Imported capital input, absorptive capacity, and firm performance: evidence from firm-level data.
Yasar, Mahmut
I. INTRODUCTION
The importance of productivity growth as a primary determinant of
the underlying difference in income across countries is now a
well-established empirical proposition (Hall and Jones 1999). Endogenous
growth theory suggests that innovation is the main source of
productivity growth (Grossman and Helpman 1991). However, the creation
of new products and technologies is concentrated mostly in developed
countries (Eaton and Kortum 2001). Developing countries rely much more
on technology and knowledge produced by high-income countries than on
direct investment in research and development. Therefore, a crucial
question for developing economies is whether, how, and to what extent
importing foreign technology can enhance the productivity of their firms
to narrow the income gap between themselves and more developed
countries.
In this article, we examine the productive impact of imported
capital input by emphasizing its interaction with the absorptive
capacity of manufacturing firms. The importing of foreign capital input,
embodied by technology and knowledge, has been recognized in the
economics literature as a significant conduit for technology transfer
across countries (Coe and Helpman 1995; Eaton and Kortum 1996, 1999,
2001; Grossman and Helpman 1991; Xu and Wang 1999). (1) Coe and Helpman
(1995), for example, find a significant impact on productivity at the
country level from importing intermediate products and capital inputs,
and Keller (2002a, 2002b) supports this finding with industry-level
data. In studies at the firm level, it was observed that the productive
impact of the imported capital input varies across countries in terms of
both statistical significance and magnitude; in some countries it is
strong, whereas in others it is weak or statistically insignificant.
Kraay, Soloaga, and Tybout (2001), Keller and Yeaple (2003), and Vogel
and Wagner (2008) find weak evidence of productivity effects of
importing at the firm level, but Amiti and Konings (2007), Fernandes
(2007), Gorg and Hanley (2005), Gorg, Hanley, and Strobl (2008),
Halpern, Koren, and Szeidl (2006), Jabbour (2007), Kasahara and Rodrigue
(2008), Lopez (2006), Lopez and Yadav (2009), and Yasar and Paul (2007)
find statistically significant but highly varying effects. (2) These
differences may stern in part from the fact that at different stages of
development, countries have differences in some firm characteristics
that help create mechanisms through which productivity gains are
realized. This calls for further study of the productive contribution of
imported capital input in various countries, at different stages of
development, by emphasizing its linkages with firm characteristics such
as input composition, skill intensity, or absorptive capacity.
The productive effects of importing can be examined using standard
least-squares techniques by including a dummy variable to indicate the
import of intermediate inputs in a production function or a productivity
equation. Such a method, however, assumes homogeneity in the productive
impact of the imported capital across firms by imposing a linearity
restriction on the outcome equation. It is expected that importing
capital from countries with higher levels of accumulated technical
knowledge will improve the productivity of firms in the developing host
country through R&D embodied in the capital and associated learning.
(3) However, a shortage of absorptive capacity could potentially limit
firms' ability to utilize these new technologies effectively. (4)
The relationship may not be linear as the degree to which knowledge
spillovers can be effectively utilized in the host country will depend
on the skill intensity or absorptive capability (5) of firms in the host
country, as well as some other firm, industry, or country
characteristics. (6) Nelson and Phelps (1966) emphasize the importance
of absorptive capability: "We suggest that, in a technologically
progressive or dynamic economy, production management is a function
requiring adaptation to change and that the more educated a manager is,
the quicker will he be to introduce new techniques of production. To put
the hypothesis simply, educated people make good innovators, so that
education speeds the process of technological diffusion." They
argue that the adoption of new technologies requires, in particular, a
threshold stock of human capital in the host country, and the extent to
which the gap between the technology frontier and current productivity
can be closed depends on the level of this stock. (7) Spillover productivity effects from importing technology would thus be expected to
occur when human capital in a host-country firm is above a certain
threshold; and if labor skill levels fall short of this threshold,
host-country firms are unlikely to be able to exploit the productive
power of the foreign technology. (8)
In this article, our goal is to examine the productive impact of
imported capital for a sample of Chinese manufacturing firms, with a
focus on the interaction between imported capital and absorptive
capacity. More specifically, we empirically assess the theoretical
predictions of the studies highlighted above, by investigating whether
the successful adoption of new technologies requires a threshold level of skilled labor in the host country and whether a higher level of
skilled labor enhances productivity improvements from importing capital.
We recognize that the parameter estimates may fail to distinguish
between productivity differences from imported technology and those
emerging from unobserved firm-specific characteristics that may have
caused firms to choose to import capital, and that the productive impact
may be heterogeneous across firms. Thus, to control for this, we
estimate our model using two alternative econometric methods to ordinary
least squares (OLS): an instrumental variable (IV) estimator to control
for potential endogeneity and newly developed threshold regression
techniques (Caner and Hansen 2004; Hansen 2000) that employ an
endogenous search algorithm to determine the threshold level of the
absorptive capacity and its statistical significance with and without
endogenous explanatory variables. We use the share of skilled workers
(technicians, engineers, and managers) as a proxy for the absorptive
capacity of the manufacturing firms and examine the effect of the
interaction of the human capital variable with imported technology on
firm productivity.
After controlling for a number of firm characteristics that affect
productivity and endogeneity, we find that importing capital is
associated with significantly higher productivity in the Chinese
manufacturing firms and that those firms with higher absorptive capacity
gain significantly more from importing foreign technology, implying that
the productive contribution of imported capital is significantly
skilled-laborusing. These productivity gains also depend on a threshold
level of human capital; the productivity differential for importing
capital becomes statistically significant when the share of managers and
engineers in total employment is about 38%, with a confidence interval of 28-44%. Furthermore, our results indicate that the productive
contribution of skilled labor is significantly higher in firms that
import foreign capital.
II. EMPIRICAL MODEL
To examine whether and to what extent the productive impact of
imported capital varies with the ability of Chinese manufacturing firms
to absorb new technologies, we use OLS, IV, and a recently developed
endogenous threshold regression estimate of a production function
specification that represents the most output, technologically
producible from the given input vector, firm characteristics, and
external conditions. (9) We assume that the production process is
represented by a Cobb-Douglas production function, (10) Y = f (K, L,
IMP, SH, IMP x SH, R), written as:
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where i is a firm subscript; ln Y is the log of value added; In L
and In K are the log values of labor and capital input, respectively;
IMP = 1 if the firm imported any machinery and 0 otherwise; SH
represents the share of technicians, engineers, and managers in total
employment; and u is a stochastic error term. (11) [R.sub.m] includes
the variables for internal firm characteristics, which are age of the
firm (AGE); whether or not the firm's products have been granted
ISO900 certification (ISO); capacity utilization (CU, defined as the
amount of output actually produced relative to the maximum amount that
could be produced with existing machinery and regular shifts); and size
(SD), (12) industry (ID), (13) and region (CD) dummies. (14)
In this model, our main variable of interest is the interaction of
the imported machinery variable (IMP) with the variable representing the
share of technicians, engineers, and managers in total employment (SH).
