首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Cooperation spillovers and price competition in experimental markets.
  • 作者:Cason, Timothy N. ; Gangadharan, Lata
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2013
  • 期号:July
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:Both competition and cooperation are important for the successful functioning of many economic systems. For example, firms compete in markets but they also cooperate with one another through arrangements such as research joint ventures, lobbying, cooperative marketing agreements, and strategic alliances.
  • 关键词:Competition (Economics);Externalities (Economics);Industrial research

Cooperation spillovers and price competition in experimental markets.


Cason, Timothy N. ; Gangadharan, Lata


I. INTRODUCTION

Both competition and cooperation are important for the successful functioning of many economic systems. For example, firms compete in markets but they also cooperate with one another through arrangements such as research joint ventures, lobbying, cooperative marketing agreements, and strategic alliances.

In this paper, we use experiments to examine how competitive interactions affect agents' propensity to cooperate. We are interested in studying spillovers that may involve cooperation in one domain (such as a research joint venture) and competition in another (such as in a market). (1) Cooperation could weaken competition, perhaps promoting collusion, or market competition could reduce incentives for non-market cooperation. These "behavioral spillovers" could go in either direction. They are distinct from another type of spillover, through knowledge externalities that occur in research and development (R&D) when the innovator cannot fully appropriate the gains to innovation, leading potentially to a socially inefficient level of research (deBondt 1996). (2) As discussed below, behavioral spillovers have been shown in experiments to increase cooperation in otherwise competitive environments, for example through establishing cooperative precedents.

A large body of theoretical research has focused on firms cooperating in research joint ventures and how this impacts competition in output markets. For example, Cooper and Ross (2009) examine the mechanism by which agreements to cooperate in one market can have negative effects on competition in other markets, even in situations when these markets are not linked via costs or demand. Cabral (2000) shows that product market prices are affected by R&D agreements between firms. Caloghirou, Ioannides, and Vonortas (2003), Lambertini, Poddar, and Sasaki (2003), and Poyago-Theotoky (2007) also discuss the impact of forming research joint ventures on product markets and cartel formation. (3)

Empirical work using field data has provided creative indirect evidence on the collusive potential of research joint ventures by exploiting natural "policy experiments," although the extent of this evidence is limited. Goeree and Helland (2010), for example, show that research joint ventures facilitate collusion because they became less popular following an enforcement policy change (leniency) that made collusion less attractive. Policy experiments such as these are often required since systematic collusion often goes undetected by authorities. Duso, Roller, and Seldeslachts (2010) also examine the link between research joint ventures and collusion, using data from the U.S. National Cooperation Research Act that granted certain research joint ventures milder antitrust scrutiny. They find that horizontal research joint ventures lead to more collusion than vertical joint ventures. Our work provides complementary and more direct evidence, since in the laboratory we can observe the level and sustainability of tacit and explicit collusion and can therefore circumvent the measurement and endogeneity issues that are often prevalent in field data.

The specific research goals of this study are the following. First, we wish to examine if agents take advantage of available gains from cooperation in the presence of payoff uncertainties that arise from stochastic innovation success. Second, we are interested in learning if a behavioral spillover of cooperation can lead to collusion in markets, or whether competition in markets reduces non-market cooperation. These notions of cooperation concern contributions to joint R&D projects or collusion in price setting, and are defined independently of any communication opportunities. Therefore, our third goal is to determine how this interaction between cooperation and competition is affected by the introduction of non-market communication opportunities. Finally, we will measure the externalities from R&D cooperation to non-innovators in the market. (4)

Subjects in our experiment trade in a computerized double auction market where they make price offers and can accept offers made by others in continuous time. Sellers have the option to contribute voluntarily to a public good, corresponding to a research joint venture, which may (stochastically) reduce their marginal costs. This cost reduction lowers equilibrium prices, so buyers can also potentially benefit from this innovation. Cooperative research is modeled as a threshold (provision point) public goods problem, in which the good (the reduction in costs) is provided if voluntary contributions exceed the required threshold level of contributions and if the research project succeeds. Many collective action scenarios can be represented as such public good games. For example, firms contributing to a research fund may require financing or effort to reach a specific threshold for any chance of successful innovation.

We find that while there are some modest behavioral spillovers, subjects often cooperate in funding the public good even though they also compete aggressively in the market. Although cooperative research occurs less frequently when subjects also compete in the market, research cooperation does not reduce the intensity of market competition. Communication helps subjects coordinate on an efficient choice of public good contributions in all environments, and we also observe significant R&D externalities that benefit non-innovators. The results therefore suggest that R&D collaborations need not diminish robust market competition.

The idea that individuals' behavior could spill over across different environments or domains has received considerable attention in the recent experimental literature, although theoretically little is understood about the relevant mechanisms (Bednar and Page 2007). Bednar et al. (2012) document behavioral spillovers for several different types of two-player bimatrix games. Falk, Fischbacher, and Gachter (2011) find that behavior does not differ from isolated controls when two coordination or public goods games are played simultaneously with different opponents. Savikhin and Sheremeta (2012) also study simultaneous play, and they find that cooperation in a voluntary contribution game reduces competitive overbidding in contests. Brandts and Cooper (2006) document behavioral spillover due to cooperative precedent established in a high incentive coordination game to a lower incentive coordination game. Cason, Savikhin, and Sheremeta (2012) show that a behavioral spillover occurs for two different coordination games, but only if they are played sequentially and not when they are played simultaneously. None of the (few) previous experiments that have considered behavioral spillovers have included markets.

In addition, our experiment is novel because few previous studies have used experiments to examine issues in R&D and competition, and even less have considered R&D joint ventures. Isaac and Reynolds (1992) report an experiment where sellers compete in prices and in cost reducing R&D. Their sellers competed in a posted offer market (with simulated buyers), and after five periods they could undertake costly innovation, which if successful lowered costs for that seller only. Davis, Quirmbach, and Swenson (1995) varied the tax subsidy available to subjects who invest in R&D and also the appropriability of returns to R&D. They find that an equal tax subsidy across investors increases levels of investment in R&D, but not in proportion to the amount of the subsidy. Buckley, Mestelman, and Shehata (2003) examine the effectiveness of alternative subsidy schemes in stimulating R&D, and show that incremental subsidies are less effective than level subsidies. Unlike all of these experiments, we have added to the market structure a stage where subjects have the opportunity to contribute toward a joint research fund. The "research" is also successful only stochastically, differentiating this threshold public goods game from most of the experimental literature. Deck and Erkal (2011) examine how the decision to form research joint ventures changes in a dynamic environment and find that cooperation can unravel as firms move forward in the R&D process and monopoly rents become more attractive.

