The value of risk: measuring the service output of U.S. commercial banks.
Basu, Susanto ; Inklaar, Robert ; Wang, J. Christina 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Services are an increasingly important part of modern economies,
both in terms of size and for their contribution to economic growth.
However, the output data for many of these services is notoriously weak,
and this is particularly the case for banking. (1) This makes it hard to
determine the sources of economic growth and even the size of the
economy. A major barrier to progress in this area has been the
inadequacy of production models for banks. Wang, Basu, and Fernald
(2009, WBF henceforth) propose a general-equilibrium model of
interactions between banks, firms, and consumers to remedy this problem.
In this paper, we estimate the value of output of U.S. banks following
the prescriptions of the WBF model for the period 1997-2007. We find
that these new estimates differ considerably from those based on current
National Accounts methods: bank output is reduced by 21% and gross
domestic product (GDP) is reduced by 0.3%. We argue that compared to
current National Accounts, these new output estimates imply a more
plausible capital share in income and internal rate of return (IRR) on
fixed capital.
Measuring the value of bank output is challenging, as much of bank
service output is not explicitly priced. Instead, the implicit charges
for financial services are bundled with interest flows between banks and
their customers, chiefly borrowers and depositors. WBF show how implicit
service revenue can be unbundled from gross interest flows by applying
the idea from financial intermediation theory that the main service
provided by banks in making loans is reducing asymmetric information between borrowers and lenders through screening and monitoring. Instead
of receiving an upfront fee for these services, an optimizing bank can
charge a higher interest rate than the rate available on a market
security with otherwise the same risk attributes.
This procedure contrasts with the typical statistical practice in
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries. (2)
According to current national accounts guidelines, banks' implicit
revenue from lending services (per unit of loan balance) equals the
spread between the gross loan interest rate and a risk-free rate. (3)
This in effect treats loan risk premia (i.e., the return differential
between a risk-free and the equally risky fixed-income security) as part
of banks' value added. A producing firm's measured output will
thus fall if it switches from market debt to bank loans, or will appear
to rise if it starts issuing bonds rather than borrowing from banks,
even if the underlying risk of the firm remains the same.
According to the WBF model, the implicit revenue from screening and
monitoring services should equal the spread of the gross loan interest
rate over the yield on an equally risky fixed-income security, not a
risk-free security such as a Treasury bill or bond. This accounting
method treats the risk premium as part of the borrowing firms' cost
of capital and hence as part of households' capital income, their
compensation for bearing risk. A key advantage of this method is that it
leads to a uniform treatment of risk premia on all debt instruments, so
that nonfinancial firms' output is invariant to their source of
debt finance--markets or banks.
In this paper, we implement a new model-implied measure of bank
output for U.S. commercial banks. To highlight the role of risk, this
paper focuses on new estimates of the nominal value of services
associated with loans, where our risk-based user-cost approach differs
substantially from current practice. Despite our conservative estimate
of risk premia, we show that imputed bank output is overstated by 45% on
average in the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA). This
translates into an overstatement of total bank output, which includes
explicit fees and commissions, of 21%. Netting out the lending services
to nonfinancial firms, which are counted as an intermediate input, this
finding implies that U.S. GDP would have been 0.3% lower on average over
our sample period of 1997-2007.
A number of plausibility checks also argue in favor of our output
measure. First, we compare the share of capital in banks' value
added with the share of capital in the total private economy and other
industries. Under current practice, banks show up as more (fixed)
capital-intensive than petroleum refining, whereas our estimates suggest
a capital share closer to the share of capital in the overall private
sector. In addition, current practice implies an IRR on fixed assets that is 8 percentage points higher than the rate in the private sector
as a whole. (4) Our new estimates imply an internal rate that is, on
average, slightly lower than the rate in the overall private sector.
This is more consistent with the basic principle that the IRR on fixed
assets should not vary much across industries as long as capital is
mobile.
The rest of this paper proceeds as follows. We begin with a brief
review of the theory-implied new output measure, focusing on the role of
risk. We then discuss data and present our results. We conclude with a
summary, and discuss directions for future research.
II. THE MODEL FOR IMPLICIT BANK SERVICE OUTPUT
This section reviews briefly the dynamic stochastic optimizing
models of banks in Wang (2003) and WBF (2009), focusing on their
implications for imputing the value of bank services that are not
explicitly charged for. (5) The key conclusion of these studies
regarding output measurement is that implicit compensation for bank
services can be inferred from a bank's total income by netting out
the pure risk-based returns (i.e., costs of funds) on assets and
liabilities held by the bank. To impute the cost of funds on any such
risky financial instrument, one should use the rate of return on (debt)
securities subject to the same risk, but without any services attached.
Total income net of the pure costs of funds then measures the true value
of bank services implicitly charged for. This conclusion is summarized
in Figure 1, which shows graphically how we impute the value of bank
services related to loans ([Y.sup.A]) and deposits ([Y.sup.D]) using
data on the interest rate paid on deposits ([r.sup.D]), the interest
rate charged on loans ([r.sup.A]), and market interest rates on
risk-free securities ([r.sup.F]) and risky securities ([r.sup.M]). This
section outlines the theoretical arguments for choosing these particular
interest rates while the next section discusses our empirical
implementation.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
A. Implicit Bank Services--The Case of Lending (6)
Before any attempt to measure, one must first define a concept. So,
what is the output of banks? Wang (2003) and WBF (2009) answer this
question through models that embed optimal bank operations within the
context of competitive financial markets. These papers recognize that
the value added of banks lies in resolving information problems and
processing transactions, not in generating returns on the resulting
financial instruments. These returns are determined entirely by the
instruments' risk characteristics and market interest rates. In
particular, in these models the value added of bank lending consists of
screening and monitoring activities to mitigate asymmetric information
problems with regard to borrowers' creditworthiness. (7) Bank
services are analogous to other professional business services, such as
legal, accounting and consulting services, and indeed analogous to all
production in the economy: output is generated through a production
process that uses primary inputs of labor and capital, as well as
intermediate inputs (such as office supplies and utilities).
In contrast, the purely risk-based returns that accrue to the stock
of financial instruments held by banks are what investors would demand
on any contingent claims with the same risk profiles, regardless of how
they are created. These pure returns also correspond to the concept of
the "user cost of funds," defined as the (risky) future payoff
from investment that compensates suppliers of funds for their forgone
current consumption and for bearing risk, but not for any attached
services. (8) The costs of funds are part of the overall user cost of
capital faced by the ultimate users of funds, such as nonfinancial
firms. These are therefore part of those firms' value added, not
the value added of the banks that provide the funds.
This paper concentrates on the measurement of nominal bank output,
but to understand the models of Wang (2003) and WBF (2009), it is useful
to consider briefly the concept of real output implied by these models.
