Government Ownership of Banks, Institutions and Financial
Development." Journal of Development Economics, 85, 2008, 218-52.
--. "Government Ownership of Banks, Institutions and Economic
Growth." Economics Discussion Paper 11/01, University of Leicester,
2010.
Ang, J. "Financial Development, Liberalization and
Technological Deepening." European Economic Review, 55, 2011,
688-701.
Arestis, P., and P. O. Demetriades. "Financial Development and
Economic Growth: Assessing the Evidence." Economic Journal, 107,
1997, 783-99.
Bai, J., and S. Ng. "Determining the Number of Factors in
Approximate Factor Models." Econometrica, 70, 2002, 191-221.
--. "A PANIC Attack on Unit Roots and Cointegration."
Econometrica, 72, 2004, 1127-77.
Bai, J., and C. Kao. "On the Estimation and Inference of a
Panel Cointegration Model with Cross-Sectional Dependence," in
Panel Data Econometrics: Theoretical Contributions and Empirical
Applications, edited by B. H. Baltagi. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science,
2006.
Chang, Y., J. Y. Park, and K. Song. "Bootstrapping Cointegrating Regressions." Journal of Econometrics, 133, 2006,
703-39.
Choi, I. "Unit Root Tests for Panel Data." Journal of
International Money and Finance, 20, 2001, 249-72.
Demetriades, P. O., and M. P. Devereux. "Investment and
Financial Restraints: Theory and Evidence." International Journal
of Finance and Economics, 5, 2000, 285-96.
Demetriades, P. O., and K. B. Luintel. "'Financial
Restraints in the South Korean Miracle." Journal of Development
Economics, 64, 2001, 459-79.
Diaz-Alejandro, C. "Goodbye Financial Repression, Hello
Financial Crash." Journal of Development Economics, 19, 1985, 1-24.
Everhart, S. S., and M. A. Sumlinski. "Trends in Private
Investment in Developing Countries, Statistics for 1970-2000 and the
Impact on Private Investment of Corruption and the Quality of Public
Investment." Discussion Paper No. 44, International Finance
Corporation, 2001.
Fachin, S. "Bootstrap Inference on Fully Modified Estimates of
Cointegrating Coefficients: A Comment." Economics Bulletin, 3,
2004, 1-8.
Fry, M. J. Money, Interest, and Banking in Economic Development.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994.
Gengenbach, C., F. C. Palm, and J. P. Urbain. "Cointegration
Testing in Panels with Common Factors." Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 68, 2006, 683-719.
Gutierrez, L. "Panel Unit-root Tests for Cross-sectionally
Correlated Panels: A Monte Carlo Comparison." Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 68, 2006, 519-40.
Hellman, T. F., K. C. Murdock, and J. E. Stiglitz.
"Liberalisation, Moral Hazard in Banking, and Prudential
Regulation: Are Capital Requirements Enough?" American Economic
Review, 90, 2000, 147-65.
Johansen, S. "Statistical Analysis of Cointegration
Vectors." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12, 1988,
231-54.
Keynes, J. M. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.
New York: Harcourt Brace, 1936.
Lane, P. R., and G. M. Milesi-Ferretti. "The External Wealth
of Nations Mark II: Revised and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and
Liabilities, 1970-2004." IMF Working Paper 06/69, 2006.
Maddala, G. S., and S. Wu. "A Comparative Study of Unit Root
Tests with Panel Data and a New Simple Test." Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 61, 1999, 631-52.
McKinnon, R. I. Money and Capitol in Economic Development.
Washington, DC: Brooking Institutions, 1973.
Moon, H. R., and B. Perron. "Testing for a Unit Root in Panels
with Dynamic Factor." Journal of Econometrics, 122, 2004, 81-126.
Pedroni, P. "Critical Values for Cointegration Tests in
Heterogeneous Panels with Multiple Regressors." Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 61, 1999, 631-53.
--. "Fully Modified OLS for Heterogeneous Cointegrated
Panels," in Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic
Panels, edited by B.H. Baltagi. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier
Science, 2000.