Suetens (2005) tests how different levels of appropriability of R&D externalities affects investment, and Suetens (2008) adds competition in the product market and finds that binding R&D cooperation facilitates price collusion in a duopoly context. Both studies employed simulated buyers. In contrast, our experiment employs more sellers in each market (triopolies) and explicitly incorporates markets where sellers compete to make trades with strategic human buyers in a realistic and competitive (double auction) trading institution. Our design also allows us to isolate the impact of behavioral spillovers, separately from R&D externalities that accrue to non-innovating buyers through lower prices.

II. DESIGN

The experiment is designed to study the links between market competition and cooperation. It uses a 3 x 2 design, summarized in Table 1, employing a total of 264 subjects. We examine two dimensions and conduct three treatments across each dimension. In one treatment, subjects participated only in a threshold public goods game, in another they traded only in a market and in the third treatment subjects participated both in a market and in a threshold public goods game. These public good provision and market pricing games require coordination to increase payoffs, and this coordination may further require non-market communication. Therefore, we vary opportunities for communication along the second dimension and all three treatments included sessions in which sellers were allowed to communicate with each other using typed text in computer-based chat rooms, contrasted with sessions in which all traders made decisions without any communication.

The Public Good Only treatment examines whether subjects coordinate and cooperate with each other when threshold public good returns are uncertain, and studies how communication affects cooperation. The Market Only treatment explores the impact of communication on collusion, prices, and trading efficiency. The main motivation for conducting these two treatments is to provide baselines to compare subjects' cooperative and competitive behavior with the combined Market and Public Good treatment (Combined), hence allowing identification of behavioral spillovers. The comparison with the Public Good Only baseline reveals how market competition may reduce cooperation, while the comparison with the Market Only baseline indicates how cooperation in providing the public good (which lowers sellers' costs) affects price competition.

A. Treatments

Combined. The Combined treatment includes data from 20 sessions. In all sessions, six subjects traded in a computerized double auction market across 27 periods. Our design is motivated in part by recent policy initiatives to mitigate climate change. Emission markets are an ideal environment to study spillovers as trading in carbon markets is being implemented or considered by different countries, while governments are also actively promoting cooperative R&D arrangements between firms to reduce the future costs of emission reductions and the discovery of new mitigation technologies. (5) Therefore, in our markets all participants have the opportunity to buy and sell units, and they were required to hold a "coupon" to be able to avoid producing a unit. One could interpret this as holding an emissions permit to avoid abating one unit of pollution, but neutral framing was used in the experiment so alternative interpretations are reasonable. Marginal costs rise as subjects increase abatement and they can avoid these cost increases by purchasing permits. As in permit markets in the field, subjects had to compare the price of permits with their individual costs and on that basis decide whether to be permit buyers or sellers. This endogenous buyer/seller role determination exists in many other market contexts, such as in asset, securities and currency markets, and was one reason why the market was organized using double auction rules. (6) Such symmetric trading rules make it transparent for subjects to take either the buying or selling side, unlike posted offer markets where pre-determined seller and buyer roles are more natural.

The double auction market is used extensively in experiments and is considered a relatively competitive trading institution, which is another reason for this institutional design choice since a main goal of this study is to determine the influence of market competition on cooperation in a joint R&D task. Even in this market institution, however, traders can exert market power (Muller et al. 2002) and this appears to be a stronger tendency when they are in flexible trader roles (as in this study) rather than predetermined buyer or seller roles. Nevertheless, super-competitive pricing is observed in some sessions and is completely absent in others, so greater concentration on one side of the market does not often lead to significantly more collusion (Cason, Duke, and Gangadharan 2003). In this study, we incorporated several design features that allow some noncompetitive opportunities to emerge in this otherwise competitive double auction institution, such as repeated seller interactions, non-market communication between sellers, and a relatively concentrated (triopoly) market structure.

As shown in Table 2, three of the six subjects had relatively low abatement costs and high permit endowments so that they should be sellers in the market. The other three subjects had higher costs and low permit endowments and so they should be buyers. (Subjects correctly recognized their role as buyers or sellers, since after the initial six periods only 0.8% of the trader-periods had a subject trading on the wrong side.) At the start of each period the buyers were endowed with 3 permits each and the sellers with 7 permits each, creating a total supply of 30 permits. The competitive equilibrium price in the market ranged from 500 to 525 with 4 units traded by each subject, as illustrated in Figure 1. At this equilibrium, the three buyers earn a total of approximately 1,425 experimental dollars each period and the three sellers earn approximately 1,500. (The exact amount depends on where prices are in the equilibrium price interval.)

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Subjects participated in this market for six initial periods and then in blocks of three periods. After the first six periods and after some of the three period blocks, the three sellers played in a threshold public goods game. (7) This public good represents a common project such as a research joint venture, and the sellers chose their level of contribution. We chose a threshold public goods game instead of a linear public goods game as we were interested in research projects that require a particular scale to be successful. If the research project is successful, this cost-reducing innovation lowered the sellers' marginal abatement costs by 100 experimental dollars for the next block of three periods. We left structural cost levels unchanged in three-period blocks because experimental markets typically require several periods to reliably approach equilibrium.

For the common research project to be successful, two conditions were necessary. First, the total group contributions by the three sellers had to reach a threshold of 1500 or more experimental dollars. Contributions above this threshold are not returned, and contributors receive no refund if total contributions do not reach the threshold. Second, if group contributions reach or exceed this threshold, with a 75% probability the research is successful. This stochastic element represents the uncertainty involved in the realization of cost-reducing benefits from R&D projects and can be interpreted as luck. As shown in Figure 1, successful R&D leads to a reduction in the equilibrium price to 450-475, with 5 units being traded by each subject in equilibrium. This leads to predicted total profits for the buyers and the sellers of approximately 2,250 and 3,000, respectively. With these parameters the sellers' total return from the innovation is 4,500 for each three-period block. Thus, the expected step return (Croson and Marks 2000) to this threshold public good, accounting for the 0.75 probability that the good is provided, is (0.75 x 4500)/1500 = 2.25. (8) Buyers also benefit from a positive externality generated by the successful R&D. In particular, in equilibrium the three buyers gain from the innovation by a total of approximately 2250-1425 = 825 per period through lower permit prices.

If the research project is unsuccessful, sellers have a new opportunity to contribute to the project again after a three-period block. After every three-period block in which they have had costs lowered, the costs return to the original, higher level for three periods. At the end of that three-period block they have another opportunity to contribute to the project to lower their costs. The design thus features stationary repetition of the cycle of contributions and three-period blocks of the trading mechanism to allow for learning.