(15) Based on the insights from theoretical studies, we expect highly
skilled workers to use imported capital more effectively. The
coefficient on the interaction term [[beta].sub.5] thus represents the
extent to which human capital augments the productive benefits of
imported machinery. As this coefficient represents the impact of
imported machinery on the productive contribution of skilled labor or on
the productive contribution of imported machinery of more skilled labor,
a significantly positive (negative) coefficient estimate implies
complementarity (substitutability) between imported machinery and
skilled labor.
The coefficient on IMP alone, [[beta].sub.3], represents the direct
impact of imported machinery on the productivity of firms; if [SH.sub.i]
= 0 the productivity differential between the importers and nonimporters
is [[beta].sub.3]. The coefficient on [SH.sub.i], [[beta].sub.4],
similarly represents the productivity impact of skilled labor share for
non-importers. The productivity impact of importing capital for firm i
including the impact of human capital is thus [partial derivative]
ln[Y.sub.i]/[partial derivative] IMP = [[beta].sub.3]+ [[beta].sub.3] x
[SH.sub.i], and the productivity impact of human capital including the
contribution of importing capital is [partial derivative] ln
[Y.sub.i]/[partial derivative] [SH.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.4] +
[[beta].sub.5] x IMP. We expect the impact of the simultaneous increase
in skilled labor share and imported capital input on the productivity of
firms to be positive. This requires [[beta].sub.5] to be positive and
statistically significant.
The other firm-specific characteristics accommodate heterogeneity across firms. AGE is included because more experience would be expected
to enhance productivity. It also represents the reputation of a firm.
Whether or not the firm's products have been granted ISO9000
certification (ISO) is included to capture the firm's managerial or
product quality. CU is included to control for the average utilization
of a firm's fixed inputs. The remaining explanatory variables are
firm-specific controls for size, industry, and region.
III. ESTIMATION METHODS
A. Ordinary Least Squares
Equation (1) can be estimated by using OLS with interaction terms
to empirically examine the productive impact of imported technology by
emphasizing its interaction with skill intensity for firms in the
Chinese manufacturing industry. If [[beta].sub.5] is positive and
statistically significant, then we can conclude that there is a
significant association between productivity and imported technology,
conditional on skilled labor share; firms differ in their stock of
skilled labor and the productive impact of imported machinery depends to
a large extent on these stocks. However, this cannot be interpreted as a
causal relationship for a few reasons. First, firms with better
performance might choose to import foreign technology. It may be that
only the most productive firms are able to enter the import market. In
other words, importing firms may be more productive at the outset, not
as a result of enjoying benefits associated with imported capital. In
addition to this self-selection, there may be some omitted determinants
of productivity that will be inherently correlated with the import
variable. In these cases, the error term will be correlated with the
imported capital variable and the OLS estimates will be biased and
inconsistent. (16)
Thus, to evaluate potential endogeneity issues that may affect the
robustness of our model, we also employ an IV estimator. (17)
B. IV Estimator
We assume that we are interested in estimating [y.sub.i] =
[x'.sub.i][beta] + [u.sub.i]. When endogeneity is present, one must
control for potential estimation biases by identifying J instruments in
an associated vector [z.sub.i]. (18) For [beta] to be a consistent
estimator, the population moment condition E[([y.sub.i] -
[x'.sub.i][beta])[z.sub.i]] = 0 must hold. The IV estimator solves
the corresponding sample moment condition 1/N [[summation].sup.n.sub.i]
([y.sub.i] - [x'.sub.i][beta])[z.sub.i] z = 0 by choosing values of
[beta] that drive this condition as close to zero as possible by
minimizing: [Q.sub.N] ([beta]) = [1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.i]
([y.sub.i] - [x'.sub.i][beta])[z.sub.i]'. [[OMEGA].sub.N] [1/N
[[summation].sup.N.sub.i]([y.sub.i] - [x'.sub.i][beta])[z.sub.i]],
where [[OMEGA].sub.N] is a weighting matrix.
Valid instruments ([z.sub.i]) must not be correlated with the error
term, that is, the instruments used must have an impact on productivity
only through the endogenous import variable and its interaction with the
skilled labor share. (19) We assume that the following variables meet
this requirement and use them as instruments to control for resulting
potential endogeneity (20): whether the general manager of the firm is
from an industrialized country (MN); whether the firm is a subsidiary or
a joint venture of a multinational firm (FO); whether the firm was an
exporter in the previous year (EXP); and the percentage of firm owned by
the state/provincial government (SO). (21) If the manager is from an
industrialized foreign country, the firm is more likely to import. Firms
with some state ownership are less likely to import. A firm that is an
exporter or a subsidiary/joint venture of a multinational firm is more
likely to import. (22) We assume that these variables do not have an
independent direct impact on firm productivity; their effect is through
import and its interaction with the skill level of the firm. (23)
C. Threshold Regression Models
To check the robustness of our results obtained by the interaction
effects using both OLS and IV estimators, we use an alternative method
that allows the data to endogenously select a sample split and
simultaneously test the presence of the threshold level of skilled labor
share. As explained earlier, the productive impact of imported
technology may be heterogeneous in the sense that it may vary at
different levels of skilled labor share, indicating that the
relationship is not monotonic but nonlinear. The failure to account for
these potential threshold effect non-linearities can potentially result
in biased results. Standard threshold models assume that one knows the
break points with certainty. However, prior knowledge of how the impact
of imported capital on productivity varies with the threshold variable
is not available with certainty. Hansen (2000) introduced a threshold
regression technique that treats the threshold as an unknown parameter
and estimates it endogenously using the data, instead of assuming it
arbitrarily. It also allows us to test the existence of this threshold.
(24)
We implement this approach to endogenously search for regime
changes in the data by using the skilled labor share as a threshold
variable.
This endogenous threshold analysis allows the impact of the
imported technology on productivity to vary with skilled labor share.
When there is a single threshold, the regression model can be rewritten
as follows. (25)
(2) [Y.sub.i] = [beta]'[X.sub.i] + [[delta].sub.i]
I([SH.sub.i] [less than or equal to] [gamma])IMP + [[delta].sub.2] I
([SH.sub.i] > [gamma])IMP + [u.sub.i],
where [Y.sub.i] is the dependent variable; [SH.sub.i] is a
threshold variable, corresponding to the skilled labor share; [X.sub.i]
is a vector of control variables explained in the previous section (26);
I is an indicator function; and [gamma] is the estimated threshold
value. This method allows the division of the impact of import into two
regimes, conditional on whether the skilled labor share is smaller or
greater than the estimated threshold level [gamma]. In other words, it
allows the regression parameters to differ depending on the value of the
threshold variable. For instance, [[delta.sub.1] is the impact of
imported technology on productivity when [q.sub.i] [less than or equal
to] [gamma] and [[delta].sub.2] is the impact of imported technology on
productivity when [q.sub.i] > [gamma]. This method estimates [gamma]
and the parameters using least-squares estimator through concentration
and obtains reliable confidence intervals for [gamma].
