Differentiated assets: an experimental study on bubbles.
Chan, Kenneth S. ; Lei, Vivian ; Vesely, Filip 等
I. INTRODUCTION
The bubble-and-crash phenomenon in experimental asset markets,
first reported in Smith, Suchanek, and Williams (1988), has been shown
to be rather robust to various manipulations in the experimental design
(see, e.g., King et al. 1993; Porter and Smith 1995; Van Boening,
Williams, and LaMaster 1993). (1) In all these markets, an asset with a
life of 15 or 30 periods is traded. The asset pays a common dividend to
all holders at the end of each trading period; and the dividend
structure is common knowledge to all traders. Rather than tracking the
fundamental value, which is derived from the expected dividend for the
number of periods remaining, prices tend to exhibit a prolonged boom and
crash pattern in a vast majority of the markets studied in the
literature.
Note that the bubble-and-crash phenomenon has also been observed in
a setting where two assets are traded in two separate double-auction
markets simultaneously. Fisher and Kelly (2000) study rate-of-return
parity in such an environment. The main treatment variable that they
consider is the expected dividends of the assets. In some treatments,
the two assets pay exactly the same expected dividend, whereas in some
others one asset pays twice as much. They find that bubbles not only
exist in both markets but also positively correlate with each other.
Childs and Mestelman (2006) manipulate the expected dividend as well as
the variance of the dividends. Their findings are consistent with Fisher
and Kelly's in that bubbles occur in both markets and that
rate-of-return parity receives less support as the assets become more
differentiated.
The main objective of this paper is to continue the research line
initiated by Fisher and Kelly (2000) and investigate if and how
differences in assets' characteristics affect investors trading
strategies and, as a result, the magnitude of bubbles. Motivated by
empirical evidence which suggests that bond markets are in general less
susceptible to the dramatic boom-and-crash price pattern, we first
construct a bond-market-like laboratory environment where investors are
free to trade assets that can be differentiated not only from their
dividend payments but also from their maturity periods. (2) The research
questions we ask are as follows: Does the existence of multiple assets
that can be differentiated from their dividends and/or maturities help
reduce mispricing, and if so, why? To tackle these questions, we adopt a
2 x 2 design in which an asset called X has a 30-period life duration
and pays, on average, 7 francs per period as a dividend. These intrinsic characteristics are fixed in all treatments. The characteristics of an
alternative asset called Y, on the other hand, vary depending on the
treatment. It pays either the same expected dividend as X or twice as
much. In terms of its life duration, it lasts either 30 or 15 periods.
As a result, we have the following four treatments for this set of the
experiment: SdurSdiv (baseline), SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv, where
S, D, dur, and div stand for same, different, duration, and dividend,
respectively.
If we assume that traders have common and rational expectations, we
would expect prices to follow fundamental values in both markets. But
since the evidence of the bubble-and-crash phenomenon is so overwhelming
in the literature, we feel that evaluating a hypothesis of no bubbles is
a bit insensitive. Instead, we propose the following hypothesis for
evaluation.
Hypothesis 1: Price deviations from the fundamental in either X or
Y market do not depend on if and how the two assets are intrinsically different.
We also evaluate the relative price between the two assets against
the prediction of rate-of-return parity as in Fisher and Kelly (2000)
and Childs and Mestelman (2006). The null hypothesis that we advance for
evaluation is stated as follows.
Hypothesis 2: Deviations from the prediction of rate-of-return
parity do not depend on if and how the two assets are intrinsically
different.
In addition to studying if and how differences in assets'
intrinsic characteristics affect the bubble formation, we also design a
second set of the experiment to investigate if and how policies or
regulations that help differentiate two otherwise identical assets
affect the intensity of bubbles. The first regulation that we consider
is a securities transaction tax (STT). Note that a STT or a Tobin tax
has long been considered by some as a policy tool to curb short-term
speculation, reduce volatility, and improve market efficiency in stock
or foreign exchange markets (see, e.g., Palley 1999; Stiglitz 1989;
Summers and Summers 1989; Tobin 1984). (3) But this policy instrument
has never received that much attention or any serious support until
recently. In the wake of the current economic crisis, the European Union
has proposed a financial transaction tax on trading of stocks, bonds,
and derivative contracts. (4)
While this proposal has received full support from France and
Germany, primarily for revenue-raising and other political reasons, the
United Kingdom, home to the biggest financial center in Europe, has
vigorously opposed to it. Without a global agreement, as it argues, an
EU-wide transaction tax would easily chase transactions elsewhere and
thus could hardly serve as an effective revenue-raising or even a
market-stabilizing tool.
Whether or not a regional transaction tax can be an effective
revenue-raising tool is not within the scope of this study. Instead, we
are more interested in the effectiveness of its traditional aims,
namely, to discourage speculative trading and to improve market
efficiency. The research questions we ask are as follows: Given that
transactions are free to move from one market to another, would a
transaction tax imposed on one asset cause transactions to migrate to
its untaxed substitute? How does such a tax affect asset prices? Does it
help reduce mispricing at least in the taxed market? To answer these
questions, we introduce a treatment, called Taxy, where the intrinsic
characteristics of X and Y are exactly the same as in the baseline
SdurSdiv treatment. A fixed transaction tax that is about 0.5% of the
initial fundamental value is imposed on asset Y. Note that our paper is
not the first study to investigate the effects of transaction fees or
STTs on bubble magnitude or market volatility. King et al. (1993) find
that a fixed transaction fee has mixed effects on the intensity of
bubbles. Bloomfield, O'Hara, and Saar (2009) find that a STT
discourages informed traders' activity as much as it does to the
uninformed. As a result, the tax has no significant impact on pricing
errors or market efficiency. Both King et al. and Bloomfield,
O'Hara, and Saar investigate the effects of STTs in a single-market
environment and thus cannot address issues concerning trading migration
from a taxed asset to its untaxed substitutes. Hanke et al. (2010) is
the only study that introduces a STT in a two-market setting. In a
treatment where only one asset is subject to the transaction tax, Hanke
et al. observe a significant amount of trading being shifted to the
untaxed market and that market efficiency decreases dramatically in the
taxed one. Our Taxy treatment differs from Hanke et al. in the following
ways. First, assets' fundamental values in Hanke et al. follow a
random walk without drift, implying that, in any given period, future
fundamental values are not known to subjects. In our study, fundamental
values follow a downward trend that is constructed in the same way as in
Smith, Suchanek, and Williams (1988). Also as in Smith, Suchanek, and
Williams, both current and future fundamental values are common
knowledge to all traders. Therefore, we believe that our study is much
simpler and more comparable to the literature pioneered by Smith,
Suchanek, and Williams. Second, while Hanke et al. use a tax rate of
0.5%, we choose a fixed transaction fee in order to further simplify our
environment.