The joint profit-maximizing (optimal collusive) price for the Figure 1 parameters is 550 experimental dollars, with Q = 12 units traded (4 sold by each seller), regardless of whether sellers have low or high costs. Therefore, if sellers collude optimally they capture all of the benefits of the cost reduction that arise through their research collaboration. (9)

In the ten sessions where sellers were allowed to communicate, they could send typewritten computer chat messages to each other for 90 s before they made their contribution decisions. Chat communication is common in economic laboratories, since it admits rich use of language while still maintaining anonymity, control, and complete observability of the information that is being exchanged. While the sellers chatted, the buyers responded to a questionnaire by typing into their computer some information about their decisions in the marke. (10) The buyers did not know that sellers were communicating and were not given any information about the sellers' public good contribution decision.

Note that the communication opportunity occurs prior to the public good investment choice, rather than immediately before market trading begins for each period. We implemented communication in this way for several reasons. First, communication about a research collaboration is explicitly permitted among firms who have an approved joint venture, whereas explicit communication about prices is, of course, per se illegal. Therefore, our setup does not encourage price communication, although we did not implement any communication restrictions to prohibit discussions about prices. The second main reason for this design choice is to extend the literature on communication and collusion in experimental markets. In previous research, the subjects typically did not have other activities to discuss besides price and quantity choices, which may have made collusion focal, or possibly even an "experimenter demand effect" (Zizzo 2010). Our Combined treatment includes a cooperative activity which separates the communication period from the market periods, and can determine whether the collusion observed previously is robust to situations in which subjects make both investment and pricing choices rather than just pricing choices alone. We do not suggest any topic of conversation to the subjects, and they can just as naturally discuss prices as contribution levels. (11)

Market Only. In the Market Only treatment (16 sessions), subjects traded with each other for 27 periods and did not have an opportunity to lower their costs. In eight sessions sellers were allowed to communicate, again while buyers filled out questionnaires about their decisions in the experiment. Communication only occurs in the Combined treatment after three-period blocks that have high costs, and costs (and thus communication periods) were endogenous in that treatment. Therefore, all of the Market Only sessions were conducted after the Combined sessions so that the subjects in both treatments had communication opportunities in exactly the same periods. (12)

Public Good Only. In the Public Good Only treatment (16 sessions) subjects participated in groups of three for eight periods. This treatment isolates the sellers' potential benefits of R&D cooperation in a simple reduced form by immediately translating successful cost reduction to increased profits. Sellers did not have to realize these profits through market trading. Each subject received at least 1500 experimental dollars every period and in certain periods they had an opportunity to increase this income to 3,000 experimental dollars. These amounts correspond to the expected profit the sellers earn in competitive equilibrium for the three-period blocks following successful cost reduction in the Combined treatment. Just like the Combined treatment, to increase payoffs the subjects had to reach a total contribution threshold of 1,500, and also have an innovation success random draw (again with 0.75 probability). Thus, the set of Nash equilibria of this threshold public goods game (see Footnote 7) is exactly the same as in the Combined treatment.

B. Procedures

The experiment was conducted using Z-tree (Fischbacher 2007) and all subjects were students at the University of Melbourne with a variety of academic backgrounds, including economics. We conducted 52 independent sessions, and all 264 subjects were inexperienced in the sense that they had not participated in previous public goods or double auction market experiments. Although subjects interacted anonymously in three- or six-person fixed groups (depending on the treatment), multiple sessions were conducted simultaneously in the laboratory using 12 to 24 subjects. Upon arrival at the laboratory, subjects were randomly assigned a computer terminal, which had large partitions to prevent visual contact between subjects. Subjects read the experimental instructions and answered a set of computerized questions that examined and reinforced their understanding of the instructions. The experiment instructions for the Combined treatment are given in Supporting Information (Appendix S1). In the Market Only and the Combined treatments buyers and sellers had different instruction sheets in the communication condition since only the sellers communicated. Before the session began, the experimenter read aloud a one-page instructions summary to establish common knowledge about the main experimental rules and conditions. At the end of their session, which lasted about 2 hours, subjects filled out a demographic survey with questions regarding their age, gender, field of study, and other characteristics. They were paid privately in cash, and earnings averaged AUD 35. (13)

III. EXPERIMENTAL RESULTS

A. Cooperative Research Funding

We first explore whether individuals can recognize and coordinate to exploit the benefits from cooperation by funding the public good of collaborative research. To determine if this depends on participation in a competitive market stage and to study the impact of communication, we examine data in the Public Good Only and Combined treatments, with and without communication. We state the results and then provide statistical support.

Result 1: Even in the presence of payoff uncertainties, subjects frequently cooperate in the provision of the public good.

Result 2: Without communication, coordination and cooperation in public good provision is lower when subjects also interact in the competitive market. Allowing communication improves coordination and cooperation in public good provision.

We define two alternative dependent variables that measure cooperation in similar but distinct ways. The first variable is the number of times subjects met the contribution threshold of 1,500 experimental dollars as a proportion of the number of times they had an opportunity to contribute. Figure 2 presents these proportions graphically for each of the 36 sessions in the Public Goods Only and Combined treatments. The second variable is the average total contributions made by subjects in the periods when they were given an opportunity to fund the good. Both variables indicate that subjects often cooperate when they are given the opportunity, even when they face uncertainties in payoffs. This result extends the existing literature on cooperation in the threshold public goods to an environment with uncertain payoffs. Unlike environments with certain payoffs for reaching the threshold and a high return, contributors often fail to reach the threshold without communication. (14)

To compare behavior across the two treatments, we conduct non-parametric two-sample Wilcoxon rank-sum tests, using exactly one (statistically independent) aggregated measure from each session. To start with, we examine the group contributions in the first possible period in both treatments without communication and this shows that average contributions are approximately double in the Public Goods Only treatment (1,388 vs. 672), a difference that is highly significant (Wilcoxon p < .01). Thus, the initial periods of market competition in the Combined treatment appear to spill over to reduce subjects' success in their first chance at cooperation.

As reported in Table 3, both the number of times the threshold was met and the total contributions are higher for the Public Good Only treatment than for the Combined treatment. For example, when subjects are not allowed to communicate, they met the threshold 66% of the time, compared to 38% in Combined. However Figure 2 shows that for many of these across-treatment comparisons there is significant overlap in the distributions of contribution frequencies, so these conservative nonparametric tests do not indicate statistically significant differences.