The estimation strategy includes three main steps. (27) First, we
estimate the threshold value [gamma] (a value that minimizes the
concentrated sum of squared errors). Let [S.sub.n]([gamma]) represent
the sum of squared errors for any given value of [gamma]. Then, the
slope coefficients are estimated by OLS by obtaining a [??] that
minimizes [S.sub.n]([gamma]). As the parameter [delta] depends on the
threshold value [gamma] (i.e., [delta]([gamma])), the model is not
linear in its parameters. Hansen (2000) suggested obtaining the OLS
estimates through concentration. Conditional on a threshold value, say
[[gamma].sub.0], the regression equation is linear in its parameters,
and the sum of the square error function can be minimized to obtain the
conditional OLS estimators [??]([[gamma].sub.0]) and
[??]([[gamma].sub.0]). Suppose the concentrated sum of square errors
function is [S.sub.n]([[gamma].sub.0]) =
[S.sub.n]([??]([[gamma].sub.0]), [??]([[gamma].sub.0]),
[[gamma].sub.0]). By trying all values of the threshold variable (SH),
the estimator of the threshold variable will be a value of [gamma] that
results in the smallest [S.sub.n]([[gamma].sub.0]), which is defined as
follows: [??] = arg min [S.sub.n]([gamma]). This minimization problem is
solved by a grid search over the values of the threshold variable (SH).
Second, we test the statistical significance of the threshold
effects. More specifically, we test the null hypothesis of no threshold
(i.e., [H.sub.0] : [[delta].sub.1] = [[delta].sub.2]) against the
alternative hypothesis of a threshold regression model (i.e.,
[H.sub.A]:[[delta].sub.1] [not equal to] [[delta].sub.2]) by using a
bootstrap procedure that allows us to obtain critical values for the
test statistic by treating the explanatory variables and the threshold
variable (SH) as given and holding their values fixed in each repeated
bootstrap sample. The bootstrap dependent variable is generated by
drawing a sample of residuals from N(0, [[??].sup.2.sub.i]), where
[[??].sub.i] is the OLS residual from the estimated threshold model.
Repeating this procedure a large number of times, the bootstrap estimate
of the p-value under the null is given by the percentage of draws for
which the simulated statistic exceeds the actual one. This approach
produces asymptotically correct p-values. The null of no threshold
effect is rejected if the p-value is smaller than the desired critical
value.
Finally, if the null hypothesis is rejected, we construct
confidence intervals for the threshold ([gamma]) variable. We first need
to test for a threshold value (i.e., [H.sub.0] : [gamma] =
[[gamma].sub.0]; [H.sub.1] : [gamma] [not equal to] [[gamma].sub.0]).
Assuming normality, a standard method to test this is to use likelihood
ratio statistics:
[LR.sub.n](y) = n([S.sub.n]([gamma]) -
[S.sub.n]([??])/[S.sub.n]([??])).
The null hypothesis is rejected when [LR.sub.n]([[gamma].sub.0]) is
too large. Hansen (2000) illustrated that [LR.sub.n]([gamma]) does not
have a standard [chi square] distribution under the endogenous threshold
specification. He derived the correct distribution function and
tabulated the asymptotic critical values.
By using this methodology, we expect to obtain a more exact
assessment of the productive impact of import than that obtained by
traditional monotonic approaches.
The threshold model introduced by Hansen (2000) assumes that all
right-hand-side variables are exogenous. Caner and Hansen (2004)
introduced a technique that allows us to estimate the threshold models
with endogenous variables but an exogenous threshold variable. First, a
threshold reduced-form model is estimated by least squares, and then the
fitted values of the endogenous variable are obtained based on this
reduced-form estimate. Finally, these fitted values are used in place of
the endogenous variables in a structural equation that is estimated by
least squares. Although the threshold parameter is estimated using a
two-stage least-squares estimator, the slope parameters are estimated by
employing a generalized method of moment estimator. We have also
estimated the threshold parameter by using this method to check the
robustness of our results. (28)
IV. DATA
To estimate the productive impact of imported technology associated
with skilled labor intensity, we use cross-section survey data from the
Investment Climate Survey conducted by the World Bank in 2003 on a
sample of Chinese manufacturing firms. The World Bank's Enterprise
Surveys use either simple random sampling or random-stratified sampling
to ensure the randomness of their sample. Face-to-face interviews were
conducted with firms' managers and accountants, using a sampling
method designed to ensure adequate representation of firms by industry,
size, ownership, export orientation, and location. The firms in the
survey are from 18 Chinese regions: Benxi, Changchun, Changsha,
Chongqing, Dalian, Guiyang, Haerbin, Hangzhou, Jiangmen, Kunming,
Lanzhou, Nanchang, Nanning, Shenzhen, Wenzhou, Wuhan, Xian, and
Zhengzhou. The industries represented are Food Processing, Garment and
Leather Products, Electronics Equipment, Electronics Parts Making,
Household Electronics, Auto and Auto Parts, Chemical Products and
Medicine, Biotech Products and Chinese Medicine, and Metallurgical
Products. Summary statistics of the data are presented in Table I.
Although the survey was conducted for firms in both the service and
manufacturing industries, we dropped the firms in the service industries
because information on input and sales was not available for many firms
in this sector.
Furthermore, we dropped observations that were clearly erroneous,
such as negative values of age, output, and labor. After dropping
erroneous observations and the missing observations for the variables
included in our model, 1,161 observations remained. Of these 1,161
firms, about 33% reported that they imported foreign capital (machinery)
and the remaining 67% did not. The average skilled labor share in our
sample is about 27%. As shown in Table 2, none of the variables of
interest for our model exhibit a very high degree of correlation,
putting aside inference problems because of multicollinearity. (29)
V. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
A. OLS Results
The OLS parameter estimates for our model are presented in Table 3
for the Chinese manufacturing firms in our data. The statistically
significant estimates are identified by asterisks. (30) The parameter
estimates show a positive productive contribution of skilled labor
associated with imported machinery and the productive contribution of
imported machinery associated with more highly skilled labor.
More specifically, the productive impact of additional skilled
labor for non-importers (IMP=0) is [[beta].sub.4] =0.918, whereas that
for importers (IMP = 1) is [[beta].sub.4] + [[beta].sub.5] x IMP = 0.918
+ 0.885 = 1.803; so [[beta].sub.5] = 0.885 indicates how much importing
capital augments the productive contribution of more human capital (a
greater share of managerial, engineering, and technical labor).