--. "Panel Cointegration: Asymptotic and Finite Sample
Properties of Pooled Time Series with an Application to the PPP Hypothesis." Econometric Theory, 20, 2004, 597-625.
Pesaran, M. H. "General Diagnostic Tests for Cross-Section
Dependence in Panels." CESifo Working Papers series 1240, IFO,
2004.
--. "A Simple Panel Unit Root Test in the Presence of Cross
Section Dependence." Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22, 2007,
265-312.
Shaw, E. S. Financial Deepening in Economic Development. New York:
Oxford University Press, 1973.
Singh, A. "Financial Liberalisation, Stockmarkets and Economic
Development." The Economic Journal, 107, 1997, 771-782.
Stiglitz, J. E. "The Role of the State in Financial
Markets," in Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on
Development Economics 1993, 1994, 19-52.
Taylor, L. Structuralist Macroeconomics: Applicable Models of the
Third World. New York: Basic Books, 1983.
Van Wijnebergen, S. "Interest Rate Management in LDCs."
Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 1983, 433-52.
MAURO COSTANTINI, PANICOS O. DEMETRIADES, GREGORY A. JAMES and
KEVIN C. LEE*
* We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the ESRC (award
RES-156-25-0009 and PTA-026-27-1437). We would like to thank
participants at the Royal Economic Society, Money, Macro and Finance
Research Group, and Emerging Markets Group conferences for comments on
earlier versions of this article. We would also like to thank workshop
participants and discussants at the Cyprus University of Technology and
at the ESRC-Garnet meeting at the University of Amsterdam. Special
thanks to Badi Baltagi, Brian Burgoon, Wendy Carlin, Stijn Claessens,
Stefano Fachin, Sourafel Girma, Luciano Gutierrez, Claudio Lupi, and
Kate Phylakfis for many constructive suggestions. Comments from an
anonymous referee substantially improved the article. The usual
disclaimer applies.
Costantini: Department of Economics and Finance, Brunel University,
UK. Phone +44 0 1895 267958, Fax +44 0 1895 269 786, E-mail
Mauro.Costantini@brunel.ac.uk
Demetriades: Department of Economics, University of Leicester,
Leicester LE1 7RH, UK. Phone +44 0 116 252 2835, Fax +44 0 116 252 2908,
E-mail pd28@le.ac.uk
James: School of Business and Economics, Loughborough University,
UK. Phone +44 0 1509 222706, Fax +44 0 1509 223910, E-mail
G.AJames@lboro.ac.uk
Lee: School of Economics, University of Nottingham, UK. Phone +44 0
115 846 8368, Fax +44 0 115 951 4159, E-mail Kevin.Lee@nottingham.ac.uk
(1.) See for example, Arestis and Demetriades (1999),
Diaz-Alejandro (1985), Hellman, Murdock, and Stiglitz (2000), Singh
(1997), Stiglitz (1994), Taylor (1983), and Van Wijnbergen (1983).
(2.) Abiad and Mody (2005) document the gradual reduction of
financial restraints around the world, whereas Lane and Milesi-Ferretti
(2005) document the increase in financial openness.
(3.) In some circumstances, such credit expansion can also feed
consumption and lead to asset price bubbles.
(4.) The model is based on Demetriades and Devereux (2000).
(5.) The model assumes that there are two groups of investors in
the country: sophisticated investors, who can lend and borrow in the
world capital market and who own shares, and unsophisticated investors,
who save only in the official banking sector.
(6.) Stocks dated t refer to the end of period t, equivalent to the
beginning of period t + 1.
(7.) In both markets, the model assumes that the nominal interest
rate is set at the time the borrowing takes place. Thus, for example,
the interest rate applying to official borrowing at the beginning of
period t (the end of period t - 1, denoted [B.sub.t-1]) is determined at
the beginning of the period and hence denoted [i.sub.t-1].
(8.) Note that firms cannot borrow from the domestic market to lend
on the international market.
