Information, institutions, and banking sector development in West Africa.
Demetriades, Panicos ; Fielding, David
I. INTRODUCTION
Banks and other financial intermediaries can perform an important
developmental function, especially in Africa, where alternative sources
of finance are limited or nonexistent. By providing firms with essential
finance, they help them to take advantage of productive investment
opportunities which may not otherwise materialize. By screening loan
applicants, they can help to address adverse selection in the credit
market and channel funds toward productive uses. By monitoring
borrowers, they can contain moral hazard behavior, for example,
excessively risky investment activity that could undermine a
borrower's ability to repay a loan. Through long-term bank-borrower
relationships, well-established banks can address both adverse selection
and moral hazard. This not only helps banks to remain solvent but also
ensures that bank finance is channeled toward productive and sound
investments.
There is a large body of empirical evidence which suggests that the
development of banking systems goes hand in hand with economic
development (see, e.g., Levine 2004). Although the evidence on causality is mixed (see, e.g., Demetriades and Hussein 1996), there is broad
consensus that well-functioning banking systems promote economic growth
(Demetriades and Andrianova 2005). It is, therefore, a puzzle that so
many countries remain financially underdeveloped. This is particularly
true of Sub-Saharan Africa, which remains one of the most financially
under-developed regions in the world. A recent study by the World Bank
has shown that African banking systems lack depth compared to other
regions in the world, but are also excessively liquid (Honohan and Beck
2007). According to the World Bank, banks themselves complain that there
is a lack of creditworthy borrowers, while at the same time households
and firms find finance to be a major constraint. The evidence presented
by the World Bank also suggests that the least developed banking systems
are also the most liquid, suggesting that excess liquidity is a common
feature of financial under-development.
This article aims to shed light on these features of financial
under-development in Africa, utilizing a panel data set comprising the
banks operating in the West African Economic and Monetary Union (UEMOA)
during 2000-2005. The UEMOA provides a uniform financial system across
eight countries; the structure of this system has changed little in the
last 15 years. Therefore, we can be sure that the variations in bank
behavior we observe within the UEMOA are not because of variations in
the nature of public financial institutions which the banks face. This
makes feasible the identification of the institutional sources of the
variations in bank behavior, which are not correlated with variations in
the quality of public financial institutions.
Our data set includes balance sheet information on each bank in the
UEMOA, including bank characteristics such as age and ownership type,
profitability, and the number of urban and rural branches. We also
utilize country-level data on loan defaults, which provides information
on the average quality of borrowers; we use this as a proxy for the
severity of information problems faced by banks in the credit market. We
combine this information with macroeconomic data including institutional
quality indices constructed by the World Bank. Our data set enables us
to examine the extent to which informational and institutional factors,
and interactions between different factors, can explain a bank's
loans to assets ratio, which is an inverse measure of bank liquidity.
Our data set is also used to examine the microeconomic and macroeconomic
determinants of the total volume of assets of an individual bank, which
is a good micro-level indicator of overall banking sector development.
Our results suggest that to a large extent financial under
development, including excess liquidity and low banking sector
development, can be attributed to severe informational problems. These
problems are particularly acute for younger banks; older, more
established banks are less affected. These results highlight the
importance of information capital in both developing banking systems and
reducing excess liquidity. Our results suggest that it is not so much
the lack of creditworthy borrowers that is the obstacle for financial
development, but the lack of a developed infrastructure that would
enable new banks to screen and monitor borrowers. This result is
consistent with evidence on the importance of credit registries in
reducing credit constraints (Galindo and Miller 2001). Our results also
indicate that banking sector development in Africa does indeed follow
economic development, but that it is also particularly sensitive to
political stability and the rule of law.
This article is structured as follows. Section II reviews the
institutional setting within which commercial banks in the UEMOA
operate, and provides the conceptual background for our analysis.
Section III describes the data and modeling strategy. Section IV
presents and discusses the empirical findings. Section V summarizes and
concludes.
II. COMMERCIAL BANKING IN THE UEMOA
The UEMOA is a monetary union arising from the final phase of
French colonialism in West Africa (1948-1962), and encompasses most of
France's former colonies in the area. The current member states are
Benin, Burkina Faso, Cote d'Ivoire, Guinea-Bissau, Mali, Niger,
Senegal, and Togo. It forms part of the Franc Zone, the other main
component of which is a second monetary union, the Economic and Monetary
Community of Central Africa (CEMAC). Both monetary unions have a central
bank issuing a currency that the French Treasury guarantees to exchange
for Euros at a fixed rate. The two currencies are both called the CFA
Franc, (1) but they are entirely separate. The arrangements that the two
monetary unions have with the French Treasury are parallel but entirely
independent of each other.
The enduring institutional link with the former colonial power
gives the UEMOA countries an unusually high level of financial
stability, compared to other African countries with similar levels of
economic development. The institutional framework is defined by a
constitutional accord dating from the period in which the colonies
became fully independent (1960-1962), and preserving many of the
features of the financial system of post-war French colonial Africa. The
main features are as follows:
(i) Guaranteed convertibility. Article 1 of the accord stipulates
that France will help UEMOA member states to ensure the free
convertibility of their currency. In practice, this means that the
French Treasury will exchange CFA Francs for Euros on demand. Lending by
the BCEAO (the UEMOA central bank) to domestic governments and to the
private sector is now limited by rules designed to prevent free-tiding
on the French guarantee.
(ii) A fixed exchange rate. Up until 1994, Article 2 of the accord
stipulated a fixed rate of 50 CFA Francs to one French Franc. The rate
has been changed only once, to 100:1, in January 1994. The entry of
France into the European Monetary Union means that the rate is now
defined in terms of Euros, but the current Euro rate is equivalent to
100:1 against the French Franc.
(iii) Free transferability. Article 6 of the accord describes the
"freedom of financial relations between France and members of the
Union." This obligation on the part of the African states is not
without qualification, and the practice of member states has not always
been in harmony with the principle. International capital transfers are
taxed, and occasionally (especially during the run-up to the devaluation in 1993) the transferability has been suspended. Nevertheless, there is
usually a reasonable degree of capital mobility between the UEMOA and
France.