The second regulation we consider in this set of the experiment is
a minimum holding period requirement. Other than more market-based
transaction taxes, direct restrictions on capital mobility have been
adopted in various forms by numerous countries to fight asset bubbles
and currency appreciation. (5) To deal with surges in capital inflows,
Indonesia is one of the most recent examples to implement control
measures including a 1- or 6-month minimum holding period on certain
securities. In a treatment called Holdy, we consider a policy tool
similar to this rather straightforward intervention to see if such a
capital control can help mitigate bubbles. Specifically, we introduce a
minimum holding period of 5 that is imposed only on asset Y. To our
knowledge, the only experimental study that has investigated the impact
of a similar trading restriction, though for a completely different
purpose, is Lei, Noussair, and Plott (2001). To investigate if
speculation is necessary to create bubbles, Lei, Noussair, and Plott
remove subjects' ability to speculate by imposing a ban on
reselling any shares acquired earlier in the experiment. They find that
the ban on the reselling is not able to moderate the magnitude of
bubbles unless a commodity market is also operated alongside. Note that
the purpose of introducing a commodity market in Lei, Noussair, and
Plott is to simply divert excess trade that is thought to be related to
decision errors in the asset market. As such, the commodity market is
operated with a simple one-period supply and demand structure repeated
under stationary conditions. Their laboratory environment is thus
dramatically different from ours in that we have two markets operated
simultaneously for trading assets that are perfect substitutes in terms
of their fundamental values.
Regarding the impact of the two trading regulations on the
magnitude of bubbles, we propose the following hypothesis for
evaluation.
Hypothesis 3: Price deviations from the fundamental in either X or
Y market of the Taxy and Holdy treatments do not differ significantly
firm those in the baseline SdurSdiv treatment.
Also, since X and Y are perfect substitutes in the treatments of
Taxy and Holdy, we expect that, as a response to the transaction tax or
the holding period requirement imposed on asset Y, a significant amount
of transactions will be shifted to market X.
Hypothesis 4: The turnover in market X (Y) is significantly higher
(lower) in the Taxy and Holdy treatments than in the baseline SdurSdiv
treatment.
Finally, since Fisher and Kelly (2000) and Childs and Mestelman
(2006) find that rate-of-return parity is supported when assets share
the same intrinsic characteristics, we expect that deviations from the
prediction of rate-of-return parity in the Taxy and Holdy treatments do
not differ significantly from those in the baseline treatment.
Hypothesis 5: Deviations from the prediction of rate-of-return
parity in either X or Y market of the Taxy and Holily treatments do not
differ significant from those in the baseline SdurSdiv treatments.
As reported in detail in Section III, the price patterns of both
assets in the baseline treatment exhibit the same bubble-and-crash
phenomenon as observed in the literature. The two bubbles coincide with
one another in most of the SdurSdiv sessions, which is consistent with
the results reported by Fisher and Kelly (2000) and Childs and Mestelman
(2006). In the other three treatments where X and Y have different
intrinsic characteristics, the deviations from fundamental values are
significantly smaller than in the baseline treatment. Note that this
difference in the overall price pattern cannot be explained by the
liquidity levels in the four treatments. Liquidity, defined as the total
cash endowment divided by the initial value of all shares, has been
shown to be positively correlated with asset bubbles (see, e.g.,
Caginalp, Porter, and Smith 2001). The liquidity level in, for example,
DdurSdiv is much larger than that in SdurSdiv. Yet, prices in most of
the DdurSdiv sessions tend to track fundamental values rather well.
While Hypothesis 1 is refuted by our data, the deviations from
rate-of-return parity in SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv are not
statistically different from those in the baseline treatment, which is
consistent with Hypothesis 2.
The results from Taxy reported in Section IV indicate that,
compared to the baseline treatment, the transaction tax imposed on asset
Y has no significant impact on the trading volume in either market. The
holding period requirement, on the other hand, significantly reduces
asset Y's turnover. Asset X's turnover remains statistically
the same as in the baseline treatment. We also find that neither trading
regulation is effective in reducing bubbles and that, consistent with
the finding in the baseline treatment, the X and Y bubbles are almost
identical in both Taxy and Holdy treatments. In summary, we find
evidence that fully supports Hypotheses 3 and 5 but not Hypothesis 4.
To explain why bubbles are significantly smaller in the SdurDdiv,
DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv treatments, we decompose traders' trading
activities within a given period into various categories through which
the frequencies of arbitrage and short-term speculation can be
constructed. We find that having two intrinsically differentiated assets
tend to generate more arbitrage across assets and, as a result, reduce
the magnitude of bubbles. The frequency of short-term speculation, on
the other hand, does not depend on if and how assets or markets are
being differentiated. Its correlation with the bubble amplitude is
positive yet insignificant. Overall, our results highlight the role of
arbitrage in improving market efficiency.
The rest of our paper is organized as follows. Section II describes
the experimental design and procedures. Sections III, IV, and V report
the results. Section VI concludes the paper.
II. THE EXPERIMENT
The experiment consisted of 22 sessions conducted at a large state
university between May 2007 and June 2009. A total of 215 subjects were
recruited from City University of Hong Kong via e-mail. Some of the
subjects may have participated in economics experiments before, but none
had any experience in experiments similar to ours. No subject
participated in more than one session of this study. On average,
sessions lasted 3 hours including software training, initial instruction
period, and payment of subjects. The experiment was programmed using the
Ztree software package (Fischbacher 2007). Trade was denominated in an
experimental currency, called "francs," which was converted to
Hong Kong dollars at a predetermined and publicly known conversion rate.
Including a participation fee of HK$20, subjects earned an average of
HK$186 (roughly US$24). (6)
There were 30 trading periods in each of the 22 sessions, and each
period lasted 3 minutes. At the beginning of period 1, subjects were
endowed with 5 units of an asset called X, 5 units of another asset
called Y, and 10,000 francs of working capital. In each period, there
were two markets open side-by-side for trading X and Y. Subjects were
free to trade in either or both markets, one unit per transaction, using
continuous double auction rules. Inventories of X and Y were carried
over from one period to the next until the end of their lives. The cash
balance, on the other hand, was carried over from period to period all
the way to period 30. (7)
To study the impact of differences in assets' intrinsic
characteristics on bubbles and crashes, we adopted a 2 x 2 design in
which the two treatment variables were asset Y's maturity and
expected dividend per period. More specifically, there were four
treatments depending on whether or not assets X and Y had the same life
duration and/or expected dividend per period. The characteristics of
asset X described in the following were fixed across all four
treatments. First, it had a life of 30 periods. Second, it paid a
dividend that was drawn from a distribution of (2, 4, 6, 8, 10, 12),
each with equal probability, at the end of each trading period. In other
words, X's expected dividend was fixed at 7 francs per period.
Asset Y, depending on the treatment, had a life of either 15 or 30
periods. In the treatments where asset Y lasted only 15 periods, each
subject was given 5 units of Y at the beginning of period 1 and, after
they expired and became useless, another 5 units at the beginning of
period 16. This procedure was done so that the total stock of units
remained constant in all periods. (8) Depending on the treatment, asset
Y's dividend payment was drawn either from (2, 4, 6, 8, 10, 12) or
from (4, 8, 12, 16, 20, 24). As a result, in two of the four treatments,
asset Y's expected dividend per period was the same as asset
X's; whereas in two others, it was twice as much. The random draw
for asset Y at the end of each period was independent from that for
asset X. Asset X's and Y's dividend distribution and expected
dividend per period were public information among traders. Tables that
described X's and Y's expected dividend streams and thus their
fundamental values in any given period were also provided to subjects.