Real bank (lending) output consists of intermediation services that
certify borrowers as credit-worthy at loan origination (screening) and
on an on-going basis (monitoring). Thus, a natural measure of real bank
output is the number of loans originated and monitored, just as a
natural measure of the output of a "normal" service provider,
like a barbershop, is the number of haircuts it provides. In principle,
certain types of loans (e.g., small business loans) may require more
information processing than others (such as conforming mortgages). Thus,
a refined measure of real output would augment the raw transactions
count with some notion of "quantity of service," just as a
high-quality coiffure by Christophe of Los Angeles (9) should be counted
as being "more haircut output" than a haircut from the local
barber shop. But in any measure of real bank output, the natural
starting point is the number of transactions of each type performed.
Inklaar and Wang (2007) count these transactions and aggregate them
into an index of real bank output. The object of this paper, of course,
is to measure nominal bank output accurately. In conjunction, these two
papers imply a complete set of national income measures for
banking--nominal output, real output, and an implicit price index for
banking services.
B. Loan-Interest-Rate Spread--Risk versus Implicit Bank Services
The key measurement implication of Wang (2003) and WBF (2009) is
that the nominal value of bank services that are not explicitly charged
for can be imputed as total income net of the purely risk-based returns
on the financial claims created by those services and held on the
bank's book. In the case of lending services, the pure cost of
funds of a loan should be inferred using the rate of return on a market
debt security with the same risk characteristics (but without any
services attached).
This method of matching risk is of the same nature as a common
application of asset-pricing theory to corporate finance--the cost of
capital for a specific investment project is set to equal the rate of
return on "like" market securities. Both of these applications
follow the same principle as the Arbitrage Pricing Theory in the work of
Ross (1976), where the expected rate of return on a portfolio is
determined given the returns on "factor" portfolios and the
absence of arbitrage opportunities. (10) One obvious implication is that
no firm--and no bank--would use the return on risk-free securities as
the appropriate opportunity cost for an investment with risky payoff.
The logic of removing risk-adjusted returns from total bank income
to impute the value of service output can be illustrated with a stylized example of "the bank that does nothing." (11) Specifically,
assume frictionless financial markets, so that firms can borrow directly
from households without the need for intermediaries to process
information or transactions. The required (net) rate of return on any
investment between periods t and t + 1, denoted [[??].sub.t+1] (with the
tilde emphasizing the random nature of the return), is determined by a
stochastic discount factor, denoted [m.sub.r+1], as follows:
(1) [E.sub.t][(1 + [[??].sub.t+1])[m.sub.t+1] = 1.
Assume entities that function solely as accounting vehicles are set
up as follows (12): households transfer their capital to these entities
in exchange for claims on the entities, which then rent the capital to
production firms. By design, these entities have balance sheets and
income statements that look like those of banks, so they are called
banks for short even though they perform no services.
For simplicity of exposition, we assume these banks are fully
equity funded. However, note that the banks' capital structure is
irrelevant for their cost of capital in this simple model economy as
here the Modigliani and Miller (MM, 1958) theorem applies. More
generally, Wang (2003) showed that the central message that the user
cost of funds must take risk into account does not depend on whether the
MM theorem holds. What remains is the practical matter of finding the
market rates most commensurate with the risk of financial instruments
held by banks, as we discuss later in detail.
Now look at the cash flow of a representative bank. Households
recognize that a bank here is just a bookkeeping device and that they
ultimately own its assets--capital used in production. So they require
the same rate of return on a bank's equity as on those assets. The
bank must therefore lend the funds to any firm at a rate set according
to Equation (1). Consequently, production firms face the same cost of
capital as they would have if they had borrowed directly from
households. Let [r.sup.i.sub.t] [equivalent to]
[E.sub.t]([[??].sup.i.sub.t+1]) denote the expected rate of return on
the loan to firm i with balance [A.sup.i.sub.t]; further denote total
balance of the loan portfolio as [A.sub.t] and the average rate of
return on the portfolio as [r.sup.A.sub.t]. Then the expected interest
income on the portfolio can be expressed as:
(2) [r.sup.A.sub.t] [A.sub.t] = [summation over (i)]
[A.sup.i.sub.t] [r.sup.i.sub.t], with [A.sub.t] = [summation over (i)]
[A.sup.i.sub.t] and [r.sup.A.sub.t] = [summation over (i)] [w.sub.t]
[r.sup.i.sub.t].
[w.sub.i] = [A.sup.i.sub.t]/[A.sub.t] is the weight of loan i in
the portfolio. Note that [r.sup.A.sub.t] [A.sub.t] is also the expected
dividend payment to the households who own the bank.
The correctly imputed value of bank service output should be zero
on average as by design the banks produce no real services. (13) This is
exactly the result if the value of services is imputed as the
bank's total income net of its risk-adjusted cost of funds, that
is, [A.sub.t] [[??].sup.A.sub.t+1] - [r.sup.A.sub.t] [approximately
equal to] 0, because [[??].sup.A.sub.t-1] - [r.sup.A.sub.t] =
[[summation].sub.i][w.sub.i] ([[??].sup.i.sub.t+1] - [r.sup.i.sub.t])
[approximately equal to] 0, where [[??].sup.i.sub.t+1] and
[[??].sup.A.sub.t+1] = [[summation].sub.i] [w.sub.i]
[[??].sup.i.sub.t+1] are the realized rate of return on loan i and on
the portfolio, respectively.
In contrast, if the value of services is imputed by subtracting
risk-free returns from total income, as in the existing national income
accounting practices, then on average the bank will be credited with
producing positive output of services, as in general the expectation of
[[??].sup.A.sub.t+1] - [r.sup.F.sub.t] [approximately equal to]
[r.sup.A.sub.t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t] > 0. (14) This result follows
directly from expanding Equation (1), which applies to [r.sup.i.sub.t]
and hence also to [r.sup.A.sub.t], and substituting 1 + [r.sup.F.sub.t]
for 1/[E.sub.t]([m.sub.t+1]) (which is itself an application of Equation
[1] to risk-free assets):
(3)
[r.sup.A.sub.t] = (1 + [r.sup.F.sub.t])[1 +
cov([[??].sup.A.sub.t+1], -[m.sub.r+1)]-- 1,
where [r.sup.F.sub.t] is the yield on a debt of the same maturity
but not subject to any risk (e.g., default), nor with any embedded options. (15) U.S. Treasury's are the best example. (16)
[r.sup.F.sub.t] only compensates investors for sacrificing current for
future consumption with certainty. A security with risky payoff that
cannot be diversified away and is (negatively) correlated with the
stochastic discount factor, however, must in expectation pay a return
premium cov([[??].sub.t+1], -[m.sub.t+1]), to make up for the
risk-induced disutility. (17) This premium is positive for almost all
risky assets (see any finance text, e.g., Campbell, Lo and MacKinlay
1997).
This stylized example serves to intuitively highlight the
conceptual problem of using the risk-free rate to impute bank output.
Wang (2003) and WBF (2009) show that similar overestimation of bank
output arises in the realistic case where banks provide actual
services-processing information and transactions-for which no explicit
fees are charged but implicit compensation is earned via an
interest-rate spread.