(9.) The initial capital stock for each country was constructed by
using [K.sub.0] = (([[summation].sup.1974.sub.t=1970]
[I.sub.t])/5)/[delta], where [delta] is the depreciation rate, assumed
to be 4%.
(10.) Although for tractability reasons, exchange rate risk is not
explicitly taken into account in the underlying theoretical model, in
reality this may deter domestic firms from borrowing in international
markets.
(11.) Other testing procedures based on factor structure generally
test the unit root only in the defactored data. See for instance Moon
and Perron (2004).
(12.) The framework used by Gengenbach, Palm, and Urbain (2006)
leads to panel statistics for the null of no cointegration that have the
same distribution as panel unit root tests and hence are not affected by
the number of regressors.
(13.) For more details see Bai and Kao (2006).
(14.) See Appendix C for the results of the Monte Carlo simulations
that confirm this. For further details on the CIPS test and the
[t.sup.*.sub.a], and [t.sup.*.sub.b] statistics see Pesaran (2007) and
Moon and Perron (2004), respectively.
(15.) One common factor is also selected when the other information
criteria proposed by Bai and Ng (2002) are considered.
(16.) See Bai and Ng (2004, 1133).
(17.) Tables reporting cross-correlations are not provided here for
brevity. These tables are available upon request.
TABLE 1
CD Tests Results
Statistics
[I.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] 4.696 (.009)
[Y.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] 7.865 (.000)
[([i.sup.*.sub.t])/(1 + [i.sup.*.sub.t]) 5.289 (.000)
(1 + [[pi].sub.jt)]([B.sub.jt]/
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([r.sup.*.sub.t] - [r.sup.*.sub.t])/ 5.077 (.006)
(1 + [i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 + [[pi].sub.jt)]
([B.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([[pi].sup.*.sub.t] - [[pi].sub.jt])/ 7.631 (.000)
(1 + [i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 + [[pi].sub.jt)]
([B.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1])
[SDEX.sub.jt]([B.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1]) 3.657 (.034)
[SDEX.sub.jt] 4.563 (.011)
Notes: Pesaran (2004) shows that under the null hypothesis
of no cross-sectional dependence CD [??] N(0, 1). p
values are in parentheses.
TABLE 2
Panel Unit Root Tests Results
[MATHEMATICAL [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] ASCII]
[I.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] -2.153 (.180) -1.037 (.717)
[Y.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] -1.742 (.410) -1.910 (.972)
[([i.sup.*.sub.t])/(1 + -1.659 (.402) -1.244 (.694)
[i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 +
[[pi].sub.jt)]([B.sub.jt]/
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([r.sup.*.sub.t] - -2.070 (.195) -0.639 (.906)
[r.sup.*.sub.jt])/(1 +
[i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 +
[[pi].sub.jt)]([B.sub.jt]/
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([[pi].sup.*.sub.t] - -1.097 (.510) -0.708 (.929)
[[pi].sub.jt])/(1 + [i.sup.*
.sub.t])(1 + [[pi].sub.jt)]
([B.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1])
[SDEX.sub.jt]([B.sub.jt]/ -2.090 (.210) -0.972 (.780)
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[SDEX.sub.jt] -1.071 (.520) -0.456 (.885)
CIPS [t.sup.*.sub.a]
[I.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] -1.512 (.840) -1.270 (.102)
[Y.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] -1.462 (.851) -0.291 (.388)
[([i.sup.*.sub.t])/(1 + -0.438 (.956) -1.145 (.120)
[i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 +
[[pi].sub.jt)]([B.sub.jt]/
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([r.sup.*.sub.t] - -2.001 (.163) -1.170 (.112)
[r.sup.*.sub.jt])/(1 +
[i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 +