Conversely, the productive contribution of importing capital for a firm
with no skilled labor is insignificantly different than zero
([[beta].sub.3] = -0.006), but skilled labor augments the productivity
of importing as [[beta].sub.5] = 0.885, which is significantly different
than zero. For example, for a firm with a mean skilled labor share of
0.271, the productivity enhancement associated with importing capital is
[[beta].sub.3] + [[beta].sub.5] x SH = -0.006 + 0.885 x (0.271) =
0.235--about 23.5%. The productive effect of importing capital is thus
driven by a strongly positive skilled labor bias; importing capital is
skilled labor intensive in the sense that the productive differential
for importers increases with additional human capital.
The significantly positive estimated coefficient on the interaction
between imported machinery and skilled labor share means that they are
complements--sometimes referred to as technology-skill complementarity.
This finding is consistent with theoretical studies that predict the
productivity of importing machinery to be positively related to a more
highly skilled workforce because effective adoption or absorption of new
technology requires human capital. Thus, firms wishing to obtain new
technology by importing machinery need to hire skilled workers to
utilize this technology effectively. Moreover, the magnitude of the
technology spillover effect from importing is larger for firms with more
human capital.
In fact, the productive impact of importing capital with no skilled
labor is essentially zero but increases significantly with more human
capital. It can thus be surmised that a threshold of skilled labor is
required to exploit the imported technology. To test this hypothesis, we
estimated the productivity impact of imported machinery at various
percentiles of skilled labor share, as reported in Table 4. This table
presents the percentage difference in productivity between importers and
non-importers at different percentiles (31) of skilled labor share. The
first column of Table 4 shows the skilled labor share; the second column
shows the differential impact of a higher skill share on the
productivity effect of importing capital based on the OLS results; and
the third column presents the differential based on the IV estimator,
which will be highlighted in the next section. The corresponding
standard errors obtained from the Delta Method are presented in
parentheses. The productive differential for importers is positive at
all percentiles of skilled labor share. However, the differential does
not become statistically significant at the conventional significance
level of 5% until the share reaches about 23%, which corresponds to the
50th percentile of the skilled labor share. At this percentile, the
productivity of importing capital becomes -0.06 + 0.885 x (0.231) =
0.199--a productivity premium of about 19.9% for importers. An increase
in the skilled labor share to 50% implies a productivity differential of
nearly 43%. These results are consistent with the suggestions in the
literature that absorptive capability of domestic firms is the main
factor affecting the degree to which knowledge spillovers can be
utilized in the host economy, and that a threshold level of human
capital must be attained to exploit such spillovers (Kokko, Tansini, and
Zejan 1996).
Further, our other coefficient estimates suggest that total factor
productivity is significantly related to the control variables. (32) The
statistically significant positive coefficient on ISO9000 indicates that
certified firms are about 28% more productive than those that are not,
and the statistically significant positive coefficient on CU indicates
that productivity increases with average CU. Finally, age seems to have
a negative linear impact on firm productivity.
B. IV Results
The parameter estimates using the IV estimator are presented in the
third column of Table 3, with robust standard errors in parentheses. The
results, denoted IV, are based on the instrument set explained above.
Using the Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions to test for the
correlation between the instruments and the error term gives the p-value
of .406, which validates the use of these instruments. We also use an
F-test to examine whether these instruments are sufficiently related to
the endogenous variables by estimating their joint significance in
reduced-form equations. F-tests show that these instruments are valid
instruments.
As shown in the third column of Table 3, (30) controlling for
potential endogeneity by IV estimation increases the productive impact
of importing. The parameter estimates show a positive productive
contribution of skilled labor associated with imported machinery and the
productive contribution of imported machinery
associated with more highly skilled labor. The productive impact of
additional skilled labor for non-importers (IMP=0) is [[beta].sub.4]
=0.721, whereas that for importers (IMP = 1) is 2.170; so [[beta].sub.5]
= 1.449 indicates how much importing capital augments the productive
contribution of a greater share of managerial, engineering, and
technical labor. Conversely, the productive contribution of importing
capital for a firm with no skilled labor is insignificantly different
than zero ([[beta].sub.3] = 0.051), but skilled labor enhances the
productivity of importing as [[beta].sub.5] = 1.449 is significantly
different than zero. For a firm with a median skilled labor share of
0.231, the productivity boost associated with importing capital is about
38.7%. This finding is consistent with the OLS results, but the
parameter estimates obtained by the IV estimator are higher. These
results indicate that OLS biases the parameter estimates downward,
assuming that the identified IVs used are strong enough. Overall, these
results also verify the previous results and the theoretical predictions
that the productivity of importing machinery is positively related to a
more highly skilled workforce.
Furthermore, as illustrated in the third column of Table 4,
although there is no significant productivity differential between the
importers and non-importers when the skilled labor is essentially zero,
the gap increases significantly with more human capital. The
coefficients for the remaining independent variables are similar in
terms of both their magnitude and significance for the IV estimation.
C. Threshold Regression Model Results
The results from the threshold regression model are reported in the
first column of Table 5. Using skilled labor share as the potential
threshold variable, Hansen's (2000) endogenous search technique
identifies a statistically significant threshold, which corresponds to a
skilled labor share of [??] = 0.427 with 95% confidence interval [0.289,
0.466]. (33) The corresponding bootstrapped p-value, which is obtained
by using a Lagrange Multiplier test for a threshold with 1,000
replications (as explained in Hansen 1996), is 0.041. Thus, the null
hypothesis is rejected at the conventional 5% significance level,
indicating that the productive impact of imported capital varies across
the two regimes, that is, there is a sample split based on our threshold
variable of skilled labor share. (34) Although import is significantly
associated with the firm productivity in the first regime only at the
conventional 10% level, it becomes statistically significant at the 1%
level when the skilled
labor share is above the threshold level of 0.427, which is the
threshold endogenously determined by the data. In the first regime,
where the skilled labor share is less than the threshold of 42.7%, the
importing firms are only 16.2% more productive than the non-importing
firms. This productive difference is not significant at either 0.05 or
0.01 significance levels. However, in the second regime, the
productivity premium for the importing firms is 49.9% and significant at
the 1% significance level. The threshold level divides the sample of
1,161 into two subsamples of 996 and 165 firms; 996 firms in the sample
have a skilled labor share that is less than [gamma], whereas 165 firms
have a skilled labor share that is higher than [??].
The normalized likelihood ratio sequence [LR.sub.n]([gamma])
statistic as a function of our threshold variable is also illustrated in
Figure I. The least-squares estimate of [gamma] is the value that
minimizes the function [LR.sub.n]([gamma]) which occurs at [??] = 0.427.
The asymptotic 95% critical value for the threshold estimates is shown
by the portion of the curve in the graph that lies below the dotted line
drawn at the critical value. As illustrated in the graph, the 95%
confidence set is [0.289, 0.466].