To infer the value of such implicitly priced services as part of
banks' net interest income, Wang (2003) solves for the optimal
interest rate charged by a value-maximizing bank when making loans with
the same (systematic) risk profile as a type of existing market debt.
The usual first-order condition gives rise to the following expression
for the rate of return (denoted [r.sup.A.sub.t]) the bank should expect
to earn on a loan portfolio:
(4) [r.sup.A.sub.t] = [r.sup.M.sub.t] + [r.sup.s.sub.t].
[r.sup.M.sub.t] [equivalent to] [E.sub.t]([[??].sup.M.sub.t+1]) is
the expected rate of return demanded by investors on the market debt
with the same risk. The [r.sup.S.sub.t] represents what we shall call
the service spread, which generates the extra interest that compensates
the bank implicitly for processing the loan. The optimal service spread
[r.sup.S.sub.t] in Equation (4) satisfies the condition that the extra
interest receipt, [r.sup.S.sub.t][A.sub.t], equals the (weighted
average) marginal cost of processing a loan multiplied by the optimal
markup. (18) This markup is determined by competition in the loan
market.
In the nomenclature of the 1993 System of National Accounts (SNA 1993), [r.sup.M.sub.t] in Equation (4) is called the reference
rate--serving as reference for the cost of funds on the loan. For a
market rate to be the proper reference, the security should not only
have similar risk, but banks should also face the same marginal tax rate and transaction costs faced by typical investors in the reference market
debt. (19) We argue that this is likely a reasonable assumption for the
reference rates used in our empirical exercise, as most of the market
securities chosen as references for bank loans are backed by securitized pools of loans, such as mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and the
securities are routinely held on bank balance sheet along with those
same categories of loans. That is, by revealed choices of asset
allocation, banks appear to consider these securities as offering
similar rates of return as the corresponding categories of loans. The
reference rate for a portfolio of loans (of varying types, maturities
and rate-reset dates) is then a weighted average of rates on the
individual loans.
C. Imputing the Value of Implicit Bank Services
Derivations in the previous section imply that, on average, a
bank's nominal output of implicit lending services to borrowers
should equal [r.sup.S.sub.t][A.sub.t] = ([r.sup.A.sub.t]
-[r.sup.M.sub.t][A.sub.t]. But neither of the expected rates of return,
[r.sup.A.sub.t] and [r.sup.M.sub.t], is observed. So, for empirical
estimations, we make use of the relationship that the expected rate of
return on a defaultable debt equals its promised yield to maturity
(i.e., the contractual interest rate, denoted by [R.sup.k.sub.t])
corrected for its expected loss rate due to default (denoted by
[d.sup.k.sub.t]) (20):
(5) [r.sup.k.sub.t] = [R.sup.k.sub.t] - [d.sup.k.sub.t], k = M, A.
[d.sup.k.sub.t] [equivalent to] [E.sub.t]([[??].sup.k.sub.t+1]),
where [d.sup.k.sub.t] is the (random) default loss rate. For market
securities, [R.sup.M.sub.t]'s are generally observed while
[d.sup.M.sub.t]'s can be estimated using time series data. (21) For
loans, [d.sup.A.sub.t]'s can be estimated as well, although
[R.sup.A.sub.t]'s are less often observed. Substitute Equation (5)
into Equation (4) and we can impute the output of lending services as
(22):
(6)
[Y.sup.A.sub.t] = [r.sup.s.sub.t][A.sub.t] = [([R.sup.A.sub.t] -
[D.sup.A.sub.t]) - ([R.sup.M.sub.t] - [d.sup.M.sub.t])][A.sub.t].
Previous discussions make it clear why the reference rate
([r.sup.M.sub.t] = [R.sup.M.sub.t]- [d.sup.M.sub.t]) should be
risk-adjusted. Therefore, the reference rate varies across loan types,
depending on risk characteristics of the loan or portfolio of loans
associated with the services considered.
In contrast, the U.S. NIPA currently impute bank services to
borrowers using a nearly risk-free rate as the reference rate:
(7)
([r.sup.A.sub.t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t])[A.sub.t] = ([r.sup.s.sub.t] +
[r.sup.p.sub.t])[A.sub.t] = [Y.sup.A.sub.t] + [r.sup.P.sub.t][A.sub.t],
where [r.sup.P.sub.t] = [r.sup.M.sub.t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t] is the
return premium of the reference risky market securities over
(maturity-matched) risk-free securities; it equals (1 +
[r.sup.F.sub.t])cov([[??].sup.M.sub.t+1], -[m.sub.t+l]) (see Equation
[3] above).
The value of output imputed according to Equation (7) will
overstate the actual value of service output. According to some, the
informal justification for Equation (7) is that [r.sup.P.sub.t][A.sub.t]
is regarded as compensation for rendering a socalled
"risk-bearing" service. Wang and Basu (2007, Section 3.4)
discuss at length why risk-bearing is not a productive service according
to the conceptual framework of SNA 1993.
More importantly, they show that the NIPA's imputation results
in inconsistent accounting of the output of borrowing firms, by making
firms' measured value added depend on their sources of funding.
Suppose two firms are identical, but one borrows from banks and the
other from the bond market. Then the firm relying on banks is credited
with producing lower value added than the one issuing bonds, even if
their actual productive activities are identical.
The value of implicit depositor services can be imputed in a
similar manner to the new way we imputed the value of implicit lending
services. Let [D.sub.t] denote the deposit balance, and [r.sup.D.sub.t]
the interest rate paid; [R.sup.M.sub.t] and [d.sup.M.sub.t] are defined
as above (but the values almost certainly differ), then nominal output
of depositor services can be imputed as:
(8) [Y.sup.D.sub.t] = [([R.sup.M.sub.t] - [d.sup.M.sub.t]) -
[r.sup.D.sub.t][D.sub.t].
For insured deposits in the United States, the relevant reference
rate should be the risk-free (Treasury) rate, that is, [R.sup.M.sub.t] =
[R.sup.M.sub.t] = [r.sup.F.sub.t], as [d.sup.M.sub.t] = 0. For the
remaining, uninsured, deposits, [R.sup.M.sub.t] - [d.sup.M.sub.t] >
[r.sup.F.sub.t], because the deposit holders are exposed to some
(default) risk in bank asset portfolios. In our empirical application,
we abstract from this issue and effectively assume that all deposits are
insured, and hence risk-free.
Note that Equation (6) implies that if a bank passively holds
market securities in its investment portfolio, there are no services
provided to the asset issuers (i.e., [Y.sup.A] = 0), as [R.sup.A] = RM
and [d.sup.A] = [d.sup.M]. Likewise, Equation (8) implies zero implicit
services (i.e., [Y.sup.D] = 0) provided to holders of bank term
liabilities (commercial paper, market bonds, and privately placed
bonds), as the interest rate paid equals the reference rate ([R.sup.D] =
[R.sup.M] and [d.sup.D] = [d.sup.M]). Also note that under virtually all
circumstances (i.e., whenever there are equity holders), ([r.sup.M] -
[d.sup.M]) in Equation (6) is greater than its counterpart in Equation
(8), because bank assets are typically riskier than bank liabilities. In
other words, the reference rates for imputing lending and depositor
services almost always differ by a positive margin.