Allowing communication between subjects, however, has a large and statistically significant impact on whether the threshold is met in both of the treatments. The top right column of Table 3 indicates that the data reject the null hypothesis that communication does not increase the frequency that subjects meet the public good provision threshold. Nevertheless, average total contributions are not different across treatments in the sessions where communication is allowed. (15) This indicates substantial miscoordination of contributions without communication. In the communication sessions the total contributions usually meet the threshold of 1,500 exactly, as agreed to in the contributors' chats. In sessions without communication, in contrast, average contributions both exceed and fall short of the threshold point in different periods. For example, in three of the ten Combined sessions without communication, the average total contributions exceed the highest of the contributions in the ten sessions with communication.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

Miscoordination also occurs in the Public Good Only sessions. For this treatment in the communication sessions, despite being allowed to contribute any amount between 0 to 1,200, individual contributions take only two values: either 0 (6% of the cases) or 500 (94% of the cases). In contrast, in sessions where subjects cannot communicate, individual contributions vary from 0 to 800, and the focal contribution of 500 occurs only 56% of the time. This increased coordination through communication has been observed previously in coordination games (Blume and Ortmann 2007; Cason, Sheremeta, and Zhang 2012). Although this public good can be provided if only two of the three agents contribute, all three contributed in every instance that the threshold was met. Not only was there no successful free-riding, but "cheap-riding" was also uncommon, since all individuals contributed at least their equal share of 500 in 94 percent of the cases where the threshold was met.

Table 4 reports results from panel regressions that examine the interaction between communication and competition in the market on cooperation in public goods provision. We estimate a probit model for the binary outcome of whether the threshold was met, and a tobit model for the total amount contributed. (16) These panel regressions assume a session-specific random effect. (17) The independent variables include a dummy variable for communication opportunities, a dummy variable for the Combined treatment and a treatment interaction term and time (expressed in the commonly used nonlinear form of 1/period). When subjects can communicate with each other, the threshold is met more often but total contributions are significantly greater only in the Combined treatment as indicated by the significant interaction term. (18) Subjects in the Combined treatment contribute significantly less on average when communication is not allowed. These reduced contributions in the Combined treatment could occur because, as documented below in Section III.C, the cost reduction from the public good provision often leads to a smaller increase in earnings than implemented in the Public Good Only treatment. Earnings depend on market trading, and the exact gains from cost reductions are variable. Behavioral spillovers could also cause subjects to be less cooperative in environments where they also participate in a competitive market stage.

B. Market Competition: Transaction Prices and Quantities

The contribution results for the Public Good Only and Combined treatments indicate that communication is important for promoting cooperation in public good provision. Given its significance in this cooperative domain, also documented elsewhere (Ledyard 1995), it is important to examine communication's impact in the competitive domain--specifically in the market stages of the Combined treatment and the Market Only treatment.

Result 3: Allowing opportunities to cooperate to fund public good provision does not significantly weaken price competition.

Result 4: Allowing subjects to communicate does not significantly increase prices in either the Combined or Market Only treatments.

To provide support for the above results we investigate how average price deviates from the competitive equilibrium, because the competitive equilibrium depends on whether sellers face high costs or low costs. As shown in Section II, in periods when sellers' costs are high the equilibrium price range is 500-525 and in periods when sellers' costs are lowered by 100 the equilibrium price range is 450-475. To identify potentially super-competitive pricing relative to this theoretical benchmark, we normalize transaction prices by subtracting the upper endpoint of the equilibrium interval (525 or 475) that is appropriate given the cost realization in each period.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Wilcoxon rank-sum tests that employ one (pooled aggregate) average transaction price per session indicate that the price deviation is significantly higher in the Market Only treatment compared to the Combined treatment when there are no communication opportunities available (18.37 vs. -13.59; p value: .019). When communication is allowed, however, no significant differences exist between these two treatments. Considering the impact of communication, in the Combined treatment the price deviation is significantly higher in sessions where communication is allowed (18.56 vs. -13.59; p value: .034). (19) This is consistent with the familiar finding that communication facilitates collusion (Isaac, Ramey, and Williams 1984). Figure 3 shows, however, that in later period blocks the differences across treatments disappear. Average prices converge to the upper endpoint of the competitive equilibrium price interval in all treatments.

To account for this time trend and other factors that can influence prices, column (1) of Table 5 presents a random effects regression of the average price deviation from competitive equilibrium during each three-period block. Explanatory variables include time (1/period), and dummy variables indicating whether sellers communicated at the beginning of the block of three periods and whether the costs they faced were low or not. Recall that costs are endogenous since they are determined based on sellers' success in (a) reaching the total contribution threshold and (b) obtaining a positive random draw leading to a successful innovation to reduce costs. We therefore use an instrumental variables approach, using the exogenous "luck" random draw for innovation success as the identification variable for low costs. (20)

The estimates indicate that the deviation of price from the competitive equilibrium is higher in periods when the sellers face lower costs. Buyers are not aware of any seller cost reductions, so this indicates that sellers succeed in maintaining higher prices and reaping a greater share of the benefits of cost reduction. Controlling for these cost reductions and the overall time trend, seller communication opportunities do not have a significant impact on prices. Column (2) of Table 5 indicates that communication does modestly increase transaction quantity, however, contrary to the expectation that sellers would use the chat room to make agreements to restrict their quantity sold. (Transaction quantity is also greater when sellers have low costs, as predicted by the competitive model, but not by the collusive model.) Recall that communication increases the probability of meeting the contribution threshold, as shown in Section III.A and Table 4, raising the probability that the sellers have lower costs. This provides a direct channel for communication opportunities to have an effect on market outcomes. (21)

Additional information regarding the relationship between communication and collusion is provided by the sellers' chat communication. While we do not attempt a detailed content analysis of their chats, a review of the communications data reveals, surprisingly, that sellers often do not discuss restricting quantities or price fixing. In particular, we identified discussions to fix prices in only four of the eight sessions in the Market Only treatment. In one session, for example, the subjects are very conspiratorial from the start of the communication stage and recognize that they are the only sellers in the market. They discuss fixing prices at a specific level and encourage each other to delay accepting offers from buyers. (22) Even in these cases, however, prices are not often above the competitive equilibrium.

Price fixing discussions were even more uncommon in the Combined treatment. Virtually none of the groups in the ten sessions attempted to conspire, in contrast to the frequent observation in previous price conspiracy experiments (dating back to Isaac and Plott 1981), where subjects usually recognize conspiratorial opportunities immediately and try to reach collusive agreements. Rather than trying to fix prices, in the Combined treatment subjects often focus instead on solving the coordination problem of funding the cost-reducing public good. They are generally cooperative and usually agree on contributing 500 each to the fund. (23)

The low rate of conspiracy in both treatments could be due, in part, to our use of the double auction trading institution. This institution is known for its competitive properties even with a small number of traders, and ample evidence exists that collusion is hard to maintain with these trading rules (Clauser and Plott 1993; Isaac, Ramey, and Williams 1984). Alternative design choices, such as a less competitive trading institution or chat rooms that were open during market trading to promote more seller discussion, could have increased the amount of collusion.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

C. Market Competition: Efficiency

A key performance measure that is directly observable in market experiments is efficiency--how well do market transactions exploit the available gains from exchange? Efficiency is the ratio of actual (observed) gains from trade to the maximum possible gains given the underlying cost and value conditions of the traders in the experimental session. Note that these maximum gains from trade are greater in the period blocks where sellers have succeeded in lowering their costs. Figure 4 presents the time series of efficiency across the treatments and shows that efficiency is lower in the Combined treatments than the Market Only treatments.

