Do real estate brokers add value when listing services are unbundled?
Bernheim, B. Douglas ; Meer, Jonathan
I. INTRODUCTION
Real estate brokers typically provide sellers with bundles of
services, most of which are ostensibly aimed at improving the terms at
which homes are sold and helping homeowners find buyers more quickly.
(1) Traditionally, access to the multiple listing service (MLS), a
pooled database of homes for sale that is owned and operated by an
association of local real estate brokers, has been an important
component of that bundle. Other components of the traditional brokerage
bundle that potentially affect the terms and timing of a sale include
market information and recommendations pertaining to the appropriate
asking price, (2) promotional services (preparing a home for sale,
circulating flyers, placing advertisements, holding open houses, and
recommending the home to individual buyers), the screening of
prospective buyers, the facilitation and acceleration of matches between
buyers and sellers, (3) and assistance with negotiations. (4)
The object of this paper is to measure the effects of real estate
brokerage services provided to sellers, other than MLS listings, on the
terms and timing of home sales. It is not obvious that sellers benefit
from those services. On the one hand, brokers offer potentially useful
knowledge and expertise. On the other hand, because the relationship
between the homeowner and the broker resembles a classical
principal-agent problem, the broker may not deploy services in ways that
promote the seller's interests. While appropriately structured
compensation schemes may alleviate the principal-agent problem to some
degree (see, e.g., the recent survey by Miceli, Pancak, and Sirmans,
2007), significant conflicts remain. As Levitt and Syverson (2008)
emphasize, an agent "has strong incentives to sell the house
quickly, even at a substantially lower price." Their empirical
analysis shows that homes owned by agents sell for nearly 4% more and
stay on the market roughly 9 days longer than other comparable houses.
Similarly, Rutherford, Springer, and Yavas (2005) find that "real
estate agents receive a premium of 3.0%-7.0% when selling their own
condominiums in comparison to similar client owned condominiums" by
waiting longer to sell. (5) While those studies shed light on the
magnitude of agency costs (i.e., the extent to which the deployment of
brokerage services departs from the first-best), they do not tell us how
those costs compare to the benefits flowing from a broker's
knowledge and expertise. Consequently, they do not answer the question
posed at the outset of this paragraph.
The importance of the question addressed in this paper is most
readily apparent within the context of the recent policy debate over
service bundling in real estate brokerage. As long as valuable MLS
listings are bundled with brokerage services, homeowners may use brokers
even if the agency costs exceed the benefits of brokers' knowledge
and expertise. In that case, unbundling would benefit homeowners and
promote efficiency. In practice, a small but growing number of brokers
now offer to place clients' homes in the MLS for a fixed fee. (6)
Yet in many jurisdictions established brokers have resisted pressures to
unbundle MLS listings from other services. In some cases, they have
pressed for "minimum service" laws that prevent agents from
offering MLS-only options. As of 2007, eight states had such laws in
place. (7) Some states have also adopted licensing requirements that
impede the entry of non-traditional real estate brokers. Where such laws
are not in force, some MLSs have adopted their own rules and procedures
to prevent or at least discourage unbundling. (8) Though the Internet increasingly provides alternatives to MLS databases (at least in some
jurisdictions), the U.S. Federal Trade Commission observed as recently
as November 2009 that "[t]he MLS is generally acknowledged to be a
superior platform for matching home buyers and sellers." (9) Thus,
the practice of bundling MLS listings with other real estate brokerage
services handicaps homeowners who wish to sell their homes either
completely independently ("for sale by owner" or FSBO transactions) or without the ancillary services of a listing broker. As
a result, that practice has become the subject of debate, litigation,
and legislative action. Both the Federal Trade Commission and the
Department of Justice have taken active roles in challenging the
practice and the laws that support it. (10) They argue that bundling
reduces competition from non-traditional channels of home sales, and
essentially compels many homeowners to purchase unwanted services (other
than MLS listings).
The task of quantifying the separate impact of brokerage services
provided to sellers, other than MLS listings, is challenging precisely
because bundling has been so prevalent. Although a number of previous
studies have examined the impact of real estate brokerage, (11) they
generally make no attempt to separate the effects of MLS listings from
those of other services. For example, Hendel, Nevo, and Ortalo-Magne
(2009) compare sales of MLS-listed homes sold through traditional
full-service brokers to sales of homes listed on a web-based FSBO
service. Their analysis is noteworthy because their data set is
reasonably large, contains many FSBO transactions, and spans a 7-year
period, which allows them to control for both home and household fixed
effects. (12) However, analyses of that type inherently cannot reveal
the separate effects of non-MLS brokerage services. (13) The policy
question calls instead for a comparison between MLS-listed homes sold
through full-service brokers, and MLS-listed FSBOs. Notably, the working
paper version of the Hendel, Nevo, and Ortalo-Magne study mentions that
the relative scarcity of listings by limited-service brokers as of
year-end 2004 precluded an analysis of MLS-only versus full-service
listings.
The analysis of Johnson, Springer, and Brockman (2005) attempts to
speak more directly to the question that motivates our study, in that
they compare the selling prices of MLS-listed homes and
"non-traditional" broker-marketed homes that were not listed
in the MLS. On its face, such a comparison would appear to reveal the
separate value of an MLS listing. However, it is not clear whether
brokerage contracts are otherwise similar for MLS-listed and
non-MLS-listed homes; hence, measured differences in sales prices may
reflect a combination of effects. It is also readily apparent that the
non-traditional transactions, which represent less than 5% of their
sample, constitute a highly selected subsample, and the authors'
cross-sectional regressions make no allowance for the likely selectivity bias. Thus, the proper interpretation of the study's central
finding--that selling prices for brokered homes are 6% higher when the
home is not MLS-listed--is obscure.
In this paper, we estimate the effect of a seller's decision
to use a broker on list prices, selling prices, and speed of sale for a
real estate market with an unusual and critical characteristic: it has a
single open-access listing service that is used by essentially all
sellers, regardless of whether they employ brokers. (14) The market
consists of roughly 800 houses and condominiums located in a collection
of largely contiguous neighborhoods on Stanford University land. Because
ownership of the homes is limited to Stanford faculty and some senior
staff, (15) the MLS plays no role. Instead, the Faculty Staff Housing
(FSH) Office maintains a free listing service, so that listings are
inherently unbundled from brokerage services. As in other markets,
brokers are compensated through standard commissions (historically in
the range of 5% to 6%), so the usual principal-agent problems are
present. Consequently, by analyzing this market, we can identify the
separate effects of brokerage services other than MLS listings.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Studying Stanford University housing offers several additional
advantages. We have data on all home sales over a 27-year period, during
which the quality of the neighborhoods remained approximately constant
due to the special nature of the market. The data also span a major
regime shift: brokered transactions were relatively rare during the
1980s but became increasingly common during the 1990s and have accounted
for roughly half of all sales in recent years (Figure 1). As a result,
neither FSBO nor brokered transactions are exceptional. There is
anecdotal evidence that this transition was driven by the aggressive
marketing efforts of several realtors rather than by a shift in
sellers' preferences. Because the data cover a relatively long time
period, they include multiple transactions not only for the same home,
but also for the same party. In many cases, the pertinent transactions
span the regime shift. Therefore, we are able to assess whether
correlations between the use of a broker and the terms or timing of a
sale reflect spurious relationships with unobserved characteristics of
sellers or their homes, and to purge our estimates of such effects.
Concerns about unobserved heterogeneity are also ameliorated to some
extent by the fact that the population of buyers and sellers is
relatively homogeneous, at least in comparison with the general
population.
Overall, there is a strong positive correlation between selling
prices and the seller's use of a broker. However, that correlation
reflects a selection effect: homes with value-enhancing characteristics
(e.g., greater size) are more likely to sell through brokers. Because
brokers earn more from the sale of more valuable homes, that pattern may
reflect targeted efforts to obtain valuable listings. When one
conditions on the observed features of a home (by running a regression),
the correlation essentially vanishes. To control in addition for the
unobserved features of a home, we add home fixed effects, and in some
specifications we also allow for the possibility that prices may have
changed over time at different rates in different market segments (e.g.,
that the prices of high-end homes, which are more frequently sold
through brokers, may have risen or fallen relative to those of low-end
homes). Based on these preferred specifications, we conclude that a
seller's use of a broker in this setting reduces the selling price
of the typical home by 5.9% to 7.7% (based on point estimates), which
indicates that agency costs exceed the advantages of brokers'
knowledge and expertise by a wide margin. In all of these
specifications, we reject the hypothesis that the broker effect equals 0
at a high level of confidence. (16) Separately, we find no evidence that
the lower prices received by sellers who use brokers are attributable to
correlations with unobserved household characteristics such as
preferences or negotiation skills. Our analysis also suggests that a
seller's use of a broker may reduce the initial asking price and
accelerate the sale, but those findings are supported with less
statistical confidence.