The expected dividend stream of asset X at the beginning of period t
equaled 7*(31 - t), where (31 - t) was the number of periods remaining
before X expired. The expected dividend stream of asset Y was calculated
in a similar fashion. Summary information for each of the four
treatments--SdurSdiv, SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv--is given in
Table 1.
Of the four treatments described above, we considered the one in
which X and Y were identical (SdurSdiv) as our benchmark. With this
benchmark treatment, we conducted two follow-up treatments in which
differences between X and Y came from institutional regulations. In the
treatment called Taxy, we introduced a STT of 2 francs, equivalent to
29% of the expected per period dividend, on asset Y (1 franc each on the
buyer and seller in every trade). In the treatment called Holdy, we
imposed a minimum holding period requirement on asset Y in that traders
were required to hold asset Y for at least five consecutive periods from
the time they acquired it on the market. In other words, if someone, for
instance, purchased 3 units of Y in period 7, he would not be allowed to
sell any of these 3 units until period 12 or later. The holding period
requirement did not apply to the initial endowment which was not
acquired through the market. Summary information regarding Taxy and
Holdy is also provided in Table 1.
III. RESULTS FOR DIFFERENCES IN ASSETS' INTRINSIC
CHARACTERISTICS
The left-hand panels of Figure 1 provide the time series of median
transaction prices in all four sessions of the benchmark SdurSdiv
treatment. In each of these panels, the closed squares/triangles
connected with a black/gray solid line represent the median transaction
prices of X/Y, whereas the line without any symbols represents the time
series of the fundamental
values. (9) It is clear that asset X's and asset Y's
prices are highly correlated and, more importantly, they both follow the
robust bubble-and-crash pattern. For instance, in session SdurSdiv 1,
both assets' prices start a bit higher than the fundamental value
and stay high until they finally collapse in period 17. In session
SdurSdiv2, X's median period price gradually escalates until period
27 when a sudden crash finally occurs. A similar pattern is also
observed for asset Y. These observations are consistent with the results
reported by Fisher and Kelly (2000) and Childs and Mestelman (2006) in
that rate-of-return parity is supported between two identical
dividend-paying assets, but not between the assets and currency.
The time series of median transaction prices in the SdurDdiv
sessions are shown in Figure 2. Bubbles occur in sessions SdurDdiv1 and
2. Price deviations of asset Y appear to be much larger than those of
asset X in SdurDdiv1. As a consequence, the relative price ratio between
X and Y in this treatment does not conform to rate-of-return parity as
closely as that in the SdurSdiv treatment.
The left-hand panels of Figure 3 provide the time series of median
transaction prices in treatment DdurSdiv. Note that, since asset X pays
the same expected per-period dividend but lasts twice as long as asset
Y, rate-of-return parity predicts that the price ratio between X and Y
will be (31 - t)/(16 - t) between periods 1 and 15 but 1 between periods
16 and 30. This prediction appears to be supported in sessions
DdurSdivl, 3, and 4, mainly because the robust bubble-and-crash
phenomenon, surprisingly, does not manage to emerge in these three
sessions. Price deviations from the fundamental, on the other hand,
exist for both assets in the first half of session DdurSdiv2.
Nevertheless, they tend to be much smaller in size compared to those in
the benchmark treatment.
The time series of median transaction prices in the three DdurDdiv
sessions are given in Figure 4. Although bubbles are observed in all
three sessions, their magnitudes are considerably smaller than those in
the benchmark SdurSdiv. On the other hand, compared to the benchmark
treatment, price patterns shown in Figure 4, especially in sessions
DdurDdiv 1 and 2, provide weaker support for rate-of-return parity which
predicts that the price ratio between X and Y will be (31 - t)/2(16 - t)
and 0.5 in the first and second halves of the experiment, respectively.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Finally, we provide trading volumes in the right-hand panels of
Figures 1-4. More asset X than asset Y was traded in the benchmark
SdurSdiv treatment. (10) This trading pattern, however, disappeared in
the rest of the three treatments.
A. Treatment Effects on Price Deviation and Turnover
Table 2 provides the statistical summary of bubble measures that
are either the same as or similar to those used in previous studies.
(11) The Price Amplitude of a bubble, first reported by King et al.
(1993), is defined as the difference between the peak and the trough of
average price deviations over the life of the asset: [max.sub.t]
{([P.sub.t] - [f.sub.t])/[f.sub.1]} - [min.sub.t] {([P.sub.t] -
[f.sub.t])/[f.sub.1]}, where [P.sub.t ] and [f.sub.t] are the median
transaction price and the fundamental value in period t, respectively.
In other words, the Price Amplitude measures the extent to which prices
swing around fundamental values. We also report the Normalized Average
Bias modified from the average bias reported by Haruvy and Noussair
(2006). Specifically, to take into account the various fundamental
patterns that result from different maturity and/or different dividend
payments, we define the Normalized Average Bias as the average deviation
of period median price from the period fundamental over the asset's
life duration T, normalized by the initial fundamental value:
([[summation].sub.t], ([P.sub.t] - [f.sub.t])/T)/[f.sub.1]. (12) A
Normalized average Bias close to zero indicates that, on average, prices
tend to stay rather close to fundamental values, whereas a large and
positive Normalized Average Bias implies that prices exhibit a tendency
to stay far above fundamental values. For the same reason described
above, our third bubble measure Normalized Average Deviation is defined
as the sum of all absolute price deviations that is adjusted with the
asset's total stock of units, life duration, and the initial
fundamental value: Normalized Average Deviation = ([[summation].sub.t]
[[summation].sub.t] [absolute value of ([p.sup.it] -
[f.sub.t])]/[f.sub.1])/(T x TSU), where [p.sub.it] denotes each
transaction price i in period t and TSU is the total stock of units.
(13) Since this measure takes not only (absolute) price deviations but
also trading volumes into consideration, it has been considered as the
most comprehensive bubble measure in the literature. Finally, we average
the turnover over the entire course of the asset's lifetime:
Average Turnover = [[summation].sub.t] [q.sub.t]/(T x TSU), where
[q.sub.t] is the number of transactions in period t.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The results reported in Table 2 roughly confirm the discussion
described above. The price amplitude, normalized average bias, and
normalized average deviation of both asset X and asset Y1 (asset Y whose
life started from period 1) are, generally speaking, the largest in
SdurSdiv and the smallest in treatment DdurSdiv. (14) In those sessions
where asset Y had a life of only 15 periods, the bubble measures in
market Y16 are smaller than those in market Y1. Taking each session as
an independent observation, matched-pairs signed-rank tests suggest that
the difference between Y1 and Y16 is significant in terms of their
normalized average biases but not in terms of their price amplitudes or
normalized average deviations. (15) These results partially support the
finding by, for example, Smith, Suchanek, and Williams (1988) and King
et al. (1993) that bubble measures decline with experience. But note
that, in Smith, Suchanek, and Williams and King et al., bubbles became
smaller only after subjects had participated in the same environment
with the same group of people at least once. The environment facing our
subjects in the second half of the DdurSdiv and DdurDdiv sessions was
not entirely the same as the first half due to the characteristics of
asset X. Therefore, it is understandable that the impact of experience
found in this study is not as strong as that in previous studies.