(iv) Harmonization of rules governing currency exchange. Article 6
of the accord notes that the "uniform regulation of the external
financial relations of member states ... will be maintained in harmony
with that of the French Republic." These regulations cover such
things as the remittance of salaries abroad (that is, outside the Franc
Zone), foreign investment, and borrowing from abroad.
(v) A common regulatory framework. Regulation of the banking system
is the responsibility of the UEMOA Banking Commission, which was created
in 1990 with French technical support. The commission has oversight over
the day-to-day activities of all banks and other financial institutions
in the UEMOA, and has the power to intervene in the operations of
individual banks when its rules are infringed. In the case of serious
infractions, the commission can impose disciplinary sanctions of
differing degrees of severity, ranging from a formal warning to the
dismissal of senior bank officials and suspension of a bank's
activities. Commission staff produce regular reports on the extent of
compliance with UEMOA banking regulations; the loan default data used in
this article are taken from statistics compiled by the Banking
Commission.
The financial stability provided by these institutions means that
commercial banks in the UEMOA are free from some of the uncertainties
facing financial institutions in other parts of Africa; the same is true
of depositors. However, other risks remain. Firstly, many banks face a
serious adverse selection problem arising from a low average level of
borrowers' creditworthiness. In our sample, the average rate of
default on bank loans exceeds 10%, which is very high by international
standards. In theory, this should depress the equilibrium volume of
loans (Stiglitz and Weiss 1981, 1983), particularly in markets where
credit bureaus are in their infancy like in most of Africa. Existing
evidence indicates that the magnitude of the problem varies considerably
across countries and over time (e.g., Fuentes and Maquieira 2001;
Koopman, Lucas, and Klaassen 2005). In our own sample, the default rate
sometimes dips below 5%, while it occasionally exceeds 30%. Secondly,
corruption could make loans less profitable, if it means that banks are
forced to ignore the commercial worth and riskiness of projects they
finance for the political elite. Direct evidence of such corruption in
Kenya is discussed by Bigsten and Moene (1996), and evidence for a link
between the corruption of bank officials and the productivity of
investments is discussed by Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2005).
Such corruption may reduce the loans-assets ratio, and may also depress
asset and liability growth.
Moreover, the quality of contract enforcement and overall political
stability in the country could affect the extent of moral hazard that
banks face when making loans. Institutions promoting the rule of law are
likely to enhance banks' ability to enforce loan contracts and may
therefore increase a bank's willingness to lend and its ability to
grow (Messick 1999), even at low levels of average borrower quality.
These institutions could act as a deterrent to moral hazard behavior by
borrowers, helping to limit the number as well as the cost of bad loans.
Governments of some UEMOA countries have enacted legislation to
facilitate the recovery of bad debts of individual banks (e.g., the
Banque de l'Habitat du Mali); however, such support for banks is by
no means universal.
These factors must be interpreted bearing in mind that many of the
banks in our sample are very young. For 25% of our observations, the age
of the bank is 7 years or less. For very young banks, raising deposits
is likely to be easier than identifying creditworthy borrowers. Older
banks are likely to have more information capital so that their ability
to screen loan applicants is likely to be better than that of younger
banks. The adverse selection problem is likely to be more acute for
younger banks, at any given average quality of borrowers. Very young
banks may therefore opt to channel most of their resources into building
up their deposit base, while their liabilities might in the first
instance be transformed into foreign assets or claims on government and
other domestic financial institutions rather than into business loans.
Therefore, we expect that very young banks will have a lower
loans-assets ratio than older, more established banks, ceteris paribus.
We might also expect younger banks to exhibit more sensitivity to
borrowers' propensity to default than older banks: a higher
national default rate imposes more of a cost for younger banks who find
it more difficult to screen customers.
Age is not the only factor that might affect banks'
sensitivity to the propensity to default. Banks owned (or partly owned)
by the government might have access to better ways to screen potential
customers, as might foreign-owned banks. Banks that are operating
intensively in provincial areas outside the financial capital of the
country, where infrastructure of all kinds is likely to be weaker, may
find customers more difficult to screen effectively. It is also possible
that some of the idiosyncratic variation in screening efficiency is
correlated with observable bank characteristics, such as profitability.
Higher levels of risk are one explanation for a relatively low
ratio of loans to assets in Africa, and risk represents one channel
through which corruption, rule of law, and political stability could
affect banking performance. Of course, it is not the only channel. For
example, Barth, Caprio, and Levine (2004) indicate that there is a
positive association between a high level of government corruption and
the existence of excessively strong supervisory agencies, severe
restrictions on bank activities and barriers to entry that limit banking
competition. However, all of these effects reinforce the mechanisms we
have already described, either by reducing the profitability of loans or
by creating a monopolistic incentive for banks to limit the quantity of
loans in order to increase profits.
All of these factors are relevant to most African countries.
However, in most African countries they are correlated with financial or
monetary stability, and are therefore difficult to identify precisely.
This is less of a problem in our sample as we restrict our attention to
banks in the member states of the UEMOA in the period 2000-2005, where
the quality of the financial system is uniform over time: there has been
no major revision of UEMOA legislation in this period. It is also
uniform across countries: there is a single authority--the Banking
Commission--responsible for regulating all banks in the monetary union.
We can therefore be confident that the effects we identify are not
because of variations in financial or monetary stability but due to
variations in the quality of governance.
III. DATA AND METHODOLOGY
A. Data
The loans and assets data used in our econometric model are taken
from the annual BCEAO publication Bilans des Banques et Etablissements
Financiers. (2) These data are used to construct two dependent variables
for bank i in year t: the loans-assets ratio ([RATIO.sub.it]) and the
logarithm of real assets ([ASSETS.sub.it]). Annual data are available
for 113 banks in the UEMOA over the period 2000-2005: 15 in Benin, 14 in
Burkina Faso, 27 in Cote d'Ivoire, 2 in Guinea-Bissau, 16 in Mali,
11 in Niger, 17 in Senegal, and 11 in Togo. This is not a balanced
panel, because some banks came into existence during the sample period;
with lags and differencing, 87 banks remain in the sample.
[RATIO.sub.it] is constructed as the ratio of commercial loans
("creances sur la clientele") to total assets ("total de
l'actif"). ln([ASSETS.sub.it]) is constructed as the log of
total assets deflated by the consumer price index reported in the BCEAO
Annuaire Statistique.