Why do sellers use brokers if doing so reduces a home's
selling price? One possibility is that sellers place sufficient value on
convenience or the speed of sale. Given the magnitude of the measured
effect plus the broker's commission (which total nearly $100,000
for the average home in our sample), we doubt that this explanation is
valid. Another possibility is that sellers are poorly informed about the
effects of brokers' services. There is some anecdotal support for
that view. An earlier version of this paper was provided to the FSH
Office in late 2006 and circulated among homeowners. As seen in Figure
1, the fraction of sellers using brokers plummeted from 59.5% in 2006 to
only 28.6% in 2007.
As with all studies that focus on usefully unusual settings, there
is a question of generalizability and external validity. While we would
not suggest that our numerical estimates can be applied directly to the
general population, there are nevertheless good reasons to think that
the Stanford housing market provides a valid laboratory for studying the
effects of interest. We discuss that issue at some length in Section II.
While we do not claim that the setting is perfectly representative, it
is nevertheless worth studying because it allows us to provide the only
available estimates of sellers' net benefits from using brokers
when listing services are unbundled, thereby informing an important
policy question (concerning the effects of bundling of MLS listings with
other brokerage services).
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section II
describes the setting and our data, and addresses the issue of
representativeness. Sections III, IV, and V evaluate the effects of a
seller's broker on, respectively, selling prices, initial asking
prices, and time to sale. Section VI describes some sensitivity analyses
and Section VII concludes.
II. SETTING AND DATA
The data used in this paper were generously provided by Stanford
University's FSH Office. Sales data and certain home
characteristics are available as far back as the 1940s, but information
relating to the use of brokers is available only through monthly sales
circulars distributed by the FSH office, which are archived back to
January 1980. We infer the use of a broker from the contact information
provided in the housing listings. Altogether, 1,064 sales were recorded
between January 1980 and January 2008, of which 794 appear in the sales
circulars. This discrepancy is attributable primarily to two factors:
some sales involved land used for new construction, and some were sold
off-market without being listed. We dropped 20 observations with
incomplete data for purchase price, construction date, or home
characteristics. We also dropped 19 observations listing Stanford
University as the buyer or seller; including those observations does not
significantly alter our results, but their prices appear to be atypical.
(17) These exclusions leave us with 755 observations, of which 133
involved brokers. (18) Some homes were removed from the FSH listings
prior to a sale, only to reappear in subsequent listings, most within 1
year. If the home reappeared in the listings within 36 months of
withdrawal, we treated it as having remained on the market since its
initial listing. Roughly a dozen homes were relisted after 36 months; we
treated those as new listings.
Other variables used in our analysis measure characteristics of the
property, including the number of bedrooms and bathrooms, site acreage,
square footage, dummies indicating the presence of a study or a pool,
the age of the home at the time of sale (calculated using its date of
construction), and neighborhood indicators. (19) We include a dummy
variable indicating sales through estates, as well as year dummies to
account for variations in market conditions. In some specifications, we
also control for the length of time the seller had lived in the home at
the time of sale. (20) That variable presumably proxies for the
seller's age or attachment to the home, and possibly for the
condition of the property. Its use further limits our sample to 691
transactions, of which 129 involved a broker. Generally, our results are
robust with respect to the combination of variables used.
We also have some information on the characteristics of the buyers
and sellers. We were able to determine the ages of 585 sellers and 720
buyers, as well as the academic department affiliation for 625 sellers
and 739 buyers. We do not observe directly whether buyers were
represented by brokers. (21)
Table 1 reports summary statistics. Figure 1 shows the fraction of
sellers using a broker by year. Notice that the proportion of brokered
transactions remained quite low through the 1980s and early 1990s, but
rose steadily from 1996 through 2006, at which point it hit 59.5%. It
then fell sharply once the first version of this paper was circulated.
The relatively small size of our data sample (788 usable observations out of 1,064 total transactions) is a potential concern,
and to some degree it limits our investigation. For example, we could
not successfully estimate a model with buyer or seller fixed effects.
Even so, we were able to evaluate the potential importance of household
heterogeneity diagnostically, and our sample is sufficiently large to
generate reasonably precise estimates for the specifications we do
present.
Before turning our attention to estimates, it is important to
discuss the representativeness of the setting. Given the focus of our
study, the critical question is whether the setting is representative in
terms of the magnitudes of agency costs on the one hand, and the
benefits of brokers' knowledge and expertise on the other. While
acknowledging that homeowners in our sample are well educated and
affluent relative to the general population, we see no reason to think
that this group is either particularly susceptible or resistant to
agency problems, conditional upon socioeconomic status. The real
question is whether there are special features of Stanford housing
transactions that limit the benefits of using a broker.
If the residential section of the Stanford campus constituted a
small, insular housing market, there might well be legitimate cause for
concern. However, there is in fact a high degree of fluidity between
on-campus and off-campus housing. A substantial fraction of faculty
members choose to live off-campus in surrounding communities, and the
prices of on-campus housing have historically tracked off-campus prices.
Thus, Stanford housing is more properly viewed as a neighborhood than as
a market.
Another possible concern is that the benefits of brokerage services
aimed at finding and screening potential buyers are abnormally low on
the Stanford campus due to the fact that the set of eligible purchasers
is relatively small. Here it is important to distinguish between the
services provided by buyers' agents and sellers' agents, and
to note that buyers' brokers are the ones who generally provide the
services in question. While it is true that the benefits of services
provided by buyers' brokers are likely much smaller on the Stanford
campus than in the typical residential real estate market, it is also
true that unbundling MLS listings in the latter markets would not
deprive FSBO sellers of those benefits. With unbundled MLS listings, an
FSBO seller would still be free to offer buyers' agents the same
commissions they currently receive for locating and prescreening
successful buyers. Accordingly, while this second concern identifies a
dimension along which Stanford housing transactions are somewhat
atypical, it is not a dimension that renders the effect of using a
seller's broker unrepresentative of markets with unbundled listing
services.
A third possible concern is that the benefits of a brokers'
knowledge of the market may be abnormally low on the Stanford campus.
This concern would be valid if homeowners on the Stanford campus had
access to better information about recent comparable transactions than
sellers in typical residential real estate markets. In fact, during the
relevant time period local papers in surrounding communities published
essentially the same information concerning listings and transactions
that was available through the Stanford FSH Office (and such information
has become even more accessible with the emergence of Web sites such as
zillow.com and redfin.com). There is also no reason to think that
Stanford homeowners have greater personal knowledge of transactions
involving nearby homes than homeowners in any other neighborhood.
Finally, even if homeowners in typical markets were less informed than
Stanford homeowners, they could easily erase that gap at relatively low
cost by engaging professional appraisers. Thus, the extent to which our
estimates understate the net benefits of using a seller's broker as
a consequence of this particular concern is bounded by the typical
appraisal fee.
A fourth possible concern is that the benefits of using a
sellers' broker may be abnormally low on the Stanford campus
because, for historical reasons, there is no stigma associated with FSBO
sales. In our view, this consideration constitutes a virtue of studying
Stanford housing transactions rather than a concern. The stigma
associated with FSBO transactions in typical markets is an artifact of
the conditions that have rendered those transactions so uncommon. To the
extent the unbundling of MLS services render FSBO transactions more
viable, one would expect that stigma to dissipate over time. The
Stanford experience provides a rare window through which one can observe
and compare FSBO and brokered outcomes when the two home-selling
strategies have been allowed to operate on a more equal institutional
footing for a significant period of time.
We close our discussion of representativeness by noting that, in
our sample, the unconditional average selling price is 43% higher for
homes sold through brokers than for FSBO homes. (22) That figure lines
up remarkably well with the national average. According to the National
Association of Realtors (2002), the median selling price of homes sold
through brokers is 37% higher than that of FSBO homes.