Finally, in terms of quantities traded, SdurSdiv and SdurDdiv have the
highest and lowest average turnover, respectively, among the four
treatments.
Given that cross-sectional and time-series variation in the data is
not controlled for, it is perhaps premature to assign much significance
to the results reported in Table 2. In the following analysis, we adopt
a population-averaged panel data linear regression model, where robust
standard errors are adjusted for first-order autocorrelation and
within-session correlation, to investigate the treatment effects on
price deviations [absolute value of ([P.supi.sub.t] -
[f.sub.i.sub.t])]/[f.sup.i.sub.1] and turnover
[q.sup.i.sub.t]/[TSU.sup.i], where i = X or Y. Note that, since asset Y
had a shorter maturity in DdurSdiv and DdurDdiv than in SdurSdiv and
SdurDdiv, we employ data only from periods 1 to 15 whenever asset Y is
involved in the regression. Results given in Table 3 include time period
t and dummy variables Ddiv and Ddur that equal 1 if assets differ in
their dividend structure and maturity, respectively. An interaction term
between Ddiv and Ddur is also included.
Result 1: Price deviations are the largest when both assets share
exactly the same intrinsic characteristics (baseline SDurSdiv).
Introducing differences in assets' maturity, period, dividend
structure or both (treatments SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv)
significantly reduces price deviations for both assets.
Support for Result 1: The estimates shown in column (1) of Table 3
imply that, compared to the baseline treatment (SdurSdiv), having an
alternative asset that has the same maturity bet pays a double expected
dividend (SdurDdiv) reduces X's price deviations by an average of
27.29% per period. Asset X's price deviations are on average 33.22%
smaller than in the baseline treatment when Y pays the same expected
dividend but has a shorter life duration (DdurSdiv). The treatment
effect of having an alternative asset Y that differs not only in its
maturity but also in its expected dividend payment (DdurDdiv) is -27.29
- 33.22 + 30.28 = -30.23%, which is significantly different from zero
([chi square] = 11.01, p value = .0035). The estimates reported in
column (3) suggest that, compared to the baseline treatment, asset
Y's price deviations between periods 1 and 15 are on average
21.71%, 29.94%, and 28.81% ([chi square] = 37.44, p value = .0000)
smaller in SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv and DdurDdiv, respectively. Finally, we
test if the hypothesis that SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv generate
the same treatment effects and yield p values of .2418 and .6352 for
assets X and asset Y.
In terms of the trading volume, the results reported in the last
column of Table 2 suggest that asset X's average per-period
turnover rate is slightly higher in the baseline SdurSdiv than in all
three treatments. (16) The average turnover rate of asset Y, on the
other hand, does not appear to vary significantly across different
treatments. In the following, we again turn to the population-averaged
panel data linear regression model as described above to investigate the
treatment effects on assets' turnover rates.
Result 2: Assets' turnovers are mostly unaffected by the
differences between the two assets.
Support for Result 2: The estimates shown in columns (2) of Table 3
indicate that, after cross-sectional and time-series variations in the
data are controlled for, asset X's turnover is 16.60% lower in
SdurDdiv than in the baseline SdurSdiv. Neither of the two other
treatments has any significant impact on the turnovers. (17) Having said
that, the hypothesis that SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv have the same
treatment effects cannot be rejected by our data (p value = .2851).
Asset Y's turnover is statistically the same across all treatments.
B. Treatment Effects on the Deviation from Rate-of-Return Parity
In this section, we investigate the treatment effects on the
deviation from the prediction of rate-of-return parity [absolute value
of (([P.sup.X.sub.t]/[P.sup.Y.sub.t]) - ([P.sup.X]/[P.sup.Y])*)]. Again,
to avoid the possibility that the treatment effects are confounded by
different experience levels in trading asset Y during the second half of
the experiment, only the first 15 periods' data are used here. The
summary statistics of the absolute deviation during these 15 periods are
reported in column (1) of Table 4. In the following, we turn to the same
regression model that takes the cross-sectional and time-series
variation in the data into consideration. The results are reported in
Table 5.
Result 3: Deviations from rate-of-return parity are not affected by
if and how the two assets are intrinsically different.
Support for Result 3: The estimates shown in column (1) of Table 5
indicate that the absolute deviations from rate-of-return parity in
SdurD-div are on average 0.69% smaller than in the baseline SdurSdiv
treatment. The absolute deviations in DdurSdiv and DdurDdiv are, on the
other hand, 5.04% and 13.95% (= -0.69 + 5.04 + 9.60) larger than in the
baseline treatment. None of the estimates is statistically significant,
suggesting that Hypothesis 2 is supported by our data.
IV. RESULTS FOR DIFFERENCES IN INSTITUTIONAL REGULATIONS
Figures 5 and 6 provide the time series of median transaction
prices and trading volumes in treatments Taxy and Holdy, respectively.
Recall that, in terms of their intrinsic characteristics, X and Y were
exactly the same assets in these two treatments. Nevertheless, the
trading regulations imposed on Y--a transaction tax in Taxy and a
minimum holding period requirement in Holdy--made Y a more
"restricted" asset than X. Therefore, it is not surprising to
see from Figures 5 and 6 that less Y was traded than X in the market.
But note that subjects in the benchmark SdurSdiv treatment also tended
to trade more asset X than asset Y. So, it is not obvious if the
transaction tax or the minimum holding duration requirement did
influence Y's trading in any significant way. In fact, the
regression analysis reported in Section IV.A indicates that only the
latter has a significant impact on asset Y's turnover. Bubbles,
comparable to those in SdurSdiv in their sizes, occurred in all sessions
of the two treatments. Also, like in SdurSdiv, prices of the two assets
appear to be perfectly correlated. Therefore, the overall impression we
have from these two treatments is that the trading regulations imposed
in our study are not strong enough to make investors price the two
intrinsically same assets differently.
A. Treatment Effects on Price Amplitude and Turnover
The price amplitude, normalized average bias, normalized average
deviation, and turnover of X and Y in Taxy and Holdy, shown in Table 2,
are only slightly smaller than those in SdurSdiv. And if we compare the
bubble measures between X and Y within the same treatment, it is clear
that trading restrictions generate almost the same behavioral pattern as
in the baseline treatment. That is, asset Y's price amplitude and
normalized average bias are not much different from asset X's.
Also, as in the baseline, the average normalized deviation of Y is much
smaller than that of X. This result is mostly due to the fact that asset
Y's turnover is, on average, 40%-50% lower than asset X's.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
In the following, we utilize the above panel data approach to
investigate if a transaction tax or a minimum holding period requirement
imposed on one asset has any influence on the price amplitude and
turnover of either asset. The regression results are reported in Table
6.
Result 4: The transaction tax or the minimum holding period
requirement imposed on asset Y has no significant impact on either
asset's price deviations.
Support for Result 4: The estimates shown in columns (1) and (3) of
Table 6 indicate that, compared to the baseline SdurSdiv treatment, the
transaction tax and the holding period requirement has a negative impact
on the sizes of bubbles. For example, compared to the baseline
treatment, the transaction tax reduces X's and Y's price
deviations by an average of 17.33% and 14.89%. The minimum holding
period requirement has a very similar effect as the transaction tax.