[[pi].sub.jt)]([B.sub.jt]/
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([[pi].sup.*.sub.t] - -1.416 (.867) -0.789 (.210)
[[pi].sub.jt])/(1 + [i.sup.*
.sub.t])(1 + [[pi].sub.jt)]
([B.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1])
[SDEX.sub.jt]([B.sub.jt]/ -0.363 (.978) -0.923 (.170)
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[SDEX.sub.jt] -1.988 (.167) -1.119 (.125)
[t.sup.*.sub.b]
[I.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] -0.107 (.410)
[Y.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1] -0.051 (.490)
[([i.sup.*.sub.t])/(1 + -0.983 (.176)
[i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 +
[[pi].sub.jt)]([B.sub.jt]/
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([r.sup.*.sub.t] - -1.042 (.150)
[r.sup.*.sub.jt])/(1 +
[i.sup.*.sub.t])(1 +
[[pi].sub.jt)]([B.sub.jt]/
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[([[pi].sup.*.sub.t] - -1.070 (.131)
[[pi].sub.jt])/(1 + [i.sup.*
.sub.t])(1 + [[pi].sub.jt)]
([B.sub.jt]/[K.sub.jt - 1])
[SDEX.sub.jt]([B.sub.jt]/ -1.120 (.134)
[K.sub.jt - 1])
[SDEX.sub.jt] -1.242 (.110)
Notes: Sample period 1972-2000. The number of common factors selected
using the IC2 criterion is equal to l. The maximum number of factors
is fixed to 4. [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], denote the Bai
and Ng (2004) unit root tests on common factor and idiosyncratic
component, respectively. The ADF test regression only includes a
constant. The number of lags is selected using the Bayesian
information criterion (BIC). The maximum number of lags is fixed to 4.
CIPS denotes the panel unit root test proposed by Pesaran (2007). The
truncated version is applied as suggested by Pesaran (2007). The
appropriate lag-length for CIPS is selected using the Akaike
information criterion (AIC) with a maximum number of lags equal to 4.
t,; and [t.sup.*.sub.b]; are the two statistics developed by Moon and
Perron (2004). p values are in parentheses.
TABLE 3
Panel Cointegration Tests Results
Models [Z.sub.[rho]] [Z.sub.t]
Test Test
Pedroni (1999, 2004) idiosyncratic cointegration
NC -18.055 (.000) -24.699 (.000)
[FR.sup.A] -6.068 (.000) -2.775 (.002)
[FR.sup.D] -6.254 (.000) -4.519 (.000)
[FR.sup.A] (unrestricted) -3.691 (.000) -6.719 (.000)
FR-ER -6.923 (.000) -7.215 (.000)
Models [H.sub.0] : r = Trace Test
Johansen (1988) factor cointegration
NC 0 23.029 (.003)
1 3.841 (.531)
[FR.sup.A] 0 31.482 (.001)
1 0.220 (.639)
[FR.sup.D] 0 24.395 (.002)
1 0.343 (.558)
[FR.sup.A] (unrestricted) 0 16.413 (.036)
1 0.074 (.785)
FR-ER 0 15.495 (.048)
1 0.189 (.663)
Notes: Sample period 1972-2000. The Pedroni tests include individual
effects. [Z.sub.[[rho] and [Z.sub.t] denote the panel coef ficient p
type and t-ratio tests. The number of cointegrating vectors in the
Johansen (1988) trace test is denoted by r and the Akaike information
criterion (AIC) lag length is 4. p values are in parentheses.
TABLE 4
Panel Estimation Results with Cross-Sectional Independence Pedroni
FMOLS
NC [FR.sup.A] [FR.sup.D]
[b.sub.2] 0.0014 * (.0004) 0.0028 * (.0007) 0.0019 * (.0006)
[b.sub.3] -0.0947 * (.0169) -0.0892 * (.0202) -0.0789 * (.0190)
[b.sub.4] -- 0.1570 (.2135) --
[[??].sub.4] -- -- 0.1320 (.2314)
[[??].sub.4] -- -- --
[b.sub.5] -- -- --
[[??].sub.5] -- -- --
[b.sub.6] -- -- --
[b.sub.1] 0.5083 * (.0923) 0.5183 * (.1023) 0.4712 * (.0893)
[FR.sup.A]
(unrestricted) FR-ER
[b.sub.2] 0.0021 * (.0008) 0.0025 * (.0007)
[b.sub.3] -0.0734 * (.0210) -0.0787 * (.0215)
[b.sub.4] -- 0.1480 (.2319)
[[??].sub.4] -- --
[[??].sub.4] 0.1243 (.1045) --
[b.sub.5] 0.2123 * (.1071) --
[[??].sub.5] -- -0.1529 * (.0768)
[b.sub.6] -- -0.1787 (.1483)
[b.sub.1] 0.4892 * (.l153) 0.5032 * (.1093)
Notes: Sample period 1972-2000. The standard errors in parentheses are
computed using a sieve bootstrap procedure (see Chang. Park, and Song
2006; Fachin 2004).