III. SELLING PRICES
First we examine the relationship between the log selling price and
the use of a broker. Table 2 contains OLS regression results, reported
with robust standard errors, clustered at the home level. Specification
(1)includes only a broker dummy and year effects. The coefficient of the
broker dummy (0.357) implies that brokered homes sold for approximately
43% more on average than homes sold without brokers. The difference is
highly statistically significant, with a t-statistic of more than 5.
Naturally, the broker coefficient in specification (1) tells us
nothing about the effect of using a broker on a home's selling
price. As a first step toward measuring that effect, we control for the
characteristics of a home that are correlated both with the home's
value and with the likelihood that it is listed through a broker.
Specification (2) adds the home characteristics discussed in Section II,
as well as dummy variables for eight Stanford neighborhoods. Notice that
the coefficient of the broker dummy drops to 0.0009 with a standard
error of 0.0232; it is both economically negligible and statistically
indistinguishable from zero. Anecdotal evidence suggests that the usual
commission in the Stanford housing market has fallen over time from 6%
to 5%; to cover even a 5% commission, the use of a broker would need to
increase a home's selling price by 5.26%, which corresponds to a
broker coefficient of 0.0513. Notably, we can confidently reject the
hypothesis that the broker coefficient equals 0.0513 (p = .030). Other
coefficients generally have the expected sign.
Specification (3) adds a measure of the length of time the seller
had lived in the home prior to listing it for sale (as well as its
square). Adding this variable reduces the size of our sample from 755 to
691. The broker coefficient rises a bit to 0.0203, with a standard error
of 0.0238. The measured effect is now larger economically, but still
less than half of the standard broker's commission, and it remains
statistically indistinguishable from zero at conventional levels of
confidence. We can no longer reject the hypothesis that the coefficient
is 0.0513 at conventional levels of confidence (here, the p value is
0.194); consequently, on the basis of this estimate, we cannot rule out
the possibility that brokers pay for themselves. The difference between
the broker coefficient in specifications (2)and (3)is partly
attributable to the smaller sample size.
In interpreting our estimates of specifications (2) and (3), one
should bear in mind that the use of a broker may be correlated with
unobserved factors that influence transactions prices. Such factors fall
into two main categories: characteristics of the home and
characteristics of the seller. We experimented with a number of
potential instruments, including the recent incidence of brokered sales
within a home's neighborhood and among members of the seller's
academic division. Unfortunately, none of the instruments we examined
had a great deal of explanatory power. As a result, the associated IV
estimates were imprecise and unstable. One instrument did have
explanatory power in the first stage: the use of a particular university
loan program that incidentally subsidized brokers' commissions upon
sale in certain situations. The second-stage point estimates of the key
parameter were consistent with those reported in Table 2, but the
standard errors were large. We were therefore compelled to address these
concerns through different methods.
A. Unobserved Characteristics of Homes
Many aspects of home quality are, of course, observable to sellers,
buyers, and brokers, but unobservable to us. The sharp contrast between
the broker coefficients in specifications (1) and (2) indicates that the
use of a broker is positively correlated with observed characteristics
that enhance a home's value. For example, larger homes are more
likely to sell through brokers than smaller homes. Since brokers earn
more from the sale of more valuable homes, this pattern is consistent
with their incentives, and may reflect targeted efforts to obtain
valuable listings. If the same pattern holds for unobserved
characteristics that contribute to a home's value, then
specifications (2) and (3) will tend to overstate the effect of using a
broker on a home's selling price.
Many of the relevant unobserved characteristics of a
home--location, views, architectural style, and so forth--remain
reasonably stable over time. In specification (4), we immunize our
estimates against the influence of such unobserved characteristics by
including home fixed effects. This strategy is feasible because our
sample period covers a reasonably long period of time (27 years), during
which many homes were sold multiple times. Our 755 observations pertain
to 466 separate homes. Of those, 277 were sold once during our sample
period, 116 were sold twice, 51 were sold three times, and 22 were sold
four or more times. In total, there are 478 observations on the 189
homes that were sold multiple times. Due to the regime shift that
occurred during the 1990s, virtually all of the early sales occurred
without brokers, while the later sales were fairly evenly split between
brokered transactions and FSBOs (Figure 1). Therefore, the sample
provides good opportunities to, in effect, compare the changes in
selling prices for homes that transitioned from FSBO to brokers with the
changes in selling prices for homes that remained FSBOs.
With home fixed effects included (specification (4)in Table 2), the
broker coefficient falls to -0.0603 with a standard error of 0.036
(implying a price impact of -5.9%). The measured effect is now negative
and significantly different from zero at the 90% confidence level (p =
.096), consistent with the hypothesis that brokers have incentives to
expedite sales, even at a lower price. We also decisively reject the
hypothesis that the brokers pay for themselves, that is, that broker
coefficient equals 0.0513. Notice that for this specification, many of
the other control variables are absorbed into the home fixed effect.
(23)
Specifications (1) through (4) do not allow for the possibility
that the prices of different types of homes may evolve differently over
time. If, for example, the prices of high-end homes were falling
(rising) over time relative to those of low-end homes (as a result of,
say, shifts in the distribution of income), then the observed
concentration of brokered sales among high-end homes during the latter
portion of our sample period would imply that the broker coefficient is
biased downward (upward). To examine this possibility, we estimated a
probit regression explaining the likelihood that the seller used a
broker as a function of all time-invariant home characteristics plus
year dummies. We used the estimated equation to compute fitted
probabilities (propensity scores) for each home in a fixed year (2000).
Finally, we re-estimated specification (4), adding interactions between
this propensity score and each of the year dummies (specification (5) in
Table 2). This specification allows for the possibility that the prices
of the types of homes sold through brokers evolved differently over time
than the prices of the types of homes sold without brokers, and it
places minimal structure on the manner in which those paths differed. To
account for the fact that propensity scores are estimated, we bootstrap the standard errors.
The coefficients of the year-propensity interaction terms (not
shown in the table) exhibit a general tendency to rise over time, which
implies that the coefficient of the broker indicator in specification
(4) is likely biased upward. Indeed, the coefficient of the broker
indicator in specification (5)is -0.0782, implying a price impact of
-7.5%. The negative price effect is even larger (in absolute value) than
the corresponding effect in specification (4), and it is significantly
different from zero at a higher level of confidence (p = .0361).
Specification (6) is the same as (5), except that we also control for
the amount of time the owner lived in the home (by adding linear and
quadratic terms), which as before reduces our sample size. The
coefficient of the broker indicator changes only slightly to 0.0796,
implying a price impact of -7.7%. We reject the hypothesis that the
coefficient is equal to zero at a similar level of confidence (p =
.035). Variants of specifications (5)and (6) that use propensity scores
constructed from estimates of a simple linear probability model rather
than a probit regression yield similar results.
The disadvantage of using a fitted propensity score is that it
introduces additional estimation error and thereby reduces precision. An
alternative is to allow for differential time trends by interacting the
year dummies with a single aspect of home quality. Typically, that
strategy does indeed yield sharper estimates, and we reject the
hypothesis that the broker coefficient is equal to zero at an even
higher level of confidence. Focusing on specification (6), the broker
coefficient is -0.0573 (SE = 0.0244, p = .019) when we use square feet
as our measure of home quality, -0.1032 (SE = 0.0276, p = .000) when we
use acreage, and -0.0723 (SE = 0.0333, p = 0.029) when we use the number
of bedrooms.
The possibility remains that the quality of a given home may have
varied over time, and that short-term variations in quality may be
correlated with the use of a broker. We have seen, however, that brokers
tend to sell higher quality homes, and that as a result improvements in
our controls for quality tend to reduce the broker coefficient.
Consequently, it would appear unlikely that such considerations explain
why the measured effect is negative.