We also estimated the threshold parameter using a method introduced
by Caner and Hansen (2004) that allows us to estimate the threshold
models with endogenous variables. As illustrated in the third column of
Table 3 and in Figure 2, this method identifies a threshold that
corresponds to a skilled labor share of 0.380, with 95% confidence
intervals of [0.289, 0.443]. These results are consistent with those
obtained by using the threshold regression technique that treats all the
explanatory variables as exogenous.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
VI. CONCLUSIONS
Recent studies have suggested that importing capital is an
important channel for firms in developing countries to transfer new
technologies from developed countries. However, the literature does not
clearly establish the importance of particular firm characteristics
(such as the firm's absorptive capacity) on the productive impact
of this capital input, which involves the mechanisms through which these
productivity gains are realized. In particular, firms' internal
conditions, such as a lack of skilled labor, might limit a firm's
ability to exploit the potential productive benefits of imported
technology. This study focuses on the role played by firms'
absorptive capacity in the link between imported technology and firm
productivity. To capture this capacity, the share of skilled workers for
a sample of Chinese manufacturing firms is interacted with a variable
representing the imported machinery in a Cobb-Douglas production
function specification. In addition to a standard least-squares (OLS)
estimator with interaction effects, two alternative econometric methods
are used to estimate the parameters of production function: an IV
estimator and the endogenous threshold regression technique.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
After controlling for observable variables that represent
heterogeneity across firms and potential endogeneity, our empirical
results suggest that importing machinery plays an important role in
enhancing firm productivity, but that the level of absorptive capacity
determines the level of positive effects attained. Thus, in keeping with
the theoretical predictions of existing literature, this study finds
that the productive impact of the import does not increase monotonically
and that the impact is more profound when the level of absorptive
capacity is above a certain threshold. Hence, a higher absorptive
capacity can allow firms to maximize benefits associated with new
technologies and manufacturing techniques transferred from high-income
countries. Conversely, importing machinery more significantly increases
the productivity of firms with higher skill shares. This gap widens as
the skill share increases. This finding implies capital-skill or
technology-skill complementarity. Thus, enhancing firm productivity will
involve simultaneously encouraging deepening capital and augmenting the
skill level of the labor force.
The productive impact of the imported technology may vary with the
country's stage of development, over time, as well as with the
capacity of the firms to absorb new technologies. Thus, further research
is needed to analyze the effects of temporal changes on firms'
performance across various countries by utilizing firm-level panel data.
The estimated productive impact of importing is higher in this study
than in some of the related studies in the literature. One apparent
explanation is that we allowed for differences in the absorptive
capacity across firms in this article. In addition, previous studies
used the intermediate material, whereas in this article we used an
import variable that represents the imported machinery. It might also be
related to the identified IVs set used and further endogeneity bias. In
subsequent research, it can be helpful to identify different instruments
and add a time series dimension to the cross-section analysis to
investigate this further. Furthermore, we used the firm-level skill
intensity as a measure for differences in absorptive capacity and
estimated the productive impact of imported machinery by allowing for
differences in absorptive capacity across firms. It can be valuable to
use other proxies for the absorptive capacity such as research and
development expenditures, the number of patents granted, or relative
initial productivity.
ABBREVIATIONS
IV: Instrumental Variable
IMP: Imported Machinery Variable
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
CU: Capacity Utilization
VIF: Variance Inflation Factors
FDI: Foreign Direct Investment
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00352.x
REFERENCES
Amiti, M., and J, Konings. "Trade Liberalization, Intermediate
Inputs. and Productivity: Evidence from Indonesia." American
Economic Review, 97(5), 2007, 1611-38.
Aw, B. Y., M. Roberts, and T. Winston. "'Export Market
Participation, Investments in R&D and Worker Training, and the
Evolution of Firm Productivity.'" World Economy, 3(1(1), 2007,
83-104.
Aw, B. Y., M. Roberts, and D. Y. Xu. "R&D Investment,
Export, and the Evolution of Firm Productivity.'" American
Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 98(2), 2008, 451-56.
--. "R&D Investment, Exporting. and Productivity
Dynamics.'" NBER Working Paper No. W 14670, 2009.
Benhabib, J.. and M. M. Spiegel. "The Role of Human Capital in
Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data."
Journal of Monetary Economics, 34, 1994, 143-73.
Bernard, A., S. Redding, and P. Schott. "'Multi-product
Firms and Trade Liberalization." NBER Working Paper No. 12782,
2006.
Bustos, P. "The Impact of Trade on Technology and Skill
Upgrading: Evidence from Argentina." Department of Economics and
Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Working Paper No. 1189, 2007.
Cameron, A.C., and P. K. Trivedi. Microeconometrics: Methods and
Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005.
Caner, M., and B. Hansen. "Instrumental Variable Estimation of
a Threshold Model." Econometric Theory. 20, 2004, 813-43.
Clerides, S., S. Lach, and J. Tybout. "Is
Learning-by-Exporting Important? Micro Dynamic Evidence from Colombia,
Mexico, and Morocco." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 53, 1998,
903-47.
Coe, D. T., and E. Helpman. "International R&D
Spillovers." European Economic Review, 39, 1995, 859-87.
Cohen, W. M., and D. A. Levinthal. "Absorptive Capacity: A New
Perspective on Learning and Innovation." Administrative Science
Quarterly, 35, 1990, 128-52.
DeLoecker, J. "Product Differentiation, Multi-Product Firms
and Estimating the Impact of Trade Liberalization on Productivity."
NBER Working Paper No. 13155, 2006.
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum. "Trade in Ideas: Patenting and
Productivity in the OECD.'" Journal of International
Economics. 40, 1996, 251 78.
--. "International Patenting and Technology Diffusion: Theory
and Measurement." International Economic Review, 40, 1999, 537-70.
--. "Trade in Capital Goods." European Economic Review,
45(7), 2001, 1195-235.
Feenstra, R. C. "Integration of Trade and Disintegration of
Production in the Global Economy." Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 12, 1998, 31-50.
Fernandes. A. "Trade Policy, Trade Volumes and Plant-Level
Productivity in Colombian Manufacturing Industries." Journal of
International Economics, 71. 2007, 52-71.
Goldberg, P., A. Khandetwat, N. Pavcnik, and P. Topalova.
"Multi-Product Firms and Product Turnover in the Developing World:
Evidence from India." NBER Working Paper No. 14127, 2009.
Gorg, H., and A. Hanley. "'International Outsourcing and
Productivity: Evidence from the Irish Electronics Industry." North
American Journal of Economics and Finance, 16(2), 2005, 255-69.
Gorg, H., A. Hanley, and E. Strobl. "Productivity Effects of
International Outsourcing: Evidence from Plant Level Data."
Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(2), 2(108, 670-88.
Grossman, G., and E. Helpman. Innovation and Growth in the Global
Econonomy Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991.
Hall, R., and C. Jones. "'Why Do Some Countries Produce
So Much More Output per Worker than Others'?" Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 114(1), 1999. 83-116.