So again, recall that Figure 1 illustrates the imputed nominal
output value of implicit bank services. Note that only part of a
bank's net interest income constitutes nominal output of bank
services; the remainder--corresponding to the risk premium, ([r.sup.M] -
[r.sup.F])A--is excluded. (23) This is precisely because the reference
rate for lending services generally exceeds that for depositor services.
The risk premium, along with actual interest expenses on bank
liabilities, constitutes a pure transfer of capital income. It is part
of the factor income generated by the capital used in the borrowing
firms' production or in the consumption of consumers. This factor
income is then transferred from the end users of funds to the ultimate
suppliers of funds--the bank shareholders. Only when all investors are
risk neutral or all risk is idiosyncratic will this risk premium
disappear. Figure 1 illuminates how our model-based output measure
differs from the NIPA's current measure, which uses a (nearly)
risk-free rate as the single reference rate (see Fixler, Reinsdorf, and
Smith 2003). (24) As we have argued, the NIPA's measure overstates
bank output by the amount of the risk premium. In the remainder of this
paper, we discuss how to estimate the risk premium and its quantitative
impact on the measured output of the U.S. commercial banking industry.
III. DATA AND EMPIRICAL ESTIMATES OF BANK SERVICE INCOME
A. Data Sources
Accounting data for individual commercial banks come from the
Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income (the Call Reports). (25)
These are quarterly financial statements filed by banks to their
regulators and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Our empirical estimates use data from the second quarter of 1997 to the
fourth quarter of 2007, mostly because some of the necessary variables
are not available for earlier years.
The Call Reports data are used to estimate the average interest
rate earned by banks on each category of loans and deposits. The Call
Reports also provide data on the repricing period of various categories
of loans. Yields on U.S. Treasury securities of varying maturities are
from the Federal Reserve Board, (26) as are yields on commercial paper
of the top two tiers of ratings; yields on the remaining tiers are from
Bloomberg. Yields on mortgage- and asset-backed securities are based on
indices constructed by Citigroup Global Markets and Merrill Lynch (ML).
Finally, interest rates charged on commercial and industrial (C&I)
loans for clients with various risk profiles come from the Federal
Reserve Survey of Terms of Business Lending (STBL). (27)
B. Implementation--Overview
The Call Reports afford no direct observation of either the
promised yield ([R.sup.A.sub.t]) or the expected default rate
([d.sup.A.sub.t]). Instead, what is reported is the average interest
rate actually received by banks on each individual category of loans and
securities, that is, [R.sup.A.sub.t] - [[??].sup.A.sub.t+1], where
[[??].sup.A.sub.t+1] is the realized default loss rate (indexed t + 1
because it becomes known only at the end of period t). Plug this into
Equation (6) and we can express the service spread [r.sup.S.sub.t] as
(9) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
This is our basic formula for imputing the value of implicitly
priced services to borrowers. As will be shown in the following text,
the expected default rate [d.sup.M.sub.t] is often considerably lower
than 1% for the market securities we use for reference rates. Therefore,
the service spread can be inferred from the realized loan interest rate
and the matched market yield [R.sup.M.sub.t], after correcting for the
deviation of the actual from the expected rate of loan default. The
empirical estimate of each term will be detailed in turn.
The Call Reports data dictate that we can match loans with market
securities in only a few broad categories: real estate loans with MBS,
consumer loans with asset-backed securities (ABS), and C&I loans
with commercial paper. So, the reference rate ([r.sup.M.sub.t] =
[R.sup.M.sub.t] -[d.sup.M.sub.t]) used for each category is a (noisy)
proxy for the true risk-matched reference rate, as we observe little of
the risk composition and only limited information about the maturity of
the loans and thus cannot assess the accuracy of the match.
Nevertheless, using market debt returns almost surely underestimate the
true risk premium on loans, as market securities on average have much
lower realized default rates and are therefore likely to command lower
risk premia as well. (28)
Another issue is that in each period we observe only the average
interest rate earned by a bank on its portfolio of a given type of
loans, regardless of when the loans were priced. In particular, for
loans with long periods of fixed rates, like mortgages, this loan
portfolio will also include loans that were priced years ago. Comparing
this average rate with current market rates to impute the service spread
is obviously not correct. Unfortunately, the data necessary for a proper
matching--gross flows of new loans originated and old loans paid off or
reset at a new interest rate in each period--are not available. So,
rather than trying to make rough assumptions about the composition of
the loan portfolios, we compare the average interest rate to the current
market reference rates in our baseline estimates. (29)
The one exception is C&I loans where we use data from the STBL,
which provides data on the interest rate charged on new C&I loans
originated by commercial banks in the survey week. In this case, we can
match the timing of bank loan interest rates and the market rate. While
still not perfect, this matching likely provides a more accurate
estimate of actual service spreads than could be obtained by using the
difference between average bank loan rates earned and current market
reference rates.
Estimating depositor services according to Equation (8) is
straightforward, especially once we assume [r.sup.M] = [r.sup.F]. This
assumption is necessary, because the Call Reports do not provide
adequate data for estimating the risk premium on uninsured deposits,
whose share is, fortunately, modest.
To further implement Equation (8), the difference between the
realized and expected default rate should be added as part of the
service spread. We estimate these terms by using data from the Call
Reports on charge-offs of the different loan categories. The expected
default rate is proxied by the period-average charge-off rate. The only
remaining piece of information is then the risk premium of each loan
category.
C. Estimates of Risk Premia
To facilitate comparison with the NIPAs' current measure of
bank output, we estimate separately the two components--the risk-free
rate and the risk premium--of the reference rate for each category of
loans. The risk premium on a reference security is (30):
(10) [r.sup.P.sub.t] = [r.sup.M.sub.t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t] =
[R.sup.M.sub.t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t] - [d.sup.M.sub.t].
Data indicate that the unconditional estimate of [d.sup.M.sub.t],
equal to the long-term average of realized defaults, is extremely low
for certain categories of market debt, such as commercial paper. For
example, according to Moody's, the historical average default rates
of commercial paper with the top two rating grades (P-1 and P-2) are
basically nil. (31) So, for certain categories of loans, when such
corporate debt is used as the reference securities, a reasonable
estimate of [r.sup.P.sub.t] is simply the yield spread between such debt
and the maturity-matched Treasury securities (i.e., [R.sup.M.sub.t] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t]); the upward bias from ignoring [d.sup.M.sub.t] should
be negligible.