B. Unobserved Characteristics of Sellers
Each seller chooses whether to engage a broker. Consequently, the
use of a broker may be correlated with unobserved characteristics of the
seller that influence the selling price. Conceptually, the direction of
the resulting bias is unclear. A seller who is more concerned about his
net yield (and who is therefore more likely to obtain a higher price
with or without a broker) may be either more or less likely to use a
broker, depending on whether he finds brokers' claims credible. A
seller who has more confidence in his own negotiating abilities may be
less likely to use a broker, as well as more likely to obtain a higher
price, unless his confidence is unwarranted. (24)
If unobserved seller characteristics are reasonably stable over
time, then it would be possible in principle to remove their influence
by including seller fixed effects. Unfortunately, only 166 observations
in our sample involved sellers who sold at least one other home. After
controlling for seller fixed effects and home characteristics, too few
degrees of freedom remain to measure the broker coefficient with useful
precision.
The available data do, however, permit us to conduct an informative
diagnostic investigation of seller heterogeneity. First we examine
correlations between fitted residuals across observations involving the
same household. If unobserved heterogeneity manifests itself in the form
of household fixed effects (e.g., some individual is a particularly
effective negotiator or consistently more sensitive to price), we would
expect to observe a strong positive correlation between the residuals
for pairs of observations where the same household is on the same side
of both transactions (i.e., it is the buyer in both instances or the
seller in both instances), and a strong negative correlation between the
residuals for pairs of observations where the same household is on
opposite sides of the two transactions (i.e., the buyer in one instance
and the seller in the other). Based on specification (2) in Table 2, we
find that residuals are effectively uncorrelated across pairs of
observations where the same household is the buyer in both instances
([rho] = 0.033, SE = 0.103, N = 65), negatively correlated across pairs
of observations where the same household is the seller in both instances
([rho] = -0.112, SE = 0.090, N = 76), and positively correlated across
pairs of observations where the same household is the seller in one
instance and the buyer in the other ([rho] = 0.078, SE = 0.074, N =
136). (25) Thus, there is no evidence that selling prices depend on
persistent household heterogeneity.
The possibility remains that a household's decision to use a
broker may be spuriously related to transitory changes in its economic
status or preferences. For example, if the inclination to engage a
broker is negatively correlated with the inclination to negotiate
aggressively (e.g., because short-term financial pressure reduces the
first inclination and enhances the second), then the estimates of
brokers' effects on selling prices in Table 2 are presumably biased
downward.
To investigate that possibility, we ask whether sellers who use
brokers obtain better terms when acting as buyers than sellers who do
not use brokers. In our sample, we have 125 observations (the
"paired buyer sample") for which the buyer is a seller in some
other paired observation (the "paired seller sample"). Of the
125 transactions in the paired seller sample, 108 did not involve
brokers while 17 did. While the latter group is quite small, it provides
a meaningful basis for some comparisons. Notably, more than 61% of the
buyer/seller observation pairs (77 of 125) involve transactions
separated by less than 12 months. Typically, these are cases in which a
household moved from one campus home to another. Presumably, any
factor--whether permanent or transitory--that enhances a
household's proclivity to negotiate aggressively when acting as a
seller creates a similar proclivity when the household acts as a buyer
in a roughly contemporaneous transaction.
To gauge the buyer's success at negotiating the terms of each
deal, we compute the discount received from the (log) asking price; that
is,
Discount = log(asking price) - log(selling price).
Our strategy is to compare the magnitudes of discounts across the
following three groups:
Group A: the observation belongs to the paired buyer sample and the
buyer used a broker when acting as a seller in the paired seller
observation
Group B: the observation belongs to the paired buyer sample and the
buyer did not use a broker when acting as a seller in the paired seller
observation
Group C: the observation does not belong to the paired buyer sample
If those who use brokers are more aggressive or effective
negotiators than those who do not, we should observe the largest
discounts on average in Group A, the second largest in Group C (which is
not selected based on broker usage), and the smallest in Group B. If
those who use brokers are less aggressive or effective negotiators than
those who do not, that ranking should be reversed.
Using our full sample, we regress the discount on two dummy
variables, one for Group A observations and the other for Group C
observations, as well as year and home fixed effects (to control for the
likely possibility that discounts vary systematically over time and
across types of homes). (26) The estimated value of Group A coefficient
is 0.0227 (SE = 0.0275). The point estimate implies that the types of
households who employ brokers when acting as sellers tend to be more
aggressive and effective negotiators when acting as buyers than those
who do not. The estimated value of Group C coefficient is 0.000589 (SE =
0.0181). The point estimate indicates that, when acting as buyers,
households who do not employ brokers in other transactions where they
act as sellers tend to be slightly less effective negotiators than Group
C households, who are not selected based on whether they used brokers in
other transactions where they sold campus homes. Thus, Group A receives
the largest discounts on average, Group C the second largest, and Group
B the smallest by a slim margin, but the differences are extremely small
and statistically significant.
We also estimate a second specification in which we control for the
home's initial asking price (in logs) in addition to all the
aforementioned variables. The asking price potentially acts as a proxy
for considerations that may systematically influence the discount the
buyer receives, such as transitory elements of home quality that are not
subsumed by the fixed effect, or the degree to which the property is
overpriced. With this variable added, the estimated value of Group A
coefficient is -0.00692 (SE = 0.0311), while the estimated value of
Group C coefficient is -0.00569 (SE = 0.0171). Thus, from this
specification it appears that Group B receives the largest discounts on
average, Group C the second largest, and Group A the smallest, but the
differences are tiny both economically and statistically.
We see no basis in these results for an inference that those who
use brokers are significantly less aggressive or effective negotiators
than those who do not, and hence no grounds for concern that the
estimates of broker effects in Table 2 are biased downward. While we
acknowledge that our ability to draw definitive conclusions is limited
by small group sizes (particularly for Group A), which reduces
precision, we note that the 95% confidence interval for the negotiating
efficacy differential between Groups A and B does not contain
differentials large enough to offset the estimated broker effects from
specifications (5) or (6) in Table 2.
IV. INITIAL ASKING PRICES
In this section, we examine the possibility that brokers influence
transaction prices in part by encouraging sellers to set lower initial
asking prices. We estimate the same six specifications as in Table 2,
except that we use the log of the initial asking price as the dependent
variable. Results appear in Table 3. Not surprisingly, specification
(1), which includes only a broker dummy and year effects, indicates that
initial asking prices tend to be significantly higher for homes that are
sold through brokers than for those that are not. Specification (2)
controls for the home characteristics discussed in Section II, as well
as for neighborhood effects. Notice that the coefficient of the broker
dummy becomes negative (-0.0265, SE = 0.0219). Although the point
estimate is economically significant, we cannot rule out the possibility
that the true effect is zero. The addition of controls for the length of
time the seller has lived in the home (specification (3), which is based
on a smaller sample) moves the coefficient toward 0 (-0.00760, SE =
0.0238). However, with home fixed effects (specification (4)), the
broker coefficient becomes considerably more negative and significant,
both economically and statistically (-0.0614, SE = 0.0325). Adding
interactions between the brokerage propensity score and the year dummies
(specification (5)) does not noticeably alter that finding: the broker
coefficient falls slightly to -0.0639 (SE = 0.0338). For specifications
(4) and (5), the coefficient is significantly different from 0 at
roughly the 94% level of confidence. However, adding controls for the
seller's tenure in the home on top of the interaction terms
(specification (6), also based on a smaller sample) moderates the
measured effect (-0.0401, SE = 0.0320). Notably, the size of the
estimated effects on initial asking price and sale price are roughly
comparable in most specifications. Although the estimates are not
sufficiently precise to permit a definitive inference, they suggest that
much of the effect of brokers on selling prices may reflect their
influence on asking prices.
V. TIME ON THE MARKET
Does the use of a broker lead the homeowner to sell his or her home
more quickly? To address this question, we estimate the same six
specifications as Tables 2 and 3, except that we use the log of the
amount of time on the market (between initial listing and sale) as the
dependent variable. Results appear in Table 4. In specification (1),
which controls only for year effects, the coefficient of the broker
dummy is -0.192 (SE = 0.081), which implies that brokered homes sell
17.5% faster than homes that are not brokered. That difference is
significant both economically and statistically. Adding controls for
home characteristics and Stanford neighborhoods has a relatively minor
effect on the estimated coefficient (-0.168) and its standard error
(0.088). When we add controls for the seller's tenure in the home,
we find that brokered homes sell about 19% faster than homes that are
not brokered (the coefficient of the broker dummy is -0.211, and its
standard deviation is 0.093); evaluated at the mean of our sample, this
finding implies that brokered homes are sold nearly 1.9 months more
quickly than non-brokered homes. However, with home fixed effects, the
measured effect is much smaller--only 5.7% (the coefficient is
-0.0651)--and no longer statistically significant (the standard
deviation is 0.112). Adding interactions between the brokerage
propensity score and the year dummies (specification (5)) weakens the
effect further: the broker coefficient falls to -0.0448 (SE = 0.134).