Halpern, L.. M. Koren, and A. Szeidl. "Imports and
Productivity." CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5139, 2006.
Hansen, B. E. "Inference When a Nuisance Parameter is Not
Identified under the Null Hypothesis." Econometrica, 64(2). 1996.
413-30.
--. "Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation."
Econometrica, 68, 2000, 575-603.
Head, K., and J. Ries. "Offshore Production and Skill
Upgrading by Japanese Manufacturing Firms." Journal of
International Economics, 58, 2002. 81-105.
Jabbour, L. "Outsourcing, Offshoring and Firm's
Performance: Evidence from the French Manufacturing Industry."
Working Paper, University of Paris, 2007.
Kasahara, H., and J. Rodrigue. "Does the Use of Imported
Intermediates Increase Productivity'? Plant-level Evidence."
Journal of Development Economics, 87(1), 2008, 106-18.
Katayama, H., S. Lu, and J. Tybout. "Firm-Level Productivity
Studies: Illusions and a Solution." International Journal of
Industrial Organization, 27(3), 2009, 403-13.
Keller, W. "Geographic Localization of International
Technology Diffusion." American Economic Review, 92, 2002a, 120-42.
--. "Knowledge Spillovers at the World's Technology
Frontier." Working Paper, University of Texas, Austin, 2002b.
Keller, W., and S. R. Yeaple. "Multinational Enterprises,
International Trade, and Productivity Growth: A Firm Level Evidence from
the United States." Brown University, Department of Economics,
Working Paper No. 2003-06, 2003.
El Khoury, A. C., and A. Savvides. "Openness in Services Trade
and Economic Growth." Economic Letters, 92(2), 2006, 277-83.
Kokko, A., R. Tansini, and M. Zejan. "Local Technological
Capability and Spillovers from FDI in the Uruguayan Manufacturing
Sector." Journal of Development Studies, 34, 1996, 602-11.
Kraay, A., I. Soloaga, and J. Tybout. "Product Quality,
Productive Efficiency, and International Technology Diffusion: Evidence
from Plant-Level Panel Data." World Bank Research Working Paper
Series No. WPS 2759, 2001.
Lopez, R. "Imports of Intermediate Inputs and Plant
Survival." Economics Letters, 92(1), 2006, 58-62.
Lopez, R., and N. Yadav. "Imports of Intermediate Inputs and
Spillover Effects: Evidence from Chilean Plants." Journal of
Development Studies, 46(8), 2009, 1385-1403.
Nelson, R., and E. Phelps. "Investment in Humans,
Technological Diffusion and Economic Growth." American Economic
Review, 56, 1966, 69-75.
Olley, G. S., and A. Pakes. "The Dynamics of Productivity in
the Telecommunications Equipment Industry." Econometrica, 64(6),
1996, 1263-97.
Papageorgion, C. "'Trade as a Threshold Variable for
Multiple Regimes." Economies Letters, 77, 2002, 85-91.
Pavcnik, N. "What Explains Skill Upgrading in Less Developed
Countries?" Journal of Development Economics, 71, 2003, 311-28.
Rodrik, D. "Institutions for High-Quality Growth: What They
Are and How to Acquire Them." Comparative International
Development, 35(3), 2000, 3-31.
--. "Industrial Development: Stylized Facts and
Policies." Working Paper, 2006. Available at
http://www.hks.harvard.edu/fs/drodrik/Research%20
Papers/industrial%20development.pdf.
Tan, H. W., and G. Batra. "Enterprise Training in Developing
Countries: Incidence, Productivity Effects, and Policy
Implications." Washington, DC, World Bank, 1995.
Van Biesebroeck, J. "'Exporting Raises Productivity in
SubSabaran African Manufacturing Firms." Journal of International
Economics, 67(2), 2005, 373-91.
Vogel, A., and J. Wagner. "Higher Productivity in Importing
German Manufacturing Firms: Self-Selection, Learning From Importing, or
Both?" Working Paper, University of Luneberg, Institute of
Economics, Working Paper No. 106, 2008.
Xu, B., and J. Wang. "Capital Goods Trade and R&D
Spillovers in the OECD." Canadian Journal of Economics, 32, 1999,
1258-74.
Yasar, M., and C. J. M. Paul. "International Linkages and
Productivity at the Plant Level: Foreign Direct Investment, Exports,
Imports and Licensing." Journal of International Economics, 72(1),
2007, 373-88.
Yasar, M., R. Raciborski, and B, Poi. "Production Function
Estimation in Stata Using the Olley and Pakes Method." The Stata
Journal, 8(2), 2008, 1-11.
(1.) See Keller (2002b) for a detailed discussion of international
technology diffusion.
(2.) Trade liberalization may also increase the firm's
productivity through the reallocation of resources across products
within firms (Bernard, Redding, and Schott 2006; Goldberg et al. 2009).
Our data do not allow us to study the relationship between importing and
changes in firms' product mix over time.
(3.) See Feenstra (1998) and Head and Ries (2002).
(4.) By developing a dynamic structural model, for instance, Aw,
Roberts, and Xu (2008, 2009) found significant interactions between
R&D, exporting, and productivity for exporting firms in the
Taiwanese electronics industry.
(5.) Absorptive capacity in this context means that firms in the
host country must have a certain proficiency level to use the imported
technology to enhance productivity.
(6.) In a more general context, it is now well established that
higher quality institutional arrangements are necessary for trade
liberalization to enhance countries' productivity and thus income
(Rodrik 2000, 2006).
(7.) Benhabib and Spiegel (1994) use country-level data to test the
Nelson-Phelps hypothesis and conclude that the flow rate of technology
spillovers from leaders to followers depends on human capital levels.
Cohen and Levinthal (1990) further show that the skills required to
benefit from knowledge spillovers are usually the same as those required
to create knowledge; benefiting from spillovers and creating knowledge
are closely related processes.
(8.) The literature on the productivity impact of foreign direct
investment (FDI) and exporting on domestic firms provides support for
these predictions. For example, using data on manufacturing firms in
Uruguay, Kokko, Tansini, and Zejan (1996) find that spillover
productivity effects are largest for host-country firms that have
sufficient human capital to effectively utilize the foreign technology.
Tan and Batra (1995) find that joint ventures with foreign companies can
also facilitate the transfer of technology because they are implemented
by foreign management and accompanied by training. Aw, Roberts, and
Winston (2007) find that a firm's investments in R&D and worker
training can bolster its ability to internalize the benefits associated
with the export market. See also Pavcnik (2003) and Bustos (2007) for
the significant relationship between trade and skill upgrading.
(9.) Although we use cross-section data, and thus most questions in
the survey obtain information from 2002, the input and sales variables
were available for the previous 2 years for some firms in the sample.
