Individual behavior and bidding heterogeneity in sealed bid auctions where the number of bidders is unknown.
Isaac, Mark ; Pevnitskaya, Svetlana ; Schnier, Kurt S. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Most of the work in sealed bid auction theory and related
experimental work has focused on the case in which the number of bidders
is known. This is, of course, not always the case in naturally occurring
environments. For instance, construction firms submitting bids in a
sealed bid procurement auction may not know exactly how many other firms
have completed the costly process of preparing and submitting a bid
until bidding has closed. There is a body of theory to address
environments with an unknown number of bidders (McAfee and McMillan
1987; Matthews 1987; Harstad, Kagel, and Levin 1990; Krishna 2002). (1)
The purpose of this article is to provide theoretical considerations and
analysis of a large data set of individual bids from laboratory sealed
bid auction markets in which buyers have some information about the
number of rivals, but not certainty. (2)
According to the received theory, the availability of information
about the number of rivals, as expected, directly affects bidding and
therefore seller revenue in first-price (FP) auctions but should not
affect bidding in the second-price (SP) auctions. Although bidding own
valuation is optimal in SP auctions (regardless of the number of
bidders), the majority of previous experimental work on auctions with
known number of bidders has shown systematic deviation (Kagel 1995)
while a few studies report coincidence with theory (see Isaac and James
2000b for an extended discussion). Earlier work on FP auctions with
known number of bidders indicated systematic overbidding compared to
risk neutral equilibrium. Risk aversion has been suggested as one of the
possible explanations for observed overbidding (Cox, Roberson, and Smith
1982).
Dyer, Kagel, and Levin (1989) is the only previous experimental
study looking at individual bidding in auctions where the number of
bidders is unknown and their design is different from this study. They
look at FP auctions with restricted auction size of either six or three
participants and ask subjects to submit three bids (two bids for
contingent bidding procedure and one bid for noncontingent bidding
procedure). Subjects submit all three bids simultaneously and do not
know at the time which procedure will be used. They find overbidding in
this environment compared to risk neutral Nash equilibrium. Although we
test for deviation from risk neutral bidding strategy in a more general
setting, our study also addresses a broader set of questions. Previous
studies of open-bid ascending "silent" auctions suggested that
there may have been revenue loss to the sellers by bidders
"guarding" their higher valued items, that is, remaining
physically proximate to the bidding stations (Isaac and Schnier 2005).
The possibility that "guarding" was at the root of the revenue
reductions was investigated by Isaac and Schnier (2006), who replaced
the open-bid ascending silent auctions with both FP and SP sealed bid
auctions, which is the environment studied in this article. Their paper
reported on the aggregate revenue effects of the switch to sealed bid
auctions but did not look at individual behavior. It is clear that such
analysis of individual bidding behavior must be informed by theories of
bidding with an unknown number of rivals, because such is the reality
facing bidders in a multiple sealed bid silent auction context. In
addition, data from a noncomputerized experiment closely approximating
field auctions allows the analysis of possible behavioral adjustments in
the field, for example, the attempt to "guard" the item and
count the number of bidders. Such an analysis is presented in this
article. (3)
Our analysis of FP auctions contributes to the discussion about the
causes of heterogeneous deviation of individual bidding from risk
neutral theory. Cox, Roberson, and Smith (1982) and Cox, Smith, and
Walker (1988) reported heterogeneous bidding above risk neutral
equilibrium in FP auctions for mechanisms with fixed number of bidders
and Palfrey and Pevnitskaya (2008) for auctions with endogenous entry,
where the number of bidders was known at the time of submitting a bid.
Those papers show that such deviations are consistent with heterogeneous
risk preferences. Risk aversion, however, is not the only suggested
explanation for deviations from risk neural Nash equilibrium in FP
auctions. Proposed explanations of overbidding include social
comparisons, learning, and regret, which have been addressed by recent
experimental studies (Engelbrecht-Wiggans and Katok 2007, 2008;
Filiz-Ozbay and Ozbay 2007). Risk aversion remains one of the plausible
options and we investigate it in the new environment where the number of
bidders is unknown. We show theoretically that in the environment with
additional uncertainty about the number of bidders, bidding above risk
neutral equilibrium remains consistent with risk averse preferences. We
find a substantial amount of coincidence with theory in SP auctions but
observe systematic deviations from risk neutral bidding in FP auctions
in terms of level effect. We test for heterogeneity in two separate
ways. First, we use latent class estimation to test for heterogeneity
without imposing any structural form on the behavior, that is, not
restricting our focus by any conjecture on what may drive deviations. We
find evidence of heterogeneity in FP but not SP auctions; furthermore,
in FP auctions heterogeneity persists with experience. This is
consistent with theory as the number of bidders and risk preferences do
not affect optimal bid in the SP auctions but are part of the optimal
bidding strategy in the FP auctions. Second, we apply a structural form
of nonlinear utility (as a result of risk preferences) and estimate risk
preference parameter of each subject and also of groups of subjects
allocated into segments by the latent estimation technique. We then
check for consistency between the two estimation approaches. We find
that heterogeneity in bidding in the FP auctions is consistent with
heterogeneity in risk preferences, the attempt to count the number of
bidders in the auction, and bidder specific noise.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. In Section II, we
present theoretical results on bidding in silent auctions. Section III
offers the experimental design and hypotheses. Estimation methods are
described in Section IV. The experimental results appear in Section V.
Section VI offers our conclusions.
II. A THEORY OF BIDDING WHERE "n" IS UNKNOWN
In the sealed bid silent auctions bidders do not know at the time
they are bidding on any specific item how many of the other bidders will
be active rivals. Specifically, at the time of submitting a bid, each
bidder knows the auction mechanism (here FP or SP), their own valuation
of the item, the distribution of valuations of other bidders, and the
distribution of the number of bidders in the auction (here over [1, N]).
We start with presenting risk neutral theory of bidding in this
environment drawing upon McAfee and McMillan (1987), Harstad, Kagel, and
Levin (1990), and Krishna (2002).
Not surprisingly, having an unknown number of active bidders, n,
out of the N total bidders does not affect the optimal bidding strategy,
B(.), for SP sealed bid auctions, namely
(1) B([[upsilon].sub.i]) = [[upsilon].sub.i]
where [[upsilon].sub.i] is bidder i's valuation.
For FP sealed bid auctions, however, the situation is much
different. The Nash equilibrium bid function for risk neutral bidders is
(2) [[beta].sub.RN]([[upsilon].sub.i] = [[summation].sub.n]
[[omega].sub.n]([[upsilon].sub.i])[[beta].sub.n]([[upsilon].sub.i])
where [[beta].sub.RN]([[upsilon].sub.i]) is a risk neutral bid in
an auction with n bidders and the weights,
[[omega].sub.n]([[upsilon].sub.i]), are functions of the bidders
expectations {[[rho].sub.k]}, which are the probabilities that the
bidder is in an auction with k bidders, [[summation].sup.N.sub.k=1] =
[[rho].sub.k] = 1. (4) That is, the equilibrium bid function when the
bidder "is unsure about the number of rivals he/she faces is a
weighted average of the equilibrium bids in auctions when the number of
bidders is known by all" (Krishna 2002, 36).
Overbidding in FP single-unit auctions with known number of bidders
has been observed in multiple studies with risk aversion being one
successful, but not the only, explanation (see Cox, Roberson, and Smith
1982 and Kagel 1995 for the discussion). However, the recent models of
bidding in FP auctions where the number of bidders is uncertain focused
only on risk neutral participants. (5) In this section, we derive
properties of the bidding functions when bidders are risk averse.
Suppose that subjects have income utility U(x), a concave,
increasing, differentiable function satisfying U(0) = 0. The symmetric Nash equilibrium bid maximizes
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [p.sub.j] is the probability of participating in an auction
with j bidders and F([upsilon]) is the cumulative distribution function
of bidders' valuations. The optimal bid satisfies the first-order
conditions for maximization resulting in the following differential
equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where the weights [w.sub.j]([upsilon]) =
([F.sup.j-1]([[upsilon].sub.i])[p.sub.j])/[[summation].sub.j]
[p.sub.j][F.sup.j-1]([[upsilon].sub.i]). The equilibrium bid function,
however, is no longer a weighted combination of bids in corresponding
j-bidder auctions. Krishna's proof breaks as it relies on revenue
equivalence which no longer holds. The Harsted, Kagel, and Levin
derivation relies on linear utility and also no longer holds. Despite
this, we can compare bidding functions of risk averse,
[beta]([upsilon]), and risk neutral, [[beta].sub.RN]([upsilon]),
bidders.