However, adding controls for the seller's tenure in the home on top
of the interaction terms (specification (6), also based on a smaller
sample) restores the effect, albeit at a reduced level of statistical
significance (-0.191, SE = 0.142).
When the homeowner is a reluctant seller, a home can remain on the
market for an extended period of time. Such sellers may also be
disinclined to use brokers, who they know will seek quick sales. The
effects discussed in the previous paragraph are not, however,
attributable to such considerations. For example, when the sample is
limited to homes selling within 12 months (n = 595), the coefficient of
the broker dummy in specification (2) remains reasonably similar: -0.183
(SE = 0.067). Further limiting the sample to those selling within 6
months (n = 463) yields a coefficient of -0.179 (SE = 0.061).
We can obtain additional insights concerning the effect of using a
broker on time to sale by examining monthly hazard rates. Specifically,
we estimate a series of probit models describing the probability of
selling a home during the t-th month after placing it on the market,
conditional on reaching the start of that month without a sale. Column
(1) of Table 5 reports the marginal effects of using a broker--in other
words, the impact on the probability of a sale. To conserve space, we
have omitted the coefficients for other variables, which include a full
set of home characteristics, neighborhood effects, and year effects. The
results indicate that the use of a broker is associated with a slightly
higher probability of sale during the first month on the market (0.0253,
SE = 0.0160, p = .070), and a substantially higher probability during
the second month (0.175, SE = 0.056, p = .00). (27) Beyond the second
month, there is no clear pattern. The measured effects are positive and
reasonably large in the third and sixth months, but not statistically
significant. However, they are negative, large, and statistically
significant in the fourth and fifth months. Thus, to the extent the use
of a broker reduces time to sale, the effect appears to involves quick
sales (i.e., within 2 months) rather than persistently elevated
probabilities.
Columns (2) and (3) of Table 5 reports the cumulative probability
of a sale for the average home in our sample, conditional on using or
not using a broker, implied by the probit regressions shown in column
(1). Notice that the use of a broker raises the cumulative probability
for every month. As a result of the inversion of relative hazard rates
in the fourth and fifth months, the probability of selling a home
without a broker nearly catches up with the probability of selling a
home with a broker by the end of the fifth month, but these
probabilities diverge once again in the sixth month.
Thus, we conclude that brokered homes likely sell somewhat faster
than similar homes that are not brokered, owing mostly to an increased
likelihood of sale within the first 2 months after being placed on the
market. We note, however, that the specifications with home fixed
effects yield ambiguous results.
VI. SENSITIVITY
The qualitative results reported in this paper are robust with
respect to a wide range of alternative specifications. Here, we briefly
summarize some of the alternatives we examined. Full results are
available upon request.
A. Variations in Market Conditions
Our basic specifications control for variations in market
conditions through the inclusion of year effects. We also estimated
specifications with seasonal effects, half-year indicators, and
quarterly indicators. Seasonal effects are marginally significant in
some specifications but change the estimated effect of using a broker
only slightly, as do half-year and quarterly indicators.
B. Buyer and Seller Characteristics
Additional characteristics of buyers and sellers, including age and
departmental affiliation, are available for most observations. To
preserve sample size, we did not include those variables in our basic
specification. Adding them sacrifices some precision, but does not
meaningfully alter our findings, even though the coefficients of the
additional variables are sometimes statistically significant
individually and/or jointly.
C. Data from 2007 and 2008
As noted in the introduction, the frequency with which buyers used
brokers dropped sharply from 2006 to 2007 after we circulated an early
version of this paper through the FSH Office. Though we see no reason to
suspect that this development would impart any particular bias, it is
nevertheless arguable that the data from January 2007 through January
2008 are somehow contaminated. The coefficients of interest change
slightly when those observations are removed from the sample, but our
conclusions are qualitatively unaltered.
D. Heterogeneity Across Brokers
Different people may respond differently to the incentives present
in principal-agent problems. It is therefore of interest to determine
whether the effects of brokerage are reasonably uniform, or if they
differ across companies and agents. (28) One company handled 54 of the
133 brokered sales in our sample, and another handled 39. One broker
with the first company accounted for 34 transactions, and another broker
with the second company accounted for 25. Accordingly, we re-estimated
various specifications with additional dummy variables, either for the
two lead companies or for the two lead brokers. The results suggest that
the effects of interest may indeed differ across some brokers. In
particular, both the selling price and the initial asking price tended
to be noticeably higher when one particular broker handled transactions,
and those differences were significant both economically and
statistically. In specifications otherwise analogous to Equation (2) in
Tables 2 and 3, the estimated impact on selling price for the broker in
question is 0.0856 (SE = 0.0374), and the estimated impact on list price
is 0.0509 (SE = 0.0390). Otherwise, broker effects on both asking prices
and selling prices were fairly uniform. In addition, the acceleration of
sales appears to be almost entirely attributable to transactions handled
by the two lead companies. With company dummies added to specification
(2) in Table 4, the main broker effect becomes positive and
statistically insignificant (0.0970, SE = 0.119). In contrast, the
coefficients of the two company indicators are large and negative
(-0.560, SE = 0.168, and -0.309, SE = 0.167). Possibly the companies
with the most experience in this particular market have an advantage in
selling homes quickly.
VII. CONCLUSION
We have employed a unique data set to examine the separate effects
of real estate brokerage services provided to sellers, other than MLS
listings, on a home's selling price, initial asking price, and time
on the market. Because a seller presumably benefits from an MLS listing,
measuring the effects of real estate brokerage services including MLS
listings (as a number of other studies have done) likely obscures the
significance of agency costs. Our central finding is that a
seller's use of a broker reduces the selling price of the typical
home by 5.9% to 7.7%, which is consistent with the presence of a fairly
severe principal-agent problem. Those estimates are statistically
significant, and are obtained from specifications that include home
fixed effects; some also allow for the possibility that prices may have
changed over time at different rates in different market segments (e.g.,
that the prices of high-end homes, which are more frequently sold
through brokers, may have risen or fallen relative to those of low-end
homes). We find no evidence that the lower prices received by sellers
who use brokers are attributable to correlations with unobserved
household characteristics such as preferences or negotiation skills. Our
analysis also suggests somewhat more tentatively that a seller's
use of a broker may reduce the initial asking price and accelerate the
sale. These results are of direct relevance to the recent policy debate
over the traditional practice of bundling MLS listings with other
brokerage services. They suggest that bundling may indeed compel many
homeowners to purchase unwanted services (other than MLS listings)
contrary to their interests.
ABBREVIATIONS
FSBO: For Sale By Owner
FSH: Faculty Staff Housing
MLS: Multiple Listing Service
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00473.x
REFERENCES
Colwell, P., D. Lauschke, and A. Yavas. "The Value of Real
Estate Marketing Systems: Theory and Evidence." Manuscript,
University of Illinois, 1992.
Doiron, J., J. Shilling, and C. F. Sirmans. "Owner Versus
Broker Sales: Evidence on the Amount of the Brokerage Commission
Capitalized." Real Estate Appraiser and Analyst, 51, 1985, 44-48.
Ehrlinger, J., and D. Dunning. "How Chronic Self-Views
Influence (and Potentially Mislead) Estimates of Performance."
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 84, 2003, 5-17.
Evans, B. "NAR's 2003 Buyer/Seller Survey." July 21,
2003. Accessed March 4, 2006.
http://realtytimes.com/rtapages/20030721_survey.htm
Federal Trade Commission. "Competition in the Real Estate
Brokerage Industry." April 2007. Accessed December 8, 2009.
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/ reports/223094.htm#IVA2.
Frew, G. D., and J. Jud. "Who Pays the Real Estate
Broker's Commission?" Research in Law and Economics, 10, 1987,
177-87.
Hendel, I., A. Nevo, and F. Ortalo-Magne. "The Relative
Performance of Real Estate Marketing Platforms: MLS versus
FSBOMadison.com." American Economic Review, 99(5), 2009, 1878-98.