To compute the respective risk premium on C&I loans, we rely on
the Federal Reserve's STBL to gauge the default risk and maturity
composition of C&I loans and find the best matched market
securities. (32) Data from this survey indicate that about 70% of
C&I loans are repriced in less than a month and over 90% in less
than a year. This suggests that commercial paper is a more appropriate
type of reference security than corporate bonds. On the other hand,
using the yields on commercial paper likely results in conservative
estimates of the risk premium on C&I loans, as C&I loans tend to
have both longer average maturities and greater default risk than
commercial paper. (33)
Among the four risk categories reported in the STBL, two have
readily available reference market securities. First, according to the
filing instructions, the "minimal-risk" classification
explicitly requires that the loans be to customers with a bond rating of
AA or higher; such firms generally also carry a P-1 short-term rating by
Moody's. Second, the "low-risk" category requires
customers to have a BBB bond rating, which maps into a P-2 rating by
Moody's. (34) However, the reference securities for the other two,
higher, risk categories, "moderate risk" and
"other," are not as clear. So we assume that the higher
interest rate related to the "low-risk" category is entirely
as a result of greater risk but not to extra implicit service revenue.
Over the sample period, the risk premia of loans in the
minimal-risk and low-risk categories average 0.2 and 0.5 percentage
points, corresponding to the risk premia on P-1 and P-2 commercial
paper, respectively. By comparison, loans in the moderate-risk and the
other-risk categories carry considerably higher average risk premia: 1.4
and 2.3 percentage points, respectively. (35) As the latter two
categories on average account for 60% of the volume of new C&I loans
reported in the STBL, the weighted average risk premium for all C&I
loans is 1.3 percentage points in our time series. This weighted average
is computed using the volume of new loans in each category as weights.
Instead of assuming that higher interest rates on moderate risk and
other C&I loans are fully because of higher risk premia, we could
also assume they are fully because of higher information processing
costs. This would imply using the commercial paper spread for low-risk
C&I loans as the market reference rate for the moderate-risk and
other categories. Doing so would reduce the overall risk premium from
1.3 to 0.5 percentage points and almost double the average service
spread from 0.9 to 1.7 percentage points on average over the period.
However, total imputed bank output would only increase by 6% on average,
which does not materially affect our main results.
The risk premia of consumer installment and credit card loans are
estimated using ML's ABS indices for fixed-rate auto and credit
card loans, respectively. A weighted average yield is computed based on
the share of credit cards versus all other loans in the portfolio. The
average rating of the ABS underlying the two indices is between BBB and
AA, as both these indices are components of ML's ABS master index.
(36) Following this procedure almost certainly yields a rather
conservative estimate of the average risk premium on the consumer loans
held on the books of banks because to receive investment-grade ratings,
the ABS invariably must obtain credit enhancement to ensure that their
holders will be subject to minimal credit risk. (37) Moreover, even at
the original loan level, the loans kept on banks' books may be
riskier than the ones that are securitized. (38) In terms of maturity,
however, no data are available to gauge how well on average the
indices' constituent bonds match consumer loans held by banks. (39)
The average duration of these ABS indices is fairly short, so we compare
the average ABS rate to an average of 1- and 2-yr Treasuries.
We thus obtain an average risk premium of 0.7 percentage points.
This is likely a conservative estimate as this is lower than the average
C&I premium of 1.3 percentage points, whereas contractual rates on
consumer loans are on average much higher than the rates charged on
C&I loans. As a sensitivity check, we also estimated the risk
premium based on a BBB-rated corporate bond index, which covers the most
risky investment-grade securities. (40) This would increase the average
risk premium from 0.7 to 1.8 percentage points and reduce the financial
service output associated with these loans by 20% and total bank output
by 7%. Because the impact on total output is quite modest, we stick to
the risk premium estimate based on the ABS index as our baseline case.
Besides, there is no concrete information to substantiate that the
BBB-rated corporate bond index is more appropriate as the market
reference for consumer loans.
To estimate the risk premium on real estate loans, we use the
maturity-weighted redemption yields on MBS issued by
government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs, such as Fannie Mae and Freddy
Mac) as the reference rate. The maturity data are available in the Call
Reports (schedule RC-C) since the second quarter of 1997. Again, this
reference rate likely gives a conservative estimate of the risk premium
on these loans as agency MBS are not subject to default risk but only to
prepayment risk: mortgage holders may repay their loans in part or in
full ahead of schedule. (41)
The real estate loans in bank portfolios have a repricing period or
remaining maturity between 6 and 10 yr in the sample period, so we
compare an MBS index with a long remaining maturity (7-10 yr) to a
maturity-matched average of Treasury yields. The resulting risk premium
is 1.2 percentage points over this period, as a sensitivity check we
again applied the 1.8 percentage points risk premium based on BBB-rated
corporate bonds. This reduced service output associated with these loans
by almost 80% and in fact led to negative service output in one-third of
the quarters. This makes it highly unlikely that banks would use such a
BBB corporate rate as the reference when setting interest rates on real
estate loans.
For the yield on the MBS index to be a good proxy for the pure
(risky) return in the loan rates, a substantial fraction of the mortgage
portfolio must be repriced in the period of consideration. This timing
requirement is made clear in Equation (9): the reference rate should be
for the period when a loan's interest rate was set or last reset.
(42) To gauge the extent to which the above baseline estimates are
affected by the interest-rate timing mismatch, a problem that we suspect
is particularly acute for long-term, fixed-rate loans such as many
residential mortgages, we also compute the risk premium on real estate
loans using a series of moving averages of current and past (up to 5 yr)
market rates. For the period 2002-2007, the average service spread on
mortgage loans using current market rates is 0.80%, while that using the
5-yr moving average rates is 0.69%. Service spreads estimated using
shorter moving averages lie in between. A maximum effect of 0.11
percentage points is modest compared to the average service spread of
0.80, so timing mismatch between bank loan rates and the market
reference rates is not a major concern for real estate loans.
In summary, except for the two least risky (minimal- and low-risk)
categories of C&I loans, we lack high-frequency data to accurately
estimate the riskiness of the loan portfolios on bank balance sheet.
Therefore, our choices of reference rates for the other bank loans rely
on the assumption that the systematic risk of each category of loans is
similar to that of the market securities based on securitized pools of
that category of loans. On the other hand, our sensitivity analysis
suggests that, even apart from the issue of theoretical justification,
raising all the reference rates to as high as yields on the lowest
investment-grade (i.e., BBB-rated) corporate bonds would not
significantly alter the results reported in the remainder of this paper.
So, hereafter we present only results based on the reference rates
derived above using market securities structured from securitized loans.
For transaction deposits, which are short-term and largely
default-risk-free debt claims, we use the 3-too Treasury bill yield as
the reference rate, which we will refer to as the risk-free rate in the
empirical subsection below. The reference rate for savings and time
deposits is the average yield on maturity-matched Treasuries. Its spread
over the 3-mo Treasury yield is a term premium. Similarly, the term
premium for each category of loans is defined as the yield spread
between the loan-maturity-matched Treasuries and 3-mo Treasury bills. We
will show how much the estimate of bank service output would be affected
even if we only account for the term premia in loan interest rates but
not the risk premia.