Result 5: Trading efficiency is lower in the Combined treatment, and is unaffected by the availability of communication.

To determine whether trading efficiency is statistically different across treatments we first conduct Wilcoxon rank-sum tests, which show that the Market Only treatment has higher efficiency levels than the Combined sessions (78 vs. 70 percent, p value <.01), for the no communication condition. The efficiency levels were not statistically different in the communication condition and also within the Combined and the Market Only treatments with and without communication. We also present a random effects regression for trading efficiency in column (3) of Table 5. The results also show that trading efficiency is lower in the Combined treatment, and the opportunity to communicate does not impact efficiency.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

D. R&D Externality

Although trading efficiency declines in the Combined treatment when sellers can collaborate to reduce their costs, this is not because total realized trading surplus declines. Efficiency is lower in this treatment relative to the Market Only treatment because the cost reductions lead to a greater maximum trading surplus. That is, a higher maximum surplus is used in the denominator of the efficiency measure in the low-cost periods. Figure 5 shows that total gains from exchange are usually higher in the Combined treatment than the Market Only treatment. (These figures do not subtract the R&D investments that sellers incur to reduce costs.) The question we address in this subsection is how this increased surplus is divided between the sellers and the buyers in the market.

Result 6: R&D externalities that benefit buyers are positive though smaller than predicted.

Both buyers and sellers earn higher profits in the period blocks in which costs are low. This is documented in random effects regressions shown in Table 5, using buyer profits (column 4) and seller profits (column 5) as dependent variables. While both agent types earn significantly higher profits in the low-cost periods, sellers' total profit increase is much higher than buyers' total profit increase. (24) This indicates that the R&D externalities that benefit buyers are positive but relatively small, and buyers' indirect benefit from the lower costs is much smaller than the sellers' direct benefit. For the parameters implemented in the experiment, buyers realize less than half of the R&D externality predicted by a strictly equilibrium analysis. This shortfall reflects the less than 100% efficiency realized by the market, and some high prices in a few sessions.

IV. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

In this paper, we present a novel experiment examining the interactions between competition and cooperation. This link can be difficult to measure empirically as both competitive and cooperative preferences are often hard to isolate in the field. Consequently, only limited evidence on this interaction has been provided by field data.

We find in this experiment that although individuals cooperate to fund a public good when given an opportunity, they cooperate somewhat less frequently in environments where they also compete in a market. These behavioral spillovers could be attributed to the increased cognitive load required to devote attention to both the public good and market trading tasks (Cason, Savikhin, and Sheremeta 2012). The lower cooperation rate could also be due to the different mechanisms through which subjects realize the benefits of cooperation. Although we chose a double auction trading institution that usually leads to high efficiency and competitive prices even with small numbers of traders, the relatively low realized trading surplus limited the benefits of cooperation accruing to the subjects. Even though sellers' profits in period blocks when they face lower costs were on average higher, compared to when costs were high, the difference between the two profit levels is less than the return implemented exogenously in the Public Good Only sessions. We observe a spillover from competition that lowers cooperation; this spillover is however only weakly significant and is overcome by the influence of communication among sellers. Whatever the source of these differences in cooperation in the public good and market environments, our results suggest that measures of cooperation in one context may not extend directly to other, external situations.

Allowing participants to communicate substantially improves their ability to coordinate in funding a public good, especially in the Combined treatment. In particular, the threshold was met almost three times more often in the Combined treatment when communication was allowed. This suggests that while communication is important in both the treatments, it has a critical role to play in the market environment, where competitive forces make cooperation more challenging.

We find no significant behavioral spillover from cooperation to weaken competition. This is inspite of the fact that we incorporated several design features that have been shown to increase collusion, such as repeated seller interactions and a concentrated (triopoly) market structure. Given our research emphasis on the impact of competitive market interactions, however, we chose a relatively competitive double auction trading institution so as to isolate the effect of competition. The strong market competition in a double auction could explain the lack of behavioral spillovers from cooperation to weaken competition. Other trading institutions that are less competitive may have increased any potential spillover to reduce price competition.

Allowing communication does not have a substantial impact on prices and efficiency, hence seller communication does not lead to collusion in our experiment. This suggests that previous results supporting collusion, such as Suetens (2008), could be attributed to the choice of trading institutions or how collusion is allowed to emerge in the market structure. Communication in our experiment nevertheless influences market performance because it leads more frequently to successful R&D collaborations and lower costs. Price deviations are higher when costs are lowered for sellers in the market because successful innovation reduces the competitive equilibrium price. Average actual prices also decrease, so giving sellers the option to cooperate increases the earnings of both sellers and buyers. R&D externalities are therefore observed in our experiment, implying that allowing one side of the market to cooperate can lead to positive benefits. Our findings are therefore in the spirit of results highlighting the social desirability of R&D (Cellini and Lambertini 2009). In future research, it may be useful to allow for communication at different stages of the experiment so as to examine if behavior is invariant to chat timings.

It is always important to be cautious in generalizing from the controlled environment of the laboratory to naturally occurring markets. With that caveat in mind, however, our findings indicate that competitive forces and preferences for cooperation can potentially co-exist. In particular, it suggests the importance of encouraging the emergence of trading institutions that are less sensitive to collusive forces, specifically in areas that could gain from cooperation such as R&D into new environmental technologies. In such situations it may be possible to encourage cooperative efforts without endangering competition and efficiency.

ABBREVIATION

R&D: Research and Development

doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00486.x

REFERENCES

Amir, R. "Modelling Imperfectly Appropriable R&D Via Spillovers." International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18, 2000, 1013-32.

Bednar, J., and S. Page. "Can Game(s) Theory Explain Culture'? The Emergence of Cultural Behavior within Multiple Games." Rationality and Society, 19, 2007, 65-97.

Bednar, J., Y. Chen, T. Liu, and S. Page. "Behavioral Spillovers and Cognitive Load in Multiple Games: An Experimental Study." Games and Economic Behavior, 74, 2012, 12-31.