Huang, B., and R. Rutherford. "Who You Going to Call?
Performance of Realtors and Non-Realtors in a MLS Setting." Journal
of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 2007, 77-93.
Johnson, K., T. Springer, and C. Brockman. "Price Effects of
Non-Traditionally Broker-Marketed Properties." Journal of Real
Estate Finance and Economics, 31(3), 2005, 331-43.
Kamath, R., and K. Yantek. "The Influence of Brokerage
Commissions on Prices of Single-Family Homes." Appraisal Journal,
50, 1982, 63-70.
Kossen, B. "For Sale by Amateur." Seattle Times.
September 16, 2000. Accessed March 4, 2006. http://marketplace.
nwsource.com/realestate/fsbo_amateur.html
Kovacic, W. E. "Opinion of the Commission in the Matter of
Realcomp II, Ltd." Federal Trade Commission Docket No. 9320.
November 2, 2009.
Kruger, J., and D. Dunning. "Unskilled and Unaware of It: How
Difficulties in Recognizing One's Own Incompetence Lead to Inflated
Self-Assessments." Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,
77, 1999, 1121-34.
Levitt, S., and C. Syverson. "Market Distortions When Agents
Are Better Informed: The Value of Information in Real Estate
Transactions." Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), 2008,
599-611.
Liao, C.-J., and C.-O. Chang. "The Asymmetric Price Effects of
Brokerage Service Using Quantile Regressions." Manuscript, National
Chengchi University. June 2005.
MacDonald, D., and M. Veeman. "Valuing Housing
Characteristics: A Case Study of Single Family Houses in Edmonton,
Alberta." The Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(Special Issue: Part
2), 1996, S510-14.
Magura, M. "How Rebate Bans, Discriminatory MLS Listing
Policies, and Minimum Service Requirements Can Reduce Price Competition
for Real Estate Brokerage Services and Why It Matters." U.S.
Department of Justice, Economics Analysis Group, Discussion Paper EAG 07-8, May 2007.
Meet, J., and E. Van Wesep. "A Test of Confidence-Enhanced
Performance: Evidence from U.S. College Debaters." Manuscript,
Stanford University. July 2007.
Miceli, T., K. Pancak, and C. F. Sirmans. "Is the Compensation
Model for Real Estate Brokers Obsolete?" Journal of Real Estate
Finance and Economics, 35(1), 2007, 7-22.
National Association of Realtors. "Profile of Home Buyers and
Sellers 2002." 2002. Accessed March 4, 2006.
http://www.realtor.org/Research.nsf/files/2002 HBHSbilites.pdf.
--. "Profile of Home Buyers and Sellers 2003." 2003.
Accessed March 4, 2006. http://www.realtor.org/
Research.nsf/files/2002HBHShilites.pdf.
Palmon, O., and B. Sopranzetti. "Brokers, Information, and
Transaction Outcomes: Evidence from the Real Estate Market."
Manuscript, Rutgers University. June 2008.
Palmquist, R. "Estimating the Demand for the Characteristics
of Housing." The Review of Economics and Statistics, 66(3), 1984,
394-404.
Parsons, G. "An Almost Ideal Demand System for Housing
Attributes." Southern Economic Journal, 53(2), 1986, 347-63.
Realty Direct Corp. "Why a Realtor?" Accessed
http://www.realty-direct.com/why_use_realtor.htm.
Rutherford, R., T. Springer, and A. Yavas. "Conflicts Between
Principals and Agents: Evidence from Residential Brokerage."
Journal of Financial Economics, 76(3), 2005, 627-65.
Salant. S. W. "For Sale by Owner: When to Use a Broker and How
to Price the House." Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics,
4(2), 1991, 157-73.
Yavas, A., and P. Colwell. "A Comparison of Real Estate
Marketing Systems: Theory and Evidence." Journal of Real Estate
Research, 10(5), 1995, 583-600.
Zumpano, L., H. Elder, and E. Baryla. "Buying a House and the
Decision to Use a Real Estate Broker." Journal of Real Estate
Finance and Economics, 13(2), 1996, 169-81.
B. DOUGLAS BERNHEIM and JONATHAN MEER *
* We are grateful to April Blaine, Shirley Campbell, Betty Oen, Jan
Thomson, and members of Stanford University's Faculty and Staff
Housing Office. Stephan D. McBride, Sriniketh S. Nagavarapu, Harvey S.
Rosen, and members of Stanford University's Labor Reading Group
provided helpful comments. Zhihao Zhang provided valuable research
assistance.
Bernheim: Department of Economics, Stanford University and National
Bureau of Economic Research, 579 Serra Mall, Stanford, CA 94305. Phone
650-725-8732, Fax 650-725-5702, E-mail bernheim@stanford.edu
Meer: Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, 3042 Allen
Building, College Station, TX 77843. Phone 979-845-2059, Fax
979-847-8757, E-mail jmeer@econmail.tamu.edu
(1.) Brokers frequently provide other services that do not directly
impact the terms or timing of sales. For example, they help with
paperwork and legal documentation, and provide referrals to mortgage
lenders. However, those services tend to be secondary.
(2.) Brokers argue that they "offer professional advice and
objective insight" (Evans 2003), while homes sold by owner
"often are priced too high and may not sell until the price is
reduced, which can turn into an unnecessarily long drawnout
process" (Kossen 2000).
(3.) See, for example, Salant (1991).
(4.) According to the National Association of Realtors, brokers are
"trained to negotiate the best possible prices and terms"
(Evans 2003).
(5.) In a similar vein, Huang and Rutherford (2007) find that
properties sold by realtors--that is, members of the National
Association of Realtors--on the MLS sell for more (and more quickly)
than those sold by agents without that designation.
(6.) The fee is generally in the range of $200 to $900. The
homeowner may then contract with the listing broker for other sales
services (which are usually provided in exchange for a smaller
commission) or sell the home without those services. In the latter case,
the homeowner may pay a "Buyer's Agent Commission" to a
broker who brings in a buyer, or avoid commissions altogether by finding
a buyer independently.
(7.) Alabama, Idaho, Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Missouri, Texas, and
Utah had minimum service laws. New Mexico passed and then rescinded a
minimum service law, and other states have actively debated that
alternative. See Magura (2007) and Federal Trade Commission (2007).
(8.) For further discussion, see Magura (2007) and Federal Trade
Commission (2007).
(9.) This passage appears in a recent decision by the Commissioners
of the Federal Trade Commission concerning the practices of Realcomp II
Ltd.; see Kovacic (2009).
(10.) For example, the U.S. District Court for the District of
South Carolina (Columbia Division) ruled in favor the government in U.S.
v. Consolidated Multiple Listing Services (Case No. 3:08-CV-01786-SB,
Final Judgement issued August 27, 2009) overturning the discriminatory
rules of an MLS in Columbia, SC, that prevented various practices
including unbundling. See http://www.justice.
gov/atr/cases/f249600/249614.htm.
(11.) Doiron, Shilling, and Sirmans (1985) and Frew and Jud (1987)
find that homes sell for more when the seller uses a broker. Kamath and
Yantek (1982), Colwell, Lauschke, and Yavas (1992), and Hendel, Nevo,
and Ortalo-Magne (2009) find no effect. Based on a matching model, Yavas
and Colwell (1995) argue that the effects of using a broker should be
heterogeneous across sellers. Liao and Chang (2005) find that broker
price effects are indeed heterogeneous, raising the price of homes at
the lower end of the distribution but lowering the price of more
expensive ones.
(12.) Prior studies generally examined cross-sectional
correlations, a strategy that offers little opportunity to control
convincingly for the fact that the use of a broker is highly correlated
with the characteristics of homes and homeowners. In most markets, FSBO
sellers constitute a small, highly selected group with potentially
unusual characteristics and inclinations: only 17% of sellers forego the
use of an agent (National Association of Realtors 2003); during the
first quarter of 2004, 44% of all FSBO homes were never placed on the
open market, as the buyer and seller knew each other in advance (Evans
2003); and FSBO sellers tend to be older and less wealthy (National
Association of Realtors 2002). Some prior studies employ sample
selection corrections, but identification is driven entirely by
functional form assumptions rather than exclusion restrictions. Also,
some earlier studies employed data samples that were extremely small and
somewhat peculiar. For example, Doiron, Shilling, and Sirmans (1985)
examined 134 transactions in two condominium complexes, while Kamath and
Yantek studied 118 transactions.