D. New Estimates of the Value of Borrower and Depositor Services
Given the reference rate for each category of loans, we now
estimate borrower and depositor services. Table 1 is a detailed
exposition using the estimates for the fourth quarter of 2007, comparing
our model-based, service-flow measure of bank output with the measure
that approximates NIPA's current methodology. (43) In total, it
lists five types of services--to holders of two types of deposit
accounts and borrowers of three types of loans. (44) Other categories of
assets and liabilities, such as investment securities and subordinated
debt, are excluded because, as explained in Section II, their holders do
not receive financial services created by banks. (45)
Table 1 shows that for 2007:Q4, the risk-adjusted reference rates
on the three types of loans are at least one percentage point higher
than the risk-free rate. Using the risk-adjusted reference rates lowers
the imputed value of borrower services by $116.8 billion (from $205 to
$88.2 billion). To gauge the impact on GDP, we net out the value of
borrower services to businesses (i.e., services related to commercial
real estate loans and C&I loans). (46) Accordingly, GDP in 2007:Q4
would be $52.9 billion, or 0.4 percentage points, lower using our
risk-adjusted bank output measure. We suspect that this figure is on the
low end because, as detailed above, we have adopted conservative
estimates of risk premia to adjust the reference rates for risk.
Figure 2 plots the respective average risk-adjusted reference rates
for deposits and loans from 1997:Q2 to 2007:Q4. Throughout the sample
period, the risk plus term premium stays positive, so the average
reference rate for loans consistently exceeds that for deposits. For
comparison, Figure 2 also plots the actual average interest rate paid on
deposits and received on loans, respectively. The quarterly average rate
is calculated as the interest received or paid during a quarter over the
average balance of the corresponding instruments for the quarter. (47)
It is clear that the interest rates paid on deposits are on average more
inertial than the risk-free reference rate, a well-documented, stylized
fact in empirical banking studies (e.g., Berger and Hannan 1989).
Likewise, the interest rates received on loans are on average less
volatile than the reference market rates.
Figure 2 also shows that the average loan rate consistently exceeds
the average loan reference rate, implying a positive service spread on
average. In contrast, the average deposit rate was higher than the
deposit reference rate between late 2001 and early 2004. This does not
mean that banks provided transaction services at a loss as bank
customers pay explicit charges as well. To illustrate: in the years when
imputed output related to deposits was negative (-$1.4 billion in 2001
and -$6.3 billion in 2002), the explicit deposit charges amounted to
$29.7 billion (2001) and $31.7 billion (2002). Furthermore, Flannery
(1982) explains negative margins on deposits as reflecting the
quasi-fixed nature of deposit relationships. That is, depositors are to
some degree "locked" into a bank account because of the costs
they would incur to switch banks; in return, banks implicitly commit to
smoothing deposit interest rates. (48) Also note that these negative
margins are not a consequence of estimating risk-adjusted reference
rates because the deposit reference rates contain no risk premia. So,
negative interest margins can well be a feature of the current NIPA
methodology. (49)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In Figure 3 we plot the service spreads for deposits and loans
directly. (50) Not surprisingly, the two spreads frequently move in
opposite directions, as their formulae carry negative signs (see
Equations [6] and [8]), while both actual rates are more inertial than
the respective reference rate. Furthermore, the spreads appear to
co-move with the business cycle: the deposit-service spread narrows,
while the loan-service spread widens following monetary easing in
economic downturns, and vice versa. Variations in the loan-service
spread can mostly be traced to C&I and consumer loans, as the
service spread on real estate loans remains fairly stable throughout the
period (see Figure A2). One possible explanation for this pattern is
that bank C&I loans become riskier relative to commercial paper in
periods of economic weakness, possibly because smaller or riskier firms
are more likely to draw on their credit lines in bad times. If this is
the case, then our empirical results underestimate the risk premium on
C&I loans in such periods.
Figure 4 depicts the imputed bank service income and the
compensation for risk. (51) Compensation for term risk and default risk
represents the difference between our new model-implied measure of bank
output and the NIPA's current measure. Variations over time in
income from the two services echo those in the two service spreads
depicted in Figure 3. The term-risk compensation too is time-varying; it
rises as the yield curve steepens, and falls as the yield curve
flattens. In comparison, the default-risk compensation is more stable
over time. Especially worth noting are the last two quarters of 2007.
Compensation for both default and term risk increased sharply because of
the turmoil in financial markets and the monetary easing that followed
in response.
We note that the output series of implicit bank services based on
our risk-adjusted reference rates is more volatile than that based on
the risk-free reference rate. (52) Some cite this fact as basis for
objecting to risk adjusting the reference rates in practice. We argue
that this result per se is little ground for counting risk compensation
as part of bank output, even considering the likely practical
difficulty.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
First of all, the volatility of growth rates of overall
risk-adjusted bank output, inclusive of explicit fees, is on par as a
number of other industries, including the "securities, commodity
contracts, and investments" industry. (53) So, while risk-adjusted
bank output is more volatile, it does not seem too volatile for use in
the NIPAs. Second, similar comparisons of volatility based on euro area
data (Colangelo and Inklaar 2009) suggest that more detailed interest
rates, such as those based on surveys conducted in the euro area (e.g.,
rates on new business by repricing period) could markedly mitigate
volatility of service spreads. While in our U.S. data the standard
deviation of the overall risk-adjusted interest margin is more than
twice as large as that based on a risk-free rate, the former is only 20%
larger than the latter in a similar comparison based on euro area data.
E. Plausibility Checks
So far, we have made the case for using our measure of bank output
on theoretical grounds, that is, we have explained why the reference
rate used to impute the value of bank service output should be adjusted
for the risk of the associated financial instrument. By removing the
risk premium, this new measure of output reduces banks' operating
surplus. (54) We now examine whether or not the lower surplus is
"implausibly small" as Fixler and Reinsdorf (2006, footnote 6)
have asserted in arguing against risk-adjusted reference rates. We focus
on two indicators, the capital share in value added and the IRR on fixed
capital, as the range of values of each indicator in other industries
can be viewed, under certain conditions, as the plausible benchmark for
comparison. The capital share, defined as the share of operating surplus
in industry value added, gives an indication of the capital intensity of
production in that industry. The IRR is the return an industry or a firm
would need to earn on its fixed capital assets, such as buildings and
computers, to exactly cover the rental cost of fixed capital.