None of these reductions, however, is statistically significant.
Result 5: The transaction tax or the minimum holding period
requirement imposed on asset Y has no significant impact on asset
X's turnover. Asset Y's turnover is significantly lower when
the minimum homing period requirement is in effect.
Support for Result 5: Asset X's turnover, shown in column (2)
of Table 6, is on average 3.99% and 8.82% lower in Taxy and Holdy,
respectively, than in the baseline SdurSdiv treatment. Neither estimate
is significantly different from zero. While the transaction tax
continues to have no significant effect on asset Y's turnover, the
minimum holding period requirement reduces Y's turnover by a
significant amount of 8.76%.
B. Treatment Effects on the Absolute Deviation from Rate-of-Return
Parity
Column (2) of Table 4 reports the mean absolute deviation of
[P.sup.X.sub.t]/[P.sup.Y.sub.t] from the predication of rate-of-return
parity in Taxy and Holdy. The same statistical summary from the baseline
SdurSdiv treatment is also provided for direct comparisons. Also, since
both assets have the same life duration of 30 periods in all three
treatments, we employ the data from all periods when computing the
averages. The mean absolute deviations from rate-of-return parity in
Taxy and Holdy are about 8.95% and 12.72% per period, which do not
appear to be much different from 10.59% in the baseline SdurSdiv
treatment. Regression results summarized below provide further support
to this observation.
Result 6: The transaction tax or the minimum holding duration
imposed on asset Y has no significant impact on the deviation of
[P.sup.X.sub.t]/[P.sup.Y.sub.t] from the prediction of rate-of-return
parity.
Support for Result 6: The estimate of the dummy variable Taxy in
column (2) of Table 5 is -1.60, implying that the absolute deviation of
[P.sup.X.sub.t]/ [P.sup.Y.sub.t] from rate-of-return parity is on
average 1.60% smaller than that in the baseline treatment. Similarly,
the estimate of Holdy is 1.71, indicating that, compared to the baseline
treatment, the deviation is 1.71% larger. Neither estimate is
statistically significant.
V. ARBITRAGE VERSUS SPECULATION
In this section, we investigate why bubbles are significantly
smaller when two assets are intrinsically different than when they are
not. We extend the concept used to construct a measure for short-term
speculation by Hanke et al. (2010) and decompose each trader's
whole trading sequence in any given period into the following four
types: same-offer/same-market, opposite-offer/same-market, same-offer/
different-market, and opposite-offer/different-market.
"Same-offer/same-market" means that two back-to-back purchases
or back-to-back sales are being executed in the same market, whereas
"opposite-offer/same-market" means that a purchase is followed
by a sale (or vice versa) in the same market. (18) "Same-offer/
different-market" and "opposite-offer/different-market"
are defined similarly except that the two subsequent trades are placed
in different markets. Therefore, for a trader who has a trading sequence
of buy X [right arrow] buy X [right arrow] sell X [right arrow] sell Y
[right arrow] buy Y, he is said to make one same-offer/same-market (buy
X [right arrow] buy X), two opposite-offer/same-market (buy X [right
arrow] sell X and sell Y [right arrow] buy Y), and one
same-offer/different-market (sell X [right arrow] sell Y) types of
trades. As a result, we can assign 1 to same-offer/same-market, 2 to
opposite-offer/same-market, 1 to same-offer/different-market, and 0 to
opposite offer/different market as the frequencies of all four types of
trading activity for this particular trader. We then compute the
relative frequency of type i trading activity across all traders and all
times periods for each session. Table 7 provides these frequencies by
treatment. It indicates that, for example, in the baseline SdurSdiv
treatment, the probability that two adjacent trades occur in two
different markets is, on average, 48% (= 33 + 15). Furthermore, given
that one switches to a different market to trade, the probability that
he will place an offer opposite to the previous one is about 31% (=
15/48).
While it is almost impossible to verify the motive behind each
single trade from the data, it is perhaps not unreasonable to assume
that a sale immediately following a purchase (or vice versa) in a
different market is more an act of arbitrage across assets. In the
following, we define the frequency of arbitrage across assets as the
probability that two adjacent trades are of opposite offers, conditional
on that they take place in different markets and that the
price/fundamental ratio of the asset being sold is greater than the
price/fundamental ratio of the asset being purchased. This measure is
reported in the third column from the right in Table 7.
Result 7: The existence of two intrinsically differentiated assets
encourages more arbitrage conducted across markets and thus helps reduce
the magnitude of bubbles.
Support for Result 7: Taking each session as an independent
observation, a non-parametric Mann-Whitney rank-sum test rejects the
hypothesis that the frequency of arbitrage across assets is independent
of the assets being intrinsically different or not (p value = .0007). In
other words, the existence of two intrinsically differentiated assets
does encourage traders to exploit mispricing across markets more
frequently. To see if arbitrage helps reduce mispricing, we calculate
the non-parametric Spearman rank correlation between the amplitudes of
the two assets and the frequency of arbitrage across assets. The
coefficient is -0.6402 (p value = .0013) for asset X and -0.5871 (p
value = .0041) for asset Y, suggesting that the more frequently traders
conduct arbitrage, the smaller bubbles are. (19)
For the measure of speculation, we follow Hanke et al. (2010) and
consider, for example, a sale immediately following a purchase (or vice
versa) within a given market as an act of short-term speculation. As a
result, we define the frequency of short-term speculation in a given
market as the probability that two adjacent trades are of opposite
offers, conditional on the probability that they are executed in the
same market. This measure is reported in the last two columns of Table
7.
Result 8: The frequency of short-term speculation is independent of
whether or not assets are intrinsically different. As a result, the
frequency of short-term speculation does not explain why bubbles are
smaller when two assets are intrinsically different than when they are
not.
Support for Result 8: Taking each session as an independent
observation, a non-parametric Mann-Whitney rank-sum test cannot reject
the hypothesis that the frequency of short-term speculation in either
market is independent of the assets being intrinsically different or not
(p value = .2334 and 0.9474 for X and Y, respectively). The Spearman
rank correlation coefficient between the bubble amplitude and the
frequency of short-term speculation is 0.2562 for market X and 0.2560
for market Y. Neither coefficient is statistically significant (p value
= .2497 and .2502 for X and Y, respectively).
VI. CONCLUSION
in this paper, we study if and how having two differentiated assets
affects bubble formation. We consider differentiation that is caused by
assets' intrinsic characteristics including their life durations
and expected per period dividends. We also consider trading regulations
such as a transaction tax and a minimum holding period requirement that
have been considered by some as policy tools that would curb speculation
and reduce asset mispricing. We impose these trading regulations only on
one of the two markets to help differentiate two otherwise identical
assets. We find that, compared to trading regulations, differences in
assets' intrinsic characteristics tend to encourage more arbitrage
across assets and thus help reduce mispricing significantly. We also
find that short-term speculation does not depend on how assets or
markets are being differentiated, and that the correlation between
short-term speculation and the bubble amplitude is statistically
insignificant. In other words, the smaller bubbles that we observe in
treatments SdurDdiv, DdurSdiv, and DdurDdiv are more likely to be the
consequence of more arbitrage, not less speculation. Overall, our
results highlight the significance of arbitrage in mitigating bubbles.
