首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The role of monitoring of corruption in a simple endogenous growth model.
  • 作者:Coppier, Raffaella ; Costantini, Mauro ; Piga, Gustavo
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2013
  • 期号:October
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:During the last 30 years, economists from various fields have contributed to the analysis of corruption. The first paper to receive widespread attention was published in 1975 (Rose-Ackerman 1975). Since then a large literature has developed and much attention has been paid to the relationship between corruption and economic growth. In the analysis of the consequences of corruption, the literature supports two opposing positions. On one hand, common wisdom views corruption as an obstacle (sand) to development and growth; on the other hand, other researchers, since the pioneering works of Left (1964) and Huntington (1968), have suggested that corruption may promote efficiency by allowing firms to bypass government failures of various sorts
  • 关键词:Corruption;Econometric models;Economic growth

The role of monitoring of corruption in a simple endogenous growth model.


Coppier, Raffaella ; Costantini, Mauro ; Piga, Gustavo 等


I. INTRODUCTION

During the last 30 years, economists from various fields have contributed to the analysis of corruption. The first paper to receive widespread attention was published in 1975 (Rose-Ackerman 1975). Since then a large literature has developed and much attention has been paid to the relationship between corruption and economic growth. In the analysis of the consequences of corruption, the literature supports two opposing positions. On one hand, common wisdom views corruption as an obstacle (sand) to development and growth; on the other hand, other researchers, since the pioneering works of Left (1964) and Huntington (1968), have suggested that corruption may promote efficiency by allowing firms to bypass government failures of various sorts

(grease corruption). More recent expositions of efficiency-enhancing corruption can be found in Lui (1985), Acemoglu and Verdier (1998, 2000), and Barreto (2000). Barreto (2000) presents a simple neoclassical endogenous growth model where the public sector's monopolistic position is explicitly considered. Results indicate that a corruption equilibrium is characterized by lower growth rates compared to the ideal situation in which public goods are provided competitively. Barreto (2000) also shows that if the public sector is subject to significant bureaucratic red-tape, all of the agents within the economy may prefer the corruption equilibrium, as corruption can bypass bureaucratic obstacles.

From a theoretical point of view, there are several ways in which corruption may reduce economic growth. Corruption can act as a tax and thus lower incentives to invest. Corruption could cause talented people to engage in rent-seeking rather than productive activities. Corruption may distort the composition of government expenditure, as corrupt politicians could be expected to invest in large non-productive projects from which considerable bribes can be extracted more easily than from productive activities.

Empirical analysis has also provided evidence of the negative effects of corruption on economic growth. Mauro (1995) shows that corruption reduces economic growth, via reduced private investment. (1) Similar results are obtained by Keefer and Knack (1995) using other measures of corruption and a different selection of countries. (2) Recently, the "grease the wheels" hypothesis has been tested and statistically supported (see Aidt 2009; Campos, Dimova, and Ahmad 2010; Meon and Sekkat 2005, among others).

In this article, we develop a theoretical endogenous growth model which incorporates corruption. In our model, the social loss brought about by corruption stems from the fact that firms must bribe a bureaucrat in order to invest, and consequently devote fewer resources to the accumulation of capital. Therefore, in our model, corruption has a negative effect on private investment. Other models share our framework. Ehrlich and Lui (1999) claim that individuals have an incentive to compete over the privilege of becoming bureaucrats (the so-called investment in political capital) since they obtain economic rents through corruption. This investment in political capital consumes economic resources which could otherwise be used for production or investment in human capital. In Del Monte and Papagni (2001), corruption arises when bureaucrats manage public resources to produce public goods and services. Corruption reduces the quality of public infrastructure resulting in a negative effect on economic growth.

The novel feature of this article is the study of the impact of monitoring of corruption on economic growth. (3) In our theoretical model, we derive a nonlinear relationship between the level of monitoring and economic growth, as well as between corruption and economic growth. (4) At low monitoring levels, the economy experiences widespread corruption and medium growth rates, whereas no corruption occurs at intermediate monitoring levels, but low growth rates are recorded. At high monitoring levels, no corruption takes place and high growth rates are observed.

The nonlinear relationship between growth and monitoring is finally investigated empirically over the period 1980-2003 in Italy. To study this relationship, new measures of monitoring are used. Our empirical evidence supports the conclusions of the model.

The article is organized as follows: Section II studies the relationship between the level of monitoring, corruption, and economic growth. In Section III, empirical implications from the theoretical model are evaluated. Section IV concludes.

II. THEORETICAL MODEL

Let us consider an infinite horizon economy in continuous time admitting a representative household with the standard constant relative risk aversion preferences. We also assume that the representative household owns a balanced portfolio of all the firms in the economy. Alternatively, we can think of the economy as consisting of many households with the same preferences as the representative household in each household holding a balanced portfolio of all the firms. Following Acemoglu (2009), the ability to hold a balanced portfolio of projects with independently disputed returns allows the individual to diversify the risks and act in a risk-neutral manner. (5) This will imply that the objective of each firm will be to maximize expected profits (without a risk premium). Firms manufacture a single homogeneous good y with one input-capital using one of the two technologies with constant returns to scale: the modern sector technology and the one of the traditional sector. Each firm is assumed to have the same quantity of capital k. The product may be either manufactured for consumption purposes or for investment purposes. The modern sector technology is y = [a.sub.M]k. The firms in the modern sector must obtain a license from the government to access the technology. To obtain such a license, a firm must submit a project to a bureaucrat and this act involves an implementation cost of sk. (6) The firm may access the traditional sector without any license being issued. In this case the output is y = [a.sub.T]k. From this point onwards, it is assumed that ([a.sub.M] - s) > [a.sub.T] > 0, that is the modern sector is more profitable than the traditional sector. While households may invest their capital in the modern sector or in the traditional one, bureaucrats cannot invest in the production activity, earning a fixed salary w. (7) Bureaucrats are corruptible, in the sense that they pursue their own interest, and not necessarily that of the State. Bureaucrats are open to bribery as they issue the license required to access the modern sector technology to the firms submitting a project. The State controls the bureaucrats in such a way that they have a probability q (monitoring level) of being detected if they undertake a corrupt transaction.

In this model, the bureaucrat may decide not to ask for a bribe and to issue the license to those firms who submit a project, or else to ask for a bribe (b hereafter) in exchange for the license. Since ([a.sub.M] - s) > [a.sub.T], the firm might find it worthwhile to offer a bribe to the corrupt bureaucrat with a view to obtaining the necessary license to access the modern sector. The bureaucrat is assumed to have both monopolistic power (i.e., after having submitted the project, the firm cannot turn to any other bureaucrat to obtain the license) and discretional power over granting the license (i.e., the bureaucrat may refuse to issue the license without being required to provide any explanation). If the bureaucrat is detected while performing a corrupt transaction, he/she incurs a cost (either monetary, moral, or criminal) equal to mk, where m > 0 (8); the firm, if detected, incurs a cost (either monetary, moral, or criminal) equal to ck, where c > 0, but the cost of the bribe paid to the bureaucrat is refunded. (9)

A. Game Description

In the following, we refer to the firm payoff by using the superscript (F) and to the bureaucrat payoff by using the superscript (B). These represent the first and the second element of the payoff vector [[eta].sub.i], i = 1, 2, 3, 4, respectively, as it will become clear below there are four payoff configurations. Consider the following three-stage game:

Stage 1. At Stage 1 of the game, the firm decides in which sector to operate, that is, whether to invest its capital in the modern or in the traditional sector. Such a decision is tantamount to the decision of whether to submit the project to the bureaucrat, considering that a license is needed to invest in the modern sector. Project submission does not automatically result in the bureaucrat issuing a license, as he/she may refuse to grant the license unless a bribe b is paid. If the firm decides not to submit the project (preferring to invest in the traditional sector instead) the game ends and then the payoff vector is given by:

(1) [[[eta].bar].sub.1] = ([a.sub.T] k, w).