We must note the close link between the IRR and the user cost of
funds. The latter is, in fact, simply the former net of depreciation
(consisting of both obsolescence and physical wear and tear). The
concept of a risk-adjusted user cost in the case of fixed capital has
long been an integral part of investment theories. The IRR in some
industries is consistently higher than in others, even after controlling
for depreciation and expected changes in the price of capital
goods--precisely because investing in those industries incurs greater
systematic risk. Investors thus demand a higher rate of payoff on
average, so long as capital is mobile and the no-arbitrage condition
holds. The risk-based user-cost measure is also routinely used in
industry-level growth accounting studies. (55) We calculate the IRR
using the standard Jorgensonian framework (e.g., Jorgenson, Gollop, and
Fraumeni 1987), and capital includes fixed reproducible assets, such as
buildings and machinery, as well as land and inventories. (56)
The first step is to gauge by how much our new measure would revise
downward total nominal output of all depository institutions. Total
output equals the sum of explicit bank service charges (comprising the
bulk of noninterest income) and implicit revenue from services (i.e.,
our estimate of borrower and depositor service output in Table 1 and
Figure 3). (57) While imputed bank output is overstated by 45% on
average, total banking output is overstated by only 21% on average over
the sample period 1997:Q2-2007:Q4. Next, we obtain a new output estimate
for all depository institutions (i.e., the credit intermediation
industry as defined in the NIPA Industry Account) by assuming that
output of the rest of the industry is overstated by the same percentage
as that of commercial banks in each year. (58) Obviously it would be
preferable to have direct estimates of the overstatement for both
savings banks and credit unions, but that is beyond the scope of this
paper.
Table 2 shows the results of our plausibility exercise comparing
capital shares and internal rates of return according to the current
NIPA measure versus our new measure of output. Under the NIPA output
measure, the banking industry's capital share averages 59%, ranking
it higher than the capital share of the petroleum refining industry and
similar to the share of coal mining. This seems an implausibly high
capital share, as the other industries with similar shares are generally
regarded as intensive users of large-scale machinery. The implication is
that the operating surplus may be implausibly large under the NIPA
measure. The new output measure, by excluding the risk premium,
decreases the capital share of the industry to 42% on average--the same
as the share of private industries as a whole. (59) This is also close
to the capital share of retail trade but higher than that of business
services.
The IRR of the banking industry, based on the NIPA measure of
output, also seems implausibly high, at 17.8%, on average, over the
period. In comparison, the IRR for the private sector as a whole is only
9.3%. The premium of 8 percentage points seems unwarranted by the
systematic risk of the credit intermediaries, as many of those with
publicly traded shares have a beta around one. Once the new measure of
bank output is used, the resulting lower operating surplus reduces the
IRR of the industry to a level close to that of the overall private
sector.
Mis-measured capital assets are a far less plausible reason for the
observed gap between the IRR of the overall private sector and the
financial intermediation industry. It may be argued that credit
intermediaries have built up more intangible assets than the average
private industry, for example, through business reorganization that
complements the investment in information technology (IT). (60) However,
the intermediation industry would need to have an investment share of
intangibles nine times higher than that of the average private industry
to account for the difference in the IRR. This seems unlikely, as the IT
investment share of banks is only 30% higher than that of the overall
private sector. (61)
The decrease in the capital share and the IRR on fixed capital
toward a more reasonable level is an indirect effect of excluding the
risk premium in our new measure of bank output. We therefore view the
results reported in Table 2 as empirical support for the new measure,
complementing the theoretical argument for risk-adjusted reference
rates.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
Banks provide important services to both borrowers and depositors.
They reduce the information asymmetries that impede borrowers'
access to credit, and provide transaction services to depositors.
However, banks generally do not charge explicit fees for these services;
instead, they bundle the fees with loan and deposit interest flows. As a
result, the output value of both borrower and depositor services must be
imputed. In the statistical and research community, it is generally
agreed that the value of such implicit bank services is most
appropriately imputed as the difference between the interest paid on
loans (and interest received on deposits) and the opportunity cost of
the associated funds as determined by a reference rate. The choice of
this reference rate, however, is more contentious. Under the current
system of National Accounts (1993) and in the U.S. NIPA, this reference
rate is stipulated to be a single, risk-free rate.
In contrast, Wang (2003) and WBF (2009) show that, in a world with
risk-averse investors, each reference rate should take account of the
nondiversifiable risk of the associated financial instrument.
Specifically, the opportunity cost of a risky loan is not the return on
a risk-free investment, but rather the return on an investment of
comparable risk. The model in the work of WBF (2009) is an abstract
representation of reality, assuming, for example, (nearly) complete and
efficient financial markets. Relaxing these assumptions would likely
affect the exact risk premium concept that should be incorporated into
the reference rates, but the core message of the model should continue
to hold: passively bearing risk that is priced in the market is not a
productive activity.
In this paper, we show that the output measure implied by the
banking model of WBF (2009) can be implemented for U.S. commercial banks
from 1997 onward. In particular, financial markets provide data on
yields of debt instruments comparable to those held on banks'
balance sheets, enabling us to derive risk-adjusted reference rates. We
show that removing the risk premium, the difference between the
risk-adjusted reference rate and the risk-free rate, is quantitatively
important. Comparing bank output calculated using our risk-adjusted
reference rate with output computed using the risk-free reference rate
according to the current NIPA method, we show that the latter
overstates, on average, imputed bank output by 45%, total bank output by
21%, and U.S. GDP by 0.3%.
Our risk-adjusted reference rates are not perfect, as the bank loan
categories for which interest rates are reported separately are quite
broad. As a result, the matching of risk characteristics between bank
loans and comparable publicly traded debt instruments is imprecise.
Nonetheless, we would argue that we have captured some of the risk
premium by using conservative estimates, and that accounting for some of
the risk premium is an improvement over not accounting for it at all.
Furthermore, estimates of the share of capital in banks' value
added, and the IRR on fixed capital of the banking industry also suggest
that our measure of bank output is more plausible than the current NIPA
measure.
We conclude by drawing two important implications of our paper.
First, we find no convincing theoretical or practical reasons for using
risk-free reference rates in estimating bank output. Instead, we show
that it is feasible to use risk-adjusted reference rates and that doing
so is quantitatively significant. The fact that our risk-adjusted
measure of bank output is both conceptually preferable and leads to more
plausible outcomes argues strongly for changing current statistical
practice to remove the compensation for risk-bearing in general from
bank output. Second, information about loan risk rating and the
attendant interest rates charged by U.S. commercial banks is scarce,
despite the central role of risk rating in measuring bank output, as
well as in studying other important banking issues such as competition
in credit supply. We, therefore, urge the statistical agencies to
improve data collection in this important area.