PROPOSITION 1. [beta]([upsilon]) > [[beta].sub.RN]([upsilon])
Proof Following Harsted, Kagel, and Levin, the first-order
conditions of the maximization problem of risk neutral bidders results
in the following differential equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Therefore inequality [beta]'([[upsilon].sub.i]) [greater than
or equal to] [[beta]'.sub.RN]([[upsilon].sub.i]) follows from the
concavity of U(x). Following Milgrom and Weber (1982) we conclude that
whenever [beta]([[upsilon].sub.i]) [less than or equal to]
[[beta].sub.RN]([[upsilon].sub.i]), [beta]'([[upsilon].sub.i]) >
[[beta]'.sub.RN]([[upsilon].sub.i]); the equilibrium boundary
condition is [[beta].sub.RN]([[upsilon].bar]) = [beta]([[upsilon].bar])
= [[upsilon].bar]. It then follows (Milgrom and Weber, lemma 2) that for
[upsilon] > [[upsilon].bar], [beta]([upsilon]) >
[[beta].sub.RN]([upsilon]). []
That is, risk averse preferences result in overbidding compared to
risk neutral behavior in FP auctions when the number of bidders is
unknown.
III. EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN AND HYPOTHESES
We use data from a total of six experimental sessions, each
consisting of five auction periods. The two bidding institutions were
alternated to allow both within-subject and across-subject comparisons.
The five bidding periods of three experimental sessions were sequenced
in an FFSSF format; the other three sessions were sequenced SSFFS. Table
1 is a "road map" to the features of this experimental design.
In each period, there were 16 items offered for sale and 8
potential bidders. For each item in each period, the number of active
(nonzero value) bidders, between two and eight inclusive, was randomly
chosen with a uniform distribution. Then, the subject IDs to receive the
positive values were randomly chosen. Finally, each bidder with a
positive value for a given auction had their value randomly chosen over
the interval (0.00, 20.00] using a uniform distribution. The subjects
were informed of these random processes.
Each item was auctioned at a separate station and a physical
separation of the bidding stations for different items, just as one
would find in naturally occurring silent auctions, was included in the
laboratory design. At each bidding station was placed a
"supersized" foam coffee mug with an opaque, slotted top. The
letter of the associated item was clearly marked on each mug. Each
bidder had a pad of bidding slips on which they were required to write
their bidder ID, the item being bid on, their bid, and the time (of 7
minutes) remaining on the clock. (6) They inserted the bidding slip into
the mug when they wished to bid for an item. (7) The instructions of the
experiment can be found in the Appendix. (8)
For the SP auctions, the formal baseline hypothesis is simple:
bidders will follow their dominant strategy and bid their value. The
experimental auction literature provides a well-known
counter-hypothesis, that bidders will generally over-bid their values in
a SP sealed bid auction (Cooper 2008).
Figures 1A and 1B display graphs of the risk neutral equilibrium
bidding function in the FP auction, [[beta].sub.RN]([[upsilon].sub.i]),
for the parameters of our experimental design (r = 1). (9) It should be
noted that the bid function here, unlike the standard case of known n,
is nonlinear in [[upsilon].sub.i]. As shown theoretically in the
previous section, risk averse bidders (0 < r < 1) are expected to
bid above [[beta].sub.RN]([[upsilon].sub.i]).
There is a plausible alternative to this theory for the silent
auction version of the FP sealed bid auction, what we will call the
counting conjecture. It is at least possible that bidders will try to
watch other bidders and discern the number of bidders in each of the
individual auctions. If so, then the silent auctions are not a part of
the standard theoretical framework but simply devolve to a series of
simultaneous FP auctions, with bidders bidding according to the formula
based on known n. Of course there are many reasons to believe that
counting is difficult: bidders must attend to their own decisions and
move between different stations; by construction some bids will be
placed after others, requiring extensive updating by counters; watching
all of the possible rivals may be difficult as they span out across the
room and each bidder may place a new bid before the auction ends. (10)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
IV. ESTIMATION METHODS
A. General Analysis of Bidding
For each auction institution we have a relatively robust number of
observations. Because the valuations for the items are independently
drawn private values, we treat auctions independently. To investigate
whether or not bidder behavior is in accordance with the theoretical
predictions we estimate a reduced form bid function under both
homogeneity and heterogeneity assumptions. The homogeneity assumption
implies that all bidders possess the same marginal bidding propensities
(regression coefficients), whereas the heterogeneous model allows for
there to exist multiple bidding functions within the population. This
was achieved utilizing latent class regressions, which have proven to be
useful in public good (Anderson and Putterman 2006) and resource
extraction experiments (Schnier and Anderson 2006). This method will be
further outlined following a general discussion of the bid function
estimated.
The bid function we estimate for each auction institution is
(3)
[b.sub.ikt] = [[gamma].sub.0] + [[gamma].sub.1] x
[Predicted.sub.ikt] + [[gamma].sub.2] x [Number.sub.kt] +
[[gamma].sub.3] x New + [[gamma].sub.4] x New x [Predicted.sub.ikt] +
[[gamma].sub.5] x New x [Number.sub.kt]
where [b.sub.ikt] represents participant i's bid on an item
with value k in time period t, within the panel for either the FP or the
SP auction. Within the SP auction the variable [Predicted.sub.ikt] is
bidder i's value for item k in period t, [Value.sub.ikt], which in
theory is equal to the bid. In the FP auction we use bidder i's
predicted risk neutral equilibrium bid for item k in period t. The
variable, [Number.sub.kt] indicates the number of active bidders for
item k in period t and is included to investigate the counting
conjecture discussed earlier. New is a dummy variable indicating whether
or not participant i's bid occurred during their first exposure to
either auction institution. (11) Should bidder behavior follow the
theoretical predictions we would expect [[gamma].sub.0] = 0,
[[gamma].sub.1] = 1, and [[gamma].sub.2] = 0. If the counting conjecture
is to be supported we would require a nonzero and significant
coefficient [[gamma].sub.2]. If individual i's behavior requires
some learning with the institution, we expect some of [[gamma].sub.3],
[[gamma].sub.4], or [[gamma].sub.5] to be nonzero. To estimate this
bidding function we utilize a double censored tobit regression with an
upper bound of $20.00, the maximum induced value in the experiment, and
a lower bound of $0.00, the minimum induced value. (12)
For the subset of "experienced" bids Equation (3)
degenerates to
(4)
[b.sub.ikt] = [[gamma].sub.0] + [[gamma].sub.1] x
[Predicted.sub.ikt] + [[gamma].sub.2] x [Number.sub.kt]
as New = 0 for all "experienced" bids. We estimate
Equation (4) to investigate the effect of experience on bidding and
heterogeneity by comparing the results to the estimation of Equation
(3). Regression results for Equation (3) where we use all data are
denoted New = 0, 1 results, indicating the presence of the New dummy
variable, and for experienced bidding when New = 0, used in Equation
(4), the results are denoted Experienced.
B. Presence and Degree of Heterogeneity in Bidding
We next test for the presence and degree of heterogeneity in
bidding. To conduct the heterogeneous estimation we use El-Gamal and
Grether's (1995, 2000) estimation classification (EC) algorithm to
endogenously group subjects into a prespecified number of bidder types.
(13) The EC algorithm assumes that each subject's bids can be
described by a bidding function, b([gamma]), as in Equation (3), where
[gamma] is an unknown parameter vector. Heterogeneity is introduced by
allowing for there to exist a prespecified number of different
"types," or segments, H, with each "type" possessing
their own parameter vector [[gamma].sub.h]. The estimation of the
parameter vectors of each type/segment h = 1, ..., H is conducted
simultaneously with the determination of each subject's type (or
segment assignment). This is achieved by having each subject's
contribution to the likelihood function, [GAMMA] = ([[gamma].sub.1],
..., [[gamma].sub.h]), be the maximum of the joint likelihood of all
their bid observations, n, across the H types. (14) In essence, each of
the H different parameter vectors is "tested" for all
individuals and only that parameter vector which best fits their
contribution to the likelihood function is selected. Furthermore, each
of the H different parameter vectors is endogenously determined within
the maximum likelihood operator and for each iteration of the
maximization the parameter vector "tests" are conducted. The
log-likelihood function utilizing the EC algorithm and the
log-likelihood for the tobit regression, denoted by
L(x), is expressed as
ln[L(b; X|[GAMMA], H)]
= [[summation].sup.m.sub.j=1] arg [max.sub.h]
[[[summation].sup.T.sub.t=1] [[summation].sup.n.sub.i=1] x
ln[L([b.sub.itj]; [X.sub.itj]|[[gamma].sub.h])]]
where m is the number of subjects in the experiment (48) and
[X.sub.itj] is a matrix of independent variables captured in the bidding
function (1). The estimates of [GAMMA] are subject to the assumptions
regarding the number of "types" within the population.
Estimation proceeds by first setting H = 1, the homogeneous model, and
then increasing H until the test statistics indicate that a sufficient
number of "types" have been specified. The test statistics
used to determine the appropriate number of "types" or
segments were the Bayesian information criterion (BIC), the Akaike
Information Criteria (AIC), the Consistent Akaike Information Criteria
(cnAIC), the corrected Akaike Information Criterion (crAIC) and
likelihood ratio (LR) test.
SP auction test statistics were not necessary because the models
continuously degenerated to the homogeneous case (H = 1). For the FP
auctions, we start with conducting the estimation for all data (New = 0,
1) and follow with estimation using only Experienced data as described
below. We note that the LR and BIC test statistics generally decrease so
we focus on the dynamics of the AIC criteria as the number of segments
increases. AIC criteria also decrease but tend to flatten for the four-
to five-tier segmentation, indicating the latter. For both data sets we
were unable to reach convergence for the six-segment models. Estimations
for the New = 0, 1 data show that increasing heterogeneity up to three
segments captures heterogeneity in bidding in terms of differences in
coefficients on core variables; however, going beyond three segments
just subdivides the existing tiers according to the effect of experience
while leaving all of the key results intact. Therefore for the New = 0,
1 data additional tiers beyond three segments are just telling us that
experience matters for heterogeneity, supporting a separate estimation
on the Experienced data which we conduct next. For the experienced data,
going from four to five segments assigns just one subject (who is
clearly an outlier) to the fifth segment. The lineup of the general
bidding propensities of segments remains unchanged. The creation of a
one-person segment also raises concerns about beginning to
"overfit" the data. If we push this model to its extreme we
could end up with a separate segment for each subject. Considering the
economic implications and statistical considerations described above and
also choosing the most conservative approach for describing the
heterogeneity results, we report estimations for three segments for all
data and four segments for data with experienced bidding. (15)
The results of these estimations are presented in Tables 2-4. In
each table we show homogeneous estimates (H = 1) as a reference point
and then report results from the best fitted number of segments.
C. Risk Preferences
We separately conduct a structural estimation of the bidding data
and estimate risk preference parameters of individual subjects as well
as groups of subjects assigned to the same segment by the latent
technique. Our objective is to evaluate the consistency of the risk
aversion hypothesis with observed behavior and the heterogeneity
classification of the previous part as well as compare our results to
the previous studies.
For estimation purposes we adopt CRRA utility function u(x)=
[x.sub.r], where r is the risk parameter such that r = 1 for risk
neutral bidders, 0 < r < 1 for risk averse bidders, and
r > 1 for risk loving bidders. For CRRA utility function and our
experimental design, the differential equation for the optimal bid
becomes:
[beta]([[upsilon].sub.i]) =
(1/r[[upsilon].sub.i])([[upsilon].sub.i] - [beta]([[upsilon].sub.i]))
([[summation].sup.8.sub.j=2] (j - 1)[([[upsilon].sub.i]/2000).sup.j-1]
[p.sub.j]) / [[summation].sup.8.sub.j=2]
[([[upsilon].sub.i]/2000).sup.j-1] [p.sub.j]).
The closed form solution for optimal bid cannot be obtained;
however, we are able to solve the above differential equation
numerically given specific valuation and risk parameter and obtain a
theoretical bid. For every valuation, theoretical bid for a given r can
be compared to the observed bid. We then estimate risk parameters in the
following way. For each experimental observation, we obtain a numerical
solution for the optimal theoretical bid based on r. The accuracy of the
theoretical prediction is reflected by the difference between
theoretical and actual bids. Our estimate of r minimizes the sum of
absolute deviations between theoretical and observed bids as illustrated
below.
The estimate of the individual risk preference parameter for each
subject i is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [[upsilon].sub.ij] is the drawn valuation of bidder i in
their auction j, [n.sub.i] is the number of auctions that bidder i
participated in, [[beta].sup.*] ([[upsilon].sub.ij], r) the optimal
theoretical bid (given r and [[upsilon].sub.ij]), and [[beta].sub.ij]
the observed bid for value [[upsilon].sub.ij].
The estimator for the whole population of bidders is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
For the whole population the estimate r = 0.375 minimizes the above
function. This value is similar to those observed in many previous
studies (Isaac and James 2000a). The estimates of risk parameters for
each segment, [G.sub.k], are
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The results of these estimations are presented in Tables 6 and 7.
V. RESULTS
We have 1,050 and 1,013 observations on bidder's value and
their corresponding bid in the SP and FP auctions, respectively. (16)
Essentially all positive valuations resulted in bids, thus not creating
an endogenous entry setup. Only about 6% of positive valuations did not
result in submitted bids and this number would be reduced further with
less conservative estimation (e.g., disqualified duplicate bids and bids
with missing information could indicate the desire to bid on all active
units but making errors in the bidding process). The number is
comparable to a robust phenomenon of "throw away" zero bids in
computerized experimental auctions (where bidders are required to submit
a bid) for lower values. The frequency of bids in all treatments
decreases over time with essentially no bids right at the closing time.
In a sealed bid setup, waiting does not provide information on the
amounts of bids of other subjects. Our design makes counting difficult
because subjects cannot see the number of already submitted bids in a
jar and, given that subjects are active on multiple items, spend
substantial time at a particular station to observe the bid submission
process. (17)
We next describe our specific findings for SP and FP auctions.
A. SP Auctions
From a purely descriptive point of view, we note that 547 (52.09%)
of the bids are equal to value, and that 740 (70.48%) were within 25
cents of value. (18) This compares favorably to other research into
dominant strategy mechanisms and is consistent with Isaac and Schnier
(2006) who report that average aggregate revenue was very close to the
theoretical predictions for these auctions. (19) This result seems
robust in our study and is not driven by previous experience in FP
auctions.
Turning to the estimation results, we note that the econometric firepower of the latent class process was essentially wasted on the SP
auctions, as both the full data set and the data restricted to
experienced periods failed to converge beyond a single class. (20) Table
2 shows that for the New = 0, 1 case subjects appear to be following the
theoretical predictions except for when they are initially exposed to
the SP auction institution. The negative coefficient on the New x Value
indicates that subjects bid more than 9% below their value when first
exposed to new auction institution. The Value coefficient is not
statistically significant from its hypothesized theoretical value (using
a t test). (21) The bidding behavior does not depend on the number of
bidders in the auction. This is not surprising because in the SP
auctions the optimal bid does not depend on n and the counting
hypothesis is irrelevant in this case.
Given the statistical significance of some of the "New"
variables, we re-estimate the results with only the experienced bidding.
The heterogeneous estimation again collapses to a single class outcome.
As shown in the right-hand column (Experienced) of Table 2, we find that
experienced subjects bid almost exactly like the dominant strategy
prediction. A t test on the Value coefficient, the only statistically
significant coefficient in the experienced model, confirmed this
hypothesis. (22) What chiefly distinguishes the full data set from that
restricted to the experienced periods is the much smaller variance
around the estimates in the latter model.
B. FP Auctions
As described in Section 4B, we report below the results for the
three-segment model for the New = 0, 1 data and the four-segment model
for the Experienced data.
Table 3 presents estimation results for homogenous (H = 1) and
heterogeneous (H = 3) specifications of the model for all New = 0, 1
data. The results from the homogeneous estimation (H = 1) indicate that
subjects, treated as one group, do not behave according to the
equilibrium theoretical predictions. Three of the coefficients are
statistically different from their hypothesized values. The constant
term is positive and statistically significant. Subjects, as an
aggregate, are influenced by initial exposure to the auction
institution; the significant coefficients on the New and the New x
Predicted variables indicate a structural shift in their bid function.
The coefficient on the Predicted variable, however, is not significantly
different from 1.00 as suggested by theory. These results provide a
preliminary look at the data. We next describe the results of the
heterogeneous model.
The heterogeneous results for the New = 0, 1 model differ from
those obtained with a homogenous model. A majority of the subjects (35),
those in Segments 1 and 2, tend to bid above the equilibrium theoretical
predictions. t tests on the Predicted coefficient indicate that this
coefficient is significantly greater than 1.00 in both cases. (23) For
all three segments the estimated constant is positive, but it is
statistically significant (with 95% confidence) only for Segment 1.
Segments 2 and 3 are distinguished from Segment 1 also by the fact that
the former show stronger structural shifts from the New condition. In no
case is there any significant evidence of the counting conjecture.
The 12 bidders in Segment 1 have a propensity to bid a large
predetermined amount, as reflected in the large and statistically
significant constant term (1.2590) and also depart from risk neutral
theory by having a coefficient on Predicted (1.1400) that is
significantly greater than 1. The 23 bidders in Segment 2 have a much
smaller constant term (0.4552) and they come closest to the coefficient
of 1.00 on the Predicted variable (1.0800). The 13 bidders in Segment 3
are particularly interesting. They have an intermediate constant of
0.8617 (which is not significant for any standard confidence level) and
their coefficient on Predicted is only 0.9076. The coefficients for this
segment tend to have larger standard errors than the other two groups.
(24)
Table 4 presents the estimations for the Experienced data and model
specification (4). The homogenous model (H = 1) yields nearly identical
parameter estimates for the Constant, Predicted, and Number coefficients
as those depicted for the homogenous case in Table 3 for all data.
Heterogeneity in bidding in the FP auctions persists with experience,
suggesting the stable cause of deviations from the RNNE that becomes
more refined when the initial noise settles down with experience.
Segments 1 and 4 (with 17 and 12 bidders, respectively) have a positive
(and significant) constant, and slightly greater than 1 coefficient on
the predicted bid. For Segments 2 and 3 (with 15 and 4 bidders,
respectively), the coefficient on the constant term is not significantly
different from zero. Segment 2's Predicted coefficient is very
close to 1, while for Segment 3 it is below 1 and equal to 0.6359.
Furthermore, Segment 2 has a Number coefficient that is significantly
different from zero (p = .02), the only time the counting hypothesis is
supported in this study. (25) This means that a small subset of subjects
attempt to access the number of bidders in the auction and slightly
adjust their bids for auctions with higher number of participants.
Unlike the SP auctions where the model always converged to 1
segment (homogeneity), in the FP auctions heterogeneity persisted with
experience resulting in four-segment specification for experienced data
and a three-segment specification for all data. Such difference in
heterogeneity between mechanisms is consistent with heterogeneity in
risk preferences which should play no role in the SP auction (where the
solution concept is dominance) and directly affect the bidding in the FP
auctions. We study these considerations in detail in the next section.
C. Individual Characteristics of Heterogeneity
We next investigate if there is any regularity in how specific
subjects are assigned to segments. Following methodology of Section 4C
we study whether the pattern of bidding consistent with risk aversion
plays a role in segment assignments.
First, consider the SP auctions, where risk preferences play no
role for the bidding strategy and the model collapsed to one segment.
Using all of the data (New = 0, 1) the point predictions of the
coefficients are similar but noisier than estimates for Experienced
bidding. This suggests the presence of noise in behavior in the face of
a new institution, a propensity that does not qualify as risk aversion.
The analysis of the FP auctions, however, indicates that
heterogeneity persists with experience. We explore below whether there
is a common factor in the segment assignments for the FP auction that is
consistent with heterogeneity in risk preferences. (26)
We report the estimated risk parameter (as well as the standard
error and the number of observations) for each individual bidder in
Table 6. Estimation results of risk parameters for the segments formed
by the EC algorithm are presented in Table 7. As the segment numbers are
arbitrary, we order the results in Table 7 in increasing risk preference
parameter, r. We perform these estimations for all data (New = 0, 1) and
for only experienced bidders' data (Experienced). Bidders risk
parameters, r, range from 0.035 (subject 27) to 34.9 (subject 7) for all
data (New = 0, 1) and from 0.045 (subject 27) to 27.30 (subject 7) for
experienced data. Subject 7's bidding is an outlier and is also
characterized by the largest noise. (27) The second highest risk
preference parameter is 2.55 for all data and 2.38 for experienced data
(subject 3). The ranking of individual risk parameters is preserved
fairly well with experience as shown in Table 6. The distributions of
the individual risk parameters are displayed in Figure 2. These
distributions are obtained by counting the frequency of individual
[r.sub.i]s in the intervals with length 0.1, that is, from 0 to 0.1,
from 0.1+ to 0.2, and so forth. The arrows on the graph indicate the
estimated risk aversion parameters of segments from Table 7. The
distribution of individual risk parameters for all data is somewhat
uniform with no distinct peaks. The estimated risk parameters of three
optimal segments formed by EC algorithm (0.21, 0.52, and 0.99) are
spread about evenly among risk averse to risk neutral range of risk
parameters. The distribution of individual risk parameters changes
dramatically when we look at only experienced bidders and has two very
distinct peaks. Segments 1 and 4 (containing a total of 29 of the 48
bidders) line up at the first peak in the distribution and Segment 2
(containing 15 out of 48 bidders) lines up near the second peak. Segment
3 is at the right tail and has the highest r = 1.505 (least risk
averse). Bidding in Segments 1, 2, and 4 is consistent with risk averse
preferences (r = 0.375, 0.505, and 0.205, respectively). Segment 2 is
the only group to show significant counting behavior. Therefore,
although a large number of bidders exhibited risk averse risk
preferences (if we were to use this hypothesis) the behavioral
phenomenon of counting also affects heterogeneity and segment
assignments.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figures 1A and 1B show bidding data by segments for Experienced
data and also two theoretical benchmarks: risk neutral (r = 1) bid and
bid function based on the optimal r estimate for each segment. The
graphs show that different segments have different levels of bidding
noise. Data in Segments 1 and 4 cluster tightly around theoretical
predictions, while data in Segment 2 has larger noise. Segment 3 is
associated with particularly large bidding noise. Some subjects, for
example, 3 and 7, bid all over the nondominated range of bids
([b.sub.ij] [less than or equal to] [[upsilon].sub.ij]). It thus appears
that the estimation technique is sorting the bidders in segments based
also on the intrinsic noise.
Table 5 presents the contingency table for the segment assignments
in all data and only in experienced periods. If there is a stable cause
of heterogeneity, the assignment of subjects to segments should be
consistent. The chi-squared statistic for the associated contingency
test is significant, indicating there is a common element to the
heterogeneity in the bidders' behavior that survives the effect of
experience. If risk preferences are stable, there would be higher
numbers along the main diagonal and lower numbers or zeros in the lower
left and upper right corners. This tendency is observed in the table
with a slight deviation, which is because of other factors affecting
heterogeneity besides risk preferences. The majority of subjects (23)
from the "middle" risk aversion Segment 2 (r = 0.515) based on
New = 0, 1 data remained in "middle" Segments 1 and 2 (r =
0.375 and 0.505, respectively) for Experienced data. Ten out of 12
subjects in the most risk averse (lowest r) segment of all data (r =
0.205) remain in the most risk averse segment of experienced data (r =
0.205). There are only two subjects, 9 and 48, who were in Segment 3 (r
= 0.985) for all data and joined Segment 1 (r = 0.205) for Experienced
data. As follows from Table 6, the estimated risk parameters for New =
0, 1 and Experienced data were, respectively, 0.36 and 0.29 for subject
9 and 0.26 and 0.24 for subject 48. Although the estimated risk
parameters of these subjects did not change much with experience, the
bidding noise (standard deviation from theoretical bid) dropped
significantly: from 2.84 to 0.28 for subject 9 and from 2.00 to 0.26 for
subject 48. Table 7 indicates that Segment 3 for all data is
characterized by the largest bidding noise (standard deviation from
theoretical bid is 4.16). This is yet another indication that bidder
specific noise is utilized by the EC algorithm to identify heterogeneity
among subjects.
Our results demonstrate that heterogeneity in bidding captured by
the latent class estimation technique is consistent with three
characteristics: risk preferences, counting the number of bidders, and
the intrinsic bidding noise of a given subject.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
Previous studies of individual bidding data in sealed bid auctions
with known number of bidders indicated that bidders deviate from
theoretical predictions and exhibit heterogeneity (Cox, Roberson, and
Smith 1982; Kagel 1995). In this article we study individual bidding
behavior in sealed bid auctions with unknown number of bidders (modeling
uncertainty in a Bayesian way) and look for the consistency of
individual bidding decisions with models of individual bidding behavior.
Previous theoretical work in this environment identified the dominant
strategy in the SP auctions and risk neutral equilibrium model in the FP
auctions, which we adapted to our experimental design. We then extended
existing risk neutral theory of bidding in FP auctions with unknown
number of bidders to account for risk preferences. The permutations on
the basic models that we considered were, first, whether there was any
indication that bidders could discern (count) the number of bidders in
each of the auctions; second, an experience effect; and third, whether
there might be individual heterogeneity and the possibility that it
could be explained by heterogeneous risk preferences.
We found solid support for the proposition that bidders come close
to the dominant strategy of truthful revelation in SP sealed bid
auctions, especially with a modest amount of repetition.
To the extent that these results differ from other studies, further
experimental examination of the causes should provide fertile ground for
exploration. We propose a few conjectures for consistency with theory in
SP auctions. Our design is slightly different from previous studies
where the number of bidders was known at the time of submitting a bid.
Not providing the information on the number of bidders may make the
dominant strategy more transparent in our setting and facilitate
subjects to figure out the optimal strategy. There is evidence that not
providing irrelevant information with respect to the decision process
helps subjects concentrate on the essential in SP auctions. For example,
Guth and Ivanova-Stenzel (2003) demonstrate that the lack of commonly
known beliefs about certain features of the game leads to crowding out
of the overbidding in SP auctions. Learning about the number of rivals
may trigger competitiveness in subjects even if this information is
irrelevant for the optimal bidding. The noncomputerized design with
multiple stations in the same round might expedite learning within each
round. Several studies report convergence to a dominant strategy over
time (see Kagel 1995 for a discussion). Cox, Smith, and Walker (1985)
report that in multiple unit, uniform price, sealed bid auctions, only a
minority of the bids were above values. (28)
In the FP auctions the majority of bidders demonstrate a modest
amount of overbidding compared to the risk neutral model and we show
theoretically that this over-bidding is consistent with risk aversion.
The latent class estimation process, which does not make any structural
assumptions on the cause of heterogeneity in bidding, indicates that
heterogeneity persists with experience and yields segment assignments
that are in general consistent with the patterns of estimated individual
and segment risk aversion, especially for experienced bidders. There is
evidence, however, that heterogeneity in bidding is driven by components
beyond the standard model of risk aversion. The segment assignments in
the New = 0, 1 case and the Experienced case are generally consistent
but not identical, indicating heterogeneity that changes with experience
in the institution.
Bidding noise differs across segments and tends to decrease with
experience in both FP and SP auctions. We find that the model converged
to relatively homogeneous behavior in the SP auctions for both the full
and experienced data sets, New = 0, 1 and Experienced, respectively. In
the FP auctions, heterogeneity persisted, while the bidding noise
decreased with experience. One of the characteristics affecting bidding
in the FP auctions is the phenomena of counting the number of bidders,
which is significant in one segment. Segment assignments are also
influenced by the magnitude of bidder specific noise (which is
heterogeneous).
Our results indicate that in the field settings where the number of
bidders is typically unknown, theory provides a good benchmark for
predictions. In the SP auctions bidding coincides with theory while
overbidding remains in the FP auctions. To the extent this phenomenon is
robust, FP auctions would generate higher revenue; in the SP auctions,
the auctioneer may reveal the number of rivals to participants to
increase the level of bidding and therefore expected revenue. These
results provide an interesting menu for further research on auctions
with an unknown number of bidders. Two obvious areas are (1) a switch to
common and affiliated as opposed to independent private values; and (2)
allowing bidders to choose bidding in FP, SP, or ascending auctions
(Ivanova-Stenzel and Salmon 2004) and analyzing comparative performance.
The results presented here also inform the longstanding debate on the
role of risk aversion in FP auction overbidding and bidding
heterogeneity. A study determining the extent to which the factors that
we identified explain heterogeneity would provide a further contribution
to the theory of individual behavior in auctions.
ABBREVIATIONS
AIC: Akaike Information Criteria
BIC: Bayesian Information Criterion
cnAIC: Consistent Akaike Information Criteria
crAIC: Corrected Akaike Information Criterion
EC: Estimation Classification
FP: First Price
LR: Likelihood Ratio
SP: Second Price
doi:10.1111/j. 1465-7295.2011.00393.x
APPENDIX: EXPERIMENTAL INSTRUCTIONS (vSFL.4)
Introduction
This is an experiment in the economics of market decision making.
Depending upon the decisions that you and other participants make, you
have the opportunity to earn a considerable amount of money which will
be paid to you in a check on a research account at the end of the
experiment. Under no circumstances will you leave the experiment owing
money to the experimenters. Your rights as a subject in an experiment
have been explained to you in your sign-in document. Except as you might
be directed in these instructions or by the experimenter, please do not
talk or otherwise communicate with any other participant during the
course of the experiment.
Today's Markets
First, we must mention that from this point on, all dollar amounts,
unless otherwise specified, are "experimental dollars" (E$).
At the end of the experiment, you will earn 25 U.S. cents for each one
experimental dollar that you earn. Thus, if your payoff earnings say
$5.00 (E$), you will actually earn $1.25. If your earnings say $8.00
(E$), you will actually earn $2.00 and so forth. The only amount that
does not get adjusted by this exchange rate is your $7.00 for showing
up. That $7.00 is already guaranteed in U.S. dollars. Therefore, from
this point on, all costs, values, payments profits, and so forth that we
use will be experimental dollars.
Around this room you will see 16 "auction stations." At
each station there is a different hypothetical item for sale by auction.
Each item is known by a letter, which has no other meaning other than to
identify each item. There is exactly one item for sale at each auction
station.
The process for selling each item is as follows. At each station,
there is a foam mug marked with the letter designation for the item for
sale. You have been given your own pad of sticky notes. If you wish to
make a bid to purchase that item, please take a sticky note and write on
it all of the following four items:
* The letter designation of the item, for example, A, B, C, D, E,
F, G, H, I, J, K, L, M, N, O, P
* Your bidder number, for example, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, or 8
* The time as shown on the clock
* Your bid in experimental dollars and cents
Your sticky note bid must have all four items on it to be a valid
bid, and all decisions by the experimenters disqualifying incomplete
bids are final. If you find that you submitted a bid with missing
information, you can at any time submit a complete, second bid. It is
recommended that you fold your completed bid form securely after you
finish writing on it. This will provide a greater degree of privacy.
You may make bids on as many or as few of the 16 items as you like.
You may submit more than one bid on an item. All auctions close at the
same time (7 minutes elapsed time on the official timer). The winning
bidder for each item is the highest bid in the coffee can when time has
expired. The winning bidder pays his/her own bid (that is, the highest
or winning bid) to the experimenter. If there is a tie for highest bid,
one of the experimenters will break the tie using a random number table.
Tie breaking decisions are final and nonnegotiable. Different bidders
may very well bid on different items. A single bidder may win zero, one,
two, several, or even all of the items.
What Are My Values for the Items? How Are They Chosen?
First, it is important to note that each of you begins with a $5.00
initial reserve simply for participating. This is in addition to your
"show up" fee. All earnings from the auction markets are on
top of this $5.00 (remember, all amounts are in experimental dollars).
At the beginning of each auction period, you will be given a
"payoff chart" so that you can keep track of your earnings.
There is a column for each of the 16 items. The next row is labeled
"my value for this item." The number in that row represents
how much we will pay to you if you win the auction for that item. Some
of these entries may be "zero."
If you win the auction for that item, then the following is how
your earnings are calculated:
(MY VALUE - MY WINNING BID)/MY EARNINGS.
If you do not win an item, your earnings at that auction station
are zero.
Suppose, for example, your value for an item was $24.00, and you
won the auction with a bid of $21.40. Then, your earnings would be:
$24.00 - $21.40 = $2.60 (remember, experimental dollars). (These numbers
are for illustrative purposes only and have no meaning for the actual
experiment).
Where do these values come from? That is a very good question. The
values for each item generally differ from one bidder to another. That
is why we used a random process to hand out the folders when you
arrived. Furthermore, each bidder will generally have different values
for different items, and different values for the same item between
periods.
In choosing the values, we first decided for each item in each
period how many bidders would have positive values. We used a random
number process to choose, independently, a number of 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7,
or 8 bidders having positive values. Each number was equally likely.
Then, we used a similar random number process to decide which bidder IDs
would be the bidders with the positive values. Each bidder ID was
equally likely to be chosen for each item. Finally, for those bidder IDs
with positive values on a particular item in a particular period, we
drew a different value number from the set of number $00.01, 00.02, ...,
19.99, 20.00. Each value was equally likely.
Notice that this means there will always be at least two bidders
with positive values for each item.
In other words, consider the G object in round one. First, a random
number process might tell us that three bidders will have positive
values. Then, a second random number process might tell us that the
three bidder IDs to receive the positive values for the G object are 1,
3, and 4. Finally, we would then draw three random values between 00.00
(29) and 20.00, say $0.78 for 1, $2.08 for 3, and $18.74 for 4. All
other bidders would have value $00.00 for G for round one. Different
numbers, IDs, and values would be drawn for each object in each round.
These numbers are hypothetical and have no relation to the actual
numbers drawn, but they illustrate the process we went through for each
object, and each bidder, in every round.
Your earnings in any one period are the sum of all of the earnings
on items you won. Your earnings (in experimental dollars) in the entire
experiment are the sum of your earnings in each period.
Closing Thoughts
As described above the values for the items are likely to be
different from one bidder to another, from one item to another for a
particular bidder, and from one period to another. Recall that these are
chosen independently, so that if you get several very low or very high
values it means nothing for what might happen in the future.
All bidders are expected to cooperate with the rules of the
experiment. By agreeing to participate, you agree to follow the rules,
and you understand that anyone who does not do so may, at the discretion
of the experimenter, be asked to leave the experiment with only the
"show up" fee of $7.00.
It is possible to lose money in an auction. This will occur if you
bid higher than your value on an item and you win the auction. In such a
case, YOUR VALUE - YOUR WINNING BID would be negative. We do not stop
anyone from doing this, however, if you bid less than or equal to your
value, you will never be in a position to lose money. If you do make
decisions such that you lose money, we will subtract it first from your
accumulated earnings, and second from your $5 initial reserve. Any
bidder who loses so much money that he/she has eliminated their
accumulated earnings and their $5.00 initial reserve will be allowed to
remain in the experiment only under a rule that they bid less than or
equal to their value on each item from then on out.
CHANGE IN MARKET PRICE RULE
Until we announce otherwise, we will be using a different rule to
determine the market price (the payment) for the winning bidder in the
auctions, as follows:
The winning bidder for each item remains the highest bid in the
foam cup when time has expired. However, the winning bidder pays to the
experimenter the highest bid submitted by a losing bidder. If there is a
tie for highest bid, one of the experimenters will break the tie using a
random number table. Tie breaking decisions are final and nonnegotiable.
All other aspects of the auctions remain exactly the same as in the
original instructions.
It is still possible to lose money in an auction. This will occur
if three things happen: (1) you bid higher than your value on an item
and (2) you win the auction, and (3) your payment (the highest bid
submitted by a losing bidder) is greater than your value. In such a
case, YOUR VALUE - YOUR PAYMENT would be negative. We do not stop anyone
from doing this, however, if you bid less than or equal to your value,
you will never be in a position to lose money. If you do make decisions
such that you lose money, we will subtract it first from your
accumulated earnings, and second from your $5 initial reserve. Any
bidder who loses so much money that he/she has eliminated their
accumulated earnings and their $5.00 initial reserve will be allowed to
remain in the experiment only under a rule that they bid less than or
equal to their value on each item from then on out.
REFERENCES
Anderson, C. M., and L. Putterman. "Do Non-strategic Sanctions Obey the Law of Demand'? The Demand for Punishment in the Voluntary
Contribution Mechanism." Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 2006,
1-21.
Cooper, D., and H. Fang. "Understanding Overbidding in Second
Price Auctions: An Experimental Study." The Economic Journal, 118,
2008, 1572-95.
Cox, J.C., B. Roberson, and V. L. Smith. "Theory and Behavior
of Single Object Auctions," in Research in Experimental Economics,
Vol. 2, edited by V. L. Smith. Greenwich: JAI Press, 1982.
Cox, J. C., V. L. Smith, and J. M. Walker. "Experimental
Development of Sealed-Bid Auction Theory: Calibrating Controls for Risk
Aversion." American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 75,
1985, 160-65.
--. "Theory and Individual Behavior of First-Price
Auctions." Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 1988, 61-99.
Dyer, D., J. H. Kagel, and D. Levin. "Resolving Uncertainty
about the Number of Bidders in Independent Private- Value Auctions: An
Experimental Analysis." The RAND Journal of Economics, 20(2), 1989,
268-79.
El-Gamal, M., and D. Grether. "Are People Bayesian? Uncovering
Behavioral Strategies." Journal of the American Statistical
Association, 90, 1995, 1137-45.
--. "Changing Decision Rules: Uncovering Behavioral Strategies
Using Estimation Classification (EC)," in Preferences, Beliefs, and
Attributes in Decision Making, edited by M. Machina and B. Munier. New
York: Kluwer, 2000
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R., and E. Katok. "Regret in Auctions:
Theory and Evidence." Economic Theory, 33(1), 2007, 81-101.
--. "Regret and Feedback Information in First-Price Sealed-Bid
Auctions." Management Science, 54(4), 2008, 808-19.
Filiz-Ozbay, E., and E. Y. Ozbay. "Auctions with Anticipated
Regret: Theory and Experiment." American Economic Review, 97(4),
2007, 1407-18.
Guth, W., and R. Ivanova-Stenzel. "Asymmetric Auction
Experiments with(out) Commonly Known Beliefs." Economic Letters,
80, 2003, 195-9.
Harstad, R. M. "Dominant Strategy Adoption and Bidders'
Experience with Pricing Rules." Experimental Economics, 3(3), 2000,
261-80.
Harstad, R. M., J. H. Kagel, and D. Levin. "Equilibrium Bid
Functions for Auctions with an Uncertain Number of Bidders,"
Economics Letters, 33, 1990, 35-40.
Isaac, R. M., and D. James. "Just Who Are You Calling Risk
Averse?" Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 20, 2000a, 177-87.
--. "Robustness of the Incentive Compatible Combinatorial
Auction," Experimental Economics, 3, 2000b, 31-53.
Isaac, R. M., and K. Schnier. "Silent Auctions in the Field
and in the Laboratory," Economic Inquiry, 43(4), 2005, 715-33.
--. "Sealed Bid Variations on the Silent Auction," in
Research in Experimental Economics, Vol. 11, edited by R. M. Isaac and
D. Davis. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2006.
Ivanova-Stenzel, R., and T. Salmon. "Bidder Preferences among
Auction Institutions," Economic Inquiry, 42, 2004, 223-36.
Kagel, J.H. "Auctions: A Survey of Experimental
Research." in The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by J.
H. Kagel and A.E., Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
1995, 501-86.
Krishna, V. Auction Theory. San Diego: Academic Press, 2002.
Levin, D., and E. Ozdenoren. "Auctions with Uncertain Number
of Bidders," Journal of Economic Theory, 118, 2004, 229-51.
Matthews, S. "Comparing Auctions for Risk Averse Buyers: A
Buyer's Point of View," Econometrica, 55(3), 1987, 633-46.
McAfee, R. P., and J. McMillan. "Auctions with a Stochastic Number of Bidders," Journal of Economic Theory, 43, 1987, 1-19.
Milgrom, P. R., and R. J. Weber. "A Theory of Auctions and
Competitive Bidding," Econometrica, 50(5), 1982, 1089-122.
Palfrey, T. R., and S. Pevnitskaya. "Endogenous Entry and
Self-selection in Private Value Auctions: An Experimental Study,"
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 66(3-4), 2008, 731-47.
Schnier, K. E., and C. M. Anderson. "Decision Making in Patchy Resource Environments: Spatial Misperception of Bioeconomic
Models." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 61, 2006,
234-54.
(1.) A recent paper by Levin and Ozdenoren (2004) looks at how
bidders and seller respond to ambiguity about the number of bidders.
(2.) In this article, we model the uncertainty about the number of
bidders in a Bayesian way (i.e., as risk and not as ambiguity). This is
a similar (but more general) framework as in Dyer, Kagel, and Levin
(1989).
(3.) One of our main objectives is therefore to explore the
usefulness of the received theory in an environment that is a closest
approximation of the field; our research is not specifically designed to
test the theory in the sense of giving it its "best shot."
(4.) Krishna's notation is stated in terms of
"'number of other bidders."
(5.) Matthews compares two auction mechanisms for buyers with CARA,
DARA, and IARA preferences.
(6.) Only one winning bidding slip (out of 480) was invalidated of
absent information. In addition, there were six nonwinning bidding slips
invalidated for various reasons of absent or incorrect information whose
status cannot be determined (out of a total of 2,205).
(7.) In order to keep bidders from wanting to pry open the slots in
order to see if they were the only bidder, each mug always contained at
least one yellow bid slip marked "blank." Subjects knew this,
and in fact a volunteer monitor from the population of subjects
(undergraduate students) saw us put one in each mug.
(8.) Isaac and Schnier (2006) used this data to look solely at the
aggregate market revenue and efficiency properties of auctions. The
primary result of Isaac and Schnier (2006) was that the sealed bid
mechanisms yielded both greater revenues and higher aggregate
efficiencies when compared with the traditional ascending silent
auctions. Specifically they find that efficiency was 0.97 for FP and
0.98 for SP auctions and the revenue index (based on risk neutral
theory) was 1.08 for FP auctions and 0.95 for SP auctions. The Isaac and
Schnier paper contains extended descriptions of some of the physical
attributes of the auctions such as geographical distribution of stations
around the room and the construction of bidding mugs.
(9.) Theoretical bid functions were obtained using CRRA utility
function of the form U = [x.sub.r], so r = 1 is risk neutrality.
(10.) A second alternative is that bidders will use a rule of thumb
rather than the nonlinear bid function implied by the theory. The most
obvious candidate is that they will work with the median numbers of
bidders, n = 5, and hence will bid 80% of their value ((n - 1)/n). We
ran a parallel series of estimations to those reported here using this
behavioral benchmark. A later footnote explains their similarity to the
main results.
(11.) New = 1 for the first round decisions with the particular
auction mechanism.
(12.) The likelihood function for the tobit estimation was
programmed in GAUSS and we utilized the MAXLIK toolbox to obtain our
parameter estimates.
(13.) Bidder heterogeneity could be controlled for using either a
fixed-effects or a random-effects tobit regression. However, this
estimation technique would not allow us to determine whether or not
individual subjects (or groups of subjects) possessed alternative
bidding functions which are statistically different from others within
the experiment.
(14.) This method may generate a likelihood function which
possesses a number of local maxima. To ensure that our parameter
estimates are the global maxima we estimate the FP model 2,000 times and
the SP model 500 times using different random starting parameters.
(15.) Detailed estimation results for up to five-segment models for
both data sets are available from the authors upon request.
(16.) The following data were excluded relative to the initial
valid data set. First, we excluded all bids from the second period of
the second FFSSF experiment as one bidder clearly acted upon a
misunderstanding of the instructions. Also we removed 62 bids that
appear to be double bids. These bids are relatively equally split
between the FP (33 out of 1,013) and SP (29 out of 1,050) auctions, and
appear to be mainly mistakes rather than re-bids as about half of them
are decreasing. We have conducted all the tests reported here including
these bids and all of the main conclusions reported here remain
unchanged.
(17.) We also conducted analysis of the relation between the timing
of the bid and valuation and estimated 12 different models. The best
statistical fit came from panel estimations (random effects and fixed
effects for individuals as well as dummy variables for periods) with bid
value entering both directly and in a squared term. In these models the
coefficients on bid value were not statistically significant. In most of
the remaining models (linear time remaining only and/or not accounting
for panel structure) the coefficients on bidder value were statistically
significant but with little in the way of quantitative effect.
Specifically, the results indicate that a $1 increase in bidder
valuation increases the time remaining in the auction by between 0.73
and 1.56 seconds (the maximum possible acceleration for the whole
interval of valuations therefore being on the order of 30 seconds in a
7-minute period). This indicates that most subjects do not attempt to
wait and count the number of bidders on their high value items. If
anything, they are submitting bids on their higher valued items a few
seconds earlier.
(18.) We report results in terms of experimental dollars (one
experimental dollar was .25). The bidder who had misunderstood the
instructions in an early round was subsequently in the first stage of
our bankruptcy rule. which restricted bidding over value. This was the
only bidder to enter any stage of the bankruptcy rule. Removing all the
data for this bidder yields revelation percentages that are actually
higher, 53.26% (exact) and 71.86% (within 25 cents), respectively. This
bidder persistently bid below value in the SP auctions.
(19.) This result is robust in our study and is not driven by
previous experience in FP auctions. When we separately analyze bidding
in SP auctions prior to exposure to FP auction in the SSFFS treatment
(dropping New data) we still find that 82.79% of bids are within 25
cents of valuation.
(20.) In fact, the tight fit of the data to the theoretical model
apparently caused problematic convergence in GAUSS for even the
single-segment model. The estimates we report in that one case are
instead from a STATA estimation.
(21.) The t test yielded a value of 0.702.
(22.) The t test yielded a value of 0.692.
(23.) The t tests yielded values of 10.294 and 5.161 for h = 1 and
h = 2, respectively.
(24.) We bad originally considered what we termed a "rule of
thumb" or "behavioral" alternative model for bidding in
the FP auctions, namely that bidders would bid the Nash equilibrium bid
as though they were in the median size group (N = 5). The risk neutral
equilibrium version would be a bid of 0.8 times value. Overbidding would
be transparently consistent with risk aversion just as in the standard
literature. As it turns out, the results using this behavioral
alternative are qualitatively very similar to those we presented here.
The results with the linear approximation do indicate a better fit in
that the constant terms are smaller and less significant, and they have
slightly larger log-likelihood. However, the change does nothing to
eliminate the apparent overbidding with respect to the prediction, in
fact, with respect to the behavioral benchmark, the estimated
overbidding is even worse. Furthermore the classification schemes are
very close.
(25.) The next smallest p value is 0.31 in Segment 1.
(26.) Harstad (2000) reports that subjects may transfer the
experience from one auction mechanism to the other. To check for the
order effect, we test for possible differences in heterogeneity along
with the level of bidding in FP auctions between the two experimental
design sequences. First, using the structural estimation of individual
risk preference parameters (that are indicative of the level of
overbidding) we construct a distribution of risk parameters (bidding
propensities) for each sequence using 11 bins range (ten risk averse
bins with the step 0.1 and one nonrisk averse bin). A chi-square test
cannot reject the hypothesis that two samples come from a common
distribution. A second test relates the possible effect of sequencing to
our core results, the latent class estimation. Because of the known
effect of experience and the more robust latent classification in the FP
results, we use the experienced FP (four-segment) classification for
analysis. We conducted a two-sample chi-squared test of observed
frequencies. The null hypothesis is that assignments to the four
categories are the same for the FFSSF individuals as for the SSFFS
individuals. The difference is not significant with the Yates correction
as a result of the fact that we only observe integral values.
(27.) As discussed earlier the five-segment model created a fifth
segment consisting of just subject 7, the "outlier." We have
elected to focus on the four-segment model to provide a conservative
profile of segmentation.
(28.) Specifically, 33% of bids of inexperienced subjects and 15%
of bids of experienced subjects were above value.
(29.) We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out the typo in
the Instructions. Note that unlike the statement in the previous
paragraph, the lowest possible value is listed as 00.00, not 00.01. A
value of 00.00 has never been drawn for the active bidder.
Isaac: Department of Economics, Florida State University,
Tallahassee, FL 32306. Phone (850) 644-7081, Fax (850) 644-4535, E-mail
misaac@fsu.edu
Pevnitskaya: Department of Economics, Florida State University,
Tallahassee, FL 32306. Phone (850) 645-1525, Fax (850) 644-4535, E-mail
spevnitskaya@fsu.edu
Schnier: Department of Economics, Andrew Young School of Policy
Studies, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA 30303. Phone (404)
413-0159, E-mail kschnier@gsu.edu
TABLE 1
Experimental Design
Number of
Institution Sessions Period 1 Period 2 Period 3
FFSSF 3 First price First price Second price
SSFFS 3 Second price Second price First price
Institution Period 4 Period 5
FFSSF Second price First price
SSFFS First price Second price
TABLE 2
Latent Class Regressions-Second-Price
Auction (a)
New = (0,1) Experienced
Variable H = 1 H = 1
Constant 0.0292 (0.14) -0.0791 (-0.981)
Value 1.0071 ** (99.01) 1.0027 ** (259.677)
Number -0.0188 (-0.61) 0.0029 (0.242)
New -0.1746 (-0.52)
New x Value -0.0939 ** (-5.91)
New x Number 0.0818 (1.61)
[[sigma].sup.2] 1.4789 0.5617
Number in segment 48 48
Log-Likelihood -1.887.89 -604.33
(a) t-Statistics for the regression coefficients are shown in
parentheses.
* Statistically significant at 90% confidence, t test.
** Statistically significant at 95% confidence, t test.
TABLE 3
Latent Class Regressions-First-Price Auction: Three-Segment Model
(New = 0,1) (a)
Homogeneous
Variable H=1 H=3;h=1
Constant 0.9389 ** (2.52) 1.2590 ** (6.13)
Predicted 1.0351 ** (46.242) 1.1400 ** (83.73)
Number 0.0125 (-0.22) -0.0066 (-0.22)
New 1.1010 ** (2.00) -0.0518 (-0.17)
New x Predicted -0.1834 ** (-5.34) 0.0175 (0.92)
New x Number -0.1153 (-1.37) 0.0005 (0.01)
[[sigma].sup.2] 2.5762 0.6613
Number in segment 48 12
Log-likelihood -2,393.01
Heterogenous
Variable H=3;h=2 H=3;h=3
Constant 0.4552 * (1.733) 0.8617 (1.733)
Predicted 1.0800 ** (69.66) 0.9076 ** (18.43)
Number 0.0605 (1.55) 0.0524 (0.37)
New 0.3452 (2.19) 1.4123 (0.91)
New x Predicted -0.0819 ** (-3.45) -0.5219 ** (-6.14
New x Number -0.0685 (-1.19) -0.0011 (-0.00)
[[sigma].sup.2] 1.2342 3.3138
Number in segment 23 13
Log-likelihood -1,795.94
(a) t-Statistics for the regression coefficients are shown in
parentheses.
* Statistically significant at 90% confidence, t test.
** Statistically significant at 95% confidence, t test.
TABLE 4
Latent Class Regressions-First-Price Auction: Four-Segment
Model (Experienced) (a)
Homogeneous
Variable H=1 H=4;h=1
Constant 0.9438 ** (3.15) 0.9664 ** (5.06)
Predicted 1.0349 ** (56.987) 1.1102 ** (100.94)
Number 0.0120 (0.270) -0.0292 (-1.03)
[[sigma].sup.2] 2.0899 0.7113
Number in segment 48 17
Log-likelihood -1,223.38
Heterogeneous
Variable H=4;h=2 H=4;h=3
Constant 0.2213 (0.68) 0.6209 (1.33)
Predicted 1.0501 ** (53.08) 0.6359 ** (8.34)
Number 0.1069 ** (2.25) 0.1252 (0.62)
[[sigma].sup.2] 1.3221 3.4998
Number in segment 15 4
Log-likelihood -827.38
Variable H=4;h=4
Constant 1.2066 ** (7.16)
Predicted 1.1547 ** (99.67)
Number -0.0043 (-0.17)
[[sigma].sup.2] 0.5690
Number in segment 12
Log-likelihood
(a) t-Statistics for the regression coefficients are shown in
parentheses.
* Statistically significant at 90% confidence, t test.
** Statistically significant at 95% confidence, t test.
TABLE 5
Contingency Table of Assignments (As a Result of Arbitrary Assignment
of Segment Numbers We Order the Segments in Increasing r)
First-Price Auction
(Experienced)
Segment 4 Segment 1
(r- = 0.205) (r = 0.375)
First-Price Segment 1 (r = 0.205) 10 2
Auction Segment 2 (r = 0.515) 0 12
(New = 0, 1) Segment 3 (r = 0.985) 2 3
Total 12 17
First-Price Auction
(Experienced)
Segment 2 Segment 3
(r = 0.505) (r = 1.505)
First-Price Segment 1 (r = 0.205) 0 0
Auction Segment 2 (r = 0.515) 11 0
(New = 0, 1) Segment 3 (r = 0.985) 4 4
Total 15 4
Total
First-Price Segment 1 (r = 0.205) 12
Auction Segment 2 (r = 0.515) 23
(New = 0, 1) Segment 3 (r = 0.985) 13
Total 48
TABLE 6
Estimates of Individual Risk Preference
Parameters
Experienced New = 0 and 1
Bid ID r SD N r SD N
1 1.125 2.223 20 1.515 2.854 27
2 0.805 0.622 14 0.965 0.885 23
3 2.375 1.957 19 2.545 1.765 27
4 0.425 0.973 19 0.425 4.546 30
5 0.205 0.718 20 0.195 0.722 28
6 0.515 1.173 15 0.565 2.001 24
7 27.3 4.370 18 34.90 3.731 25
8 0.295 2.372 19 0.865 2.242 27
9 0.285 0.284 11 0.355 2.836 17
10 0.295 0.524 7 1.395 2.582 16
11 0.185 0.567 9 1.025 1.428 18
12 0.615 0.419 10 0.705 2.589 18
13 0.385 1.118 10 0.455 0.962 23
14 0.425 1.191 9 1.345 3.245 20
15 0.285 0.370 9 0.535 0.769 19
16 0.385 0.683 10 0.675 1.581 17
17 0.505 0.432 21 0.515 1.854 27
18 0.595 0.923 13 0.575 0.898 21
19 0.265 0.581 18 0.335 5.681 26
20 0.235 1.310 19 0.315 2.151 30
21 0.505 0.731 16 0.515 0.987 23
22 0.785 0.748 17 0.785 0.744 27
23 0.895 2.413 17 0.995 2.441 27
24 0.255 1.577 21 0.415 1.409 32
25 0.135 0.213 7 0.135 0.233 16
26 0.345 0.601 10 0.335 0.607 20
27 0.045 0.152 7 0.035 0.144 19
28 0.455 0.741 6 0.455 0.753 7
29 0.515 0.573 7 0.515 0.548 15
30 0.565 1.129 9 0.725 0.910 23
31 0.355 0.418 9 0.265 0.988 20
32 0.305 0.461 11 0.275 0.403 19
33 0.515 1.273 7 0.465 0.895 16
34 0.265 1.885 11 0.265 1.373 21
35 0.115 0.246 7 0.105 0.193 19
36 0.625 2.751 9 0.865 5.797 19
37 0.105 1.074 7 0.125 0.727 15
38 0.235 0.134 9 0.205 0.267 22
39 0.265 0.792 9 0.315 1.389 20
40 0.505 1.552 10 0.505 1.306 17
41 0.145 0.406 7 0.185 0.410 15
42 0.255 0.404 11 0.215 0.362 21
43 0.325 0.861 6 0.515 0.864 18
44 0.295 0.821 12 0.315 0.681 24
45 0.525 0.601 7 0.515 0.459 13
46 0.235 0.274 9 0.235 0.341 23
47 0.985 1.188 9 0.695 1.387 19
48 0.235 0.264 11 0.255 2.004 20
All 0.375 2.205 568 0.455 2.846 1,013
TABLE 7
Risk Preference Parameters by Segments (Segments Are Ordered in
Increasing r for Presentation; N, Number of Observations)
Experienced New = 0 and 1
Bid ID r SD N r SD N
All 0.375 2.205 568 All 0.455 2.846 1,013
Segment 4 0.205 0.738 117 Segment 1 0.205 0.652 238
Segment 1 0.375 0.636 177 Segment 2 0.515 1.316 476
Segment 2 0.505 1.423 200 Segment 3 0.985 4.162 299
Segment 3 1.505 3.824 74