The econometric model also incorporates a number of explanatory variables, as follows. The countrywide default rate facing a bank in
country j in year t ([DEFAULT.sub.jt]) is the ratio of the total bad
debt of all commercial banks in the country to the total commercial
lending of those banks. The figures for bad debt ("credits en
souffrance") are taken from the UEMOA Banking Commission's
Rapport Annuel. Data on the fraction of bank capital owned by the
government ([GOVERNMENT.sub.it]) and foreigners ([FOREIGN.sub.it]), and
on the number of years each bank has been in operation by year t
([AGE.sub.it]), are taken from the BCEAO publication Annuaire des
Banques et Etablissements Financiers de l'UEMOA, as are data on the
number of branches outside the financial capital ([PROVINCIAL.sub.it]).
Data on bank profitability ([PROFITABILITY.sub.it]), measured as the
ratio of profits to turnover, are taken from the Bilans des Banques et
Etablissements Financiers. (3)
Data on the log of total real GDP in the country in which a bank is
operating ([GDP.sub.jt]) are taken from the Annuaire Statistique; this
is likely to be a correlate of the total asset volume of the banks of
the country, because higher income will induce higher asset demand.
In order to capture the effects of variation in country-specific
institutions that may impact on contract enforcement relevant for
lending, we make use of the indicators reported in the World Bank World
Governance Indicators. These indicators are described and discussed by
Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2007). Our measure of the extent to
which a country is corruption-free is the "control of
corruption" index in World Governance Indicators. There are several
different governance indicators that may be associated with ease of
contract enforcement: "rule of law," "voice and
accountability," "political stability," "government
effectiveness," and "regulatory quality." These
indicators are quite highly correlated with each other, so it does not
make sense to include them all in a single regression equation. However,
there are no strong a priori grounds for supposing that one particular
indicator is an especially good measure of the extent to which banks are
protected from moral hazard effects. The methodology section that
follows explains how we deal with the multicollinearity of the
governance indicators.
Descriptive statistics for the variables in our model are presented
in Table 1, while Figures 1-3 depict some of our key variables. Note
that the governance variables are normalized, so that the mean of each
is equal to zero across a worldwide sample. Negative means in our sample
indicate that the UEMOA countries perform below the worldwide average in
terms of governance, despite their financial stability.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
On average, the ratio of loans to assets is 56.7%, which is low by
international standards, and the ratio of defaults to total loans is
14.3%, which is high by international standards. The standard deviations
around these two means are quite high, providing useful variation in the
data. Correspondingly, the range of both variables is substantial:
0.00-0.96 for the loans to assets ratio and 0.05-0.42 for the default
rate. The variation in the two dependent variables is shown in the
histograms in Figures 1-2. It can be seen from Figure 1 that a majority
of banks lend between 40% and 70% of their assets. However, there is
also a substantial fraction lending over 80%, and some lending less than
20%. Figure 2 shows a similarly wide dispersion in asset levels.
There is substantial variation in the bank ownership variables:
some banks are wholly government or foreign owned, while others are
owned by the domestic private sector. Somewhat surprisingly, there is
also substantial variability in the governance indicators over time, as
shown in Figure 3. Annual changes in individual governance variables are
often a large fraction of one unit (the worldwide variance in each of
the variables). Political stability is the most variable governance
indicator, but annual changes in the others are not always trivially
small.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
B. Methodology
The discussion in Section II suggests that banks' willingness
to lend depends on aggregate credit market conditions, particularly
borrower creditworthiness and the quality of contract enforcement, and
on individual bank characteristics that capture a bank's
informational capital, such as bank age and the location of its
branches. We conjecture that the loans-assets ratio (RATIO) is
decreasing in the loan default rate in a country (DEFAULT), and
increasing in the quality of governance (as captured by the governance
indicators), bank profitability (PROFITABILITY), and bank age (AGE). Age
and other bank characteristics (GOVERNMENT; FOREIGN; PROVINCIAL) may
also affect the impact of borrower creditworthiness, so various
interaction terms in DEFAULT are included in our RATIO regression
equation. Because we are using panel data, we also allow for both fixed
and time effects as well as persistence in the dependent variable. Given
that the governance indicators are quite highly correlated with each
other (see Table 1), we avoid fitting a model with more than one such
indicator. Because we have no strong a priori view on which of these
indicators best captures the contract enforcement effect, we report
results with all six indicators entered one at a time in the model.
Thus, our model for the loan to assets ratio is as follows:
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Here, i [member of] j indicates the ith bank in the jth country,
and t indicates the year. The [alpha] and [beta] parameters capture time
and bank fixed effects, and u is a regression residual. (4) GOVERNANCE
is measured by one of the six governance indicators. Note that
GOVERNMENT, FOREIGN, and PROVINCIAL appear only in interaction terms,
not as linearly separable effects. This is because in our sample they do
not exhibit any substantial variation over time, and so are collinear with the bank fixed effects. (5)
Our second model is designed to explain variations in the logarithm
of real assets. Our modeling strategy is similar to the one above, but
the assets model contains one additional effect: we control for the size
of the economy in which a bank is operating, as measured by ln(GDP).
However, interaction terms in GOVERNMENT, FOREIGN, and PROVINCIAL are
never statistically significant in the assets regressions, and are
excluded from the models reported below; the same is true of
PROFITABILITY. Our assets regressions take the following form:
(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
In estimating the parameters in a dynamic panel model such as
Equation (1) or (2), we need to allow for the fact that the lagged
dependent variable--[RATIO.sub.it - 1] or ln[(ASSETS).sub.it - 1]--will
be correlated with the error term [u.sub.it]. Moreover, [DEFAULT.sub.jt]
and [PROFITABILITY.sub.it] may also be endogenous and correlated with
[u.sub.it]. OLS estimates of the parameters will therefore be biased.