Blume, A., and A. Ortmann. "The Effects of Costless Pre-Play Communication: Experimental Evidence from Games with Pareto-Ranked Equilibria." Journal of Economic Theory, 132, 2007, 274-90.

Brandts, J., and D. Cooper. "A Change Would Do You Good: An Experimental Study of How to Overcome Coordination Failure in Organizations." American Economic Review, 96, 2006, 669-93.

Buckley, N., S. Mestelman, and M. Shehata. "Subsidizing Public Inputs." Journal of Public Economics, 87, 2003, 819-46.

Cabral, L. "R&D Cooperation and Product Market Competition." International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18, 2000, 1033-47.

Caloghirou, Y., S. Ioannides, and N.Vonortas. "Research Joint Ventures." Journal of Economic Surveys, 17(4), 2003, 541-70.

Cason, T., C. Duke, and L. Gangadharan. "Market Power in Tradable Emission Markets: A Laboratory Testbed for Emissions Trading in Port Phillip Bay, Victoria." Ecological Economics, 46, 2003, 469-91.

Cason, T., A. Savikhin, and R. Sheremeta. "Behavioral Spillovers in Coordination Games." European Economic Review, 56, 2012, 233-45.

Cason, T., R. Sheremeta, and J. Zhang. "'Communication and Efficiency in Competitive Coordination Games." Games and Economic Behavior, 76, 2012, 26-46.

Cellini, R., and L. Lambertini. "Dynamic R&D with Spillovers: Competition vs. Cooperation." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 33, 2009, 568-82.

Clauser, L., and C. Plott. "On the Anatomy of the 'Nonfacilitating' Features of the Double Auction Institution in Conspiratorial Markets," in The Double Auction Market: Institutions, Theories, and Laboratory Evidence, edited by D. Friedman and J. Rust. New York: Addison-Wesley, 1993.

Cooper, R., and T. Ross. "Sustaining Cooperation with Joint Ventures." The Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 25(1), 2009, 31-54.

Croson, R., and M. Marks. "Step Returns in Threshold Public Goods: A Meta and Experimental Analysis." Experimental Economics, 2(3), 2000, 239-59.

Dannenberg, A., A. Loschel, G. Paolacci, C. Reif, and A. Tavoni. "Coordination under Threshold Uncertainty in a Public Goods Game," ZEW Discussion Paper No. 11-065, 2011.

Davis, J., H. Quirmbach, and C. Swenson. "Income Tax Subsidies and Research and Development Spending in a Competitive Economy: An Experimental Study." The Journal of the American Taxation Association, 17 (Supplement), 1995, 1 26.

d'Aspremont, C., and A. Jacquemin. "Cooperative and Non-cooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers." American Economic Review, 78, 1988, 1133-37.

deBondt, R. "Spillovers and Innovative Activities." International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15, 1996, 1-28.

Deck, C., and N. Erkal. Forthcoming. "An Experimental Analysis of Dynamic Incentives to Share Knowledge." Economic Inquiry, 2011. doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00333.x

Duso, T., L. Roller, and J. Seldeslachts. "Collusion through Joint R&D: An Empirical Assessment", Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, TI 2010-112/1, 2010.

Falk, A., U. Fischbacher, and S. Gachter. Forthcoming. "Living in Two Neighborhoods--Social Interaction Effects in the Lab." Economic Inquiry, 201 I. doi: 10.1111/j. 1465-7295.2010.00332.x

Fischbacher, U. "z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-Made Economic Experiments." Experimental Economics, 10, 2007, 171-78.

Godby, R. "Market Power and Emissions Trading: Theory and Laboratory Results." Pacific Economic Review, 5, 2000, 349-64.

Goeree, M., and E. Helland. "Do Research Joint Ventures Serve a Collusive Function?" Working Paper No: 448, University of Zurich, 2010.

Harabi, N. "The Impact of Vertical R&D Cooperation on Firm Innovation: An Empirical Investigation." Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 11, 2002, 93-108.

Isaac, R. M., V. Ramey, and A. Williams. "The Effects of Market Organization on Conspiracies in Restraint of Trade." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 5, 1984, 191-222.

Isaac, R. M. and C. Plott. "The Opportunity for Conspiracy in Restraint of Trade: An Experimental Study." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 2, 1981, 1-30.

Isaac, R. M., and S. Reynolds. "Schumpeterian Competition in Experimental Markets." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 17, 1992, 59-100.

Jaffe, A., R. Newell, and R. Stavins. "Environmental Policy and Technological Change." Environmental and Resource Economics, 22, 2002, 41-69.

Kamien, M., E. Muller, and I. Zang. "Research Joint Ventures and R&D Cartels." American Economic Review, 82, 1992, 1293-306.

Lambertini, L., S. Poddar, and D. Sasaki. "RJV's in Product Innovation and Cartel Stability." Review of Economic Design, 7, 2003, 465-77.

Ledyard, J. +'Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research," in The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by J. Kagel and A. Roth. Princeton, N J: Princeton University Press, 1995.

Ledyard, J., and Szakaly-Moore, K., "Designing Organizations for Trading Pollution Rights." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 25, 1994, 167-96.

Muller, R. A., S. Mestelman, J. Spraggon, and R. Godby. "Can Double Auctions Control Monopoly and Monopsony Power in Emissions Trading Markets'?" Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44, 2002, 70-92.

Poyago-Theotoky, J. '+The Organization of R&D and Environmental Policy." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 62, 2007, 63-75.

Savikhin, A., and R. Sheremeta. Forthcoming. "Simultaneous Decision-Making in Competitive and Cooperative Environments." Economic Inquiry, 2012. doi: 10.1111/j. 1465-7295.2012.00474.x

Smith, V., G. Suchanek, and A. Williams. "Bubbles, Crashes, and Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets." Econometrica, 56, 1988, 1119-51.

Suetens, S. "Cooperative and Non-cooperative R&D in Experimental Duopoly Markets." International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23, 2005, 63-82.

--. "Does R&D Cooperation Facilitate Price Collusion? An Experiment." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 66+ 2008, 822-36.

Zizzo, D. "'Experimenter Demand Effects in Economic Experiments." Experimental Economics, 13, 2010, 75-98.

SUPPORTING INFORMATION

Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online version of this article:

Appendix S1. Experiment Instructions.

Figure S1. Seller's Decision Screen (Price Offers).

Figure S2. Buyer's Decision Screen When Two Prices Are Observed.

Figure S3. Buyer's Decision Screen When One Price Is Observed.

Figure S4. "Virtual" Dice Roll to Determine Whether Period Ends Before All Buyers Purchased.

Figure S5. Example Seller Outcome Screen.