ABBREVIATIONS
STT: Securities Transaction Tax
TSU: Total Stock of Unit
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00494.x
REFERENCES
Aliber, Z., B. Cbowdhry, and S. Yan. "Some Evidence that a
Tobin Tax on Foreign Exchange Transactions May Increase
Volatility." European Finance Review, 7(3), 2003, 481-510.
Ariyoshi, A., K. Habermeier, B. Laurens, I. Otker-Robe, J.
Canales-Kriljenko, and A. Kirilenko. "Capital Controls: Country
Experiences with Their Use and Liberalization," IMF Occasional
Paper No. 190, 2000.
Bloomfield, R., M. O'Hara, and G. Saar. "How Noise
Trading Affects Markets: An Experimental Analysis," Review of
Financial Studies, 22(6), 2009, 2275-302.
Caginalp, G., D. Porter, and V. Smith. "Financial Bubbles:
Excess Cash, Momentum, and Incomplete Information," Journal of
Psychology and Financial Markets, 2(2), 2001, 80-99.
Campbell, J. Y. and K. A. Froot. "International Experiences
with Securities Transaction Taxes," in The Internationalization of
Equity Markets, edited by J. A. Frankel. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1994, 277-303.
Childs, J., and S. Mestelman. "Rate-of-Return Parity in
Experimental Asset Markets." Review of International Economics,
14(3), 2006, 331-47.
Dooley, M. P. "The Tobin Tax: Good Theory, Weak Evidence,
Questionable Policy," in The Tobin Tax: Coping with Financial
Volatility, edited by M. Haq, I. Kaul, and I. Grunberg. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1996, 83-108.
Dufwenberg, M., T. Lindqvist, and E. Moore. "Bubbles and
Experience: An Experiment." American Economic Review, 95, 2005,
1731-37.
Fisher, E., and F. Kelly. "Experimental Foreign Exchange
Markets." Pacific Economic Review, 5(3), 2000, 365-87.
Hanke, M., J. Huber, M. Kirchler, and M. Sutter. "The Economic
Consequences of a Tobin Tax--An Experimental Analysis." Journal of
Economic Behavior & Organization, 74, 2010, 58-71.
Haruvy, E., and C. Noussair. "The Effect of Short Selling on
Bubbles and Crashes in Experimental Spot Asset Markets." Journal of
Finance, 61(3), 2006, 1119-57.
Haruvy, E., Y. Lahav, and C. Noussair. "Traders'
Expectations in Asset Markets: Experimental Evidence." American
Economic Review, 97, 2007, 1901-20.
Hu, S. "The Effects of the Stock Transaction Tax on the Stock
Market--Experiences from Asian Markets." Pacific-Basin Financial
Journal, 6(3-4), 1998, 347-64.
Johnson, R., and P. Young. "Bond Market Volatility Compared
with Stock Market Volatility: Evidence from the UK." Journal of
Asset Management, 3, 2002, 101-11.
Jones, C., and J. Wilson. "The Changing Nature of Stock and
Bond Volatility." Financial Analysts Journal, 60, 2004, 100-13.
King, R., V. Smith, A. Williams, and M. Van Boening. "The
Robustness of Bubbles and Crashes in Experimental Stock Markets,"
in Nonlinear Dynamics and Evolutionary Economics, edited by I Prigogine,
R. Day, and P. Chen. New York: Oxford University Press, 1993.
Kupiec, P. H. "A Securities Transaction Tax and Capital Market
Efficiency." Contemporary Economic Policy, 13(1), 1995, 101-12.
Lei, V., C. Noussair, and C. Plott. "Non-Speculative Bubbles
in Experimental Asset Markets: Lack of Common Knowledge of Rationality
vs. Actual Irrationality." Econometrica, 69(4), 2001, 831-59.
Lei, V., and F. Vesely. "Market Efficiency: Evidence from a
No-Bubble Asset Market Experiment." Pacific Economic Review, 14(2),
2009, 246-58.
Lugovskyy, V., D. Puzzello, and S. Tucker. "An Experimental
Study of Bubble Formation in Asset Markets Using the Tatonnement Trading
Institution," Working Paper, 2010.
Noussair, C., S. Robin, and B. Ruffieux. "Price Bubbles in
Laboratory Asset Markets with Constant Fundamental Values."
Experimental Economics, 4(1), 2001, 87-105.
Noussair, C., and S. Tucker. "Futures Markets and Bubble
Formation in Experimental Asset Markets." Pacific Economic Review,
11(2), 2006, 167-84.
Ostry, J.D., A.R. Ghosh, K. Habermeier, M. Chamon, M. S. Qureshi,
and D. B. S. Reinhardt. "Capital Inflows: The Role of
Controls," IMF Staff Position Note, 2010.
Palley, T. I. "Speculation and Tobin Taxes: Why Sand in the
Wheels Can Increase Economic Efficiency." Journal of Economics,
69(2), 1999, 113-26.
Porter, D., and V. Smith. "Futures Contracting and Dividend
Uncertainty in Experimental Asset Markets." Journal of Business,
68(4), 1995, 509-41.
--. "Stock Market Bubbles in the Laboratory." Journal of
Behavioral Finance, 4(1), 2003, 7-21.
Roll, R. "Price Volatility, International Market Links, and
Their Implications for Regulatory Policies." Journal of Financial
Services Research, 3, 1989, 211-46.
Schwert, W. G., and P. J. Sequin. "Securities Transaction
Taxes: An Overview of Costs, Benefits, and Unresolved Questions."
Financial Analysts Journal, 49(5). 1993, 27-35.
Smith, V., G. Suchanek, and A. Williams. "Bubbles, Crashes and
Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets."
Econometrica, 56, 1988, 1119-51.
Stiglitz, J.E. "Using Tax Policy to Curb Speculative
Short-Term Trading." Journal of Financial Services Research, 3,
1989, 101-15.
Summers, L. H., and V. P. Summers. "When Financial Markets
Work Too Well: A Cautious Case for a Securities Transaction Tax."
Journal of Financial Services Research, 3(2-3), 1989, 261-86.
Tobin, J. "On the Efficiency of the Financial System."
Lloyds Bank Review, 153, 1984, 1-15.
Umlauf, S. R. "Transaction Taxes and the Behavior of the
Swedish Stock Market." Journal of Financial Services Research, 33,
1993, 227-40.
Van Boening, M., A. Williams, and S. LaMaster. "Price Bubbles
and Crashes in Experimental Call Markets." Economics Letters, 4l,
1993, 179-85.
Westerboff, F. H., and R. Dieci. "The Effectiveness of
Keynes-Tobin Transaction Taxes When Heterogeneous Agents Can Trade in
Different Markets: A Behavioral Finance Approach." Journal of
Economic Dynamics & Control, 30, 2006, 293-322.
Young, P., and R. Johnson. "Bond Market Volatility vs. Stock
Market Volatility: The Swiss Experience." Financial Markets and
Portfolio Management, 18(1), 2004, 8-23.
KENNETH S. CHAN, VIVIAN LEI and FILIP VESELY *
* We are grateful to the Department of Economics and Finance at the
City University of Hong Kong for financial and laboratory support. We
thank participants at the 2007 North-American Economic Science
Association Conference for helpful comments.
Chan: Department of Economics and Finance, City University of Hong
Kong; Lingnan College, Sun Yat-Sen University, China. Phone (852)
3442-2659, Fax (852) 3442-8858, E-mail chanken93@gmail.com
Lei: Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee,
Bolton Hall 818, Milwaukee, WI 53211; Department of Economics and
Finance, City University of Hong Kong. Phone (414) 229-6494, Fax (414)
2293860, E-mail vlei@uwm.edu
Vesely: Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee,
Bolton Hall 818, Milwaukee, WI 53211. Phone (414) 229-4910, Fax (414)
229-3860, E-mail vesely@uwm.edu
(1.) In addition to trading experience that has been shown to be
able to consistently eliminate bubbles (see Dufwenberg, Lindqvist, and
Moore 2005; Haruvy, Lahav, and Noussair 2007; Smith, Suchanek, and
Williams 1988; Van Boening, Williams, and LaMaster 1993), Noussair and
Tucker (2006) find that the presence of a complete set of futures
markets is able to facilitate backward induction and thus help eliminate
bubbles in the spot market. Lei and Vesely (2009) find that a pre-market
phase in which subjects passively experience the realization of a
dividend stream can prevent bubbles from occurring. Lugovskyy, Puzzello,
and Tucker (2010) study a tatonnement trading institution that is used
to address the lack of common knowledge of rationality as well as the
lack of rationality itself. They find that bubbles are significantly
attenuated with the tatonnement trading institution.
(2.) See, for example, Johnson and Young (2002). Young and Johnson
(2004), and Jones and Wilson (2004) for bond market volatility versus
stock market volatility.
(3.) Skeptics, on the other hand, argue that the adverse effects of
a STT on market liquidity may well destabilize the market rather than
stabilize it. For instance, Kupiec (1995) argues that a STT that reduces
a taxed asset's liquidity may increase investors' required
rate of return and thus make it difficult to mitigate the degree of
mispricing. Schwert and Sequin (1993) note that, since a STT affects
noise and fundamental traders indiscriminately, it is not clear if the
tax would have a greater impact on noise traders. There are also
concerns over the coverage or the enforcement of a STT. Campbell and
Froot (1994) argue that a STT would encourage traders to shift trading
from the taxed asset to its untaxed close substitutes or from the
domestic market to offshore ones. The migration from one market to
another, according to Westerhoff and Dieci (2006), generates an
ambiguous impact on the markets as a whole. Empirical studies undertaken
so far have yet been able to produce much convincing evidence to suggest
that STTs can help reduce market volatility in either stock or foreign
exchange markets (see, e.g., Aliber, Chowdhry, and Yan 2003; Dooley
1996; Hu 1998; Roll 1989; Umlauf 1993).
(4.) The text published by the European Commission on September 28,
2011 proposes a tax of 0.1% on trading of stocks and bonds and a tax of
0.01% on all derivatives transactions.
(5.) See Ariyoshi et al. (2000) and Ostry et al. (2010) for
summaries of capital controls that have been adopted since the 1990s.
(6.) Back in 2007, workers at fast food chains in Hong Kong earned
an average hourly rate that was less than US$3.00.
(7.) Dividend earnings were not included in the cash balance for
making transactions.
(8.) In the instructions, we called the units of Y whose lives
started from period 1 and ended at the end of period 15 asset Y1, and
those units whose lives started from period 16 and ended at the end of
period 30 asset Y16. Subjects were reminded that there was no difference
between Y1 and Y16 except that Y1's life started from period 1 and
Y16's life started from period 16.
(9.) In Figure 1 and all subsequent figures in the paper, an open
square or triangle indicates that no transaction took place during that
period, and the value indicated as the median price is the midpoint between the final bid-offer spread.
(10.) Since asset X was displayed on the left side of the screen in
our experiment, this result is consistent with the observation in Hanke
et al. (2010) in that most trading took place in the Left market than in
the Right market even though both assets were exactly identical.
(11.) See, for example, King et al. (1993), Van Boening, Williams,
and LaMaster (1993). Porter and Smith (1995), Noussair, Robin, and
Ruffieux (2001), and Haruvy and Noussair (2006).
(12.) In Haruvy and Noussair (2006), the average bias is defined as
[[summation].sub.t]([P.sub.t] - [f.sub.t])/T, where T denotes
asset's life duration.
(13.) The normalized deviation reported in previous studies is
defined as [[summation].sub.t] [[summation].sub.i] [absolute value of
([p.sub.it] - [f.sub.t])]/TSU.
(14.) The average size of bubbles in our baseline treatment
SdurSdiv is comparable to those in most of the previous studies where
only one asset was traded. For example, the price amplitudes are, on
average, 1.24 in Smith, Suchanek, and Williams (1988), 1.87 in the
equal-endowment treatment of King et al. (1993), 4.19 in Van Boening,
Williams, and LaMaster (1993), 1.53 in the baseline treatment of Porter
and Smith (1995), 1.21 in the baseline treatment of Porter and Smith
(2003), 2.61 in the baseline treatment of Haruvy and Noussair (2006),
and 8.83 in Market 1 of Haruvy, Lahav, and Noussair (2007). The price
amplitudes in our X and Y markets are 1.44 and 1.37, respectively.
(15.) The insignificant results about Y1's and Y16's
price amplitudes and normalized average deviations might be partially
due to the fact that there are only seven observations available for the
signed-rank tests here.
(16.) The turnover rates in the X and Y markets of our baseline
SdurSdiv treatment are 0.26 and 0.18, which are slightly smaller than in
most of the previous studies where there exists only one asset for
people to trade. Specifically, after adjusted for assets' life
durations, the average per-period turnover rate is 0.33 in Smith,
Suchanek, and Williams (1988), 0.42 in the equal-endowment treatment of
King et al. (1993), 0.34 in Van Boening, Williams, and LaMaster (1993),
0.37 in the baseline treatment of Porter and Smith (1995), 0.39 in the
baseline treatment of Porter and Smith (2003), 0.81 in the baseline
treatment of Haruvy and Noussair (2006), and 0.15 in Market 1 of Haruvy,
Lahav, and Noussair (2007).
(17.) The estimates reported in column (2) suggest that, compared
to the baseline treatment, asset X's turnover in DdurDdiv is about
-11.40% lower. This estimate is nonetheless insignificant ([chi square]
= 1.44, p value = .2299).
(18.) The term "offer" here concerns only the direction
of a transaction (buy or sell).
(19.) For the treatments in which asset Y lasts 15 periods, we use
the amplitude of asset Y from the first half of the experiment where
mispricing is more prominent. This is done to also avoid the impact of
learning effects.