If the firm decides to submit the project, it asks the bureaucrat to issue the license. In this case the game continues to Stage 2.

Stage 2. At this stage the bureaucrat, on facing a firm who has submitted a project incurring a cost sk, may decide to issue the license without asking for a bribe (b = 0). (10) In this case the game ends and the payoff vector is given by:

(2) [[[eta].bar].sub.2] = ([a.sub.M] k - sk, w).

Alternatively, if he/she demands the payment of a bribe (b > 0) from the firm before agreeing to issue the license, the game continues to Stage 3.

Stage 3. At Stage 3, the payoffs will depend on whether, on one hand, the agreement between the bureaucrat and the firm is achieved or not and, on the other hand, whether the bureaucrat and the firm are reported (with probability q) or not. Should it decide to negotiate the payment of a bribe with the bureaucrat, the two parties will find the bribe corresponding to the Nash solution to a bargaining game ([b.sup.NB]). If agreement is not reached, the bureaucrat will refuse to issue the license; thus the game ends with the bureaucrat receiving his/her salary and the firm, after having been denied the license, will be left with no other option but to invest in the traditional sector. In this case, the game ends and the corresponding payoff vector is given by:

(3) [[[eta].bar].sub.3] = ([a.sub.T] k - sk, w).

If agreement is reached, the expected payoffs will depend on the probability q with which the bureaucrat and the firm are monitored. (11) In this case, the expected payoff vector is given by:

(4) [[[eta].bar].sub.4] = (([a.sub.M] - s)k - qck - [b.sup.NB] (1 - q), x w - qmk + [b.sup.NB](1 - q)).

It should be noted that [[[eta].bar].sub.2] is preferred to [[[eta].bar].sub.3] by both agents, and therefore the bureaucrat--will never ask for a bribe if he/she knows that the agreement will not be achieved.

B. The Solution to the Game

The model described in the previous section well reflects the pervasive uncertainty which is typically experienced by firms when dealing with the Public Administration. The game may be solved by starting from the last stage using backward induction, determining the bribe [b.sup.NB] (which is the Nash solution to a bargaining game). The bribe [b.sup.NB] is the outcome of a negotiation between the bureaucrat and the firm (see Appendix A for the proof).

PROPOSITION 1. Let q [not equal to] 1. (12) Then there is a unique non negative bribe ([b.sup.NB]), as the Nash solution to a bargaining game, given by:

(5) [b.sup.NB] = [alpha][([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])k/(l - q) -(q(c - m)k/(1 - q))],

where [alpha] and (1 - [alpha]) are parameters which can be interpreted as the bargaining strength measures of the bureaucrat and the firm, respectively.

Let us assume, without loss of generality, that the firm and the bureaucrat share the surplus on an equal basis. (13) Thus we have a standard Nash case, when [alpha] = (1 - [alpha]) = 1/2 and the firm and the bureaucrat receive equal shares. Hence the bribe is equal to:

(6) [b.sup.NB] = 1/2[(([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])k/(1 - q)) -(q(c - m)k/(1 - q))].

Static Analysis. The game is solved by means of backward induction starting from the last stage and the solution is formalized by the following proposition (see Appendix A). (14)

PROPOSITION 2. Define [q.sub.2] = (([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])/ (c + m)) - (2s/(c + m)) and [q.sub.1] = ([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])/ (c + m) with [q.sub.1] > [q.sub.2]. Then, if [q.sub.2] [greater than or equal to] 0, [q.sub.1] [less than or equal to] 1 and (c + m) > 2s:

(C) If q [member of] [0, [q.sub.2]] then the equilibrium payoff vector is:

(7) [[[eta].sub.4] = ((([a.sub.M] + [a.sub.T])k/2) - sk - (q(c + m)k/2), w + (([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])k/2) - (q(c + m)k/2))

this is the payoff vector connected to equilibrium C (see below);

(B) if [q.sub.2] < q < [q.sub.1] the equilibrium payoff vector is:

(8) [[eta].sub.1] = ([a.sub.T] k, w)

this is the payoff vector connected to equilibrium B (see below);

(A) If q [member of] [[q.sub.1], 1] the equilibrium payoff vector is:

(9) [[eta].sub.2] = (([a.sub.M] - s)k, w)

this is the payoff vector connected to equilibrium A (see below).

The previous proposition shows that, depending on the parameter values, one of the three perfect Nash equilibria is obtained in the subgames:

* Equilibrium C: corruption and high output. When 0 [less than or equal to] q [less than or equal to] [q.sub.2], that is if the monitoring level is low enough, the firm will enter the modern sector and will be asked to pay a bribe by the bureaucrat. Monitoring intensity is so low that the difference in gross profits, ([a.sub.M] = [a.sub.T])k, between the modern and the traditional sector is high enough to outweigh a (relatively low) expected cost of corruption and the cost of the project.

* Equilibrium B: no corruption and low output. When [q.sub.2] < q < [q.sub.1] that is if the monitoring level is intermediate, the firm will not enter the modern sector and therefore will not ask for a license. Monitoring intensity is not low enough for the firm to justify paying for the cost of the project along with the additional expected cost of paying a bribe. The difference in gross profits between the modern and the traditional sector does not compensate for the expected cost of corruption plus the cost of the project. Furthermore, monitoring intensity is not of a high enough level to deter the bureaucrat from asking for a bribe where the firm would have paid to pay the cost of the project.

* Equilibrium A: no corruption and high output. When q [is greater than or equal to] [q.sub.1], that is if the monitoring level is high enough, the level of monitoring intensity by the State is so high that the firm would turn down a request for a bribe even after having paid the (sunk) cost of submitting a project. Realizing this fact, the bureaucrat will refrain from asking for a bribe to issue the license. Thus the firm will enter the modern sector and will not be asked for a bribe by the bureaucrat.

Notice that in equilibrium B there is no corruption, but low output compared to equilibrium C, where corruption is at its highest, but output is higher. Should a State wish to lead the economy toward one of these three viable equilibria by employing a certain level of monitoring, it would realize that equilibria A and C imply a greater output than equilibrium B. Equilibria A and C allow the same output to be obtained, even though they are considerably different from one another in terms of level of corruption (which is greatest in C and nonexistent in A).

From a static perspective, equilibrium A is better than equilibrium C which implies the same output as equilibrium A but is characterized by widespread corruption, entailing a higher cost, summarized by parameters c and m. A is also better than B, while B and C cannot be ranked a priori.

Dynamic Analysis. Following the work of Del Monte and Papagni (2007), we expand the game perspective in order to examine the dynamic consequences of corruption on investment and hence on economic growth. As we said, the household's satisfaction is derived from consumption according to a simple constant elasticity utility function:

U = ([C.sup.1 - [sigma]] - 1)/(1 - [sigma])

Each household maximizes utility over an infinite period of time subject to a budget constraint. This problem is formalized as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

subject to

[??] = [[eta].sup.F.sub.i] - C,

where C is consumption, [rho] is the discount rate over time, [[eta].sup.F.sub.i] is the household's payoff.

Since [[eta].sup.F.sub.i] is different in each of the three equilibria, the problem is solved for each of the three cases. In the equilibrium with corruption (equilibrium C), the household's payoff is:

[[eta].sup.F.sub.4] = [([a.sub.M] + [a.sub.T]k/2 - sk - (q(c + m)k/2)],

thus the constraint is:

[??] = [(([a.sub.M] + [a.sub.T])k/2) - sk - (q(c + m)k/2)] - C.

The Hamiltonian function is:

H = [e.sup.-[rho]t] ([C.sup.1 - [sigma]] - 1/1 - [sigma]) + [lambda][(([a.sub.M] + [a.sub.T])k/2) - sk - (q(c + m)k/2) - C]

where [lambda] is a costate variable. Optimization provides the following first-order conditions:

(10) [e.sup.-[rho]t] [C.sup.-[sigma]] - [lambda] = 0

and

(11) [??] = -[lambda][(([a.sub.M] + [a.sub.T])/2)

- s - (q(c + m)/2)].

By differentiating the first condition in Equation (10) with respect to time and substituting it into the second condition in Equation (11), the consumption growth rate is obtained:

[y.sup.C.sub.C] = 1/[sigma][(([a.sub.M] + [a.sub.T])/2)

- s - (q(c + m)/2) - [rho]].

In equilibrium A, the household's payoff is

[[eta].sup.F.sub.s] = [a.sub.M]k - sk.

In this case, optimization provides the first-order conditions that allow the corresponding consumption growth rate to be obtained:

[[gamma].sup.C.sub.A] = 1/[sigma][[a.sub.M] - s - [rho]].

In equilibrium B, the household's payoff is

[[eta].sup.F.sub.1] = [a.sub.T]k

and the corresponding consumption growth rate is

[[gamma].sup.C.sub.B] = 1/[sigma][[a.sub.T] - [rho]].

It should be noted that:

[[gamma].sup.C.sub.A] > [[gamma].sup.C.sub.C] > [[gamma].sup.C.sub.B]

that is equilibrium A (no corruption, high-level monitoring) has the highest consumption growth rate; in equilibrium C (pervasive corruption, low monitoring) the consumption growth rate is intermediate; and finally in equilibrium B (no corruption, intermediate monitoring level) the firm invests in the traditional sector, with low profits, low accumulation of capital, and a low growth rate. Furthermore, it can be shown that capital and income also have the same growth rate as consumption. Therefore, of the three equilibria, from a dynamic viewpoint, equilibrium A is the most conducive to economic growth. This is shown in Figure 1 in terms of monitoring level and growth rate: equilibrium A (high-level monitoring without corruption) produces the highest growth rate since the firms, who are investing in the modern sector without paying bribes, are able to generate greater accumulation of capital; in equilibrium C the growth rate is intermediate, since although the firm manages to invest in the modern sector, it must pay bribes in order to do so and ends up accumulating less; finally in equilibrium B the firm invests in the traditional sector, with low revenues and low accumulation of capital. Thus a nonlinear U-shaped relationship between the monitoring of corruption and economic growth is obtained and this shall be tested empirically in the next section.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

III. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

The relatively recent Italian nationwide Mani Pulite ("Clean Hands") scandal, in conjunction with judicial authorities implementing greater levels of monitoring as a consequence, drastically affected Italy's economic environment. This Italian experience lends itself naturally to verifying the impact of the monitoring level on corruption and growth. (15) This section aims to empirically investigate the relationship between the level of monitoring of corruption and economic growth in Italy. The nonlinear character of the relationship between the monitoring level and the growth rate of income is formalized by using an empirical specification reflecting a parabolic relationship between these two variables. The theoretical model is tested using new monitoring measures. The empirical analysis is first performed considering all the Italian regions and then three subsamples, namely the North, Center, and South of Italy. The three subsamples are considered in order to investigate whether the U-shaped relationship may simply reflect the structural differences within the subsamples.

A. Data

The empirical analysis is based on annual data from Italian regions over the period 1980-2003. With the exception of monitoring and human capital variables, the annual data are drawn from the Prometeia Regional Accounting data set (courtesy of ISAE). The data relating to monitoring are selected from ISTAT and the Ministero dell'Economia e delle Finanze, and data regarding human capital are drawn from the Costantini and Destefanis (2009) data set. Appendix B provides a detailed description of the variables and their sources. The descriptive statistics of the variables are found in Appendix C.

With regard to the monitoring variable, three different measures are provided with a view to study the effects of monitoring on economic growth. The first is based on the number of corruption crimes and is denoted as [M.sub.1]. The second and the third measures use the number of pertinent judges and police officers as proxies to indicate how much of the State resources are allocated to fighting corruption-related crimes. These two measures are denoted as [M.sub.2] and [M.sub.3], respectively. The first measure ([M.sub.1]) is the ratio between the number of corruption crimes detected and the estimated total number of corruption crimes (see Appendix D). This is an expost variable since it only considers the results of State control activity. Therefore, this index expresses the effectiveness of the monitoring activity, that is the monitoring that leads to the corrupt bureaucrat being successfully charged. The second and third measures are based on the number of judges assigned to penal law cases ([M.sub.2]) and on the number of police officers employed in the investigation of corruption crimes ([M.sub.3]), respectively. Incentives for corruption increase as the probability of being caught and punished decreases and this probability is positively dependent on the actions of judges and police officers. These two proxies are of an ex-ante nature, since they allow us to assess the level of monitoring implemented by the State.

B. Estimation Methods

The specification of the basic estimated equation corresponds to a reduced form so as to evaluate the implications of the theoretical model. We consider the following specification equation:

(12) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

where the disturbance error term, [[epsilon].sub.it], has three components: the fixed effect (which accounts for any individual-specific effect), [[mu].sub.i], the unobservable time effect (which accounts for any time-specific effect and it is individual-invariant), [[lambda].sub.t], and the idiosyncratic shocks, [v.sub.it] (see Baltagi 2005). [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is the growth rate of per capita income at 2000 constant prices, ln [y.sub.it-1] is the logarithm of the lagged value of the per capita income level, ln([monitor.sub.it-1]) is the log monitoring level delayed by one period, (ln([monitor.sub.it-1]))2 is the square of the logarithm of the monitoring variable lagged by one period, [inv.sub.it] is the share of investment in Gross Domestic Product (GDP), [conpa.sub.it] is public consumption over GDP and [h.sub.it] is the stock of human capital. (16) The index i refers to the cross-section dimension (regions) and the index t to the time dimension. The share of investment over GDP and the level of public consumption over GDP are important control variables (see Barro 1991 and Levine and Renelt 1992). The monitoring variable is included in the equation with a delay of one period for two reasons. Firstly, changes in the monitoring level are very likely to require some time before they influence the agents' decisions. Secondly, any distortions due to simultaneity, resulting from the possible endogeneity of the monitoring variable, need to be mitigated, since a higher growth rate may result in more tax revenue and, therefore, more resources being allocated to monitoring activity.

Equation (12) is estimated using the system generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998) with a finite sample correction for the two-step covariance matrix derived by Windmeijer (2005). This estimator augments the difference GMM estimator developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) which uses first-differences to remove the unobserved time-invariant country-specific effects ("fixed effects") and instruments the right-hand side variables in first-differenced equations using levels of the series lagged two periods or more. Blundell and Bond (1998) show that the difference GMM estimator is likely to perform poorly when the series are persistent. In this case the available instruments are only weakly correlated with endogenous variables, and the difference GMM estimator is likely to suffer from serious bias as well as imprecision. Blundell and Bond (1998) suggest making use of additional information besides the differences. They consider an additional assumption which requires a restriction on the initial conditions. (17) This allows the use of lagged first-difference of the series as instruments for equations in level. Thus, the system GMM estimator stacks the equations in first differences and the equations in levels together and employs both lagged levels and first differences as internal instruments (see Roodman 2006). (18) The consistency of the GMM estimators depends on whether lagged values of the explanatory variables are valid instruments in the growth equation. In the empirical analysis, we address this issue by considering two specification tests suggested by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Arellano and Bover (1995). The first is a Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions, which tests the overall validity of the instruments by analyzing the sample analog of the moment conditions used in the estimation process. Failure to reject the null hypothesis gives support to the model. The second test examines the null hypothesis that the error term is not serially correlated. As in the case of the Sargan test, the model specification is supported when the null of no serial correlation cannot be rejected. The estimation results are summarized in Section C.

C. Results

The empirical results are reported in Tables 1-4. In the system GMM estimates, investment (Inv), human capital ([h.sub.it]), and public consumption (conpa) are treated as endogenous. These endogenous variables are instrumented with suitable lags of their own differences for the regression equation (see notes in Table 1). Results of Sargan tests of over-identifying restrictions for the GMM estimator confirm the validity of the instruments. For all the regressions, we find that the p value is larger than 5%. In addition, the results of the Arellano and Bond (1991) tests for AR(2) autocorrelation in the first-difference residuals show that null hypothesis of no serial correlation cannot be rejected and the moment conditions are correctly specified.

The coefficient on the [lny.sub.it] is used to test the convergence hypothesis. A negative sign denotes conditional convergence of growth rates. In our estimation, the sign of the parameter [[beta].sub.1] is negative and also statistically significant in all the cases. The convergence rate is stronger across the poorest regions (South) than that across the richest regions (North). Therefore, we can argue that the forces of convergence are stronger in lower levels of per capita income and less intensive in higher levels of income. These results are in line with those in the Italian literature (see, e.g., Cellini and Scorcu 1995).

The estimated regression coefficients of the square of the logarithm of the monitoring variables are all positive and statistically significant (see Tables 1-4). Although these results confirm the existence of a U-shaped relationship as predicted by the theoretical model, differences regarding the upward and downward sloping part of the relationship are found at macro-regional level (North, Center, and South) and among the monitoring measures (M j, [M.sub.2], and [M.sub.3]). (19) When considering all the Italian regions as a whole, the upward sloping part of the relationship is the most relevant for all the monitoring measures. Furthermore, the positive marginal effects show that more monitoring implies less corruption and therefore higher economic growth. In this respect, the most effective instrument of monitoring is represented by the judicial system which is independent from the political power (see Della Porta 2001). (20)

When accounting for the different macroarea, contrasting results are found. As regards the North and the Center of Italy, the upward sloping part of the relationship is the most relevant. Furthermore, among the monitoring measures, the most effective ex-ante instrument for controlling for corruption seems to be the number of pertinent judges ([M.sub.2]), while the police officers measure ([M.sub.3]) is the least effective.

In the South of Italy, the situation seems to be reversed. The relevant part of the U-shaped relationship is the downward sloping one. Also, the negative marginal effects show that a higher level of monitoring implies a lower economic growth. This result can be interpreted in light of the theoretical model: the South of Italy mainly lies in a situation where a rise of monitoring involves paying a higher bribe, fewer resources are devoted to capital accumulation, and lower economic growth is expected. In this case the government is unable to prevent waste, fraud, and mismanagement from occurring in the monitoring activities and then it is likely to be generally less effective in its capacity to govern (see, e.g., Putnam 1993). When considering the different measures of monitoring, a rise in number, the police officers imply a smaller reduction in the economic growth than that obtained with an increase in the number of pertinent judges.

As regards the investment/GDP ratio (Inv) variable, the estimated coefficients are all positive and statistically significant in all the cases. These results would seem to be in line with the literature concerning growth models (see, e.g., Levine and Renelt 1992) and similar findings are also found in other studies of Italian regions (see Auteri and Costantini 2004). As far as the performance of investment in the three subsamples is concerned, a larger estimated coefficient is found for the North of Italy (the estimated coefficient varies from 0.178 to 0.199). This result may be due to the fact that the public infrastructures are more developed in the North than in the other macro-areas.

The public consumption variable has positive coefficients in all cases. When all the Italian regions are considered, the estimated coefficient values vary from 0.201 to 0.263 and are all statistically significant. Del Monte and Papagni (2007) found similar results, although their evidence of a positive impact of public consumption on economic growth is weaker. As regards the three subsamples, the highest value of the estimated coefficient of public consumption is found for the North of Italy. This result reflects the fact that public expenditures are more efficient in the North than in the other subsamples. Indeed, Chang and Li (2011) point out that what is important for the effectiveness of public spending is not the size of the government, but the quality of the government itself.

With respect to the human capital variable, a positive and statistically significant effect on economic growth is also found. The level of education has a crucial impact on growth as it determines the economy's capacity to carry out technological innovation (see, e.g., Woo 2009, on education and technology). When the three subsamples are considered, the strongest impact of human capital on economic growth is found in the Northern regions (the estimated coefficient varies from 0.050 to 0.053).

IV. CONCLUSIONS

In this article, a new theoretical model of the link between monitoring of corruption and growth is developed. The model highlights the nonlinear relationship between the level of State monitoring and economic growth: when monitoring against corruption is low (high), high (low) corruption and high income prevail. However, when monitoring is intermediate, income production in the economy remains low. Similar results prevail in a dynamic framework. The nonlinear relationship is investigated using regional data for Italy over the period 1980-2003. An empirical analysis is then carried out considering all Italian regions and the three Italian macro-areas (North, Center, and South). The empirical results confirm the existence of a U-shaped relationship as predicted by the theoretical model, with differences regarding the upward and downward sloping part of the relationship found at the macro-regional level. In particular, we find, as predicted by our model, that in the Northern and Center part of Italy a direct relation between monitoring and economic growth prevails, so that making controls more pervasive depresses corruption and boosts growth. On the contrary, in Southern Italy more monitoring leads to less economic growth. This is too coherent with our model where, when monitoring is low to begin with--and corruption widespread but compatible with investment and growth--and is raised through greater controls, this induces bureaucrats to ask for a higher bribe, depressing in turn investment and economic activity. We believe that a nonlinear pattern of this kind may provide also interesting insights for the future study of cross-country differences in the relationship between the fight against corruption and growth.

ABBREVIATIONS

GDP: Gross Domestic Product

GMM: Generalized Method of Moments

APPENDIX A

THE NASH BARGAINING BRIBE [b.sup.NB]

Let [[PHI].bar].sub.[DELTA]] = [[PHI].sup.(F).sub.[DELTA]], [[PHI].sup.(B).sub.[DELTA]] be the vector of the differences in the payoffs between the case of agreement and disagreement regarding the bribe between the firm and the bureaucrat, In accordance with generalized Nash bargaining theory, the division between two agents will solve:

(A1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

that is

(A2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

which is the maximum of the product between the elements of [[PHI].bar].sub.[DELTA]] and where [([a.sub.T]k - sk), w] is the point of disagreement, that is the payoffs that the firm and the bureaucrat would obtain respectively if they failed to reach an agreement. The parameters (1 - [alpha]) and [alpha] can be interpreted as measures of bargaining strength. It is now easy to check that the bureaucrat gets a share [alpha] of the surplus [tau], that is the bribe is [b.sup.NB] = [alpha][tau]. More generally [alpha] reflects the distribution of bargaining strength between the two agents.

Then the bribe [b.sup.NB] is an asymmetric (or generalized) Nash bargaining solution and is given by:

(A3) [b.sup.NB] = [alpha] [(([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])k(1 - q)) - (q(c - m)k/(1 - q))]

which is the unique equilibrium bribe in the last subgame, [for all]q [not equal to] 1.

SOLUTION TO THE STATIC GAME

The static game is solved using backward induction, which enables the equilibria to be obtained.

Proof of Proposition 2.

Proof Backward induction method.

(3) At Stage 3, the agreement is achieved if, and only if,

[[eta].sup.(F).sub.4] > [[eta].sup.(F).sub.3] [??] ([a.sub.T]k - sk) < (([a.sub.M] + [a.sub.T])k/2) - sk - (q(c + m)k/2)

that is if the firm negotiates the bribe its payoff is greater than its payoff if it refuses. That is verified [for all]q < (([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])/(c + m)) = [q.sub.1].

Notice that in order to have an admissible probability set, q must belong to [0, 1]. It should be noted that [q.sub.1] is greater than one by assumption.

Furthermore, from now on we assume that [q.sub.1] < 1, that is the difference in returns between the two sectors must not be greater than the expected cost of corruption; consequently the presence of the probability q determines the firm's choice of whether to enter into the transaction. Then if q < [q.sub.1] the firm negotiates the bribe, otherwise if q [greater than or equal to] [q.sub.1] it refuses the bribe. Otherwise, if [q.sub.1] [greater than or equal to] 1 then the firm will always negotiate the bribe (See Appendix A3 for details).

(2) Ascending the decision-making tree, at Stage 2 the bureaucrat decides whether or not to ask for a bribe.

* If q [greater than or equal] [q.sub.1] then the bureaucrat knows that the firm will not accept any bribe. Should he/she decide not to ask for a bribe, his/her payoff will be w, whereas should he/she decide to ask for a bribe, he/she knows there is no room for negotiation, and therefore he/she will refuse to grant the license to the firm, which will be forced to invest in the traditional sector. In this case the bureaucrat's payoff will be w. Thus the bureaucrat's payoff is the same as if he/she decides to ask for a bribe equal to zero. As noted, in this case of equal payoffs, it may be assumed that the bureaucrat will prefer to be "honest," and thus not ask for a bribe.

* If q < [q.sub.1] then the bureaucrat knows that if he/she asks for a bribe then the firm will start a negotiation and the final bribe will be [b.sup.NB]. Then, at stage 2 the bureaucrat asks for a bribe if and only if the bureaucrat's payoff on asking for a bribe is greater than his/her payoff if he/she does not.

[[eta].sup.(B).sub.4] > [[eta].sup.(B).sub.2] [??]

w + (([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])k/2) - (q(c + m)k/2) > w

that holds [for all]q < [q.sub.1]. Thus we can conclude that if q < [q.sub.1] then the bureaucrat asks for a bribe which the firm accepts.

(1) At stage 1, the firm has to decide whether to present the project.

* If q [greater than or equal to] [q.sub.1] then the firm knows that if it presents a project no bribe will be asked. Should it decide not to submit the project, its payoff will be equal to [a.sub.T]k, whereas if it decides to submit its project, its payoff will be equal to [a.sub.M]k - sk. Therefore, it will present the project if and only if

[[eta].sup.(F).sub.2] > [[eta].sup.(F).sub.1] [??] ([a.sub.M]k - sk) > [a.sub.T].

The previous inequality is always verified by hypothesis.

* If q < [q.sub.1] then the firm knows that the bureaucrat will ask for the bribe which it will accept. Should it decide not to submit the project, its payoff will be [a.sub.T]k, whereas should it decide to submit the project and to pay the bribe to the bureaucrat, its payoff will be (([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])k/2) - sk - (q(c + m)k/2). Thus the firm decides to submit the project if and only if

[[eta].sup.F.sub.4] [greater than or equal to] [[eta].sup.F.sub.1] [??] (([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T])k/2) - sk - > (q(c + m)k/2) [greater than or equal to] [a.sub.T]k

which is verified if and only if

q [less than or equal to] ((([a.sub.M] - [a.sub.T]) - 2s)/(c + m)) = [q.sub.2].

Because [q.sub.2] < [q.sub.1] and since we assumed that [q.sub.1] [less than or equal to] 1, then [q.sub.2] [less than or equal to] 1. From now on we assume that [q.sub.2] > 0, that is half of the surplus (as the difference than the returns of the two productivity sectors) must be greater than the project cost (see Appendix A3 for the other cases).

EQUILIBRIA UNDER ALL PARAMETER CONDITIONS

If (c + m) [greater than or equal to] 2s we obtain the following five cases depending on parameter conditions:

If (c + m) < 2s we obtain the following five cases depending on parameter conditions:

[TABLE A1 OMITTED]

[TABLE A2 OMITTED]

APPENDIX B
TABLE A3
Data and Sources

GDP at market prices       1980-2003: PROMETEIA
  2000
Gross Fixed Investment     1980-2003: PROMETEIA
  at 2000 prices
Corruption level           1980-2003: ISTAT
                           "Annuario Statistico e
                             Giudiziario"
                           various years
Criminal judges            1980-2003: Ministero
                             dell'Economia e delle Finanze
                           "Dipendenti delle
                             Amministrazioni Statali"
                           various issues
Police forces              1980-2003: Ministero del
                             Tesoro
                           "Dipendenti delle
                             Amministrazioni Statali"
                           various issues
Population                 1980-2003: PROMETEIA
Public infrastructures     1980-2003: PROMETEIA
  spending
  at 2000 prices
Public consumption         1980-2003: PROMETEIA
  at 2000 prices

Human capital              1980-2003: Costantini and
                             Destefanis (2009)

Notes: The legal statistics of ISTAT are one of the main
sources for region-based corruption analysis. Corruption
crimes fall into two classes of crimes considered by ISTAT.
The first class includes crimes by public officials considered
by the criminal code (arts. "314" and "322") and referred
to as embezzlement of public funds or misappropriation
(art. "324"); the second class concerns private interests
in official deeds. The data considered in this study refer
to the total number of crimes classified by ISTAT with
classification numbers from "286" to "294," namely: "286"
Embezzlement of public funds; "287" Embezzlement by
drawing profit from another's error; "288" Misappropriation
to the damage of private individuals; "289" Extortion; "290"
Corruption for official deeds; "291" Corruption for deeds
contrary to official duties; "292" Corruption of a party
in charge of a public service; "293" Corruptor's liability;
"294" Incitement to corruption; Police forces data include:
Arma dei Carabinieri (paramilitary police) and Polizia di
Stato (state police) (see "Conto Annuale," "Dipendenti delle
amministrazioni statali", codice "9," Ministero del Tesoro);
Judges data include several categories (see codice "12").


APPENDIX C
TABLE A4
Descriptive Statistics

                  No. of
                 Observa
Variables         tions       M       Min      Max       SD

GDP                479      4.4      -9.6      5.6     0.559
(growth rate)
M,                 478      2.230     0.967    3.204   0.336
M2                 460      5.446     0.693    7.577   1.155
M3                 460      8.448     5.575   10.822   1.010
Investment/GDP     480      0.228     0.142    0.448   0.056
Public             480      0.248     0.129    0.396   0.067
consump
tion/GDP
Human capital      480      7.224     4.498    9.144   1.060

Notes: The growth rate of real per capita GDP is
expressed in percentages. With reference to public
consumption and investment, the unit of measurement used is
millions of Euro at 2000 constant prices. [M.sub.1],
[M.sub.2], and [M.sub.3] indicate the three measures of
monitoring.


APPENDIX D

We consider the ratio between the number of detected corruption crimes and the estimated total number of corruption crimes. The number of reported corruption crimes is both a function of the corruption level and a function of the level of prevention in place to reduce the phenomenon. The probability of being detected, q, may be estimated by the ratio between detected corruption crimes, [C.sub.o], and the estimated total number of corruption crimes, [C.sub.e]:

(A4) q = [C.sub.o]/[C.sub.e]

Most econometric studies find that corruption is a function of several variables (the legal system, government intervention, probability of being detected, etc.). Therefore, we can define the estimated total number of corruption crimes:

(A5) [C.sub.e] = A * IP

where IP is public infrastructure spending, and the constant A represents all the other variables which affect corruption. The rationale for focusing on public infrastructure spending is that activities surrounding public works construction are the classic locus of illegal monetary activities between public officials, both elected and appointed, and businesses. Although corruption occurs in settings other than public works contracting, the process of public works contracting is, because of inherent informational asymmetries, especially vulnerable, as substantial empirical and theoretical literatures suggest (see McMillan 1991; Porter and Zona 1993).

We assume that q is a nonlinear function of the monitoring level:

(A6) q = [Monitoring.sup.[alpha]]

By substituting Equations (A5) and (A6) in Equation (A4), we have:

(A7) [Monitoring.sup.[alpha]] = [C.sub.o]/(A * IP) [??]

(A8) [C.sub.o]/IP = A * [Monitoring.sup.[alpha]]

Taking logs, Equation (A8) is written as follows:

(A9) log[C.sub.o]/IP = logA + [alpha]logMonitoring

Then we use log[C.sub.o]/IP as a proxy for the dynamic of logMonitoring:

logmonitor = logdetected corruption crimes/ x public infrastructure spending.

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D. Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.

Acemoglu, D., and T. Verdier. "Property Rights, Corruption and the Allocation of Talent: A General Equilibrium Approach." Economic Journal, 108, 1998, 1381-403.

--. "The Choice between Market Failures and Corruption." American Economic Review, 90(1), 2000, 194-211.

Aidt, T. "Corruption, Institutions, and Economic Development." Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 25(2), 2009, 271-91.

Arellano, M., and S. Bond. "Some Test of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and Application to Employment Equations." Review of Economic Studies, 58, 1991, 277-97.

Arellano, M., and O. Bover. "Another Look at the Instrumental Variables Estimation of Error Components Models." Journal of Econometrics, 68, 1995, 29-51.

Auteri, M., and M. Costantini. "Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: The Case of Italian Regions." Review of Regional Studies, 34, 2004, 72-93.

Baltagi, B. Econometric Analysis of Panel Data. 3rd ed. Chichester, UK: Wiley, 2005.

Barreto, R. "Endogenous Corruption in a Neoclassical Growth Model." European Economic Review, 44, 2000, 35-60.

Barro, R. J. "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 199t, 407-44.

Blackburn, K., N. Bose, and M. E. Haque. "The Incidence and Persistence of Corruption in Economic Development." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30, 2006, 2447-67.

--. "Endogenous Corruption in Economic Development." Journal of Economic Studies, 37, 2010, 4-25.

Blundell, R., and S. Bond. "Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models." Journal of Econometrics, 87, 1998, 115-43.

Campos, N., R. Dimova, and S. Ahmad. "Whither Corruption? A Quantitative Survey of the Literature on Corruption and Growth." CEPR Discussion Paper No. 8140, 2010.

Cellini, R., and A. E. Scorcu. "How Many Italies? What Data Show about Growth and Convergence across Italian Regions, 1970-91." Working Paper 251, Universit a di Bologna, 1995.

Cerqueti, R., R. Coppier, and G. Piga. "Corruption, Growth and Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization: A Theoretical Game Model." Journal of Economics, 106(2), 2012, 153-81.

Chang, T. S., and Y. Li. "A Macroeconomic Model on the Quality of Government and Economic Performance." Economic Inquiry, 49, 2011, 174-84.

Costantini, M., and S. Destefanis. "Cointegration Analysis for Cross-sectionally Dependent Panels. The Case of Regional Production Functions." Economic Modelling, 26, 2009, 320-27.

Del Monte, A., and E. Papagni. "Public Expenditure, Corruption and Economic Growth." European Journal of Political Economy, 17(1), 2001, 1 - 16.

Della Porta, D. "A Judges' Revolution? Political Corruption and the Judiciary in Italy." European Journal of Political Research, 39, 2001, 1-21.

Della Porta, D., A. Vannucci. Un Paese Anormale. Come la Classe Politica ha Perso l'Occasione di Mani Pulite, Edizioni Laterza, 1999.

--. "The Determinants of Corruption in Italy: Regional Panel Data Analysis." European Journal of Political Economy, 23(2), 2007, 379-96.

Ehrlich, I.. and F. T. Lui. "Bureaucratic Corruption and Endogenous Economic Growth." Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), 1999, 270-93.

Fan, S. C. "Kleptocracy and Corruption." Journal of Comparative Economics, 34, 2006, 57-74.

Friehe, T. "Correlated Payoffs in the Inspection Game: Some Theory and an Application to Corruption." Public Choice, 137, 2008, 127-43.

Harstad, B., and J. Svensson. "Bribes, Lobbying, and Development." American Political Science Review, 105(1), 2011, 46-63.

Hijzen, A., T. Inui, and Y. Todo. "Does Offshoring Pay? Firm-Level Evidence from Japan." Economic Inquiry, 48, 2010, 880-95.

Huntington, S. P. Political Order in Changing Societies, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1968.

ISTAT. "Annuario Statistico e Giudiziario." Various years.

--. "Conti Economici Nazionali." Various years*

--. "Conti Economici Regionali." Various years.

--. "Opere Pubbliche." Various years*

Keefer, P., and S. Knack. "Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Test Using Alternative Institutional Measures." Economics and Politics, 1995, 207-27.

Left, N. H. "Economic Development through Bureaucratic Corruption." American Behavioral Scientist, 1964, 8-14.

Levine, R., and D. Renelt. "A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regression." American Economic Review, 82, 1992, 942-63.

Lui, F. "An Equilibrium Queuing Model of Bribery." Journal of Political Economy, 1985, 760-81.

Mauro, P. "Corruption and Growth." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 1995, 681-712.

--. "The Persistence of Corruption and Slow Economic Growth." IMF Staff Papers, 51 (1), 2004, 1 - 18.

McMillan, J. "Dango: Japan's Price-Fixing Conspiracies." Economics and Politics, 3, 1991, 201-18.

Meon, P., and K. Sekkat. "Does Corruption Grease or Sand the Wheels of Growth?" Public Choice, 122, 2005, 69-97.

Mishra, A. "Persistence of Corruption: Some Theoretical Perspective." World Development, 34, 2006, 349-58.

Mocan, N. "What Determines Corruption? International Evidence from Microdata." Economic Inquiry, 46, 2008, 493-510.

Murphy, K., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny. "Why Is Rent-Seeking So Costly to Growth?" AEA Papers and Proceedings, 1993, 409-14.

Porter, R. H., and J. D. Zona. "Detection of Bid Rigging in Procurement Auctions." Journal of Political Economy, 101, 1993, 518-38.

Putnam, R. D. Making Democracy Work: Civie Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1993.

Reed, R. W. "The Determinants of U.S. State Economic Growth: A Less Extreme Bounds Analysis." Economic Inquiry,, 47, 2009, 685-700.

Roodman, D. "How to Do xtabond2: An Introduction to 'Difference" and "System' GMM in Stata." Working Paper No. 103, Center for Global Development, 2006.

Rose-Ackerman, S. "The Economics of Corruption." Journal of Public Economics, 4, 1975, 187-203.

--. Corruption and Govermnent. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1999.

Shaw, P., M. Katsaiti, and M. Jurgilas. "Corruption and Growth under Weak Identification." Economic Inquiry, 49, 2011,264-75.

Svensson, J. "Eight Questions about Corruption." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 2005, 19-42.

Windmeijer, F. "A Finite Sample Correction for the Variance of Linear Two-step GMM Estimators." Journal of Econometrics, 126, 2005, 25-51.

Woo, J. "Productivity Growth and Technological Diffusion through Foreign Direct Investment." Economic Inquiry, 47, 2009, 226-48.

(1.) For a recent review of Mauro's influential work see Shaw, Katsaiti, and Jurgilas (2011).

(2.) Since corruption data are available, almost exclusively, at the aggregate country level, most of the empirical literature has focused on cross-country analysis. An exception is, for example, Mocan (2008) who investigates the determinants of being asked for a bribe at the individual level.

(3.) The implicit assumption in our work. as in most of the literature, is that a higher monitoring level will reduce corruption. However, as stressed by Svensson (2005), the institutions are weak in many poor countries and, therefore, providing more resources for monitoring activities might not be the right strategy in order to reduce corruption. In fact, little evidence exists--Hong Kong and Singapore are the most cited exceptions--that allocating more resources to monitoring institutions will reduce corruption.

(4.) See also Cerqueti, Coppier, and Piga (2012) for a nonlinear relationship between corruption and economic growth.

(5.) "When individuals are risk averse, this may imply that there should be a risk premium associated with such stochastic streams of income. This is not necessarily the case, however, when the following three conditions are satisfied:

(1) there are many firms involved in research;

(2) the realization of the uncertainty across firms is independent;

(3) consumers and firms have access to a 'stock market.' where each consumer can hold a balanced portfolio of various research firms.

When this is the case, even though each firm's revenue is risky, the balanced portfolio held by the representative household will have deterministic returns," pp. 562-563.

(6.) The cost of the project submission to the bureaucrat is a function of the investment. The underlying assumption is that, as the size of the investment grows, the cost for the firm's bureaucratic practices also grows.

(7.) It is assumed that no arbitrage is possible between the public and the private sector allowing bureaucrats to become households, even if their salary w is lower than the firm's net return. This may be assumed since although individuals in the population (bureaucrats) have a job, they have no access to capital markets, and therefore may not become households.

(8.) Like Harstad and Svensson (2011), we assume that the penalty increases in k because the penalty for such a serious crime is larger.

(9.) See Rose-Ackerman (1999) for details regarding the assumption of a non-constant punishment function.

(10.) If agents are indifferent about whether to ask for a bribe or not, they will prefer to be honest.

(11.) It is possible to consider q to depend on the number of corrupt individuals or on other economic variables as, for example, fiscal revenues. We deliberately avoid doing this in order to better highlight how the monitoring level can influence the economic growth rate (this approach has been also considered by Blackburn, Bose, and Haque 2006, 2010; Del Monte and Papagni 2001; Fan 2006; Friehe 2008; Mishra 2006). Furthermore, there is no clear-cut evidence regarding how the level of corruption may endogenously affect the monitoring activity. In fact, some literature considers that the greater the corruption rate, the more likely the detection is (see, e.g., Barreto 2000); while other authors assume that the more corrupt people there are, the less might be the probability of being caught (see Mauro 2004; Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny 1993).

(12.) If q = 1 this stage of the game is never reached.

(13.) Leaving the bargaining strength of the bureaucrat and of the firm generic, that is equal to a and 1 - [alpha], respectively, does not change qualitatively the results of the static game and, therefore of the dynamic one. The proof is available upon request.

(14.) We here focus on the case where parameters allow the greatest number of equilibria depending on the level of monitoring by the State. In Appendix A we show the results under all parameter conditions.

(15.) Mani pulite (Italian for "Clean Hands") was a nationwide Italian judicial investigation into political corruption, held in the 1990s. As Della Porta and Vannucci (1999) said "In Italy the history of corruption does not begin (let alone end) on February 17, 1992 (the official date that Clean Hands began). What starts at that point are the extraordinary events of public exposure of corruption, a scandal affecting the highest levels of the political and economic system, causing the most serious political crisis of the Italian Republic". The corruption system that is uncovered by these investigations is usually referred to as Tangentopoli, or "bribesville."

(16.) For a recent analysis on the determinants of growth. see Reed (2009).

(17.) For further details see Blundell and Bond (1998).

(18.) For a discussion on endogeneity and system GMM estimator see, e.g., Hijzen, Inui, and Todo (2010).

(19.) We would like to thank a referee for having raised this point.

(20.) In particular the author finds evidence that for political corruption, "the efficacy of the magistracy is, to a large extent, determined by its degree of independence from political authority.... In Italy, there is an unusually high level of (at least formal) independence of the judiciary from political power. Mechanisms which can allow for a certain degree of control by politicians over judges are not available in Italy; the Constitution ensures that the magistracy could not become the 'long arm of the government' as it had been during the fascist regime."

RAFFAELLA COPPIER, MAURO COSTANTINI, and GUSTAVO PIGA *

* The authors would like to thank Francesco Busato, John Bennett, Luca De Benedictis, Gianni De Fraia, Pietro Reichlin, Maria Cristina Rossi. and seminar participants at the Department of Economic Sciences at the University of Rome "La Sapienza" and at the Department of Economic and Financial Institutions at the University of Macerata for their very helpful suggestions. A special thanks to Francesco Nucci. The usual disclaimer applies.

Coppier: Department of Economic and Financial Institutions, University of Macerata, Macerata 62100, Italy. Phone +39 07332583245, Fax +39 07332583206, E-mail raffaellacoppier@unimc.it

Costantini: Department of Economics and Finance, Brunel University, Uxbridge UB8 3PH, UK. Phone +44 (0)1895 267958, Fax +44 (0)1895 269770, E-mail Mauro.Costantini@brunel.ac.uk

Piga: Department of Business, Government, Philosophy Studies, University of Rome-Tor Vergata, Rome 133, Italy. Phone -t-39 0672595701, Fax +39 062020500, E-mail gustavo.piga@uniroma2.it

doi: 10.1111/ecin.12007
TABLE 1
Growth and Monitoring (All Italian Regions,
1980-2003)

                                       Dependent Variable:
                                    [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                    NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCCI]

Variables                            [M.sub.1]     [M.sub.2]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                     -0.082        -0.088
                                    (2.83) ***    (2.84) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1]))              -0.079        -0.099
                                    (2.72) ***    (3.09) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]      0.013         0.012
                                    (3.17) ***     (2.40) **
Inv                                    0.161         0.174
                                    (3.04) ***    (3.05) ***
conpa                                  0.263         0.223
                                     (2.58) **     (2.42) **
[h.sub.it]                             0.050         0.058
                                    (3.13) ***     (2.63) **
constant                               0.321         0.334
                                      (1.34)      (3.04) ***
Sargan test: [chi square]              16.92         16.79
p values                                921          0.928
z-statistics                           0.245         0.235
p values                               0.749         0.768
No. of observations                     475           457

                                       Dependent Variable:
                                    [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                    NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCCI]

Variables                                   [M.sub.3]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                             -0.096
                                            (2.91) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1]))                      -0.123
                                            (2.93) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]             0.009
                                            (3.00) **
Inv                                           0.168
                                            (2.95) ***
conpa                                         0.201
                                            (2.37) **
[h.sub.it]                                    0.059
                                            (2.81) ***
constant                                      0.310
                                              (1.35)
Sargan test: [chi square]                     16.35
p values                                      0.937
z-statistics                                  0.456
p values                                      0.659
No. of observations                            457

Noter: Instruments used for Equation (12) are [DELTA]ln  ([y.sub.i,t-
2]), [DELTA]ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2]),
[DELTA][(ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2])).sup.2],  [DELTA]In[v.sub.i,t-1],
[DELTA][conpa.sub.i,t-1] and [DELTA][h.sub.it-1]. t-Statistics are in
parentheses. z-statistics indicate Arellano-Bond test for  second-
order autocorrelation in the first-difference residuals. ***
Significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at  10% levels,
respectively.

TABLE 2
Growth and Monitoring (Northern Italian
Regions, 1980-2003)

                                       Dependent Variable:
                                    [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                    NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Variables                            [M.sub.1]     [M.sub.2]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                     -0.068        -0.073
                                    (2.96) ***    (2.81) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])               -0.078        -0.095
                                    (3.01) ***    (2.97) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]      0.020         0.016
                                    (2.86) ***     (2.67) **
Inv                                    0.183         0.199
                                    (3.21) ***    (2.93) ***
conpa                                  0.276         0.237
                                     (2.56) **     (2.52) **
[h.sub.it]                             0.053         0.052
                                    (3.12) ***     (2.26) **
constant                               0.341         0.352
                                      (1.48)      (3.01) ***
Sargan test: [chi square]              16.17         16.41
p values                               .948          .924
z-statistics                           0.225         0.400
p values                               .779          .700
No. of observations                     192           187

                                       Dependent Variable:
                                    [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                    NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Variables                                   [M.sub.3]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                             -0.085
                                            (2.93) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])                      -0.0122
                                            (2.84) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]             0.008
                                            (2.67) **
Inv                                           0.178
                                            (2.58) **
conpa                                         0.232
                                            (2.64) **
[h.sub.it]                                    0.050
                                            (2.38) **
constant                                      0.315
                                              (1.31)
Sargan test: [chi square]                     16.51
p values                                       .927
z-statistics                                  0.435
p values                                       .690
No. of observations                            187

Notes: Instruments used for Equation (12) are
[DELTA]ln([y.sub.i,t-2]), [DELTA]ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2]),
[DELTA][(ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2])).sup.2], [DELTA]ln[v.sub.it-1],
[DELTA][conpa.sub.it-1] and [DELTA][h.sub.it-1]. t-Statistics are in
parentheses. z-statistics indicate Arellano-Bond test for second-
order amocorrelation in the first-difference residuals.

***Significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at
10% levels, respectively.

TABLE 3
Growth and Monitoring (Central Italian
Regions, 1980-2003)

                                        Dependent Variable:
                                     [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                     NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Variables                             [M.sub.1]     [M.sub.2]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                      -0.073        -0.079
                                     (2.81) ***    (2.93) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])                -0.071        -0.102
                                     (2.84) ***    (2.91) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]       0.017         0.011
                                     (2.83) ***    (2.75) ***
Inv                                     0.109         0.139
                                     (3.03) ***    (3.16) ***
conpa                                   0.214         0.209
                                      (2.09) *      (2.01) *
[h.sub.it]                              0.029         0.031
                                      (2.42) **     (2.39) **
constant                                0.402         0.389
                                       (1.61)        (1.46)
Sargan test: [chi square]               15.90         16.02
p values                                .964          .951
z-statistics                            0.228         0.329
p values                                .772          .742
No. of observations                      94            87

                                        Dependent Variable:
                                     [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                     NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Variables                                    [M.sub.3]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                              -0.094
                                             (2.76) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])                        -0.116
                                             (3.29) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]              0.007
                                             (2.33) **
Inv                                            0.136
                                             (2.52) **
conpa                                          0.201
                                              (2.05) *
[h.sub.it]                                     0.036
                                             (2.77) **
constant                                       0.401
                                               (1.42)
Sargan test: [chi square]                      15.02
p values                                        .979
z-statistics                                   0.328
p values                                        .744
No. of observations                              87

Notes: Instruments used for Equation (12) are
[DELTA]ln([y.sub.i,t-2]), [DELTA]ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2]),
[DELTA][(ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2])).sup.2], [DELTA]ln[v.sub.it-1],
[DELTA][conpa.sub.it-1] and [DELTA][h.sub.it-1]. t-Statistics are in
parentheses. z-statistics indicate Arellano-Bond test for second-
order amocorrelation in the first-difference residuals.

*** Significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at
10% levels, respectively.

TABLE 4
Growth and Monitoring (Southern Italian
Regions, 1980-2003)

                                        Dependent Variable:
                                     [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                     NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Variables                             [M.sub.1]     [M.sub.2]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                      -0.103        -0.101
                                     (3.21) ***    (3.26) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])                -0.070        -0.101
                                     (2.92) ***    (2.89) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]       0.013         0.008
                                     (3.25) ***    (2.67) ***
Inv                                     0.100         0.101
                                      (2.13) **     (2.24) **
conpa                                   0.199         0.198
                                       (1.48)       (1.83) *
[h.sub.it]                              0.011         0.021
                                      (1.83) *      (1.75) *
constant                                0.378         0.362
                                       (1.61)       (2.65) **
Sargan test: [chi square]               16.91         17.10
p values                                .919          .898
z-statistics                            0.268         0.202
p values                                .740          .792
No. of observations                      189           183

                                          Dependent Variable:
                                      [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
                                     NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Variables                                    [M.sub.3]

ln([y.sub.i,t-1])                              -0.108
                                             (3.18) ***
ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])                        -0.121
                                             (3.18) ***
[(ln([monitor.sub.i,t-1])).sup.2]              0.007
                                             (2.33) ***
Inv                                            0.102
                                             (2.17) **
conpa                                          0.178
                                              (1.82) *
[h.sub.it]                                     0.012
                                              (1.71) *
constant                                       0.328
                                               (1.54)
Sargan test: [chi square]                      16.87
p values                                        .919
z-statistics                                   0.209
p values                                        .790
No. of observations                             183

Notes: Instruments used for Equation (12) are
[DELTA]ln([y.sub.i,t-2]), [DELTA]ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2]),
[DELTA][(ln([monitoring.sub.i,t-2])).sup.2], [DELTA]ln[v.sub.it-1],
[DELTA][conpa.sub.it-1] and [DELTA][h.sub.it-1]. t-Statistics are in
parentheses. z-statistics indicate Arellano-Bond test for second-
order amocorrelation in the first-difference residuals.

*** Significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at
10% levels, respectively.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有