* Denotes significance at the 5% level.
TABLE 5
Panel Estimation Results with Cross-Sectional Dependence Bai and Kao
FMOLS
NC [FR.sup.A]
Two Stage
[b.sub.2] 0.0482 * (.0215) 0.0512* (.0143)
[b.sub.3] -0.2165 * (.1024) -0.2521* (.0831)
[b.sub.4] -- 0.2323 * (.0754)
[[??].sub.4] -- --
[[??].sub.4] -- --
[b.sub.5] -- --
[[??].sub.5] -- --
[b.sub.6] -- --
[b.sub.1] 0.7378 * (.1513) 0.7810 * (.1934)
Iterative
[b.sub.2] 0.0461 * (.1083) 0.0501 * (.0152)
[b.sub.3] -0.2191 * (.1023) -0.2651 * (.0689)
[b.sub.4] -- 0.2231 * (.0739)
[[??].sub.4] -- --
[[??].sub.4] -- --
[b.sub.5] -- --
[[??].sub.5] -- --
[b.sub.6] -- --
[b.sub.1] 0.7630 * (.1456) 0.7832 * (.1835)
[FR.sup.A]
[FR.sup.D] (unrestricted)
Two Stage
[b.sub.2] 0.0498 * (.0141) 0.0503 * (.0145)
[b.sub.3] -0.2461 * (.0804) -0.2435 * (.0811)
[b.sub.4] -- --
[[??].sub.4] 0.5321 * (.1841) --
[[??].sub.4] -- 0.2127 * (.0639)
[b.sub.5] -- 0.2699 * (.0923)
[[??].sub.5] -- --
[b.sub.6] -- --
[b.sub.1] 0.6951 * (.1653) 0.7352 * (.2397)
Iterative
[b.sub.2] 0.0489 * (.0139) 0.0502 * (.0141)
[b.sub.3] -0.2414 * (.0789) -0.2419 * (.0792)
[b.sub.4] -- --
[[??].sub.4] 0.5215 * (.1823) --
[[??].sub.4] -- 0.2214 * (.0721)
[b.sub.5] -- 0.2701 * (.0923)
[[??].sub.5] -- --
[b.sub.6] -- --
[b.sub.1] 0.6783 * (.1735) 0.7414 * (.1998)
FR-ER
Two Stage
[b.sub.2] 0.0494 * (.0141)
[b.sub.3] -0.2672 * (.0762)
[b.sub.4] 0.2412 * (.0761)
[[??].sub.4] --
[[??].sub.4] --
[b.sub.5] --
[[??].sub.5] -0.3131 * (.0982)
[b.sub.6] -0.5017 * (.1218)
[b.sub.1] 0.7012 * (.2476)
Iterative
[b.sub.2] 0.0494 * (.0154)
[b.sub.3] -0.2710 * (.0796)
[b.sub.4] 0.2504 * (.0761)
[[??].sub.4] --
[[??].sub.4] --
[b.sub.5] --
[[??].sub.5] -0.3529 * (.1123)
[b.sub.6] -0.5271 * (.1391)
[b.sub.1] 0.7234 * (.1956)
Notes: Sample period 1972-2000. The standard errors in parentheses are
computed using a sieve bootstrap procedure (see Chang, Park, and Song
2006; Fachin 2004).
* Denotes significance at the 5% level.