Thus, we also used a two-step approach, where we first estimate the
total factor productivity using both OLS and a semi-parametric technique
introduced by Olley and Pakes (1996), which allows us to control for
simultaneity bias when estimating a production function and thus obtain
consistent parameter estimates (Yasar, Raciborski, and Poi 2008). The
two-step approach produces similar results to those reported here.
(10.) We also estimated our model using a translog production
function, which allows for a full range of substitution among inputs and
thus captures differential productivity patterns for firms with
heterogeneous input composition. The coefficients for the variables of
interest were similar to those reported here.
(11.) We also used gross output formulation. The results were
consistent. For instance, the coefficient on the interaction term was
0.673 in the IV model, which was statistically significant at the 0.01
significance level.
(12.) We use two size dummies (representing small and medium firms
with less than 100 employees and large firms with 100 or more employees)
to capture differences in production technology across different size
firms.
(13.) One may reasonably argue that firms belonging to different
industries in the sample will use different imported capital that
embodies a different "kind of technology. To capture this
heterogeneity across the industries, we also interacted the industry
dummies with the import variable, but the coefficients on the interacted
terms were neither individually nor jointly significant. The results are
available upon request.
(14.) As shown by two recent influential papers, Katayama, Lu, and
Tybout (2009) and DeLoecker (2006), measured plant-level productivity
may confound true plant-level productivity and differences in mark-ups
across plants. The data on unit prices are not available, making it
impossible to tackle this issue at this point. Using concentration
ratios does not change the results (Amiti and Konings 2007).
(15.) We also interacted the import variable with the capital
input, the foreign ownership, and export variables, but the magnitude
and the significance of the variables of interest were similar to those
obtained without these interactions.
(16.) One may also expect the firms with high productivity to hire
more skilled labor. An omitted variable may result in increases in
skilled labor and productivity among importing firms. Thus, we also used
two sets of instruments for the skilled labor share to check the
robustness of the results. First, we used whether or not the firms have
a contractual relationship with universities or research institutions as
an instrument for the skilled labor share. We alternatively used the
average levels of the skilled labor share for other firms (j [not equal
to] i) in a firm's location category for each industry. The results
are consistent with those presented in this article, but the first
instrument is not strong enough.
(17.) Another way of controlling for the endogeneity is to jointly
estimate an import status equation with the production function
(Clerides, Lach, and Tybout 1998: Van Biesebroeck 2005). We tried this
also and obtained consistent results. However, as we are also interested
in the interaction of the import variable with the skilled labor share,
we do not report the results from this approach.
(18.) See Cameron and Trivedi (2005) for more detailed information.
(19.) To evaluate the correlation between the instruments and the
error term, we use the Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions. The
null hypothesis is that the instruments and the error terms are
independent, so failure to reject this hypothesis validates the use of
the instruments.
(20.) Similar instruments were used by Van Biesebroeck (2005) to
examine the relationship between exports and productivity for the sub
Saharan African manufacturing firms.
(21.) It is possible that any of these instruments may affect firm
productivity not only through import and its interaction with the skill
level of the firm but also through some other channels. Thus, to check
the sensitivity of the results to the specification of the instruments,
we alternatively used different sets of these four instruments, which
produce similar results. We alternatively added the averages of the
import variable for other firms (j [not equal to] i) in a firm's
location category for each industry and its interaction with the skilled
labor share to the instrument sets. The results are consistent with
those presented in this article.
(22.) To assess whether our instruments are sufficiently related to
the endogenous variable, we use an F-test of the joint significance of
the instruments in reduced form.
(23.) We estimate two reduced-form equations: one for the imported
capital input variable and one for the interaction of the imported
capital input with the skill share variable. We then obtain the fitted
values for imported capital input and its interaction with the skilled
labor share to form estimates of these two reduced-form equations,
replace the imported capital input and its interaction with skilled
labor share in the original model by its fitted values, and estimate the
resulting model by least squares.
(24.) See Hansen (2000) and Caner and Hansen (2004) for details.
(25.) Papageorgiou (2002) and Khoury and Savvides (2006) use this
method to examine the relationship between openness to trade and growth.
(26.) Because of convergence issues the region and industry dummies
are not included in the base model. We, however, included the region and
industry dummies that were not highly collinear with other variables in
the threshold model that allows an endogenous regressor. The resulting
threshold parameter estimate was 0.385, with a confidence interval of
[0.380, 0.413]. Thus, including these dummy variables does not change
the threshold parameter, but results in a narrower confidence interval.
(27.) We estimated the threshold models using the modified Gauss
programs written by Bruce Hansen, which are available at his website
http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/ ~bhansen/progs/progs.htm.
(28.) We also implemented a recently developed "heterogeneous
treatment effects" model, which allows for the treatment to vary
with the values of explanatory variables (see Wooldridge 2002, chapter
18). We estimated our model by interacting the import variable with the
demeaned skilled labor share to allow for the treatment effect to vary
with the skilled labor share. We used the predicted values from a first
stage logit model and the interaction of these predicted values with the
demeaned skilled labor share as instruments in the second stage. The
heterogenous effects are captured by the coefficient on the demeaned
interaction term. The results are consistent with those presented in
this article; the coefficient on the interaction term, the heterogenous
effects, was statistically significant at a 0.05 significance level, but
the coefficient on the import variable was insignificant.
(29.) None of the variables had VIFs greater than 10 and tolerance
levels less than 0.1, which are generally accepted thresholds to
identify multicollinearity problems. Thus, multicollinearity tests based
on variance inflation factors (VIFs) and tolerance levels (presented in
Table 2) illustrate that relying on the variables in Equation (1)is
justified.
(30.) The statistically significant estimates are identified by
asterisks: three asterisks mean statistical significance at the I%
level, two at the 5% level, and one at the 10% level.
(31.) For instance, 50th percentile indicates that 50% of the firms
had a skilled labor share of 23. 1% or less and 50% of the firms in the
sample had a skilled labor share equal to or higher than 23.1% of the
total employment.
(32.) Originally, we also included the exports and foreign direct
investment as explanatory variables in our model but it did not change
the results discussed here. The parameter estimate for exporting was not
statistically significant, but the coefficient on the foreign direct
investment variable indicated that the firms with foreign shares are
more productive.
(33.) One would expect that there are multiple thresholds for the
productive impact of importing across the skilled labor share
distribution. Thus, we searched for another sample split in the sample
of firms with skilled labor share above the first threshold. The second
sample split produced an insignificant p-value of 0.194 using 1,000
replications, indicating that there is no significant sample split. The
statistically insignificant threshold corresponds to a skilled labor
share of [??] = 0.540 with 95% confidence interval [0.444, 0.559].
(34.) The firms below and above the threshold value have similar
observable characteristics, indicating that the difference in the
outcome variable can be considered attributable to importing and
different level of skilled labor.