ABBREVIATIONS
ABCP: Asset-Backed Commercial Paper
ABS: Asset-Backed Securities
C&I: Commercial and Industrial
CP: Commercial Paper
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
GSEs: Government-Sponsored Enterprises
IRR: Internal Rate of Return
IT: Information Technology
MBS: Mortgage-Backed Securities
ML: Merrill Lynch
MM: Modigliani and Miller
NIPA: National Income and Product Accounts
NP: Not Prime
PD: Probability of Default
SNA: System of National Accounts
STBL: Survey of Terms of Business Lending
WBF: Wang, Basu, and Fernald
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00304.x
APPENDIX. DETAILS OF DATA AND ESTIMATION PROCEDURES
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A2 OMITTED]
TABLE A1
Call report items used in calculating
commercial bank interest rates
1997Q2-2000Q4 2001Q1-2007Q4
Interest income
and expenses
Income on real
estate loans RIAD401 I+RIAD4246 RIAD4011
Income on
consumer loans RIAD4013+RIAD4247 RIAD4013
+RIAD4248
Income on commercial
and industrial loans RIAD4012 RIAD4012
Expenses on time and
savings deposits RIAD0093+RIADA517 RIAD0093+RIADA517
+RIADA518 +RIADA518
Loan/deposit balance
Real estate loans RCON 1410 RCON 1410
Credit card loans RCON2008 RCONB538
Other consumer loans RCON2011 RCONB539+RCON2011
Commercial and
industrial loans RCON1766 RCON1766
Time and savings
deposits RCON2385 RCON2385
Demand deposits RCON2210 RCON2210
Maturity data
Real estate loans
(1-4 family) RCONA564-RCONA569 RCONA564-RCONA569
Loans except 1-4
family real
estate loans RCFDA570-RCONA575 RCFDA570-RCONA575
Time deposits of
less than $100 000 RCONA579-RCONA582 RCONA579-RCONA582
Time deposits of
$100,000 or more RCONA584-RCONA587 RCONA584-RCONA587
Notes: Entries refer to the mnemonics used in the Call
Reports, listed under the relevant period(s). Data were
downloaded from the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
(http://www-chicagofed-org/webpages/banking/financial-institution
-reports-commercial-bank-data.cfm). Using the Entity Type Code
variable (RSSD9331), only data covering commercial banks
were selected. A bank is included in the loan interest rate
calculation only when data on both interest income and the
loan balance are available. This requirement mostly affects
banks with less than $25 million in assets, because before
2001 these banks did not have to provide a breakdown of
total interest income by loan category. In 2007, this
category of banks represented around 0.1 % of total
commercial bank assets.
TABLE A2
Notes on Changes in Variable Definitions in the
Call Reports, 1997-2007
Code/Item Note
RIAD4246, Up to 2000, small and medium-sized banks
RIAD4247, used these variables to report their
RIAD4248 interest income for the different loan
categories. RIAD4249 covers interest
income on Commercial and Industrial
loans, but also on all other loans, so
this variable was omitted at the cost of
coverage of the industry loan totals.
Banks with fewer than $25 million in
assets did not have to report any of
these variables.
RCON2008, Up to 2000, banks with domestic and
RCON2011 foreign offices only had to distinguish
between credit card loans and consumer
installment loans for the consolidated
bank. Total loans to individuals are
available for the bank's domestic
offices. To increase coverage, the share
of credit card loans and of consumer
installment loans was calculated based
on the consolidated totals (codes
RCFD2008 and RCFD2011) and applied to
the total for the bank's domestic
offices.
RCONB538, From 2001 onwards, credit card loans
RCONB539 (RCONB538) do not include other
revolving loans (RCONB539) anymore.
REFERENCES
Allen, F., and A. M. Santomero. "What Do Financial
intermediaries Do?" Journal of Banking and Finance, 25(2), 2001,
271-94.
Barnett, W. A. "The User Cost of Money." Economic
Letters, 1(2), 1978, 145-9.
Berger, A. N., and T. H. Hannah. "The Price-Concentration
Relationship in Banking." Review of Economies and Statistics,
71(2), 1989, 291-9.
Berlin, M., and L. Mester, "Deposits and Relationship
Lending." Review of Financial Studies, 12, 1999, 579-607.
Bhattacharya, S., and A. Thakor. "Contemporary Banking
Theory." Journal of Financial Intermediation, 3(1), 1993, 2-50.
Calomiris, C. W., and J. R. Mason. "Credit Card Securitization and Regulatory Arbitrage." Journal of Financial Services Research,
26(1), 2004, 5-27.
Campbell, J. Y., A. W. Lo, and A. C. MacKinlay. The Econometrics of
Financial Markets. Princeton, N J: Princeton University Press, 1997.
Cochrane, J. H. and S. Requejo. "Beyond Arbitrage: GoodDeal
Asset Price Bounds in Incomplete Markets." Journal of Political
Economy, 108(1), 2000, 79-119.
Colangelo, A., and R. Inklaar. Forthcoming. "Measuring the
Output of the Banking Sector: Shortcomings of the Current European
Methodology and New Perspectives." ECB Working Paper Series, 2009.
Corrado, C. A., C. R. Hulten, and D. E. Sichel. "Intangible
Capital and Economic Growth." NBER Working Papers, no. 11948, 2006.
Diewert, W. E. "Intertemporal Consumer Theory and the Demand
for Durables." Econometrica, 42(3), 1974, 497-516.
--. "What Is to Be Done for Better Productivity
Measurement." International Productivity Monitor, 16, 2008, 40-52.
Duffle, D., and K. J. Singleton. Credit Risk: Pricing, Measurement,
and Management. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003.
Dunn, K., and J. McConnell. "Valuation of GNMA Mortgage Backed
Securities." Journal of Finance, 36, 1981, 599-616.
Fixler, D. J. and M. B. Reinsdorf. "Computing Real Bank
Services." Paper presented at the NBER/CRIW Summer Institute
Workshop, 2006. Available at http://
www.nber.org/~confer/2006/si2006/prcr/reinsdorf.pdf.
Fixler, D. J., M. B. Reinsdorf, and G. M. Smith. "Measuring
the Services of Commercial Banks in the NIPA: Changes in Concepts and
Methods." Survey of Current Business, 83(9), 2003, 33-44.
Flannery, M. J. "Retail Bank Deposits as Quasi-Fixed Factors
of Production." American Economic Review, 72(3), 1982, 527-36.
Griliches, Z. (ed). "Output Measurement in the Service
Sectors." NBER Studies in Income and Wealth No. 56, University of
Chicago, 1992.
Griliches, Z. "Productivity, R&D, and the Data
Constraint." American Economic Review, 84(1), 1994, 1-23.
Inklaar, R., M. P. Timmer, and B. van Ark. "Market Services
Productivity across Europe and the US." Economic Policy, 23(53),
2008, 139-94.
Inklaar, R., and J.C. Wang. "Not Your Grandfather's Bank
Any More? Consistent Measurement of Non-Traditional Bank Output."
Mimeo. University of Groningen and Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 2007.
Jorgenson, D. W., F. Gollop, and B. Fraumeni. Productivity and U.S.
Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1987.
Kau, J., D. Keenan, W. Muller, and J. Epperson. "A Generalized
Valuation Model for Fixed-Rate Residential Mortgages." Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, 24, 1992, 279-99.
Modigliani, F. F., and M. H. Miller. "The Cost of Capital,
Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment." American
Economic Review, 48, 1958, 261-97.
Ross, S. A. "The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset
