Who benefits from child benefit?
Blow, Laura ; Walker, Ian ; Zhu, Yu 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Over most of the developed world large financial transfers are made
to parents by virtue of their parenthood. For example, in the United
States the recently introduced Child Tax Credit (CTC), which goes to the
vast majority of children, (1) costs almost $1 billion each week, or
about 0.4% of GNP. The United Kingdom government spends on average about
$25 (at present exchange rates) each week on each child in the form of a
lump sum transfer called Child Benefit (CB) which goes to all children,
and in addition, the United Kingdom has its own version of CTC which
goes to almost all families with children--and together CB and CTC
account for approximately 1% of GNP. (2) In the United Kingdom, CB and
CTC represent a sizeable contribution to family net incomes, especially
for the single parent households considered in this paper.
The typical rationale for these payments that are ostensibly earmarked for children is that they are good for our children. Such
transfers are usually motivated by concern for the welfare of children
and implicitly presume that there is some market failure that prevents
parents from investing in the desired quality and/or quantity of
children throughout their lives. This might arise, for example, through
child quality being a household public good implying parental
free-riding in quality investments, or through imperfections in
fertility control, or credit market constraints that prevent households
from smoothing the costs of children. A further motivation is that this
is a form of intra-household redistribution so that, in households where
resources are not pooled, a transfer payment via the mother may have
different effects on spending than other forms of income. Moreover,
particular concern arises for children in poor households, and the
United States and the United Kingdom are distinctive in having child
poverty rates that are considerably higher than that in most other
developed countries. (3) Thus, there may be credit market constraints
that prevent households, especially poor ones, from spreading the costs
associated with children across their lifetimes that CB can help
mitigate.
This paper is concerned with the impact on household spending
patterns of exogenous changes in a lump sum cash transfer that is made
to all parents. The United Kingdom is an excellent laboratory to address
this issue because CB has been a simple lump sum universal transfer for
a period of more than 20 years from 1980 up to the introduction of CTC,
which is a means-tested supplementary transfer, in 2001. Since that
reform in the late 1970's, the level of payments has varied
dramatically over time.
Rather than consider intra-household distribution issues, our aim
here is to try to complement existing research on the relationship
between child outcomes and household income by trying to infer how CB is
spent--in particular, we are interested in how CB affects spending on
adult and child specific goods. That is, we investigate the impact of CB
on household spending patterns with a view to estimating its impact on
goods that are "assignable" to either children or adults.
Thus, this paper takes a direct approach as to whether "money
matters" by investigating the effect of variations in transfer
households with children on household spending decisions. We provide
separate estimates for lone mothers, where intra-household
distributional issues do not arise, from mothers with partners present,
where it may. Thus, for lone mothers our results indicate the pure
effect of the fact that CB is "labeled," while for couples any
such effect is confounded with any intra-household distributional
effect. We are particularly concerned with spending on "child
goods" and use spending on children's clothing to reflect
this. In contrast, we also look at how transfers to parents affect
spending on "adult goods" and use alcohol, tobacco, and adult
clothing as examples of these. (4)
Our headline finding is that CB is spent differently from regular
income--but, paradoxically, it is spent disproportionately on
adult-assignable goods. This appears to be true for single parents as
well as for couples and so is not attributable to just intra-household
redistribution. On the face of it, this might be interpreted as implying
that mothers have a callous disregard for the welfare of their children.
We resolve this paradoxical finding when we disaggregate our variation
in CB into anticipated variation and unanticipated variation in CB,
which we are able to do by virtue of a peculiarity of the CB system in
the United Kingdom. We are motivated to disaggregate variations in CB in
this way because altruism toward one's children would, in a simple
model at least, imply that mothers would insure their children against
surprises in income, including CB. Thus, we would expect anticipated
variation in CB to have an effect on spending on child-assignable goods
that is the same as other anticipated variations in income. In contrast,
unanticipated changes in CB should be spent on adult-assignable goods
and not at all on child-assignable goods.
These theoretical propositions are broadly supported by our
empirical analysis. Our cleanest results are for lone parents where
there is no intra-household distribution issue. Here the unanticipated
variation in CB, driven by policy changes, is spent disproportionately
on adult-assignable goods. In contrast, we find that there is no
significant overall difference in the way in which this is spent,
relative to other income sources. Thus, it is parents who benefit from
unanticipated variation in CB--a result that is consistent with the view
that mothers are altruistic toward their children and so insure them
against income shocks.
Although CB is universal (i.e., not means tested), it clearly
contributes to a reduction in child poverty as measured in the United
Kingdom. (5) In any event, it seems plausible that lessons that we learn
here from this universal program applies to means-tested transfers that
are explicitly aimed at relieving child poverty. (6) CB, in 2010, was
worth 20 [pounds sterling] ($30) per week for the first child, (7) and
13.20 [pounds sterling] ($20) for subsequent ones, and this has recently
been joined by the CTC which is a further program that provides a tax
credit for children structured in such a way that its value only falls
as income rises at a level of income that is far above the mean level of
household income. (8) This credit was further superseded in April 2003
by the CTC worth 10.40 [pounds sterling] (around $15) per household per
week, slightly more than the Children's Tax Credit, and where the
means testing starts higher up the income distribution. The total of all
child-related cash benefits amounts to 2% of GDP in 2010 in the United
Kingdom, about half of which is accounted for by CB and CTC, compared to
1.5% in the late 1970's, despite the dramatic fall in fertility.
Indeed, the recent reforms to the welfare system have been driven by the
desire to ensure that absolute cash support for children is independent
of parental circumstances such as unemployment, sickness, and
disability. (9)
To anticipate our findings, we show that CB is spent differently
from other sources of income--but, paradoxically, we find that it is
spent disproportionately on adult-assignable goods, not on
child-assignable goods. (10) We resolve this paradox by making a
distinction between anticipated and unanticipated variation in CB. The
plan of the paper is as follows: Section II outlines the existing
literature on child outcomes and parental incomes which motivates our
analysis and reviews the few existing papers that investigate spending
patterns; Section III summarizes our data on CB variation and on
household spending patterns; Section IV provides our empirical findings
that relates the two; and Section V draws the conclusion.
II. LITERATURE
Economists take it for granted that giving additional income to
individuals will improve their welfare. But understanding how important
giving additional income to parents is likely to be for the well-being
of their children is more complex. This is because children depend on
the behaviors and decisions made by their parents to determine how much,
and in what way, they will benefit from additional income into the
household. Most straightforwardly, parental income could be important
for child outcomes because parents could use additional income to buy
goods and services that are good for their children and represent an
investment in their children's future well-being. Such theories of
parental investment in their children have been the focus of many
economists' thinking about the role of parental income in
determining children's outcomes (Becker and Tomes 1986).
Recent work on spending on child and adult clothing by Kooreman
(2000) for the Netherlands suggests the fact that the money is labeled
as child benefit motivates households to indeed spend it
disproportionately on child goods essentially because of a "mental
accounting" effect. (11) That paper exploits differential variation
in CB by age of child for one-child households and finds that the
estimated marginal propensity to spend on child clothing is higher for
CB than for other income and so argues that this is evidence of a
"labeling effect." However. identification relied on a single
change in the rate for young children versus older children that was
almost coincident with the change in the payment mechanism. Under this
reform the recipient, in the overwhelming number of cases, ceased to be
the head of household and became the mother. (12) The only statistically
significant finding was for one-child married couples--for larger
households and for single mothers there were no significant effects of
CB.
Moreover, further work on Slovenia by Edmonds (2002) found no
significant effects. However, this work exploited the dependence of
Slovenian CB on household income and the number of children in the
previous year and so requires that these have no direct effect on
current expenditure patterns--something that seems unlikely because of
serial correlation in incomes, habit persistence, and the fact that
changes in the number of children in the household are likely to be
anticipated. (13) As in the Netherlands, UK CB over the period 1980 to
2000 was a universal (not means-tested) program, where payments depended
on the current number of dependent children, went to the mother,
payments were not subject to taxation, and participation was effectively
100%. (14) Thus, the United Kingdom offers an interesting laboratory to
study the effect of CB because we do not have to correct for program
nonparticipation. Indeed, it was this absence of selectivity that
allowed Lundberg, Pollak, and Wales (1997) to investigate the impact of
the UK "wallet to the purse" reform in the late 1970's.
The argument for such a reform was that mothers are better agents for
their children than fathers. The authors show, in grouped data, that
there is an increase in spending on child clothing relative to adult
clothing and female adult clothing relative to male adult clothing
following the reform which gave mothers control over this source of
income. (15) These findings, that household members fail to pool their
resources in making spending decisions, have been echoed in other
studies (16) and suggest a rejection of the unitary model of household
behavior. Here, we abstract from these considerations by only using data
post 1979, by which time the wallet-to-purse reform had been fully
implemented, (17) and using the couples samples separately from the lone
parents sample. In the latter, there is no intra-household issue,
whereas in the former our estimates are conditional on it. (18)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
III. DATA AND IDENTIFICATION
Our analysis covers the 21 years from 1980 (when CB had finally
entirely replaced the earlier system of Family Allowances whose main
beneficiaries were fathers) to 2000 (after which tax credits for parents
were introduced which would complicate our analysis because these
credits were means tested and were subject to a potential take-up
problem). Across this period there have been wide variations in real CB
within years induced by differences in inflation across years, and large
changes in the real value of CB between years driven by reforms whereby
CB was reflated by more or less than the inflation rate from the
previous uprating. For example, a large reform occurred in 1991 whereby
CB entitlement of the first child rose by a considerable amount, and a
further increase for the first child occurred in 1999. Figure 1 shows
the two sources of variation in real CB for first and subsequent
children and for lone parents and couples separately. (19) The sawtooth shape in the 1980's clearly shows the effects of
inflation--something that is not obvious in later years when inflation
was considerably lower. The real reductions over the period 1984 to 1990
shows the effect of not uprating in line with price inflation in the
period when the Conservative government of the day had (implicitly)
adopted a policy of targeting support on the very poorest households
through real rises in the generosity of the in-work welfare program for
parents (then called Family Credit) at the expense of CB. In 1991, a
large real rise in CB for the first child of a couple was
introduced--this distinction between first and subsequent children had
always been a feature of CB for lone parents (lone parents received a
supplement to CB known as OPB that created this wedge between first and
subsequent children) but not for couples. In a controversial change in
1997, the new Labor government abolished the OPB and so effectively
eliminated this distinction between couples and lone parents. (20)
However, the adverse effect on (new) lone parents was soon ameliorated
when the rate for all first children was subject to a large real
increase.
Until 1999, and the Labour government's commitment to abolish
child poverty, the real value of CB was lower than it had been when it
was first introduced in 1978 and that remained the case for the first
children of lone parents and for all subsequent children in 2001, and
still remains to the present. The real value of CB for the first child
of lone parents had fallen by more than 10%, whereas the value for all
subsequent children had fallen by more than 15%. It is only with the
recent introduction of the supplement to CB known as Child Tax Credit
(CTC) that the real values of child-contingent financial support enjoyed
by parents back in 1979 have been matched. Our analysis relies on the
real variation in CB for given household types. That is, we make no
attempt to exploit the variation in CB across household types at a point
in time. We do this because we do not want to rely on functional form
assumptions that restrict how different numbers of children affect
household spending. Moreover, we do not want to make any assumptions
about the nature of intra-household distribution of income so we present
estimates separately for lone parent households and couples (which
include repartnered divorcees). Finally, we also decompose our data into
those on in-work welfare (WFTC) and out-of-work welfare (IS) and those
not. CB interacts with the latter because CB counts as income for the
purposes of computing IS payments and nominal CB rises are effectively
taxed at 100%--although the situation is complicated by the fact that
the child-related component of IS is also increased over time. We choose
not to attempt to exploit this source of variation on the grounds that
it may be too subtle for consumers to detect and the group affected is,
in any case, quite small. Thus, most of our analysis will be conducted
over households who are not on either in-work or out-of-work welfare.
Effectively, identification comes from two sources: the variation
in inflation rates across years that ensures that we can identify
anticipated effects independently of seasonality (effectively we assume
that the seasonality in the data is orthogonal to inflation); and from
the various reforms that ensure that there are discontinuities in
anticipated CB (that cannot account for smooth changes in expenditure
patterns).
We use Family Expenditure Survey (FES) data on household spending
patterns, which contain detailed household (21) expenditure information,
constructed from two consecutive weekly diary records supplemented with
information about regular payments. The expenditure data is regarded as
being quite accurate with the exception of alcohol and tobacco, (22)
which are under-recorded relative to other sources of information.
Moreover, there is considerable consistency over time. The data also
records sources of income and their levels and periodicity, and the
detailed characteristics of respondent households including the number
and ages of children. (23) Table 1 shows the breakdown of the data by
household type. Table 2 shows some summary statistics for households
with exactly one child.
IV. ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS
In our parametric work, we test for differential marginal
propensities to consume out of CB compared to other income for different
commodity groups. Unlike earlier research, we model the whole of
household (nonhousing) spending--both child-assignable goods as well as
those that are adult-assignable and those that are not assignable at all
(food, and all other nonhousing expenditure (24)). Identification relies
on the sizeable real variation in CB over time--at least part of which
is discontinuous arising from reforms. Because we exploit only time
series CB variation, we present estimates in the body of the paper based
on samples of households that contain only one child. We assume that
expenditure on good i by household h is given by [e.sub.ih] = [f.sub.i]
([X.sub.h], [CB.sub.h]) + [Z.sub.h] [[beta].sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.ih]
where [x.sub.h] is household h's other income (25) (defined as
total expenditure minus CB), [Z.sub.h] is vector of exogenous
characteristics such as age and age squared of the household head, dummy variables to control for having a child aged 0-4 and 5-10 (relative to
11-15), region to control for regional differences in spending, and a
linear trend (26) and a vector of month dummies to capture seasonal
variations in spending, and [[epsilon].sub.ih] captures the unobservable
determinants of spending patterns. (27)
Because each of the expenditure equations contains the same
explanatory variables we estimate the system using the usual Seemingly
Unrelated Regression method to allow us to test cross equation
restrictions. We impose adding up in the usual manner of omitting one
arbitrary equation. We omit all other expenditure apart from the
assignable ones (male, female, and child clothing, alcohol, and tobacco)
and food so just six equations are reported.
In our parametric analysis discussed later, we further assume that
[f.sub.i]([x.sub.h], [CB.sub.h]) is linear and additively separable.
Linearity here is unlikely to be important--we are estimating a local
approximation around the mean of total expenditure and the effect of CB
is, itself, small variation around that mean. The specification follows
earlier research by Kooreman (2000) and Edmonds (2002) who estimate
simple specifications where expenditure on each good is assumed to be a
linear function of CB and of total expenditure less CB. To ensure that
our results are as robust as possible we select relatively homogenous samples to minimize the importance of Z. Our objective is to test
whether [f.sub.i]([x.sub.h], [CB.sub.h]) is such that child benefit has
the same effects on expenditures as total expenditure CB does--we refer
below to this latter effect as the Engel curve slope. (28) We estimate
separate systems for couples and lone parents. (29) We are particularly
interested in this distinction for two reasons. Firstly, the single
parents sample is immune from the problem that there may be an
intra-household pooling issue which might cause CB, which is given to
mothers, to have different effects from other sources of income because,
in the case of lone mothers, all sources of income are at the disposal
of the mother. Secondly, if underinvestment in child quality arises from
each parent free-riding on the other, then this would be reflected in
the behavior of couples and not in that of lone mothers.
A. Benchmark Results
The benchmark results are shown in Table 3, which provides
estimates using the couples and lone parents data for those with one
child aged under 16, (30) who are not on welfare. (31) The assignable
goods equations and the food equation are presented (the residual
spending equation is not presented and the estimates are independent of
the excluded equation). The coefficients show the effect of 1 [pounds
sterling] of CB and of other income on spending on each good. The key
result here is that it is alcohol spending that changes when CB changes
with a marginal propensity of 0.49 for couples (0.21 for single
parents)--much larger than the marginal propensity to spend on alcohol
from other income. For lone mothers we find that there is a significant
effect (0.71) on adult women's clothing. In the case of couples the
CB effect on alcohol (and for lone parents the effect of CB on
mother's clothing) is more than ten times larger than the Engel
curve slope. The [chi square] and p-statistics test for the restriction
that marginal propensity to spend out of CB income is the same as that
out of other income (defined as total expenditure minus CB). The
restriction that the marginal propensities to spend out of CB and other
income are the same is rejected for alcohol in the couples sample, and
for women's clothing in the lone parent sample. The overall [chi
square] and p values test the restrictions, across all goods, that the
effects of CB and other expenditure are the same. We strongly reject
this restriction for couples although the value for lone parents is not
quite significant. (32)
B. Robustness of Benchmark Results
Infrequency of purchase is clearly an issue in short-survey
datasets. This gives rise to a measurement error problem that would lead
to biased estimates. Keen (1986) shows that this can be resolved by
instrumenting total expenditure, and here we use total household income
as an instrument. Moreover, alcohol is well known to be under-reported
in survey data. Because alcohol is a component of total expenditure then
this would normally give rise to the other income coefficient being
biased toward zero. Under-reporting of spending on any good induces
nonclassical measurement error in total expenditure and, because of
adding up it seems likely that bias will affect all equations. There do
not appear to be any analytical results of the effects of this sort of
measurement issue in the literature and there are no strong a priori grounds for thinking the bias should be systematically in one direction.
(33)
The results are reported in Table 4. In comparison with Table 3
there are some changes in magnitude but there is no change in the
pattern or significance of results. In Table 5, we re-estimate using
Tobit to allow for the zeroes in the expenditures. There is no change,
relative to Table 3, for couples but for lone parents the result for
women's clothing becomes insignificant while alcohol becomes larger
and significant. Thus, it seems unlikely that our results are driven by
measurement error. If anything, our instrumental variable and Tobit
results strengthen our conclusion from Table 3.
The identification of the CB coefficients in Table 3 derives
entirely from the time series variation. Although the real value of CB
does not exhibit a time trend (and, in any event our modeling includes
both a linear trend and a set of month controls), we first test for the
robustness of the results in Table 3 by re-estimating over the
1980's data (1980-1989) separately from the 1990's (1990-2000)
data. These results are presented in Table 6 for the 1980's and the
1990's separately. The results in Table 3 for the pooled data over
the whole period are confirmed--with alcohol being the source of
rejection for couples--men's clothing in the latter period, and
women's clothing being the problem for lone mothers but only in the
1990's. In Table 7, we re-estimate for subsamples of mothers with
different levels of education: left school at 16 (the minimum), at
17/18, or 19+. Our conclusion remains: couples reject through alcohol,
whereas lone mothers reject through mother's clothing.
Table 8a and 8b divides the samples into the top, middle, and
bottom thirds of the respective income (total expenditure) distributions
because one might be concerned that Engel curves are nonlinear. Again
the headline results are broadly confirmed: all but the bottom third of
couples significantly reject because of alcohol; while the top third of
the lone mothers reject because of women's clothing. Even for the
bottom third the alcohol and women's clothing coefficients on CB
are much larger than the respective other income coefficients, albeit
not significant.
Table 9 replicates Table 3 but uses only the data for children
under 11. We do this in case the benchmark results are contaminated by
the possibility that parents may be wearing child clothing. (34) The
strong results for couples remain although the precision of the lone
mothers sample falls sufficiently that the effects become insignificant.
Nevertheless, the sizes of the coefficients for lone mothers are
comparable with Table 3.
C. Anticipated and Unanticipated Variation
Despite the weight of evidence here that suggests that variations
in CB are reflected in adult-assignable, and not in spending on
child-assignable, goods it would be inappropriate to conclude that the
lack of equivalence between CB and other income implies that parents put
less weight on the welfare of their children than on their own so that,
at the margin, they favor expenditure on adult goods. Rather, an
alternative explanation would be that parents may place so much weight
on the welfare of their children that they fully insure them against
income variations so that, at least unanticipated, variation in incomes
does not affect spending on the children.
Suppose the simplest case where all goods are exclusive to either
adults or children and the utility function of the altruistic parent is
defined as [V.sub.a] (y - x) + [delta][V.sub.c] (x + b) where [delta]
> 0 indicates altruism, y is the household income (assumed to be the
adult's (a)), x is the transfer from parent to child (c), b is a
transfer from the government to the child. Differentiating with respect
to x shows that the equilibrium transfer to the child is such that
[[lambda].sub.a] = [delta][[lambda].sub.a] (for an interior optimum
where some positive transfer takes place), where the [lambda]'s are
the respective marginal utilities of income. The optimal transfer,
[x.sup.*], is such that it would be the same if the welfare transfer, b,
had been made to the parent rather than the child. (35) In the case
where b is uncertain it is useful to consider a simple benchmark case of
[V.sub.a] and [V.sub.c] being CRRA functions of y - x and x + b,
respectively. In this case, the 35. See Bergstrom (1989) for discussion
of Becker's rotten kid theorem. optimality property allows us to
solve for x in terms of b. As before, the optimal [x.sup.*] depends on
the value of b, but the size of the effect of b on x now depends on the
ratio of the degrees of relative risk aversions and the extent of
altruism. Only if the parents are sufficiently risk averse with respect
to the child's consumption, relative to their own consumption, and
altruism is sufficiently large, will x vary inversely with b. In
general, parents will not fully insure their children unless they
themselves are risk neutral.
There is some qualitative evidence that suggests that parents
(especially mothers) are likely to "go without" to protect
spending on their children in the face of adverse shocks. (36) To
investigate this issue we assume that households form static
expectations of real CB. That is, we assume that households expect the
government to reinstate the real level of CB to the value at the
previous uprating date 1 year ago by an appropriate increase in the
nominal CB. We assume that, between uprating dates, households form
rational expectations about the price level and so anticipated real CB
falls according to the actual inflation rate. That is, we assume that
households assume that CB will be indexed in line with inflation because
the last increase--and so have static expectations of policymakers.
Thus, we decompose real child benefit according to the following
formula:
[CB.sup.a.sub.ym] = [CB.sub.y - 12]/([P.sub.y-m]/[P.sub.y-12])
where [CB.sup.a.sub.ym] is the level of child benefit that would be
anticipated in year y some m months after the uprating, [CB.sub.y-12] is
the nominal value of CB at the last uprating and
[P.sub.y-m]/[P.sub.y-12] is the inflation adjustment over the last m
months since the uprating. This captures the variation in CB arising
from the inflation that has occurred since the last uprating. The
difference between actual CB and anticipated CB captures the change in
CB that has occurred because of the nominal uprating that last
occurred--which we assume is unpredictable and call unantici pated CB,
[CB.sup.a.sub.ym]. We allow for there to be a differential effect of
these two components by writing our Engel curves as
[e.sub.ih] = [[alpha].sub.i][CB.sup.a] + [[gamma].sub.i][CB.sup.u]
+ [[eta].sub.i][M.sup.h] + [Z.sub.h][[beta].sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.ih]
where M is other expenditure which we assume is driven by long-run
differences between households arising from skills differences. The
results are reported in Table 10 in the case where we assume that
expectations of inflation are formed rationally.
The anticipated CB effects are generally badly determined and
therefore are not significantly different from the coefficients on other
expenditure. This is reassuring: nominal CB shocks associated with the
annual changes only have a temporary impact on spending on adult goods.
Thereafter, the CB becomes part of permanent income and is spent like
other permanent components of income. However, the unanticipated CB
effects are consistent with our earlier results and with the
interpretation that parents do insure their children against shocks so
that unanticipated CB is spent disproportionately on adult goods. For
couples, spending on alcohol out of unanticipated CB is significantly
different from spending out of other income. For lone parents the same
is true for both alcohol and women's clothing. The F- and
p-statistics show that in the couples' sample the restriction that
the marginal propensity to consume out of unanticipated CB is the same
as that out of other income jointly for all equations is strongly
rejected. However, the same restrictions cannot be rejected in the lone
parent sample because of a smaller sample size and a lack of precision.
V. CONCLUSIONS
Our analysis finds that unanticipated variation in CB that is
driven by policy induced changes in its real value is disproportionately
spent on adult-assignable goods. The results for couples suggest that,
at the margin, as much as a half of unanticipated changes in CB is spent
on alcohol. The results for lone parents are less strong but nonetheless
still apparent. These findings contrast with those of Kooreman (2000),
which exploits variation in Dutch CB, and of Edmonds (2002), based on
data from Slovenia. However, this earlier work made no distinction
between anticipated and unanticipated variation in CB.
A weakness of this line of research is that it is unclear what
inferences can be drawn from an equivalence (or lack of it) between CB
and other income. One might be tempted to conclude that CB is treated
differently because there is something different about it. For example,
CB is usually given to the mother so that a lack of equivalence may
suggest imperfect pooling of household incomes. However, our results are
also true for lone parents where there is no intra-household
distributional issue, so this cannot account for all of this lack of
equivalence. It is true that the effect for lone parents is less
pronounced, the alcohol coefficient for CB is around half the size as in
the couples samples, and this is consistent with the idea that there is
some free-tiding between partners which does not occur in single parent
households. A second issue might be that real CB variation tracks the
business cycle implying that our results are attributable to cyclical effects in spending. However, we find no such cyclical effects in the
spending patterns of households without children and there is little
reason to expect households with children to differ in this respect.
Finally, a simple but important innovation in this work has been to
distinguish between anticipated and unanticipated variation in CB. We
find that it is unanticipated CB variation that is reflected in
adult-assignable good expenditure suggesting that parents are successful
in providing at least some insurance for their children. This finding
suggests a high degree of altruism on the part of parents. The
implication is that CB may simply finance spending on children that
would have otherwise occurred.
ABBREVIATIONS
CB: Child Benefit
CRRA: Constant Relative Risk Aversion
CTC: Child Tax Credit
DWP: Department of Work and Pensions
FES: Family Expenditure Survey
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
GNP: Gross National Product
JSA: Job Seeker's Allowance
IS: Income Support
OPB: One Parent Benefit
TANF: Temporary Assistance for Needy Families
WFTC: Working Families' Tax Credit
REFERENCES
Adam, S., and M. Brewer. Supporting Families: The Financial Costs
and Benefits of Children since 1975. York, UK: Joseph Rowntree Foundation, Policy Press, 2004.
Becker, G. S., and N. Tomes. "Human Capital and the Rise and
Fall of Families." Journal of Labor Economics, 4, 1986, S1-S39.
Bergstrom, T. C. "A Fresh Look at the Rotten Kid Theorem--And
Other Household Mysteries." Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1989,
1138-59.
Bingley, P., and I. Walker. 1997, "There's No Such Thing
as a Free Lunch: Evidence of Altruism from In-kind Transfers to
Children." IFS Working Paper 97/07.
Blundell. R. W., and I. Walker. "A Lifecycle Consistent Model
of Family Labour Supply." Review of Economic Studies, 53, 1986,
539-58.
Blundell, R. W., P. Pashardes, and G. Weber. "What Do We Learn
About Consumer Demand Patterns from Micro Data?" American Economic
Review, 83, 1983. 570-659.
Bourguinon, F, M. Browning, P.A. Chiappori, and V. Lechene.
"Intra Household Allocation of Consumption: A Model and Some
Evidence from French Data." Annales d'Economie et
Statistiques, 29, 1993, 137-56.
Bradbury, B. "Consumption and Within-Household Income
Distribution: Outcomes for an Australian Natural Experiment."
Economic Studies, 50(3), 2005, 501-540.
Bradshaw, J., and N. Finch. "A Comparison of Child Benefit
Packages in 22 Countries." Department of Work and Pensions Research
Report 174, 2002. Accessed November 13, 2010.
http://research.dwp.gov.uk/asd/ asd5/rrep174.pdf.
Brewer, M. "The New Tax Credits," IFS Briefing Note 35,
2003.
Burman, L. E., and L. Wheaton. "Who Gets the Child Tax
Credit?" Washington, DC: Urban Institute, 2005.
http://www.urban.org/url.cfm?ID=411232.
Edmonds, E. V. "Reconsidering the Labeling Effects of Child
Benefits: Evidence from a Transitional Economy."
Economics Letters, 76, 2002, 303-09.
Farrell, C., and W. O'Connor. "Low-Income Families and
Household Spending." Department of Work and Pensions, Research
Report 192, 2003.
Greener, K., and R. Cracknell. "Child Benefit." House of
Commons Research Paper 98/79, 1998.
Gregg, P., J. Waldfogel, and E. Washbrook. "That's the
Way the Money Goes: Expenditure Patterns as Real Incomes Rise for the
Poorest Families with Children," in A More Equal Society? edited by
J. Hills and K. Stewart. York, UK: Joseph Rowntree Foundation, 2004.
Hotchkiss, J. L. "Do Husbands and Wives Pool Their
Resources?" Journal of Human Resources, 40, 2005, 519-31.
Jacoby, H. "Is There an Intrahousehold "Flypaper
Effect"? Evidence from a School Feeding Program." Economic
Journal, 112, 2002, 196-221.
Keen, M. "Zero Expenditures and the Estimation of Engel
Curves." Journal of Applied Econometrics, l, 1986, 277-86.
Kooreman, P. "The Labeling Effect of a Child Benefit
System." American Economic Review, 90, 2000, 571-83.
Lundberg, S., R. A. Pollak, and T. J. Wales. "Do Husbands and
Wives Pool Their Resources?" Journal of Human Resources, 32, 1997,
463-80.
Micklewright, J. "Child Poverty in English-Speaking Countries." IZA Working Paper 1113, 2004.
Middleton, S., K. Ashworth, and I. Braithwaite. Small Fortunes.
York, UK: Joseph Rowntree Foundation, 1997.
Phipps, S. A., and P. S. Burton. "What's Mine is Yours?
The Influence of Male and Female Incomes on Patterns of Household
Expenditure." Economica, 65, 1998, 599-613.
Schluter, C., and J. Wahba. "Are Poor Parents Altruistic?:
Evidence from Mexico." Journal of Population Economics, 23, 2008,
1153-74.
Tanner, S. "How Much do Consumers Spend? Comparing the FES and
National Accounts," in How Reliable Is the Family Expenditure
Survey: Trends in Incomes and Expenditures, edited by J. Banks and P.
Johnson. London: IFS, 1998.
Thaler, R. "Savings, Fungability and Mental Accounts."
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4, 1990, 193-205.
UNICEF. Poverty Reduction Begins with Children. New York: UN, 2000.
Ward-Batts, J. "Out of the Wallet and Into the Purse: Modeling
Family Expenditures to Test Income Pooling." Journal of Human
Resources, 43, 325-51.
(1.) See Burman and Wheaton (2005).
(2.) See Bradshaw and Finch (2002) for details of 22 countries.
(3.) For international comparisons, see Micklewright (2004) and
UNICEF (2000).
(4.) Our analysis is one of a complete demand system where we
impose the adding up condition. Thus there is an excluded category of
expenditure whose coefficients are implicit.
(5.) Child poverty is measured by counting the number of children
in households whose incomes fall below 60% of the median of the overall
household income distribution so that it is a relative measure. Thus, a
reform that increases the incomes of households with children through CB
and leaves other households unaffected must decrease child poverty even
though it is not a means-tested transfer. The UK finance minister, then
Gordon Brown, described child poverty as "a scar on the soul of
Britain" in a speech at the 1999 SureStart Conference. He went on
to promise that increases in CB under the Labour government were part of
"immediate and direct action" to provide "cash help to
lift children out of poverty".
(6.) Income Support (IS) and Job Seekers' Allowance (JSA), the
out-of-work welfare programs (mainly for poor lone parents, the
disabled, and the unemployed), have also benefited from increasingly
generous additions for dependent children, as has Working Families'
Tax Credit (WFTC), the main in-work welfare program.
(7.) Prior to 2007 there was a higher rate of CB paid to lone
parents, called One Parent Benefit (OPB). This was fixed in nominal
terms in 2000 and inflation between 2000 and 2007 closed the
differential.
(8.) WFTC and Children's Tax Credit has recently been replaced
by Working Tax Credit (WTC) and CTC but they broadly retain their
earlier structure (Brewer 2003). In contrast to the extensive cash
support for children in the United Kingdom and the relative unimportance
of means-testing, the United States, until recently, relied heavily on
in-kind transfers such as food stamps, targeted nutrition schemes such
as the school breakfast program, the health care cover provided by
MedicAid, and Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) which
typically provides extensive childcare support but rather little
explicit cash. Indeed, the cash that is provided is time limited.
(9.) See Adam and Brewer (2004) for a review of the development of
all UK child-related benefits including CB.
(10.) Remember that our result is for lone mothers so has nothing
to do with intra-household distributional issues as in Lundberg, Pollak,
and Wales (1997).
(11.) See Thaler (1990) for why this phenomenon might exist and why
it leads to differences in marginal propensities to consume out of
different forms of income.
(12.) Thus. the paper places some weight on the presumption that
this 'wallet-to-purse'" transfer had an equal effect on
spending patterns across households with different aged children. Since
maternal market labor supply may be affected by the intra-housebold
transfer this seems unlikely.
(13.) Jacoby (2002) investigates in-kind (food) transfers targeted
on children and finds no evidence of a "flypaper" effect of
such transfers increasing the calorific intake of the children. Bingley
and Walker (1997) consider the effects of giving food and milk to
children on household spending patterns--we find significant effects on
household milk spending. Schluter and Wahba (2008) examine the effects
on household spending patterns of the Mexican Progressa experiment
whereby schooling subsidies were randomly assigned. They show
significant effects of the subsidy on child clothing expenditure which
they interpret as altruistic behavior. However. the subsidy is
conditional on attending schools and it seems likely that this
conditionality affects how the money is spent--for example, attending
school may itself have an impact on clothing needs.
(14.) Private correspondence with DWP confirms that this also
applies to the supplement to CB that is paid to lone parents--OPB.
(15.) However, analyses of the microdata by Ward-Baits (20001 and
Hotchkiss (2005) cast doubt on the original conclusions. Limited studies
exist elsewhere: for example, Bradbury (2004) analyzes a similar natural
experiment in Australia and finds no effect of the redistribution. Here
we abstract from this issue entirely by concentrating on the spending
patterns of single parent households. We intend to revisit the
intra-household distributional issue that Lundberg et al. investigated
because there is significant variation in the level of CB paid to
mothers in couples that could be very informative.
(16.) See Phipps and Burton (1998) and Bourguignon et al. (1993),
for example. However, these studies simply examine whether spending
patterns are affected by the individual composition of household income
without regard to the potential endogeneity of that composition.
(17.) Our data record who receives the CB in the household: the
proportion of two-parent households where the mother is the recipient is
99.1%.
(18.) More recently Gregg. Waldfogel, and Washbrook (2004) have
described how patterns of spending have changed between 1996/97 and
2000/01, for low income households relative to other households as their
relative disposable incomes varied (for a variety of reasons, not just
CB). They find that spending on alcohol and tobacco for low income
households with children relative to those with higher income has
fallen, and that spending on toys, games, and clothing and footwear has
risen. However, their analysis takes no account of changing composition
of the low income group relative to the rest--which will have been
dramatic because of the large change in in-work welfare entitlements
that occurred in 1999, the introduction of the National Minimum Wage in
1999, and the unfolding New Deals, especially for lone parents, all of
which will have contributed to a reduction in worklessness among this
low income group of parents. Moreover, there will have been cyclical
effects that have more pronounced effects on the bottom of the
distribution than the rest.
(19.) See Greener and Cracknell (1998) for the historical
background and development of CB in the United Kingdom.
(20.) Lone parents who were already in receipt of OPB prior to 1997
were allowed to retain it.
(21.) Spending data at the individual level is not available in the
public use files. However, since 1995 the data has separately recorded
the expenditure of all children aged 7-15.
(22.) See Tanner (1998) for an analysis of the reliability of FES
expenditure data. The deficiency in the alcohol and tobacco categories
is thought to be largely associated with differential response rates of
smokers and drinkers and not because of under-recording by respondents.
We find no evidence that under-recording is correlated with the real
variation in CB.
(23.) We drop all households where the youngest child is 16 and
over because the FES treats the clothing of children aged 16 and over as
adult clothing. We also exclude multiple benefit unit households so that
our sample consists of "nuclear" families only.
(24.) This latter is the excluded category. Homogeneity of demands
would allow us to recover the parameters of this excluded category form
the parameters estimated assuming that adding-up holds. The estimates
are guaranteed to be independent of which commodity forms the excluded
category.
(25.) We use total expenditure (minus CB) as our explanatory
variable rather than income. This is to ensure consistency with an
intertemporally separable lifecycle maximizing model (Blundell and
Walker, 1986). Results using total (net of tax and welfare) income
(minus CB) are essentially the same and are available on request.
(26.) We included a cubic spline in month of survey to capture
smooth changes in tastes but were able to reject this in favor of a
simple linear trend.
(27.) Estimates which include relative prices are available on
request. We do not control for relative prices here because when we
tested for the time series correlation between CB and monthly relative
prices we found an insignificant partial correlation of only 0.088.
Including relative prices does not affect our estimates in any way apart
from slightly increasing their precision.
(28.) We experimented with nonlinear Engel curves. For example, we
found that when we entered CB and other expenditure quadratically the
marginal effects, evaluated at the means, were essentially unchanged. In
any event we do go on to provide estimates for subsets of the data
broken down by income and find that our main results carry over to each
subset of the income distribution.
(29.) We refrain from using childless households in the analysis
because they are uninformative about the question at hand. They clearly
cannot be used to estimate the effect of CB. Moreover, while they can be
used to estimate the Engel curve slope for adult goods, they cannot he
used to estimate the Engel curve slopes for child-assignable goods since
there is no such expenditure in childless households. Although they can
be used to estimate the Engel curve slopes for adult-assignable goods,
such estimates would not be comparable with the estimates for household
with children since "adding up" (i.e., homogeneity of degree
zero) is imposed across a smaller set of goods.
(30.) Results restricted to children under 11 are almost identical.
(31.) We investigated the sensitivity to including welfare
recipients in the samples. For welfare recipients CB counts as income
when computing other welfare payments to households. Thus, we do not
expect any effect of CB in such households and this is, indeed, what we
do find.
(32.) Clearly part of the variation in real CB arises because of
differential inflation rates across years. There is a possibility that
the differential effect on spending patterns is due to business cycle
effects that are correlated with inflation and not adequately controlled
in the model by the inclusion of total expenditure. If the variation in
the expenditures of households with children was being affected by the
business cycle rather than by real CB variation then we would expect the
same to be true of households without children. We investigated this by
looking at the correlation matrix between expenditures and inflation for
both singles and couples without children. We found no correlation.
Thus. we feel that our results are not contaminated by omitted business
cycle effects.
(33.) This instrument is commonly used in demand system estimation
(Blundell, Pashardes, and Weber, 1993). The absence of any analytical
results of the effects of this sort of measurement issue in the
literature prompted us to simulate some data with varying degrees of
under-recording and our consequent estimates (not shown here but
available from the authors upon request) suggest that the basic findings
still hold, even with substantial degrees of under-reporting (e.g., with
up to half of households under-reporting true alcohol expenditure by 50%
on average).
(34.) Although there is a sales tax distinction between adult and
child clothing that is defined by sizes, the FES clothing data is
self-reported as child or adult.
(36.) Two recent examples of such work are Middleton, Ashworth, and
Braithwaite (1997) and Farreli and O'Connor (2003). However. the
datasets used in these studies are small and formal hypothesis tests are
not conducted. Indeed, such qualitative research makes no attempt to
distinguish between anticipated and unanticipated variation in income in
any very formal way. Thus. the work here complements that qualitative
research.
Online Early publication December 15, 2010
LAURA BLOW, IAN WALKER and YU ZHU *
* This research was funded by Her Majesty's Treasury's
Evidence Based Policy Fund with the support of the Department for
Education and Skills, Department of Work and Pensions, Department of
Culture, Media and Sports, and the Inland Revenue. The work was
completed while Walker was a visiting fellow at Princeton University,
funded by the Leverhulme Trust. Material from the Family Expenditure
Survey is Crown Copyright and has been made available by the Office of
National Statistics through the Economic and Social Research
Council's Data Archive at the University of Essex. The data is used
with the permission of Her Majesty's Stationery Office but can be
made available to other researchers under conditions imposed by the
Archive. We are grateful for comments from an anonymous referee, Mike
Brewer at the Institute for Fiscal Studies, Mike Bielby, Ilona Blue, and
Mario Pisani of the Inland Revenue. Andrew Oswald at Warwick, and
seminar participants at the Department for Education and Skills, the
Department of Work and Pensions, the University of Warwick, the
University of Kent, the Cardiff Business School, and Queen Mary and
Westfield College of the University of London. The opinions expressed in
this paper are those of the authors.
Blow: Senior Research Economist, Institute for Fiscal Studies,
London, UK. Phone +44-20 7291 4800, Fax +44-20 7323 4780, E-mail
l.blow@ifs.org.uk
Walker: Professor, Lancaster University Management School,
Lancaster, UK. E-mail ian.walker@lancaster.ac.uk
Zhu: Senior Lecturer, School of Economics, University of Kent,
Canterbury, Kent, UK. Phone +44-1227 827438, Fax +44-1227 827850, E-mail
yz5@kent.ac.uk
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00348.x
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics: Household Types (Numbers and Proportions)
1 Child
Married Lone All
Not on Welfare 8,575 744 9,319
0.87# 0.25# 0.73#
On Out-of-Work Welfare 948 1,836 2,784
0.10# 0.63# 0.22#
On In-Work Welfare 288 340 628
0.03# 0.12# 0.05#
Total 9,811 2,920 12,731
2 Children
Married Lone All
Not on Welfare 12,967 570 13,537
0.88# 0.25# 0.80#
On Out-of-Work Welfare 1,255 1,453 2,708
0.09# 0.65# 0.16#
On In-Work Welfare 441 216 657
0.03# 0.10# 0.04#
Total 14,663 2,239 16,902
3+ Children
Married Lone All Total
Not on Welfare 4,502 165 4,667 27,523
0.76# 0.16# 0.67# 0.75#
On Out-of-Work Welfare 1,000 783 1,783 7,275
0.17# 0.76# 0.26# 0.20#
On In-Work Welfare 422 81 503 1,788
0.07# 0.08# 0.07# 0.05#
Total 5,924 1,029 6,953 36,586
Note: Figures in italics are column proportions.
Note: Figures indicated with # are column proportions.
TABLE 2
Summary Statistics: Expenditure Patterns for Households with 1
Child, Weekly Amounts ([pounds sterling]) and Standard Deviations
Couples
Not on On Out-of-Work
Welfare Welfare
Child Clothing Expenditure 7.72 4.51
(12.49) (8.90)
Positive exp 61.94 52.95
Expenditure|exp > 0 12.46 8.52
(13.89) (10.75)
Women's Clothing Expenditure 10.24 4.25
(19.08) (10.09)
% Positive exp 61.17 41.98
Expenditure|exp > 0 16.75 10.12
(22.06) (13.536)
Men's Clothing Expenditure 6.64 3.08
(18.34) (8.88)
% Positive exp 36.00 24.68
Expenditure|exp > 0 18.45 12.5
(26.77) (14.24)
Food Expenditure 68.06 46.51
(27.83) (18.69)
% Positive exp 99.97 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 68.08 46.51
(27.81) (18.69)
Alcohol Expenditure 14.63 9.03
(19.02) (14.05)
% Positive exp 83.78 65.4
Expenditure|exp > 0 17.47 13.81
(19.55) (18.69)
Tobacco Expenditure 7.15 12.06
(10.86) (11.8)
% Positive exp 46.33 73.52
Expenditure|exp > 0 15.43 16.41
(11.26) (10.87)
Child Benefit Expenditure 11.38 11.44
(1.91) (1.60)
% Positive exp 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 11.38 11.44
(1.91) (1.60)
All Other Expenditure 298.30 157.03
Expenditure (181.7) (96.07)
% Positive 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 298.30 157.03
(181.7) (96.07)
Household Income Expenditure 395.59 213.77
(239.5) (133.20)
% Positive exp 99.93 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 395.92 213.77
(239.32) (133.2)
No Obs 8,575 948
Couples
On In-Work
Welfare Total
Child Clothing Expenditure 5.23 7.34
(8.49) (12.13)
Positive exp 56.25 60.90
Expenditure|exp > 0 9.29 12.05
(9.51) (13.60)
Women's Clothing Expenditure 4.59 9.50
(8.62) (18.28)
% Positive exp 45.83 58.86
Expenditure|exp > 0 10.02 16.14
(10.40) (21.46)
Men's Clothing Expenditure 3.38 6.20
(8.93) (17.47)
% Positive exp 29.86 34.73
Expenditure|exp > 0 11.31 17.86
(12.36) (25.90)
Food Expenditure 52.70 65.52
(22.51) (27.77)
% Positive exp 100.00 99.97
Expenditure|exp > 0 52.70 65.84
(22.51) (27.75)
Alcohol Expenditure 9.51 13.94
(14.28) (18.56)
% Positive exp 71.88 81.65
Expenditure|exp > 0 13.23 17.07
(15.32) (19.20)
Tobacco Expenditure 10.98 7.74
(12.23) (11.11)
% Positive exp 64.24 49.49
Expenditure|exp > 0 17.10 15.64
(11.33) (11.21)
Child Benefit Expenditure 12.16 11.41
(1.93) (1.89)
% Positive exp 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 12.16 11.41
(1.93) (1.89)
All Other Expenditure 188.71 281.43
Expenditure (106.0) (179.1)
% Positive 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 188.71 281.43
(106.0) (179.1)
Household Income Expenditure 245.47 373.62
(123.9) (235.9)
% Positive exp 100.00 99.94
Expenditure|exp > 0 245.47 373.89
(123.9) (235.81)
No Obs 288 9,811
Lone Parents
Not on On Out-of-Work
Welfare Welfare
Child Clothing Expenditure 9.16 4.81
(15.78) (8.35)
Positive exp 55.91 53.65
Expenditure|exp > 0 16.38 8.97
(18.09) (9.63)
Women's Clothing Expenditure 11.65 4.01
(23.75) (8.80)
% Positive exp 58.60 42.76
Expenditure|exp > 0 19.88 8.39
(28.28) (11.44)
Men's Clothing Expenditure 1.85 0.59
(8.91) (4.75)
% Positive exp 11.69 5.99
Expenditure|exp > 0 15.78 9.90
(21.51) (16.91)
Food Expenditure 46.93 30.34
(20.95) (13.96)
% Positive exp 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 46.93 30.34
(20.95) (13.96)
Alcohol Expenditure 6.54 2.61
(9.96) (5.14)
% Positive exp 66.94 43.74
Expenditure|exp > 0 9.78 5.96
(10.80) (6.36)
Tobacco Expenditure 4.61 6.67
(7.42) (7.61)
% Positive exp 37.77 60.29
Expenditure|exp > 0 12.22 11.07
(7.27) (6.89)
Child Benefit Expenditure 15.91 14.93
(3.35) (3.55)
% Positive exp 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 15.91 14.93
(3.35) (3.55)
All Other Expenditure 205.34 90.52
Expenditure (158.3) (54.47)
% Positive 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 205.34 90.52
(158.3) (54.47)
Household Income Expenditure 254.97 117.09
(208.9) (55.65)
% Positive exp 99.87 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 255.32 117.09
(208.92) (55.65)
No Obs 744 1,836
Lone Parents
On In-Work
Welfare Total
Child Clothing Expenditure 6.60 6.13
(10.47) (11.11)
Positive exp 55.59 54.45
Expenditure|exp > 0 11.88 11.25
(11.60) (13.00)
Women's Clothing Expenditure 7.34 6.35
(15.48) (15.20)
% Positive exp 54.12 48.12
Expenditure|exp > 0 13.57 13.19
(18.95) (19.74)
Men's Clothing Expenditure 0.99 (1.96
(3.71) (6.02)
% Positive exp 11.47 8.08
Expenditure|exp > 0 8.62 11.86
(7.43) (17.89)
Food Expenditure 38.53 35.52
(16.39) (17.79)
% Positive exp 99.71 99.87
Expenditure|exp > 0 38.64 35.53
(16.28) (17.78)
Alcohol Expenditure 4.80 3.86
(7.83) (7.21)
% Positive exp 59.12 51.44
Expenditure|exp > 0 8.12 7.51
(8.76) (8.57)
Tobacco Expenditure 6.15 6.09
(7.84) (7.64)
% Positive exp 52.35 53.63
Expenditure|exp > 0 11.75 11.35
(7.18) (7.00)
Child Benefit Expenditure 17.12 15.44
(2.51) (3.47)
% Positive exp 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 17.12 15.44
(2.51) (3.47)
All Other Expenditure 136.47 125.12
Expenditure (72.59) (106.1)
% Positive 100.00 100.00
Expenditure|exp > 0 136.47 125.12
(72.59) (106.1)
Household Income Expenditure 178.79 159.41
(55.71) (130.1)
% Positive exp 100.00 99.97
Expenditure|exp > 0 178.79 159.46
(55.71) (130.08)
No Obs 340 2,920
TABLE 3
Estimated Effects of 1 [pounds sterling] of CB and 1 [pounds
sterling] of Other Income on Spending on Each Good: Parents with
One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Explanatory Variables Child Women's Men's
Clothing Clothing Clothing
Couples, N = 8.575
CB 0.014 0.213 0.196
(0.2) (1.9) (1.8)
Other Expenditure 0.017 0.039 0.028
(22.8) (34.7) (24.9)
[chi square] (CB=Other exp) 0.00 2.44 2.30
p .97 .12 .13
Overall [chi square] (6) = 26.87
p = .0002#
Lone Parents, N = 744
CB 0.154 0.706# 0.074
(0.9) (2.9) (0.8)
Other Expenditure 0.025 0.064 0.007
(6.6) (12.4) (3.1)
[chi square] (CB=Other exp) 0.54 7.11# 0.47
p .46 .01# .49
Overall [chi square] (6) = 11.81
p = .0664
Explanatory Variables
Food Alcohol Tobacco
Couples, N = 8.575
CB -0.188 0.491# -0.005
(1.3) (4.3) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.075 0.033 0.000
(51.8) (28.9) (0.6)
[chi square] (CB=Other exp) 3.32 16.47# 0.01
p .07 .00# .94
Overall [chi square] (6) = 26.87
p = .0002#
Lone Parents, N = 744
CB -0.096 0.212 0.009
(0.5) (2.1) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.067 0.019 0.001
(16.0) (8.6) (0.4)
[chi square] (CB=Other exp) 0.68 3.51 0.01
p .41 .06 .92
Overall [chi square] (6) = 11.81
p = .0664
Notes: Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. Other
explanatory variables are: a linear trend; month, region, and
dummy variables for whether the child was aged 0-4, 5-10
(relative to I1-15); a quadratic in age of household head; and a
lone father dummy in the lone parent sample. The F statistic in
each equation is a test of whether the coefficient on CB and on
other income is equal, and the overall F statistic is a test that
all of the CB coefficients equal the corresponding other income
coefficients. Bold values indicate statistical significance at 5%
level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5% level.
TABLE 4
Instrumental Variable Estimates of Engel Curves: One Child Not on
Welfare, 1980-2000
Explanatory Variables Child Women's Men's
Clothing Clothing Clothing
Couples, N = 8,560
CB -0.011 0.152 0.158
(0.1) (1.3) (1.4)
Other Expenditure 0.006 0.014 0.008
(10.6) (15.9) (8.5)
[[chi square].sub.CB 0.05 1.38 1.72
= Other exp)]
p .83 .24 .19
Overall [chi square] (6) = 25.72
p = .0003#
Lone Parents, N = 738
CB 0.169 0.712# 0.076
(0.9) (2.7) (0.8)
Other Expenditure 0.006 0.023 0.002
(2.1) (5.6) (1.5)
[[chi square].sub.CB 0.81 6.95# 0.54
= Other exp)]
p .37 .01# .46
Overall [chi square] (6) = 12.52
p = .0513
Explanatory Variables Food Alcohol Tobacco
Couples, N = 8,560
CB -0.309# 0.434# 0.000
(2.0) (3.7) (0.0)
Other Expenditure 0.035 0.015 -0.003
(29.0) (16.3) (6.2)
[[chi square].sub.CB 4.74# 12.99# 0.00
= Other exp)]
p .03# .00# .96
Overall [chi square] (6) = 25.72
p = .0003#
Lone Parents, N = 738
CB -0.062 0.244# 0.013
(0.3) (2.3) (0.2)
Other Expenditure 0.028 0.008 -0.001
(7.9) (4.8) (0.7)
[[chi square].sub.CB 0.16 4.94# 0.03
= Other exp)]
p .69 .03# .86
Overall [chi square] (6) = 12.52
p = .0513
Notes: Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. Other
explanatory variables are: a linear trend; month, region, and
dummy variables for whether the child was aged 0-4, 5-10
(relative to 11-15); a quadratic in age of household head; and a
lone father dummy in the lone parent sample. Households with
negative other incomes are excluded. Bold values indicate
statistical significance at 5% level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5% level.
TABLE 5
Tobit Estimates of Engel Curves: One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Explanatory Variables Child Women's Men's
Clothing Clothing Clothing
Couples, N = 8.575
CB 0.014 0.275 0.174
(0.1) (1.6) (0.7)
Other Expenditure 0.024 0.053 0.057
(21.2) (32.1) (22.4)
[F.sub.(CB-Other exp)] 0.01 1.70 0.19
p .93 .19 .66
Lone Parents. N = 744
CB 0.152 0.673 0.678
(0.5) (1.8) (1.0)
Other Expenditure 0.039 0.085 0.031
(6.4) (10.9) (2.3)
[F.sub.(CB-Other exp)] 0.15 2.37 0.93
p .70 .12 .33
Explanatory Variables
Food Alcohol Tobacco
Couples, N = 8.575
CB -0.188 0.522# 0.020
(1.3) (4.0)# (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.075 0.038 -0.004
(51.8) (29.1) (2.5)
[F.sub.(CB-Other exp)] 3.31 13.89# 0.03
p .07 .00# .86
Lone Parents. N = 744
CB -0.094 0.421# 0.141
(0.5) (2.8) (0.7)
Other Expenditure 0.067 0.025 0.000
(16.0) (8.1) (0.0
[F.sub.(CB-Other exp)] 0.67 6.98# 0.45
p .41 .01# .50
Notes: Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. Other
explanatory variables are: a linear trend: month, region, and
dummy variables for whether the child was aged 0-4, 5-10
(relative to 11-15); a quadratic in age of household head: and a
lone father dummy in the lone parent sample. Bold values indicate
statistical significance at 5% level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5%
level.
TABLE 6
Engel Curves: Parents with One Child Not on Welfare: 1980-1989
and 1990-2000
Child Women's Men's
Explanatory Variables Clothing Clothing Clothing
Couples, N = 4,554 (1980-1989)
CB 0.019 -0.127 -0.311
(0.1) (0.6) (1.6)
Other Expenditure 0.017 0.045 0.033
(16.0 (26.1) (20.1)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.00 0.67 2.96
p .99 .41 .09
Overall [chi square](6) = 19.95
p = .0028#
Lone Parents, N = 325 (1980-1989)
CB 0.223 0.305 0.198
(0.8) (0.8) (1.0
Other Expenditure 0.030 0.058 0.014
(4.2) (6.2) (2.9)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.49 0.46 0.95
p .48 .50 .33
Overall [chi square](6) = 2.28
p = .89
Couples, N = 4,021 (1990-2000)
CB -0.045 0.265 0.456#
(0.4) (1.8) (3.0)#
Other Expenditure 0.017 0.036 0.024
(16.0 (23.6) (15.5)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.34 2.41 7.92#
p .56 .12 .00#
Overall [chi square](6) = 23.25
p = 0.0007#
Lone Parents, N = 419 (1990-2000)
CB 0.166 1.043# -0.038
(0.7) (3.2)# (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.022 0.066 0.003
(5.1) (10.8) (1.9)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.39 8.78# 0.19
p .53 .00# .67
Overall F, p [chi square](6) = 16.52
p = .0112#
Explanatory Variables Food Alcohol Tobacco
Couples, N = 4,554 (1980-1989)
CB -0.682# 0.607# -0.003
(2.7)# (2.6)# (0.0
Other Expenditure 0.076 0.045 0.002
(35.6) (23.0) (1.8)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 8.67 5.72# 0.00
p .00# .02# .97
Overall [chi square](6) = 19.95
p = .0028#
Lone Parents, N = 325 (1980-1989)
CB 0.080 0.094 -0.014
(0.3) (0.7) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.069 0.015 0.003
(9.8) (4.1) (0.9)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.00 0.33 0.02
p .97 .57 .89
Overall [chi square](6) = 2.28
p = .89
Couples, N = 4,021 (1990-2000)
CB 0.241 0.509# -0.054
(1.2) (3.9)# (0.6)
Other Expenditure 0.075 0.025 -0.002
(36.6) (19.0) (1.9)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.68 13.43# 0.33
p .41 .00# .56
Overall [chi square](6) = 23.25
p = 0.0007#
Lone Parents, N = 419 (1990-2000)
CB -0.333 0.337 0.045
(1.2) (2.2) (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.066 0.020 -0.001
(12.4) (7.3) (0.3)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 1.91 4.37# 0.15
p .17 .04# .69
Overall F, p [chi square](6) = 16.52
p = .0112#
Notes: Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. Other
explanatory variables are: a linear trend; month, region, and
dummy variables for whether the child was aged 0-4, 5-10
(relative to 11-15): a quadratic in age of household head: and a
lone father dummy in the lone parent sample. Bold values indicate
statistical significance at 5% level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5% level.
TABLE 7
Engel Curves and Maternal Education: 1980-2000
Child Women's Men's
Clothing Clothing Clothing
Mother Left School at 16: Couples, N = 5.271
CB 0.017 0.459# 0.590#
(0.2) (3.4) (4.6)
Other Expenditure 0.020 0.040 0.029
(18.2) (27.8) (21.1)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.00 9.65# 18.75#
p .98 .00# .00
Overall [chi square](6) = 32.15
p = .0000#
Mother Left School at 17/18: Couples, N = 1.980
CB -0.146 -0.017 -0.129
(1.2) (0.1) (0.7)
Other Expenditure 0.016 0.043 0.026
(10.4) (16.8) (11.7)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 1.74 0.09 0.79
p .19 .77 .37
Overall [chi square](6) = 17.24
p = .0084#
Mother Left School at 19+; Couples, N = 1,324
CB 0.543# -0.042 -0.377
(2.0) (0.l) (0.7)
Other Expenditure 0.016 0.035 0.029
(8.9) (12.2) (8.5)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 3.66 0.03 0.57
p .06 .86 .45
Overall [chi square](6) = 9.92
p = .1279
Mother Left School at 16: Lone Parents, N = 366
CB 0.109 0.618# -0.092
(0.6) (2.4) (1.2)
Other Expenditure 0.054 0.095 0.012
(8.9) (11.5) (5.2)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.08 4.03# 1.99
p .78 .04# .16
Overall [chi square](6) = 8.33
p = 0.2151
Mother Left School at 17/18; Lone Parents, N = 154
CB 0.318 1.185# 0.073
(0.5) (2.1) (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.033 0.031 0.002
(3.3) (3.3) (0.6)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.22 4.29# 0.17
p .65 .04# .68
Overall [chi square](6) = 8.03
p = 0.2357
Mother Left School at 19+; Lone Parents, N = 224
CB 0.051 1.111 0.497
(0.2) (2.0) (1.9)
Other Expenditure 0.009 0.061 0.007
(1.7) (6.3) (1.5)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.02 3.67 3.59
P .89 .06 .06
Overall [chi square](6) = 8.82
p = 0.1841
Food Alcohol Tobacco
Mother Left School at 16: Couples, N = 5.271
CB -0.086 0.378# 0.018
(0.5) (2.8) (0.2)
Other Expenditure 0.078 0.037 0.002
(39.6) (26.1) (1.9)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.78 6.43# 0.02
p .38 .01# .88
Overall [chi square](6) = 32.15
p = .0000#
Mother Left School at 17/18: Couples, N = 1.980
CB -0.246 0.579# -0.013
(1.0) (3.5) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.074 0.030 0.003
(23.9) (14.6) (2.0)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 1.72 11.27# 0.02
p .19 .00# .88
Overall [chi square](6) = 17.24
p = .0084#
Mother Left School at 19+; Couples, N = 1,324
CB -0.710 0.892 -0.014
(1.3) (1.6) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.068 0.031 0.001
(19.0) (8.7) (1.0)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 1.92 2.40 0.01
p .17 .12 .91
Overall [chi square](6) = 9.92
p = .1279
Mother Left School at 16: Lone Parents, N = 366
CB -0.081 0.135 0.019
(0.3) (1.2) (0.2)
Other Expenditure 0.086 0.022 0.000
(11.2) (6.0) (0.0)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.47 0.93 0.02
p .49 .33 .88
Overall [chi square](6) = 8.33
p = 0.2151
Mother Left School at 17/18; Lone Parents, N = 154
CB -0.252 0.367 0.182
(0.6) (1.5) (1.1)
Other Expenditure 0.077 0.009 0.003
(10.7) (2.2) (1.2)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.59 2.19 1.23
p .44 .14 .27
Overall [chi square](6) = 8.03
p = 0.2357
Mother Left School at 19+; Lone Parents, N = 224
CB -0.224 0.171 -0.011
(0.5) (0.7) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.052 0.023 0.002
(7.0) (5.6) (0.8)
[[chi square].sub.(CB=Other exp)] 0.44 0.41 0.01
P .51 .52 .93
Overall [chi square](6) = 8.82
p = 0.1841
Notes: Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. Other
explanatory variables are: a linear trend; month, region, and
dummies for whether the child was aged 0-4, 5-10; and a quadratic
in age of household head. Bold values indicate statistical
significance at 5% level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5% level.
TABLE 8
Engel Curves and Household Income
(a) Couples with One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Child Clothing Women's Clothing
Couples in Bottom Third of Income Distribution N = 2,859, Mean
Income = 215.81 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.060 0.275
(0.4) (1.3)
Other Expenditure 0.019 0.043
(12.9) (20.0)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.08 1.18
exp)]
p .78 .28
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.95
p = .2415
Couples in Middle Third of Income Distribution N = 2,858, Mean
Income = 349.59 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.094 -0.017
(0.8) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.018 0.036
(11.4) (17.1)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.42 0.11
exp)]
p .52 .74
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.13
P = .3085
Couples in Top Third of Income Distribution N = 2,858, Mean
Income = 621.44 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB -0.086 0.343
(0.6) (1.6)
Other Expenditure 0.016 0.038
(11.5) (18.1)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.57 2.13
exp)]
p .45 .14
Overall [chi square](6) = 19.99
p = .0028#
(b) Lone Parents with One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Child Clothing Women's Clothing
Lone Parents in Bottom Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 123.28 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB -0.269 0.462
(1.0) (1.8)
Other Expenditure 0.060 0.074
(5.1) (6.5)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 1.49 2.17
exp)]
p .22 .14
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.8
p = .2531
Lone Parents in Middle Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 224.79 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.138 0.091
(0.5) (0.3)
Other Expenditure 0.057 0.047
(6.7) (4.3)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.09 0.02
exp)]
p .77 .90
Overall [chi square](6) 2.89
p = 0.8221
Lone Parents in Top Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 416.85 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.595 1.560#
(1.7) (2.6)
Other Expenditure 0.012 0.065
(2.2) (7.1)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 2.83 6.41#
exp)]
p .09 .01#
Overall [chi square](6) = 14.35
14.35 p = .0260#
(a) Couples with One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Men's Clothing Food
Couples in Bottom Third of Income Distribution N = 2,859, Mean
Income = 215.81 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.072 -0.571
(0.4) (1.8)
Other Expenditure 0.028 0.085
(13.8) (27.0)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.05 4.43
exp)]
p .83 .04
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.95
p = .2415
Couples in Middle Third of Income Distribution N = 2,858, Mean
Income = 349.59 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB -0.132 -0.016
(0.8) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.030 0.067
(15.0) (22.9)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 1.09 0.14
exp)]
p .30 .71
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.13
p = .3085
Couples in Top Third of Income Distribution N = 2,858, Mean
Income = 621.44 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.508# -0.184
(2.4) (0.7)
Other Expenditure 0.027 0.065
(12.6) (26.0)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 5.14# 1.01
exp)]
p .02# .31
Overall [chi square](6) = 19.99
p = .0028#
(b) Lone Parents with One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Men's Clothing Food
Lone Parents in Bottom Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 123.28 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.058 -0.101
(0.5) (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.026 0.107
(4.7) (9.9)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.06 0.72
exp)]
p .80 .40
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.8
p = .2531
Lone Parents in Middle Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 224.79 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB -0.081 0.101
(0.8) (0.3)
Other Expenditure 0.001 0.072
(0.4) (7.2)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.69 0.01
exp)]
p .41 .93
Overall [chi square](6) 2.89
p = 0.8221
Lone Parents in Top Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 416.85 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.401 -0.607
(1.7) (1.4)
Other Expenditure 0.003 0.052
(0.7) (7.6)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 2.74 2.22
exp)]
p .10 .14
Overall [chi square](6) = 14.35
14.35 p = .0260#
(a) Couples with One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Alcohol Tobacco
Couples in Bottom Third of Income Distribution N = 2,859, Mean
Income = 215.81 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.315 0.068
(1.4) (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.040 0.005
(17.8) (2.8)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 1.54 0.12
exp)]
p .21 .73
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.95
p = .2415
Couples in Middle Third of Income Distribution N = 2,858, Mean
Income = 349.59 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.348# 0.035
(2.3) (0.3)
Other Expenditure 0.023 0.004
(11.3) (2.7)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 4.60# 0.06
exp)]
p .03# .80
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.13
p = .3085
Couples in Top Third of Income Distribution N = 2,858, Mean
Income = 621.44 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.701# -0.036
(3.3) (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.031 0.001
(14.2) (0.8)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 9.87# 0.16
exp)]
p .00# .69
Overall [chi square](6) = 19.99
p = .0028#
(b) Lone Parents with One Child Not on Welfare, 1980-2000
Alcohol Tobacco
Lone Parents in Bottom Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 123.28 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.166 0.089
(1.5) (0.7)
Other Expenditure 0.015 0.001
(3.0) (0.1)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 1.86 0.46
exp)]
p .17 .50
Overall [chi square](6) = 7.8
p = .2531
Lone Parents in Middle Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 224.79 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.225 -0.040
(1.3) (0.3)
Other Expenditure 0.020 0.003
(3.6) (0.5)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 1.34 0.07
exp)]
p .25 .79
Overall [chi square](6) 2.89
p = 0.8221
Lone Parents in Top Third of Income Distribution N = 248,
Mean = 416.85 [pounds sterling]/wk
CB 0.196 -0.017
(0.9) (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.015 0.002
(4.2) (0.0)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = Other 0.63 0.02
exp)]
p .43 .90
Overall [chi square](6) = 14.35
14.35 p = .0260#
Notes: Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. Other
explanatory variables are: a linear trend; month, region, and
dummy variables for whether the child was aged 0-4, 5-10
(relative to 11-15); and a quadratic in age of household head.
Bold values indicate statistical significance at 5% level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5% level.
TABLE 9
Engel Curves and Household Income: Child Aged Up to 10 Only
Explanatory Variables Child Clothing Women's Clothing
Couples, N = 6.564
CB -0.101 0.268#
(1.4) (2.2)
Other Expenditure 0.016 0.039
(21.3) (29.8)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = 2.71 3.52
Other exp)
p .10 .06
Overall [chi square](6) = 22.92
p = .0008#
Lone Parents. N = 404
CB -0.093 0.592
(0.5) (1.8)
Other Expenditure 0.037 0.072
(8.4) (9.8)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = 0.46 2.60
Other exp)
p .50 .11
Overall [chi square](6) = 5.01
p = .5420
Explanatory Variables Men's Clothing Food
Couples, N = 6.564
CB 0.267# 0.001
(2.1) (0.0)
Other Expenditure 0.031 0.077
(22.9) (45.2)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = 3.54 0.23
Other exp)
p .06 .63
Overall [chi square](6) = 22.92
p = .0008#
Lone Parents. N = 404
CB 0.135 0.150
(0.8) (0.6)
Other Expenditure 0.014 0.076
(3.7) (12.6)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = 0.52 0.08
Other exp)
p .47 .78
Overall [chi square](6) = 5.01
p = .5420
Explanatory Variables Alcohol Tobacco
Couples, N = 6.564
CB 0.486# 0.021
(3.8) (0.3)
Other Expenditure 0.033 0.000
(23.8) (0.5)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = 12.79# 0.09
Other exp)
p .00# .77
Overall [chi square](6) = 22.92
p = .0008#
Lone Parents. N = 404
CB 0.134 0.095
(1.0) (0.9)
Other Expenditure 0.020 0.004
(6.3) (1.6)
[[chi square].sub.(CB = 0.69 0.74
Other exp)
p .41 .39
Overall [chi square](6) = 5.01
p = .5420
Notes: Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. Other
explanatory variables are: a linear trend; month, region, and
dummy variables for whether the child was aged 0-4, 5-10
(relative to 11-15); a quadratic in age of household head; and a
lone father dummy in the lone parent sample. The F statistic in
each equation is a test of whether the coefficient on CB and on
other income is equal, and the overall F statistic is a test that
all of the CB coefficients equal the corresponding other income
coefficients. Bold values indicate statistical significance at 5%
level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5% level.
TABLE 10
Anticipated Versus Unanticipated CB Effects: Rational Expectations
Child Clothing Women's Clothing
Couples, N = 8,575
Anticipated CB -0.233 0.403
(1.3) (1.5)
Unanticipated CB 0.066 0.173
(0.8) (1.4)
Other Expenditure 0.017 0.039
(22.8) (34.8)
[[chi square].sub.(antCB 1.83 1.78
= Other exp])
p .18 .18
Overall [chi square](6) = 23.84
p = 0.0006#
[[chi square].sub.anant(CB 0.34 1.19
= Other exp])
p .56 .27
Overall [chi square](6) = 20.06
p = 0.0027#
Lone Parents, N = 744
Anticipated CB 0.085 0.775
(0.1) (0.7)
Unanticipated CB 0.156 0.704#
(0.9) (2.9)#
Other Expenditure 0.025 0.064
(2.4) (12.4)
[[chi square].sub.(antCB 0.01 0.47
= Other exp])
p .94 .49
Overall [chi square](6) = 1.28
p = 0.97
[[chi square].sub.anant(CB 0.55 6.93#
= Other exp])
p .46 .01#
Overall [chi square](6) = 11.44
= 0.0758
Men's Clothing Food
Couples, N = 8,575
Anticipated CB 0.141 -1.368#
(0.5) (3.9)
Unanticipated CB 0.208 0.059
(1.7) (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.028 0.075
(24.9) (51.7)
[[chi square].sub.(antCB 0.17 16.66#
= Other exp])
p .68 .00
Overall [chi square](6) = 23.84
p = 0.0006#
[[chi square].sub.anant(CB 2.16 0.01
= Other exp])
p .14 .92
Overall [chi square](6) = 20.06
p = 0.0027#
Lone Parents, N = 744
Anticipated CB -0.079 -0.326
(0.2) (0.4)
Unanticipated CB 0.079 -0.089
(0.8) (0.4)
Other Expenditure 0.007 0.067
(3.1) (16.0)
[[chi square].sub.(antCB 0.04 0.21
= Other exp])
p .84 .65
Overall [chi square](6) = 1.28
p = 0.97
[[chi square].sub.anant(CB 0.53 0.61
= Other exp])
p .46 .44
Overall [chi square](6) = 11.44
p = 0.0758
Alcohol Tobacco
Couples, N = 8,575
Anticipated CB 0.330 0.174
(1.2) (1.1)
Unanticipated CB 0.524# -0.043
(4.2)# (0.6)
Other Expenditure 0.033 0.000
(28.8) (0.6)
[[chi square].sub.(antCB 1.16 1.11
= Other exp])
p .28 .29
Overall [chi square](6) = 23.84
p = 0.0006#
[[chi square].sub.anant(CB 15.57# 0.32
= Other exp])
p .00# .57
Overall [chi square](6) = 20.06
p = 0.0027#
Lone Parents, N = 744
Anticipated CB 0.323 0.143
(0.7) (0.4)
Unanticipated CB 0.208# 0.005
(2.0)# (0.1)
Other Expenditure 0.019 0.001
(8.6) (0.4)
[[chi square].sub.(antCB 0.46 0.16
= Other exp])
p .50 .69
Overall [chi square](6) = 1.28
p = 0.97
[[chi square].sub.anant(CB 3.31# 0.00
= Other exp])
p .07# .96
Overall [chi square](6) = 11.44
p = 0.0758
Notes: Other expenditure is defined as total expenditure minus
CB. Figures in parentheses are absolute t-values. The lone
parent's equations include a dummy variable for lone father. Bold
values indicate statistical significance at 5% level.
Note: Values with # indicates statistical significance at 5% level.