TIMOTHY N. CASON and LATA GANGADHARAN *

* We thank Cary Deck, Jim Murphy, Ralph Siebert, John Stranlund, Nori Tarui, Christian Vossler, two anonymous referees, an editor, and audiences at UNSW, La Trobe, Purdue, East Anglia, University of Montpellier, Economic Science Association conferences, and the World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists (Montreal) for helpful discussions and comments. Justin Krieg provided excellent research assistance. Part of this research was conducted while Cason was a visiting fellow with the Department of Economics, University of Melbourne. This research has been supported by a grant from the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency's National Center for Environmental Research (NCER) Science to Achieve Results (STAR) program. Although the research described in the article has been funded in part through EPA grant number R833672, it has not been subjected to any EPA review and therefore does not necessarily reflect the views of the Agency, and no official endorsement should be inferred. Funding from the Australian Research Council contributed toward the payments for experimental subjects. We are responsible for any errors or omissions.

Cason: Department of Economics, Purdue University, 100 S. Grant Street, West Lafayette, IN 47907-2076. Phone 765-494-1737, Fax 765-494-9658, E-mail cason@purdue.edu

Gangadharan: Department of Economics, Monash University, Clayton Campus, Victoria, Australia. Phone +61 3 9905 2345, Fax +61 3 9905 5476, E-mail Lata.Gangadharan@monash.edu

(1.) Climate change is a prominent example highlighting the need for both cooperation and competition. While cooperation among firms and countries is needed to solve this complex international collective action problem, competition between firms is also essential to provide incentives for innovation to reduce the costs of controlling emissions. This complementarity has led to a growing interest in both competition and cooperation, with economists and policy makers endeavoring to find market solutions to social dilemmas, such as markets for emissions permits.

(2.) Cellini and Lambertini (2009) however show that irrespective of the amount of R&D spillover, cooperative behavior in R&D would be preferable from both a private and a social point of view. Their dynamic model allows for investment smoothing over time, hence the externality is internalized via the joint profit maximization in the R&D phase and this is socially desirable irrespective of the spillover effects. Amir (2000) compares different earlier models with R&D spillovers and illustrates the sensitivity of the results to small changes in model specifications.

(3.) Many of the theoretical models developed in these papers build on the seminal research by d'Aspremont and Jacquemin (1989) and Kamien, Muller, and Zang (1992).

(4.) These "downstream" benefits through lower market prices are similar to surplus externalities that can motivate vertical R&D collaborations (Harabi 2002).

(5.) Jaffe, Newell, and Stavins (2002) discuss the importance of including innovation and technological change for understanding alternative policy responses to environmental challenges.

(6.) Ledyard and Szakaly-Moore (1994), Godby (2000), and Muller et al. (2002) are examples of other market experiments using an environmental context that also feature endogenous role determination. Smith, Suchanek, and Williams (1988) is an early example of all asset market experiment sharing this same feature.

(7.) An alternative design could introduce the punic good coordination problem prior to introducing the market. We chose to introduce the market first, since the value of the public good is realized through market trading. It is necessary for subjects to first understand how their costs influence their profit before they can reasonably understand the benefits of investments required to lower those costs.

(8.) Multiple Nash equilibria exist in this threshold public goods game. In a Pareto-dominated equilibrium no agent contributes anything and the good is not provided. For the parameters used in the experiment, any total contributions that sum to 1500--as long as no individual (risk neutral) agent contributes more than the expected benefit (1,125 per agent)--constitute a Pareto efficient equilibrium. No equilibria exist with only one positive contributor. With three potential contributors and a threshold of 1,500, clearly the focal, efficient equilibrium is a contribution of 500 per agent. As documented in the results section, this is the equilibrium that is typically played.

(9.) Individual sellers could withhold one (marginal) unit unilaterally in both cost conditions and benefit sufficiently from higher prices received on other units to make this profitable, but of course this creates another public goods problem with each seller having the incentive to free-ride on others' quantity restriction.

(10.) This buyer activity led all subjects to type during the same time intervals. This was intended to obscure buyer and seller identities and reduce possible suspicions by the buyers that the sellers were communicating with each other.

(11.) In the Combined treatment, market trading commenced within 60 s of the chat conclusion in 80% of the periods, and the median time between chat and trading was 47 s. So the contribution and pricing decisions both followed quickly after the communication phase.

(12.) To ensure comparability with the no-communication sessions in the Combined treatment, buyers answered the same within-session questionnaire even in sessions where sellers were not allowed to communicate.

(13.) At the time the experiment was conducted, 10 Australian dollars could be exchanged for about 8.5 U.S. dollars.

(14.) Most previous experimental studies on provision point public goods with uncertainty implement threshold uncertainty, in which contributors do not know exactly what level of contribution is necessary to provide the public good. For example, see Dannenberg et al. (2011) for a recent discussion. By contrast, in our design the threshold is known to subjects, but even if the threshold is met it is not certain whether the public good (in our case R&D success resulting in a cost reduction) is provided. This reflects the nature of R&D, where even well-funded projects can be unsuccessful. An interesting extension for future work would make the probability of success a function of how much is invested in R&D, rather than having a constant probability of success whenever the threshold is reached.

(15.) The distributions of average total contributions are marginally significantly different in the communication and no communication conditions for the Combined treatment according to a Kolmogorov-Smirnov test (p value = .055).

(16.) We only examine the data from periods when there is a potential opportunity for the subjects to participate in a common project. There is a maximum of seven such opportunities per session. The tobit model is appropriate for the model of total contributions, since 17 of the 179 contributions were at the lower threshold of zero.

(17.) With one minor exception noted below in Footnote 22, all of the regression results shown in Tables 4 and 5 are qualitatively unchanged when using cluster-robust standard errors rather than random effects to capture the non-independence of errors within sessions.

(18.) The impact of communication is also clearly observed in an unreported random effects probit regression of individual contributions, in which the dependent variable is whether the subject has contributed 500 or more in the Public Good Only environment. In this regression we also control for demographic and individual specific characteristics such as gender, course of study, region of origin, academic performance, and experience.

(19.) All of these results continue to hold when restricting the Combined treatment to just the high-cost periods. The conclusions based on multiple pairwise comparisons that employ the Combined treatment without communication are robust to using an application of the Holm-Bonferroni adjustment.

(20.) Subjects can influence the costs by contributing more to reach the threshold, but cannot influence the random draw (luck) by their decisions. Hence luck is an appropriate instrument, as it is merely the realization of an independent random draw. In the first stage regression where the costs are regressed on the full set of exogenous variables including the instrument, luck, we find that the instrument used is highly significant (p value = .00) in explaining the costs faced by subjects.