Arellano and Bond (1991) propose a GMM estimator that takes into account
the endogeneity of the lagged dependent variable. Firstly, we can take
differences of Equation (1) to account for country fixed effects:
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The same can be done with Equation (2). For any bank i and any year
t, [RATIO.sub.it - 2] will be a valid instrument for
[DELTA][RATIO.sub.it - 1], because as long as [u.sub.it] is serially
uncorrelated, [RATIO.sub.it - 2] will be orthogonal to
[DELTA][u.sub.it]. In fact, all the other lags back to [RATIO.sub.i2000]
will be orthogonal to [DELTA][u.sub.it], which gives us a whole set of
moment conditions with which to identify the parameter [rho] :
[RATIO.sub.i2000] is orthogonal to [DELTA][u.sub.i2002],
[RATIO.sub.i2000] and [RATIO.sub.i2001] are orthogonal to
[DELTA][u.sub.i2003], and so on. (6) Following Blundell and Bond (1998),
we can take the GMM approach a step further: because [RATIO.sub.it] is
stationary, we can treat Equations (1) and (3) as a system and make use
of the orthogonality of [u.sub.it] to [DELTA][RATIO.sub.it - 2], and to
other lags back to [DELTA][RATIO.sub.i2000], to help identify [rho].
We still need to identify the [delta] and [eta] parameters in our
model, bearing in mind the potential endogeneity of
[PROFITABILITY.sub.it] and [DEFAULT.sub.jt]. In the results reported
below, identification is achieved by using moment conditions analogous to those used to identify [rho], rather than by fitting separate
equations for [PROFITABILITY.sub.it] and [DEFAULT.sub.jt] using some set
of instrumental variables. We impose the restriction that lags of
[PROFITABILITY.sub.it] and [DEFAULT.sub.jt] (including the interaction
terms) are orthogonal to [DELTA][u.sub.it], and that lags of
[DELTA][PROFITABILITY.sub.it] and [DELTA][DEFAULT.sub.jt] are orthogonal
to [u.sub.it]. In the Appendix, we explore the consequences of
identifying the parameters by using standard instrumental variables.
This alternative strategy produces results that are qualitatively very
similar to the ones that we now discuss.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Tables 2 and 3 contain the main empirical results of this article:
Table 2 reports the results of fitting Equation (1) to our data and
Table 3 reports the results of fitting Equation (2).
The diagnostic statistics in Table 2 provide evidence of the
appropriateness of the estimator and the validity of the instruments
used. The Sargan test does not reject the over-identification
restrictions. The residual autocorrelation tests reject the null of no
first order serial correlation but do not reject the null of no second
order serial correlation, confirming that the residual series prior to
differencing are white noise processes.
In Table 2, the lagged dependent variable is positive and highly
significant, suggesting considerable persistence and underlining the
appropriateness of a dynamic panel model. The coefficients on the lagged
dependent variable (in the range 0.7-0.75) indicate that the half-life
of a temporary shock to the loans to assets ratio is about 2 years. When
the following paragraphs mention coefficient magnitudes, these indicate
the immediate impact of each explanatory variable. With a lagged
dependent variable coefficient of 0.75, the eventual effect of a
permanent change in an explanatory variable would be four times higher.
There is strong evidence that default rates represent a major
obstacle to bank lending in the UEMOA. Estimates of the [[eta].sub.0]
coefficient in Equation (1) are negative and significant in all six
versions of the model (one for each governance indicator). This
coefficient indicates the effect of the default rate on the loans to
assets ratio of a privately owned bank in its first year of operation
with branches only in the financial capital of its country. The
coefficient is very large: estimates of [[eta].sub.0] range from -1.51
to -1.22. In our sample, the standard deviation of DEFAULT is 8.5
percentage points, so a two standard deviation increase in this variable
entails a 20-25 percentage point reduction in the loans to assets ratio.
Over the sample period, average default rates range from 8.3 percentage
points in Burkina to 34.6 percentage points in Togo; using our estimates
of [[eta].sub.0], this spread entails a 30-40 percentage point
difference in the average loans to asset ratio. In fact, the difference
between Burkina's average ratio and Togo's is only 13
percentage points, because the [[eta].sub.0] coefficient does not
represent the effect of DEFAULT on the average bank. The various
interaction terms in DEFAULT indicate that the effects of loan defaults
(i) diminish with bank age (ii) increase with the number of provincial
branches, and (iii) are much smaller for government-owned or
foreign-owned banks.
Because so many of the interaction terms in Table 2 are
statistically significant, individual default coefficients are not in
themselves very meaningful. However, computation of different linear
combinations of the interaction terms (and of corresponding standard
errors using the Delta Method) permits the following observations.
Firstly, consider a private bank with no provincial branches. If the
bank is completely new, then the DEFAULT effect is given by the
coefficient [[eta].sub.0]. As the bank ages the DEFAULT effect
diminishes, and for banks older than 35-40 years the effect is
insignificantly different from zero. Now consider a bank with 35
provincial branches (the maximum observed in the sample). For a
completely new bank, the DEFAULT effect is approximately twice as large
as for a bank with no provincial branches, and although age diminishes
the effect, it is still statistically significant at age 50. At this
age, the DEFAULT effect is roughly the same as for a completely new bank
with no provincial branches, that is, [[eta].sub.0].
Now consider a bank that is partly government or foreign owned.
Because the GOVERNMENT and FOREIGN interaction terms have positive
coefficients, the DEFAULT effect for a young bank with some government
or foreign ownership is smaller, although still significantly negative.
However, the effect is positive for very old banks with a very high
share of government or foreign ownership. For a bank owned completely by
the government, or for a bank with at least a 70% foreign ownership
share, the DEFAULT effect is significantly greater than zero at age 50.
In other words, there may be some banks which increase their loans to
assets ratio in the presence of high default rates, although most do
not. A riskier environment deters most banks from lending a large share
of their assets to domestic customers, but there are a few
banks--perhaps the ones with most informational capital--which partially
fill the resulting vacuum in the market.
As anticipated, all of the governance indicators have a positive
and highly significant effect. The coefficients range from 0.04
(political stability) to 0.09 (government effectiveness). That is, a
unit increase in the indicator is associated with an increase in the
loans to assets ratio of between 4 and 9 percentage points. One unit
corresponds to one standard deviation in the worldwide sample, although
the standard deviations in our sample are a little smaller. At the mean
sample value of the default rate (14 percentage points), a one standard
deviation increase in the governance indicator has roughly the same
effect on the loans to assets ratio as transferring the bank from
private control to government or foreign control.
The impact of age on the loans to assets ratio depends on the value
of DEFAULT. At the minimum sample default rate (5%), the derivative of
the ratio with respect to age is insignificantly different from zero; at
the maximum sample value of DEFAULT (42%), the derivative is slightly
below 0.01, and significantly greater than zero. Age matters only when
default rates are high. At the highest default rates, one extra year of
bank life is associated with a loans to assets ratio that is just under
1 percentage point higher.