(13.) If one is willing to accept without evidence the assumption
that MLS-listings lead to higher sales prices than the non-MLS listings
studied by Hendel, Nevo, and Ortalo-Magne (2009), then their finding
that the use of a seller's broker has no impact on sales price
would imply that services other than MLS listings collectively have an
offsetting negative impact on sales price. Of course, the confidence
interval of the effect they estimate includes positive values, so the
preceding implication only follows for their point estimate.
(14.) Throughout this paper, we use the term "market"
somewhat loosely, and not in the formal sense employed, for example, in
antitrust analyses.
(15.) Stanford enforces this restriction by retaining ownership of
the land. Stanford provides the homeowner with a long-term land lease
involving modest monthly payments.
(16.) For all but one such specification we reject that hypothesis
at the 95% level of confidence or higher. For the remaining (and most
restrictive) specification, which does not allow prices to follow
different time paths based on home quality, we reject it at the 90%
level of confidence.
(17.) Among other things, the selling prices for those homes rarely
differ from the asking prices.
(18.) Eighteen buyers switched from FSBO to using a broker over the
course of listing their property, while five switched from using a
broker to FSBO. For our analysis of the initial asking price, we treat
the seller as using a broker if it did so when initially listing the
property; for our analysis of the selling price and time on the market,
we treat the seller as using a broker if it did so at the time of sale.
Dropping these observations does not significantly alter our results.
(19.) Numerous studies (MacDonald 1996; Palmquist 1984; Parsons
1986, and others) have demonstrated the importance of these
characteristics in determining the price of a home. Two of the
neighborhood indexes correspond to condominium complexes. Because all
condominiums are in one of these two complexes, it is not necessary to
include a separate dummy variable indicating whether the home is a house
or condominium.
(20.) We calculate this variable by determining the last date of
sale for the same property. In some cases, that information is
unavailable.
(21.) Levitt and Syverson (2005) found that the absence of a
buyer's agent "has a negligible impact on sale price."
Similarly, Zumpano, Elder, and Baryla (1996) model the buyer's
decision to use a broker and, accounting for this selection, find that
there is no effect on sale price.
(22.) See specification (1) in Table 1.
(23.) Though home renovations can lead to changes in certain
variables such as the number of bedrooms, bathrooms, and square footage,
such changes are relatively rare in our data, and their effects are not
usefully identified.
(24.) A substantial body of evidence suggests that people tend to
be overconfident (see, e.g., Ehrlinger and Dunning 2003, or Meer and Van
Wesep 2007). Those with low competence are particularly likely to
overestimate their abilities (see, e.g., Kruger and Dunning 1999).
(25.) Because the correlations between these fitted residuals
depend on fitted coefficients, we bootstrapped the standard errors for
the correlation coefficients. Using residuals created by specification
(3) and specification (4) results in qualitatively similar correlations.
(26.) The regression employs 755 observations, of which 277 are
effectively dummied out by the home fixed effects (i.e., they correspond
to homes for which we have only one observation).
(27.) Due to the inclusion of year effects, all observations within
a given year are dropped if all of the associated homes either sold or
failed to sale within a given month after listing. That is why the
sample size is smaller for the first month after listing than for the
second month after listing.
(28.) Notably, Palmon and Sopranzetti (2008) find that broker
quality matters in the sale of a home.
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics
Variable M Median SD
Selling price (2008 dollars, thousands) 795.80 659.48 507.82
Initial asking price (2008 dollars, 855.38 712.95 562.65
thousands)
Months between initial listing and 9.79 5 14.89
close of escrow
Whether the seller used a broker 0.176 0 0.381
Age of the home at the date of initial 26.65 22.27 18.30
listing (in years)
Time seller had lived in the home at 14.31 9.21 12.82
the date of initial listing (in years)
Whether the home has a study 0.364 0 0.482
Number of bedrooms 3.18 3 1.16
Number of bathrooms 2.48 2 0.7002
Whether the home has a pool 0.555 1 0.497
Square footage of the home 2002 1931 797.0
Size of the lot (in acres) 0.203 0.24 0.237
Whether the home was sold through an 0.056 0 0.2294
estate
Buyer's age 43.5 41 11.2
Seller's age 58.3 56 17.9
Variable Minimum Maximum
Selling price (2008 dollars, thousands) 162.34 3089.22
Initial asking price (2008 dollars, 168.83 4422.72
thousands)
Months between initial listing and 1 217
close of escrow
Whether the seller used a broker 0 1
Age of the home at the date of initial 2.08 98.6
listing (in years)
Time seller had lived in the home at 0.605 60.13
the date of initial listing (in years)
Whether the home has a study 0 1
Number of bedrooms 1 7
Number of bathrooms 1 5.5
Whether the home has a pool 0 1
Square footage of the home 638 6168
Size of the lot (in acres) 0 1.41
Whether the home was sold through an 0 1
estate
Buyer's age 24 89
Seller's age 28 105
TABLE 2
OLS Regressions for Log Selling Price (2008 dollars)
Variable (1) (2)
Home fixed effects No No
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood No Yes
effects
Year-Propensity No No
interactions
Broker dummy 0.357 0.0009
(0.0621) (0.0232)
Home age -- -0.0144
(0.0024)
Home age squared -- 1.56 x [10.sup.-4]
(2.78 x [10.sup.-5])
Time in home -- --
Time in home squared -- --
Study -- 0.0381
(0.0160)
Bedrooms -- 0.0207
(0.0140
Baths -- 0.0446
(0.0177)
Pool -- 0.0607
(0.0278)
Square feet -- 4.72 x [10.sup.-4]
(7.80 x [10.sup.-5])
Square feet squared -- -5.72 x [10.sup.-5]
(1.18 x [10.sup.-8])
Estate -- -0.0823
(0.0309)
Acreage -- 0.532
(0.297)
Acreage squared -- -0.360
(0.202)
Observations 755 755
[R.sup.2] 0.255 0.928
Variable (3) (4)
Home fixed effects No Yes
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood Yes N/A
effects
Year-Propensity No No
interactions
Broker dummy 0.0203 -0.0603
(0.0238) (0.0361)
Home age -0.0113 0.0145
(0.0027) (0.0093)
Home age squared 1.21 x [10.sup.-4] 3.17 x [10.sup.-4]
(2.86 x [10.sup.-5]) (5.85 x [10.sup.-5])
Time in home -0.0066 --
(0.0021)
Time in home squared 9.74 x [10.sup.-5] --
(4.30 x [10.sup.-4])
Study 0.0376 --
(0.0167)
Bedrooms 0.0286 --
(0.0164)
Baths 0.0300 --
(0.0191)
Pool 0.0481 --
(0.0279)
Square feet 5.55 x [10.sup.-4] --
(8.09 x [10.sup.-5])
Square feet squared -6.69 x [10.sup.-8] --
(1.23 x [10.sup.-8])
Estate -0.0510 -0.1505
(0.0349) (0.0485)
Acreage 0.463 --
(0.331)
Acreage squared -0.283 --
(0.207)
Observations 691 755
[R.sup.2] 0.937 0.818
Variable (5) (6)
Home fixed effects Yes Yes
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood N/A N/A
effects
Year-Propensity Yes Yes
interactions
Broker dummy -0.0782 -0.0797
(0.0375) (0.0378)
Home age 0.0153 0.0203
(0.0086) (0.0101)
Home age squared 1.21 x [10.sup.-4] -1.15 x [10.sup.-4]
(8.16 x [10.sup.-5]) (1.23 x [10.sup.-4])
Time in home -- -0.0014
(0.0043)
Time in home squared -- -5.63 x [10.sup.-5]
(1.44 x [10.sup.-4])
Study -- --
Bedrooms -- --
Baths -- --
Pool -- --
Square feet -- --
Square feet squared -- --
Estate -0.0813 0.0097
(0.0682) (0.0649)
Acreage -- --
Acreage squared -- --
Observations 755 691
[R.sup.2] 0.888 0.907
Note: Robust standard errors clustered at the home level are reported.
Standard errors for specifications (4) and (5) are bootstrapped with
2,000 repetitions to account for the estimated propensity score.