TABLE 1
Summary of Treatments and Sessions
Expected Life
Dividend Duration
# of
Treatment Session Subjects X Y X Y
SdurSdiv SdurSdiv1 10 7 7 30 30
(baseline) SdurSdiv2 9
SdurSdiv3 10
SdurSdiv4 10
SdurDdiv SdurDdiv1 9 7 14 30 30
SdurDdiv2 10
SdurDdiv3 10
DdurSdiv DdurSdiv1 10 7 7 30 15
DdurSdiv2 10
DdurSdiv3 9
DdurSdiv4 10
DdurDdiv DdurDdiv1 10 7 14 30 15
DdurDdiv2 9
DdurDdiv3 10
Taxy Taxy1 10 7 7 30 30
Taxy2 9
Taxy3 10
Taxy4 l0
Holdy Holdy1 10 7 7 30 30
Holdy2 10
Holdy3 10
Holdy4 10
Transaction Holding
Tax Period
Treatment Session X Y X Y
SdurSdiv SdurSdiv1
(baseline) SdurSdiv2
SdurSdiv3
SdurSdiv4
SdurDdiv SdurDdiv1
SdurDdiv2
SdurDdiv3
DdurSdiv DdurSdiv1
DdurSdiv2
DdurSdiv3
DdurSdiv4
DdurDdiv DdurDdiv1
DdurDdiv2
DdurDdiv3
Taxy Taxy1 [check]
Taxy2
Taxy3
Taxy4
Holdy Holdy1 [check]
Holdy2
Holdy3
Holdy4
TABLE 2
Observed Bubble Measures in All Treatments
Normalized
Amplitude Average Bias
Treatment X Y1 Y16 X Y1 Y16
SdurSdiv 1.44 1.37 0.48 0.42
SdurDdiv 0.37 0.55 0.04 0.08
DdurSdiv 0.20 0.27 0.20 0.03 0.07 0.03
DdurDdiv 0.33 0.30 0.27 0.09 0.12 0.04
Taxy 1.00 1.05 0.43 0.41
Holdy 1.20 1.12 0.39 0.36
Normalized Average
Average Deviation Turnover
Treatment X Y1 Y16 X Y1 Y16
SdurSdiv 0.150 0.084 0.26 0.18
SdurDdiv 0.010 0.017 0.09 0.11
DdurSdiv 0.006 0.026 0.011 0.13 0.16 0.14
DdurDdiv 0.020 0.019 0.011 0.15 0.16 0.19
Taxy 0.107 0.065 0.21 0.11
Holdy 0.076 0.048 0.17 0.10
TABLE 3
Effects of Intrinsic Differences on Assets' Price Deviation
([absolute value of ([P.sup.i.sub.t] - [f.sup.i.sub.t])]
/ [f.sup.i.sub.l] / [f.sup.i.sub.l]) and Turnover
([q.sup.i.sub.t] / [TSU.sup.i])
Asset X (Periods Asset Y (Periods
1-30) 1-15)
(1) Price (2) (3) Price (4)
Deviation Turnover Deviation Turnover
(in %) (in %) (in %) (in %)
Constant 38.11 *** 34.40 *** 34.87 *** 28.58
(7.34) (8.24) (5.85) (5.85)
Period -0.05 -0.49 *** 0.39 -0.55
(0.32) (0.16) (0.36) (0.37)
Ddiv -27.29 ** -16.60 * -21.71 ** -10.32
(11.35) (8.64) (9.05) (6.82)
Ddur -33.22 *** -12.32 -29.94 *** -7.79
(10.25) (8.36) (5.49) (7.57)
Ddiv * Ddur 30.28 *** 17.52 * 22.84 ** 9.99
(11.56) (9.89) (9.84) (8.36)
Obs. 420 420 210 210
Notes: The table reports results from a population-
averaged panel data linear regression model. The standard
errors, given in parentheses, are corrected for first-order
autocorrelation and within-session correlation.
***, ** and * Significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels,
respectively.
TABLE 4
Summary Statistics of
[absolute value of (([P.sup.X.sub.t] / [P.sup.Y.sub.t])
- ([P.sup.X] / [P.sup.Y])*)] (in %)
Treatment (1) Periods 1-15 (2) Periods 1-30
SdurSdiv 9.82 10.59
(18.54) (20.96)
SdurDdiv 7.51
(9.26)
DdurSdiv 14.06
(12.37)
DdurDdiv 22.47
(25.09)
Taxy 8.95
(37.21)
Holdy 12.72
(34.56)
Notes: Standard deviations are in parentheses.
TABLE 5
Treatment Effects on [absolute value of (([P.sup.Y.sub.t] /
[P.sup.Y.sub.t]) - ([P.sup.X] / [P.sup.Y])*)] (in %)
(1) Periods 1-15 (2) Periods 1-30
Constant 3.37 -1.41
(8.97) (6.95)
Period 0.78 0.79 ***
(0.63) (0.24)
Ddiv -0.69
(6.67)
Ddur 5.04
(6.77)
Ddiv * Ddur 9.60
(10.54)
Taxy -1.60
(6.03)
Holdy 1.71
(6.14)
Obs 210 360
Notes: The table reports results from a population-
averaged panel data linear regression model. The standard
errors, given in parentheses, are corrected for first-order
autocorrelation and within-session correlation.
*** Significant at the 1% level.
TABLE 6
Effects of Institutional Differences on Assets'
Price Deviation ([absolute value of ([P.sup.i.sub.t] -
[f.sup.i.sub.t])]/[f.sup.i.sub.l]) and Turnover
([q.sup.i.sub.t]/[TSU.sup.i])
Asset X (Periods Asset Y (Periods
1-30) 1-30)
(1) Price (2) (3) Price (4)
Deviation Turnover Deviation Turnover
(in %) (in %) (in %) (in %)
Constant 36.75 *** 33.72 *** 38.51 *** 22.23 ***
(7.08) (8.78) (7.81) (4.99)
Period -0.17 -0.47 ** -0.39 * -0.23 *
(0.37) (0.22) (0.23) (0.13)
Taxy -17.33 -3.99 -14.89 -7.15
(11.60) (9.77) (11.02) (4.83)
Holdy -16.36 -8.82 -15.54 -8.76 **
(10.82) (8.75) (10.06) (4.28)
Obs. 360 360 360 360
Notes: The table reports results from a population-
averaged panel data linear regression model. The standard
errors, given in parentheses, are corrected for first-order
autocorrelation and within-session correlation.
***, ** and * Significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels,
respectively.
TABLE 7
Relative Frequencies of Different Trading Activities
Same Opposite Same Opposite
Offer Offer Offer Offer
Treatment Same Market Different Market
SdurSdiv 28% 24% 33% 15%
SdurDdiv 36% 21% 24% 18%
DdurSdiv 36% 19% 26% 19%
DdurDdiv 49% 19% 16% 15%
Taxy 41% 22% 27% 10%
Holdy 39% 19% 28% 14%
Frequency of Frequency of
Frequency of Short-Term Short-Term
Arbitrage Speculation Speculation
Treatment across Assets in Mkt X in Mkt Y
SdurSdiv 4% 47% 44%
SdurDdiv 8% 39% 36%
DdurSdiv 10% 38% 29%
DdurDdiv 7% 31% 28%
Taxy 1% 39% 27%
Holdy 2% 34% 26%