When we use government effectiveness or control of corruption to
measure governance, the profitability coefficient is significantly
greater than zero at the 10% level, and using regulatory quality instead
increases the significance level to 5%. Otherwise, the effect of
profitability is insignificantly different from zero, so we have no
robust evidence that more profitable banks tend to lend more to domestic
customers, ceteris paribus. (7)
Table 3 presents results for the models of the total real volume of
assets. In this case, the Sargan test rejects the overidentification
restrictions at the 5% level in one model (the one using regulatory
quality); it also rejects the restrictions at the 10% level in three
other models. Relaxing some of the orthogonality conditions used to
identify the model reduces these significance levels, but also reduces
the precision of our estimates somewhat. The most reliable results are
the ones using political stability or rule of law to measure governance,
for which the Sargan test statistics are insignificant at the 10% level.
The residual autocorrelation tests are uniformly satisfactory,
indicating first-order but not second-order serial correlation in all
six cases. Again, the lagged dependent variable is positive and highly
significant, and takes a value of just less than 0.9 (implying a
half-life of around 5 years). Therefore, if there were any permanent
change in an explanatory variable, the eventual impact on asset volumes
would be an order of magnitude greater than the immediate effect
indicated below.
Table 3 provides additional evidence that high loan defaults are a
major obstacle to financial development in the region. It shows that a
higher default rate is associated with a significantly lower level of
total assets. This means that the impact of default on the total volume
of loans is even larger than what is suggested by Table 2. The
coefficient on the default rate in Table 3 is negative and highly
significant, ranging from -1.25 to -1.98. Once again, the negative
effect of loan defaults is mitigated by bank age. The model that uses
political stability to measure governance implies that although a 1
percentage point increase in the default rate reduces the loan volume of
a very young bank by nearly 2%, it increases the loan volume of a
50-year old bank by over 1%. Both effects are statistically significant.
The tipping point is at about 35 years of age. Again, some of the
reduction in the asset volumes of younger banks is offset by the
expansion of older banks, which raise not only their loans to assets
ratio, but also their total asset base.
All the governance indicators have a positive and significant
effect on total asset volumes. The coefficient itself ranges from 0.10
(regulatory quality) to 0.22 (rule of law).
There is only one model in which GDP per capita is statistically
significant, namely the model with political stability, in which case
the coefficient is positive, as anticipated; the elasticity is just
under 0.08.
V. CONCLUDING REMARKS
Our results suggest that a major factor explaining why most banks
in Africa choose to remain excessively liquid is a high default rate
among borrowers. The same factor appears to be a serious obstacle to the
growth of bank balance sheets. Our results also suggest that older
government-owned and foreign banks suffer less from this problem; this
is consistent with an information capital story in which banks without
sufficient information capital are unwilling to lend and unable to grow
their assets. Young, privately owned banks suffer the most. It is
therefore unrealistic, in current circumstances, to expect much
financial development to come from the emergence and growth of new
banks. Such banks will have little or no information capital, unless
there is more effort to establish credit bureaus and other mechanisms
that improve information on prospective borrowers (IMF 2001; Sacerdoti
2005). Given that high default rates and limited public information
about borrowers serve to bolster the market share of the oldest
government-owned and foreign banks, the political will to engage in such
reform may well be lacking.
Our findings also suggest that good governance, however measured,
has a uniformly positive on both banks' willingness to lend and
their ability to grow their balance sheets. While all aspects of
governance are important, government effectiveness appears to have the
largest economic impact on the loans to assets ratio, closely followed
by control of corruption. Rule of Law, on the other hand, appears to
have by far the largest impact on the volume of bank business.
Our results relate to a region of Africa across which there is a
high degree of homogeneity in financial and monetary systems. This makes
it relatively straightforward to identify the impact of variations in
governance and default rates on bank behavior. Future research might
examine the extent to which these results are more widely applicable in
the rest of Africa, and also in other developing regions where default
rates are high. However, such research will need to deal with the
challenge of identifying the effects of governance and credit risk when
there is also substantial variation in financial and monetary systems.
ABBREVIATIONS
CEMAC: Economic and Monetary Community of Central Africa
UEMOA: West African Economic and Monetary Union
APPENDIX
In the model presented in the main text, DEFAULT and PROFITABILITY
are potentially endogenous regressors; their effect on RATIO, as
presented in Table 2, is identified using moment conditions of the kind
outlined by Blundell and Bond (1998). In this appendix, we present some
alternative results in which the set of identifying restrictions is
supplemented by modeling DEFAULT and PROFITABILITY as a function of two
indicators of macroeconomic conditions in each country. These indicators
affect the default rate and profitability, but are unlikely to have any
direct impact on the loans to assets ratio.
The two indicators are a terms of trade index, taken from the World
Bank World Development Indicators, and the consumer price inflation
rate. The terms of trade index ([TOT.sub.jt]) is measured as the
logarithm of the ratio of export prices to import prices. It represents
a source of exogenous shocks to domestic income: improvements in the
terms of trade may stimulate domestic demand, increasing bank
profitability and making defaults less likely. The inflation rate
([INF.sub.jt]) is measured using the consumer price index discussed in
the main text. Higher inflation reflects a more unstable macroeconomic
environment in which profitability may be lower and default more likely.
Using these instruments, we first fit a regression equation for
[DEFAULT.sub.jt]:
(A1) [DEFAULT.sub.jt] = [[beta].sub.j] + [rho] x [DEFAULT.sub.jt -
1] + [theta] x [TOT.sub.jt] + [xi] x [INF.sub.jt] + [u.sub.jt]
Here again, the lagged dependent variable is correlated with the
error, so the parameters in Equation (A1) are estimated using the
Blundell-Bond method. The parameter estimates are: [rho] = -0.499
(significant at 10%), [theta] = -0.174 (significant at 1%), and [xi] =
0.886 (significant at 1%). Default rates do rise significantly when the
terms of trade deteriorate or when inflation rises. We then fit a
regression equation for [PROFITABILITY.sub.it]:
(A2) [PROFITABILITY.sub.it] = [[beta].sub.j] + [rho] x
[PROFITABILITY.sub.it - 1] + [theta] x [TOT.sub.jt] + [xi] x
[INF.sub.jt] + [u.sub.jt]
In this case, the parameter estimates are [rho] = 0.072, [theta] =
-0.014, and [xi] = -0.478. The estimate of [theta] is insignificantly
different from zero, but [xi] is significant at the 5% level.
Profitability as we measure it does not appear to be affected by the
terms of trade, but higher profits are associated with lower inflation.
Interestingly, none of the governance indicators is statistically
significant when added to Equations (A1) and (A2): the quality of
governance has no impact on bank profitability or the propensity to
default on loans. Similarly, when we include as a regressor the level of
bank assets, we do not produce a statistically significant coefficient:
default rates and profitability do not depend on bank size. (This result
is the same whether we use moment restrictions on lags of the asset
level or the exogenous variables in Table 3 to instrument the current
level of bank assets.) Nevertheless, the default rate does respond
significantly to macroeconomic conditions, as captured by TOT and INF,
and profitability does respond significantly to INF, so these variables
will be strong instruments in a regression of RATIO on DEFAULT and
PROFITABILITY.
Table A1 therefore presents the results of estimates of the
parameters in Equation (1)--the equation for RATIO--using TOT and INF as
instruments for DEFAULT and PROFITABILITY. In these estimates, the
effects of DEFAULT and PROFITABILITY are identified by both the moment
conditions outlined in the main text and the exclusion of TOT and INF
from the RATIO equation. Using the Sargan Tests in the table, we cannot
reject the null that the exclusion restrictions are valid. Comparison of
the parameter estimates in Table A1 with those in Table 2 of the main
text shows very little difference between the two sets of results,
either in terms of the size of the estimated coefficients or in terms of
their level of significance.
TABLE A1
Dynamic Panel Estimation of the Loans-Assets Ratio (RATIO)
of 87 West African Banksa with Supplementary Instruments
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
VOICE & POLITICAL
ACCOUNTABILITY STABILITY
[RATIO.sub.-1] 0.7114 *** 0.7054 ***
0.0536 0.0448
AGE -0.0009 ** -0.0006
0.0004 0.0004
GOVERNANCE 0.0532 *** 0.0276 ***
0.0115 0.0079
PROFITABILITY 0.0229 0.0531
0.0407 0.0392
DEFAULT -1.3207 *** -1.1740 ***
0.1409 0.1318
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0241 *** 0.0220 ***
0.0039 0.0036
DEFAULT x GOVERNMENT 0.6367 *** 0.4280 ***
0.1741 0.1654
DEFAULT x FOREIGN 0.5877 *** 0.4270 ***
0.1596 0.1430
DEFAULT x PROVINCIAL -0.0306 *** -0.0300 ***
0.0066 0.0067
Number of observations 304 304
Sargan test p-value 0.4108 0.4567
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0045 0.0029
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.8668 0.8102
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
GOVERNMENT REGULATORY
EFFECTIVENESS QUALITY
[RATIO.sub.-1] 0.7238 *** 0.7175 ***
0.0510 0.0487
AGE -0.0003 -0.0008 ***
0.0003 0.0003
GOVERNANCE 0.0839 *** 0.0783 **
0.0177 0.0399
PROFITABILITY 0.0702 * 0.0923 **
0.0364 0.0371
DEFAULT -1.0164 *** -1.0717 ***
0.1274 0.1344
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0180 *** 0.0214 ***
0.0036 0.0038
DEFAULT x GOVERNMENT 0.5692 *** 0.4551 ***
0.1548 0.1650
DEFAULT x FOREIGN 0.5431 *** 0.3601 **
0.1432 0.1424
DEFAULT x PROVINCIAL -0.0291 *** -0.0326 ***
0.0060 0.0059
Number of observations 304 304
Sargan test p-value 0.4423 0.3321
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0024 0.0045
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.7166 0.5163
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
CONTROL OF
RULE OF LAW CORRUPTION
[RATIO.sub.-1] 0.7013 *** 0.7198 ***
0.0483 0.0514
AGE -0.0004 -0.0006
0.0004 0.0004
GOVERNANCE 0.0430 *** 0.0619 ***
0.0138 0.0164
PROFITABILITY 0.0689 * 0.0782 **
0.0382 0.0383
DEFAULT -1.0242 *** -1.0877 ***
0.1264 0.1242
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0170 *** 0.0213 ***
0.0038 0.0037
DEFAULT x GOVERNMENT 0.4879 *** 0.4088 ***
0.1583 0.1336
DEFAULT x FOREIGN 0.4542 *** 0.3273 **
0.1482 0.1483
DEFAULT x PROVINCIAL -0.0291 *** -0.0372 ***
0.0065 0.0054
Number of observations 304 304
Sargan test p-value 0.3576 0.4422
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0033 0.0027
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.7113 0.6796
(a) Standard errors are in italics. Estimates are
obtained using the xtdpd command in Stata 10.0.
The regression also includes time fixed effects.
* Significant at 10%; **significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.
REFERENCES
Arellano, M., and S. Bond. "Some Tests of Specification for
Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment
Equations." Review of Economic Studies, 58, 1991, 277-97.
Barth, J. R., G. Caprio, and R. Levine. "The Regulation and
Supervision of Banks around the World: A New Database," in
Integrating Emerging Market Countries into the Global Financial System,
Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services, edited by R. E. Litan,
and R. Herring. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 2001.
--. "Bank Regulation and Supervision: What Works Best?"
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13, 2004, 205-48.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic. "Financial and
Legal Constraints to Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?" Journal of
Finance, 40, 2005, 137-77.
Bigsten, A., and K. O. Moene. "Growth and Rent Dissipation:
The Case of Kenya." Journal of African Economies, 5, 1996, 177-98.
Blundell, R., and S. Bond. "Initial Conditions and Moment
Restrictions in Dynamic Panel-Data Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 87, 1998, 115-43.
Demetriades, P., and S. Andrianova. "Sources and Effectiveness
of Financial Development: What We Know and What We Need to Know."
Research Paper RP2005/76, World Institute for Development Economic
Research, Helsinki, 2005.
Demetriades, P., and K. Hussein. "Does Financial Development
Cause Economic Growth? Time Series Evidence from 16 Countries."
Journal of Development Economics, 51, 1996, 387-411.
Fuentes, R., and C. P. Maquieira. "Why Borrowers Repay:
Understanding High Performance in Chile's Financial Market,"
in Defusing Default: Incentives and Institutions, edited by M. Pagano.
Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank/Johns Hopkins University
Press, 2001.
Galindo, A., and M. Miller. "Can Credit Registries Reduce
Credit Constraints? Empirical Evidence on the Role of Credit Registries
in Firm Investment Decisions." Presentation to Towards
Competitiveness: The Institutional Path, Annual Meeting of the Board of
Governors, Inter-American Development Bank and Inter-American Investment
Corporation, Santiago, Chile, March 16, 2001. Accessed January 31, 2010.
http://socsci2.ucsd.edu/~aronatas/project/academic/
Credit%20Registries.pdf.
Honohan, P., and T. Beck. Making Finance Work for Africa,
Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2007.
International Monetary Fund. Senegal: Financial System Stability
Assessment. Country Report 01/189, Washington, DC, 2001.
Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. "Governance Matters
VI: Aggregate and Individual Governance Indicators 1996-2006."
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4280, 2007.
Koopman, S. J., A. Lucas, and P. Klaassen. "Empirical Credit
Cycles and Capital Buffer Formation." Journal of Banking and
Finance, 29, 2005, 3159-79.
Levine, R. "Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence."
NBER Working Paper 10766, Cambridge, MA, 2004.
Messick, R. "Judicial Reform and Economic Development: A
Survey of the Issues." World Bank Research Observer, 14, 1999,
117-36.
Sacerdoti, E. Access to Bank Credit in Sub-Saharan Africa: Key
Issues and Reform Strategies. Washington, DC: International Monetary
Fund, Working Paper WP/05/166, 2005.
Stiglitz, J., and A. Weiss. "Credit Rationing in Markets with
Imperfect Information." American Economic Review, 71, 1981,
393-410.
--. "Incentive Effects of Terminations: Applications to Credit
and Labor Markets." American Economic Review, 73, 1983, 912-27.
(1.) CFA originally stood for Colonies Francaises en Afrique. It
now stands for Communaute Financiere Africaine (for the UEMOA currency)
and Cooperation Financiere en Afrique (for the CEMAC currency).
(2.) All publications mentioned in this section are available
online at www.bceao.int. Other international studies of banking sector
performance use data sources different from ours, for example the Doing
Business indicators of the World Bank or the data set of Barth, Caprio,
and Levine (2001). However, for our countries the Doing Business data
are available in 2004 at the earliest, and in some cases not until 2008;
the Barth, Caprio, and Levine (2001) data set does not contain any
francophone developing countries.
(3.) It makes very little difference to the results if profits are
measured as a fraction of total bank assets.
(4.) There will be some heterogeneity in the performance of banks
that is difficult to measure or observe. Some banks lend almost
exclusively to firms in a specific sector; for example, a number of
agricultural banks in the Sahelian countries are highly exposed to the
cotton-producing sector.
(5.) When an interaction term in DEFAULT and PROFITABILITY is
included, the effect is statistically insignificant. Similarly, it was
not possible to find any robust significant interaction effects in
GOVERNANCE. We also tested the sensitivity of RATIO to bank size by
including ln(ASSETS) in Equation (1) as an endogenous regressor; the
effect of ln(ASSETS) is statistically insignificant.
(6.) After taking lags and differences, our sample comprises 4
years. If for every t we use all lags back to [RATIO.sub.i2000] as
instruments for [DELTA][RATIO.sub.it - 1] then we have dozens of moment
conditions, and there is a risk of generating spurious results as our
degrees of freedom diminish. In the main results reported in the
article, we use only moment conditions involving [RATIO.sub.it - 2].
However, increasing the number of conditions does not make an enormous
difference to our results. For the model of ln(ASSETS), in which there
are fewer regressors and more degrees of freedom, we use lags up to t -
3.
(7.) All of our other results are qualitatively similar if the
profitability coefficient is set to zero.
PANICOS DEMETRIADES and DAVID FIELDING *
* We would like to thank Chris Haig for her outstanding assistance
with this article.
Demetriades: Department of Economics, University of Leicester,
University Road, Leicester LE1 7RH, U.K. Phone +44 116 252 2835, E-mail
pd28@le.ac.uk
Fielding: Department of Economics, University of Otago, P.O. Box
56, Dunedin 9054, New Zealand. Phone +64 3479 8653, Fax +64 3479 8174,
E-mail david.fielding@ otago.ac.nz
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2011.00376.x
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics
Obs. Mean SD
(i) Univariate statistics
RATIO 482 0.567 0.199
In(ASSETS) 487 5.515 1.577
AGE 588 17.306 16.075
PROFITABILITY 392 0.076 0.103
DEFAULT 588 0.143 0.085
GOVERNMENT 582 0.159 0.250
FOREIGN 582 0.544 0.360
PROVINCIAL 522 3.736 6.355
VOICE & ACCOUNTABILITY 588 -0.447 0.654
POLITICAL STABILITY 588 -0.448 0.821
GOVERNMENT 588 -0.678 0.401
EFFECTIVENESS
REGUALTORY QUALITY 588 -0.444 0.245
RULE OF LAW 588 -0.669 0.436
CONTROL OF CORRUPTION 588 -0.565 0.369
VOICE & ACC- POLITICAL GOVERNMENT
OUNTABILITY STABILITY EFFECTIVENESS
(ii) Weighted Correlation Coefficients for the Governance Variables
(with Weights for the Number of Banks in Each Country)
POLITICAL STABILITY 0.80
GOVERNMENT 0.81 0.56
EFFECTIVENESS
REGUALTORY QUALITY 0.65 0.57 0.76
RULE OF LAW 0.88 0.83 0.84
CONTROL OF CORRUPTION 0.47 0.49 0.63
Min. Max.