Specifications (4) and (5) include 277 observations that are dummied
out; specification (6) includes 270 such observations. The [R.sup.2]
for the fixed-effects regression pertains to "within" variation.
TABLE 3
OLS Regressions for Log Asking Price (2008 dollars)
Variable (1) (2)
Home fixed effects No No
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood No Yes
effects
Year-Propensity No No
interactions
Broker dummy 0.286 -0.0265
(0.0626) (0.0219)
Home age -- -0.01519
(0.002968)
Home age squared -- 1.46 x [10.sup.-4]
(2.86 x [10.sup.-5])
Time in home -- --
Time in home squared -- --
Study -- 0.0547
(0.0189)
Bedrooms -- 0.0328
(0.0172)
Baths -- 0.0380
(0.0189)
Pool -- 0.0814
(0.0304)
Square feet -- 3.54 x [10.sup.-4]
(1.05 x [10.sup.-4])
Square feet squared -- -3.76 x [10.sup.-8]
(1.66 x [10.sup.-8])
Estate -- -0.0367
(0.0266)
Acreage -- 0.285
(0.326)
Acreage squared -- -0.0356
(0.221)
Observations 755 755
[R.sup.2] 0.216 0.914
Variable (3) (4)
Home fixed effects No Yes
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood Yes N/A
effects
Year-Propensity No No
interactions
Broker dummy -0.0076 -0.0614
(0.0238) (0.0325)
Home age -0.01449 -0.02402
(0.003229) (0.008655)
Home age squared 1.26 x [10.sup.-4] 2.78 x [10.sup.-4]
(3.09 x [10.sup.-5]) (6.21 x [10.sup.-5])
Time in home -0.0050 --
(0.0024)
Time in home squared 7.86 x [10.sup.-5] --
(4.76 x [10.sup.-5])
Study 0.0486 --
(0.0173)
Bedrooms 0.0292 --
(0.0183)
Baths 0.0258 --
(0.0209)
Pool 0.0765 --
(0.0312)
Square feet 4.85 x [10.sup.-4] --
(1.02 x [10.sup.-4])
Square feet squared -5.49 x [10.sup.-8] --
(1.67 x [10.sup.-8])
Estate -0.0168 -0.103
(0.0295) (0.0413)
Acreage 0.385 --
(0.326)
Acreage squared -0.0395 --
(0.213)
Observations 691 755
[R.sup.2] 0.927 0.777
Variable (5) (6)
Home fixed effects Yes Yes
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood N/A N/A
effects
Year-Propensity Yes Yes
interactions
Broker dummy -0.0638 -0.0401
(0.0338) (0.0320)
Home age -0.01681 -0.01014
(0.00913) (0.00866)
Home age squared 1.75 x [10.sup.-5] -1.81 x [10.sup.-4]
(1.13 x [10.sup.-4]) (1.09 x [10.sup.-4])
Time in home -- 0.0023
(0.0037)
Time in home squared -- -1.52 x [10.sup.-4]
(1.18 x [10.sup.-4])
Study -- --
Bedrooms -- --
Baths -- --
Pool -- --
Square feet -- --
Square feet squared -- --
Estate -0.0420 0.0114
(0.0515) (0.0542)
Acreage -- --
Acreage squared -- --
Observations 755 691
[R.sup.2] 0.869 0.897
Note: Robust standard errors clustered at the home level are reported.
Standard errors for specifications (4) and (5) are bootstrapped with
2,000 repetitions to account for the estimated propensity score.
Specifications (4) and (5) include 277 observations that are dummied
out; specification (6) includes 270 such observations. The [R.sup.2]
for the fixed-effects regression pertains to "within" variation.
TABLE 4
OLS Regressions for Log Time on Market
Variable (1) (2)
Home fixed effects No No
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood No Yes
effects
Year-Propensity No No
interactions
Broker dummy -0.192 -0.168
(0.0815) (0.0884)
Home age -- -0.0462
(0.0125)
Home age squared -- 2.36 x [10.sup.-4]
(1.02 x [10.sup.-4])
Time in home -- --
Time in -- --
home squared
Study -- 0.122
(0.0667)
Bedrooms -- 0.0721
(0.0465)
Baths -- -0.0107
(0.0712)
Pool -- -0.0011
(0.109)
Square feet -- -9.35 x [10.sup.-4]
(2.93 x [10.sup.-4])
Square feet squared -- 1.50 x 10-7
(4.45 x 10-8)
Estate -- 0.209
(0.113)
Acreage -- -0.0020
(1.012)
Acreage squared -- 0.635
(0.712)
Observations 755 755
[R.sup.2] 0.300 0.379
Variable (3) (4)
Home fixed effects No Yes
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood Yes N/A
effects
Year-Propensity No No
interactions
Broker dummy -0.211 -0.065
(0.0928) (0.112)
Home age -0.0631 -0.604
(0.0143) (0.0931)
Home age squared 3.98 x [10.sup.-4] -1.81 x 10-5
(1.16 x [10.sup.-4]) (1.44 x [10.sup.-4])
Time in home 0.05483 --
(0.009159)
Time in -1.11 x [10.sup.-3] --
home squared (1.87 x [10.sup.-4])
Study 0.0548 --
(0.0716)
Bedrooms 0.0262 --
(0.0504)
Baths -0.0201 --
(0.0775)
Pool 0.0455 --
(0.119)
Square feet -8.03 x [10.sup.-4] --
(3.14 x [10.sup.-4])
Square feet squared 1.34 x [10.sup.-7] --
(4.67 x [10.sup.-8])
Estate 0.167 0.432
(0.124) (0.158)
Acreage 0.3469 --
(1.207)
Acreage squared 0.516 --
(0.896)
Observations 691 755
[R.sup.2] 0.422 0.723
Variable (5) (6)
Home fixed effects Yes Yes
Year effects Yes Yes
Neighborhood N/A N/A
effects
Year-Propensity Yes Yes
interactions
Broker dummy -0.045 -0.191
(0.134) (0.142)
Home age -0.583 -0.552
(0.105) (0.104)
Home age squared -1.31 x [10.sup.-4] 1.22 x [10.sup.-4]
(2.46 x [10.sup.-4]) (4.77 x [10.sup.-4])
Time in home -- 0.02634
(0.0168)
Time in -- -5.72 x [10.sup.-4]
home squared (4.60 x [10.sup.-4])
Study -- --
Bedrooms -- --
Baths -- --
Pool -- --
Square feet -- --
Square feet squared -- --
Estate 0.446 0.479
(0.202) (0.225)
Acreage -- --
Acreage squared -- --
Observations 755 691
[R.sup.2] 0.744 0.763
Note: Robust standard errors clustered at the home level are reported.
Standard errors for specifications (4) and (5) are bootstrapped with
2,000 repetitions to account for the estimated propensity score.
Specifications (4) and (5) include 277 observations that are dummied
out; specification (6) includes 270 such observations. The [R.sup.2]
for the fixed-effects regression pertains to "within" variation.
TABLE 5
Probit Models for Probability of Sale
(1) Estimated Impact
of Broker on
Probability of
Month After Number of Sale, Given No
Listing Observations Previous Sale
First month 374 0.0253
(0.0160)
Second month 513 0.175
(0.0564)
Third month 601 0.0665
(0.0569)
Fourth month 470 -0.114
(0.0275)
Fifth month 385 -0.107
(0.0286)
Sixth month 281 0.0817
(0.0806)
(2) Fitted (3) Fitted
Cumulative Cumulative
Probability Probability of
Month After of Sale if Sale if
Listing No Broker Used Broker Used
First month 0.0533 0.123
(0.0493) (0.0982)
Second month 0.240 0.498
(0.151) (0.196)
Third month 0.476 0.701
(0.236) (0.188)
Fourth month 0.646 0.721
(0.211) (0.189)
Fifth month 0.764 0.773
(0.213) (0.192)
Sixth month 0.776 0.811
(0.184) (0.165)
Note: The left-hand-side variable is a dummy for selling in the t-th
month conditional on not having sold up to that point. Other right-
hand-side variables include home characteristics, neighborhood
effects, and year effects. Robust standard errors clustered at the
home level are reported in parentheses. Marginal probability effects
evaluated at the means of the explanatory variables are reported in
column (1).