MAHMUT YASAR *
* I am indebted to the co-editor and an anonymous referee for their
constructive and useful suggestions, I wish to acknowledge helpful
comments by Gary Ferrier, Takao Kato, Fabio Mendel Kaz Miyagiwa,
Catherine J. Morrison Paul, Jigna Sampat, Zhizhong Shan, seminar
participants at the University of Arkansas, and participants at the
International Industrial Organization conference, North American
Productivity Workshop, and Southern Economic Association meetings on the
earlier version of the article. I also would like to thank the World
Bank Enterprise Surveys Staff for helpful discussions about the data.
Yasar: Assistant Professor of Economics, Department of Economics,
University of Texas, Arlington, 701 S. West Street, Arlington, TX 76019.
Phone 817-272-3290, Fax 817-272-3145, E-mail myasar@uta.edu;
Adjunct Assistant Professor of Economics, Emory University,
Department of Economics. Atlanta GA 30322.
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics (N = 1,161)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
Log value added of firm (In Y) 8.760 2.239
Log capital input (In K) 9.106 2.249
Log labor input (In L) 5.185 1.360
Whether or not firm imported any machinery
(IMP) (a) 0.334 0.472
Share of managers, engineers, and technical
workers in total employment (SH) (b) 0.270 0.171
Age of the firm (AGE) (c) 16.310 13.753
Capacity utilization (CU) (d) 72.112 24.146
Whether or not firm's products have been
certified by IS0900 certification (ISO) (e) 0.508 0.500
Whether or not the firm is a subsidiary or a
joint venture of a multinational firm (FO)
(f) 0.115 0.320
Whether or not the firm is an exporter in the
previous year (EXP) (g) 0.242 0.429
Whether or not the general manager is from an
industrialized country (MN) (h) 0.396 0.195
Percentage of firms owned by the state/
provincial government (SO) (i) 0.043 0.196
(a) In the survey, managers were asked whether they imported any
machinery. We use a dummy variable that is equal to I if firms
imported any machinery, and 0 otherwise.
(b) Share of managerial, engineering, and technical workers in total
employment.
(c) Managers were asked in what year their firm began operations.
(d) Capacity utilization is the amount of output actually produced
relative to the maximum amount that could be produced with existing
machinery and equipment and regular shifts.
(e) Managers were asked whether the firm's products have been
certified by IS0900 certification. We use a dummy variable that is
equal to 1 if the firm has a certified product, and 0 otherwise.
(f) Managers were asked whether the firm is a subsidiary or ajoint
venture of a multinational firm. We use a dummy variable that is
equal to 1 if firms have a foreign partner, and 0 otherwise.
(g) Mnnagers were asked what percent of sales are exported. We use a
dummy variable that is equal to I if firms reported positive shares,
and 0 otherwise.
(h) In the survey, managers were asked about the nationality of the
general manager. We use a dummy variable that is equal to I if firms
have a general manager who is from an industrialized country, and 0
otherwise.
(i) Managers were asked what percent of the firm is owned by the state
or provincial government.
TABLE 2
Tests of Multicollinearity: Variance Inflation
Factors (VIF) and Tolerance
Variable VIF Tolerance
In K 3.510 0.285
In L 4.900 0.204
IMP 4.390 0.228
SH 1.860 0.538
IMP x SH 4.250 0.235
AGE 4.000 0.250
[AGE.sup.2] 3.740 0.268
CU 1.180 0.849
ISO 1.470 0.682
Mean VIF 3.420
Note: The "rule of thumb" in the econometric literature
is that a VIF > 10 or a tolerance level < 0.1 is a sign of
a severe multicollinearity problem. Age variable is mean
adjusted.
TABLE 3
Parameter Estimates: Dependent
Variable = Natural Log of Value Added
Independent
Variables OLS Estimates IV Estimates
IMP -0.006 (0.146) 0.051 (0.283)
SH 0.918 (0.262) *** 0.721 (0.294) **
IMP x SH 0.885 (0.415) ** 1.449 (0.577) **
In K 0.355 (0.027) *** 0.3336 (0.033) ***
In L 0.706 (0.053) *** 0.708 (0.054) ***
AGE -0.022 (0.011) * -0.021 (0.011) *
[AGE.sup.2] 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000)
CU 0.015 (0.001) *** 0.015 (0.001) ***
ISO 0.278 (0.079) *** 0.258 (0.083) ***
Number of 1,161 1,161
observations
[R.sup.2] 0.759 0.758
Sargan test (p-value) 0.406
Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses.
* Significant at the 10% level, ** significant at the 5%
level, *** significant at the 1% level. The standard errors
clustered by industry and region are much smaller.
The regression run in this table includes dummy variables
that control for size, industry, and region characteristics.
However, they are not reported here in the interest of
space. They are available from the author upon request.
TABLE 4
Skilled Labor Share and Productive Impact Differential between
Importers and Non-importers
Productive Impact Productive Impact
Percentiles of Share of Managers, Differential: Differential:
Engineers and Technicians in Between Importers Between Importers
Total Employment and Non- and Non-
importers (Based importers (Based
on OLS Results) on IV Results)
1th percentile of SH = 0.036 0.026 (0.134) 0.103 (0.271)
10th percentile of SH = 0.092 0.076 (0.117) 0.184 (0.256)
20th percentile of SH = 0.132 0.111 (0.107) 0.243 (0.248)
30th percentile of SH = 0.169 0.144 (0.098) 0.296 (0.241)
40th percentile of SH = 0.200 0.171 (0.093) * 0.341 (0.237)
50th percentile of SH = 0.231 0.199 (0.089) *** 0.387 (0.235) *
60th percentile of SH = 0.271 0.234 (0.086) *** 0.444 (0.233) *
70th percentile of SH = 0.310 0.269 (0.087) *** 0.501 (0.234) **
80th percentile of SH = 0.378 0.329 (0.095) *** 0.599 (0.241) ***
90th percentile of SH = 0.500 0.437 (0.125) *** 0.776 (0.267) ***
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, which are obtained by
using the Delta Method.
* Significant at the 10% level, ** significant at the 5% level, ***
significant at the 1% level.
TABLE 5
IV Threshold Model Statistics
Statistics TR Model IV TR Model 2
Threshold value (y) 0.427 0.380
95% confidence interval--White [0.289, 0.466]
correction for
heteroskedasticity
Confidence interval-- [0.289, 0.443]
heteroskedasticity is
corrected by using quadratic
variance estimate
Confidence interval-- [0.289, 0.444]
heteroskedasticity is
corrected by using
nonparametric kernel
LM-test for no threshold 24.512
LM-test for no threshold 0.041
(p-value)
[[??].sub.1] 0.162 (0.093) *
[[??].sub.2] 0.499 (0.190) ***
Number of observations 1,161 1,161
Number of observations with a 996 936
SH < y
Number of observations with a 165 225
SH > y
* Significant at the 10% level, ** significant at the 5% level, ***
significant at the I%n level.