(i) Univariate statistics
RATIO 0.00 0.96
In(ASSETS) 1.43 8.37
AGE 0.00 106.00
PROFITABILITY 0.00 0.59
DEFAULT 0.05 0.42
GOVERNMENT 0.00 1.00
FOREIGN 0.00 1.00
PROVINCIAL 0.00 35.00
VOICE & ACCOUNTABILITY -1.54 0.41
POLITICAL STABILITY -2.45 0.71
GOVERNMENT -1.44 0.04
EFFECTIVENESS
REGUALTORY QUALITY -1.00 -0.06
RULE OF LAW -1.57 -0.04
CONTROL OF CORRUPTION -1.24 0.12
REGUALTORY RULE OF
QUALITY LAW
(ii) Weighted Correlation Coefficients for the Governance Variables
(with Weights for the Number of Banks in Each Country)
POLITICAL STABILITY
GOVERNMENT
EFFECTIVENESS
REGUALTORY QUALITY
RULE OF LAW 0.73
CONTROL OF CORRUPTION 0.79 0.68
TABLE 2
Dynamic Panel Estimation of the Loans-Assets Ratio (RATIO)
of 87 West African Banks (a)
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
VOICE & POLITICAL
ACCOUNTABILITY STABILITY
[RATIO.sub.-1] 0.7259 *** 0.7126 ***
0.0576 0.0479
AGE -0.0014 *** -0.0011 **
0.0004 0.0005
GOVERNANCE 0.0538 *** 0.0356 ***
0.0117 0.0080
PROFITABILITY 0.0214 0.0463
0.0436 0.0416
DEFAULT -1.5077 *** -1.4427 ***
0.1587 0.1542
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0308 *** 0.0292 ***
0.0049 0.0047
DEFAULT x GOVERNMENT 0.5920 *** 0.4611 ***
0.1682 0.1601
DEFAULT x FOREIGN 0.5321 *** 0.4085 ***
0.1667 0.1529
DEFAULT x PROVINCIAL -0.0340 *** -0.0345 ***
0.0070 0.0070
Number of observations 304 304
Sargan test p-value 0.4002 0.5304
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0013 0.0008
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.8755 0.8589
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
GOVERNMENT REGULATORY
EFFECTIVENESS QUALITY
[RATIO.sub.-1] 0.7457 *** 0.7428 ***
0.0525 0.0493
AGE -0.0009 ** -0.0013 ***
0.0004 0.0004
GOVERNANCE 0.0878 *** 0.0754 *
0.0178 0.0397
PROFITABILITY 0.0679 * 0.0942 **
0.0396 0.0393
DEFAULT -1.2174 *** -1.2249 ***
0.1522 0.1467
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0252 *** 0.0270 ***
0.0050 0.0046
DEFAULT x GOVERNMENT 0.5308 *** 0.4264 ***
0.1455 0.1566
DEFAULT x FOREIGN 0.4524 *** 0.2810 *
0.1521 0.1489
DEFAULT x PROVINCIAL -0.0328 *** -0.0362 ***
0.0064 0.0060
Number of observations 304 304
Sargan test p-value 0.4568 0.3219
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0007 0.0010
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.7296 0.5068
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
RULE OF CONTROL OF
LAW CORRUPTION
[RATIO.sub.-1] 0.7435 *** 0.7426 ***
0.0508 0.0520
AGE -0.0011 ** -0.0013 ***
0.0005 0.0005
GOVERNANCE 0.0493 *** 0.0600 ***
0.0133 0.0166
PROFITABILITY 0.0600 0.0789 *
0.0411 0.0409
DEFAULT -1.3437 *** -1.3040 ***
0.1523 0.1505
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0272 *** 0.0292 ***
0.0051 0.0051
DEFAULT x GOVERNMENT 0.4709 *** 0.3952 ***
0.1457 0.1280
DEFAULT x FOREIGN 0.3647 ** 0.2224
0.1563 0.1610
DEFAULT x PROVINCIAL -0.0357 *** -0.0427 ***
0.0068 0.0059
Number of observations 304 304
Sargan test p-value 0.4263 0.5086
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0010 0.0006
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.7471 0.7054
(a) Standard errors are in italics. Estimates are obtained using the
xtdpd command in Stata 10.0. The regression also includes time
fixed effects.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.
TABLE 3
Dynamic Panel Estimation of the Log of Real
Assets (ln(ASSETS)) of 87 West African Banks (a)
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
VOICE & POLITICAL
ACCOUNTABILITY STABILITY
ln(ASSETS.sub.-1) 0.8693 *** 0.8669 ***
0.0313 0.0300
AGE -0.0105 *** -0.0103 ***
0.0012 0.0011
GOVERNANCE 0.1038 *** 0.1374 ***
0.0337 0.0199
ln(GDP) 0.0295 0.0774 **
0.0305 0.0308
DEFAULT -1.6472 *** -1.9750 ***
0.4055 0.3964
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0596 *** 0.0723 ***
0.0129 0.0127
Number of observations 385 385
Sargan test p-value 0.0642 0.2947
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0350 0.0332
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.8407 0.8438
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
GOVERNMENT REGULATORY
EFFECTIVENESS QUALITY
ln(ASSETS.sub.-1) 0.8773 *** 0.8835 ***
0.0323 0.0306
AGE -0.0088 *** -0.0090 ***
0.0010 0.0010
GOVERNANCE 0.0934 ** 0.1001 **
0.0425 0.0472
ln(GDP) -0.0335 -0.0116
0.0268 0.0257
DEFAULT -1.4257 *** -1.2531 ***
0.3644 0.3814
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0431 *** 0.0418 ***
0.0103 0.0105
Number of observations 385 385
Sargan test p-value 0.0728 0.0493
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0346 0.0334
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.7721 0.7654
GOVERNANCE INDICATOR
RULE OF CONTROL OF
LAW CORRUPTION
ln(ASSETS.sub.-1) 0.8996 *** 0.8895 ***
0.0302 0.0330
AGE -0.0081 *** -0.0086 ***
0.0010 0.0010
GOVERNANCE 0.2208 *** 0.1061 **
0.0387 0.0486
ln(GDP) 0.0262 -0.0122
0.0284 0.0263
DEFAULT -1.4708 *** -1.2550 ***
0.3839 0.3806
DEFAULT x AGE 0.0466 *** 0.0381 ***
0.0108 0.0105
Number of observations 385 385
Sargan test p-value 0.1923 0.0798
Residual AR(1) test p-value 0.0440 0.0318
Residual AR(2) test p-value 0.8169 0.7977
(a) Standard errors are in italics. Estimates are obtained using
the xtdpd command in Stata 10.0. The regression also includes
time fixed effects.
* Significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.