(21.) Prices do not immediately adjust to their new equilibrium level following a cost change, of course, due to hysteresis effects that are commonly observed in market experiments. To reduce the influence of these effects on our conclusions, we also estimate the price regression after dropping the first period of each three-period block, which is the period that could immediately follow a cost change. The estimation results are qualitatively unchanged, so we do not report this regression result here.

(22.) The entire chat script of the first chat room for this session (which is opened after Period 6) is as follows, where different statements (typically made by different subjects) are separated by semicolons: "gday; hi; hello; okay i have a tonne of coupons, ill sell him for around 550 each time, sound good?; me too ill sell; who's buying'?; no sell higher; sounds good; sell higher?; ok; what price; keep the price high; 600? 700? 1ol; 600 is fine; dont spoilt market; ok 600; cool; put 750 at start, reduce slowly; ok, min 550; ok; sweet; yeah anything below 540 is a loss lol; lol"

(23.) The data do not indicate that sellers in the Combined treatment were time constrained in the 90 s of chat to discuss a price conspiracy, since they actually exchanged a significantly smaller fraction of their chat messages in the final 30 s than sellers did in the Market Only sessions (Wilcoxon p < .05). In other words, more groups tended to finish their chats early in the more complex Combined treatment than the Market Only treatment. In addition, a count of the number of statements per chat shows that sellers in the Combined treatment wrote fewer statements than in the other two treatments (13.0 statements per chat in Combined, 15.4 in Market Only, and 18.5 in Public Goods Only treatment).

(24.) Moreover, this marginally significant increase in profit (454) for buyers when seller costs are low is not statistically significant in an alternative (unreported) specification of the error structure, using robust-clustering at the session level rather than session random effects.
TABLE 1
Experimental Design (264 Total Subjects)

 Market and
 Public Goods Public Goods
 Only Market Only (Combined)

With Eight sessions Eight sessions Ten sessions
 communication (24 subjects) (48 subjects) (60 subjects)
Without Eight sessions Eight sessions Ten sessions
 communication (24 subjects) (48 subjects) (60 subjects)

TABLE 2
Marginal Abatement Costs Assigned to Firms

Units of Abatement Buyer 1 Buyer 2 Buyer 3

1 400 400 400
2 450 450 450
3 500 500 500
4 550 550 550
5 600 600 600
6 650 650 650
7 700 700 700
8 750* 750* 750*
9 800* 800* 800*
10 850* 850* 850*
Endowment 3 3 3

Units of Abatement Seller 1 Seller 2 Seller 3

1 175 (75) 175 (75) 175 (75)
2 225 (125) 225 (125) 225 (125)
3 275 (175) 275 (175) 275 (175)
4 325 (225)* 325 (225)* 325 (225)*
5 375 (275)* 375 (275)* 375 (275)*
6 425 (325)* 425 (325)* 425 (325)*
7 475 (375)* 475 (375)* 475 (375)*
8 525 (425)* 525 (425)* 525 (425)*
9 575 (475)* 575 (475)* 575 (475)*
10 625 (525)* 625 (525)* 625 (525)*
Endowment 7 7 7

Total Endowment = 30

Competitive Equilibrium Price = 500-525; Units
Traded: 4 each

Competitive Equilibrium Price (with cost reduction)
= 450-475; Units Traded: 5 each

Collusive Outcome, Price = 550; Units Traded: 4 each

Notes: The permits endowed (pre-trading) allow firms to avoid the
abatement costs shown in bold. Costs in periods with successful cost
reduction are shown in parentheses.

Note: The permits endowed (pre-trading) allow firms to avoid the
abatement costs is indicated with *.

TABLE 3
Summary of Results by Communication and Market Treatment

Description No Communication Communication

Fraction of Public Good Only 0.663 0.950
opportunities Combined 0.377 0.935
threshold is met Wilcoxon p value .21 .50

Average total Public Good Only 1423.2 1425.0
contributions Combined 867.7 1463.6
 Wilcoxon p value .14 .61

Description Wilcoxon p value

Fraction of Public Good Only .04 **
opportunities Combined .01 ***
threshold is met Wilcoxon p value

Average total Public Good Only .47
contributions Combined .25
 Wilcoxon p value

** Significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

TABLE 4
Random Effects Probit and Tobit Regressions
of Project Contributions

 Threshold Total
Variables is Met (a) Contributions (b)

Communication allowed 2.485 * -0.32
 (dummy) (1.134) (202.90)
Combined treatment -1.547 -598.47 ***
 (dummy) (0.996) (190.95)
Communication x 0.874 642.87 **
Combined interaction (1.586) (271.94)
 (dummy)
1/Period -0.263 257.61 ***
 (0.485) (78.15)
Constant 0.841 1311.00 ***
 (0.751) (145.97)
Probability > [chi square] 0.02 0.0001
Number of observations 179 179

Note: The numbers in the parentheses are the standard
errors.

(a) Random effects probit regression.

(b) Random effects tobit regression.

* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%;
*** significant at 1%0.

TABLE 5
Random Effects Regressions of Market Performance Measures

 (1) (2) (3)
 Price Transaction Trading
 Deviations Quantity Efficiency
Variables IV Regression IV Regression IV Regression

Lowcost (a) 41.69 *** 1.635 *** -0.005
 (9.23) (0.616) (0.024)
1/Period 22.93 *** -4.042 *** -0.192 ***
 (6.79) (0.451) (0.017)
Combined treatment -9.14 -0.540 -0.091 ***
 (dummy) (12.54) (0.736) (0.022)
Communication -1.69 1.410 * -0.007
 allowed (dummy) (12.58) (0.740) (0.023)
Sellers communicated -4.83 -0.148 -0.007
 at the beginning of (6.55) (0.436) (0.017)
 three-period block
 (dummy)
Constant -0.21 14.394 *** 1.007 ***
 (11.26) (0.660) (0.020)
Observations 288 228 288
Number of sessions 36 36 36

 (4) (5)

 Buyer Profits Seller Profits
Variables IV Regression IV Regression

Lowcost (a) 454 * 3113 ***
 (270) (284)
1/Period -1116 *** -482 **
 (198) (209)
Combined treatment 33 -776 **
 (dummy) (338) (358)
Communication -42 -7
 allowed (dummy) (340) (360)
Sellers communicated 40 -130
 at the beginning of (191) (201)
 three-period block
 (dummy)
Constant 3532 *** 4642 ***
 (304) (322)
Observations 288 288
Number of sessions 36 36

Note: Standard errors in parentheses.

(a) Lowcost is instrumented and the
estimates are from an IV regression.

*** p<.01; ** p<.05; * p<.1.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有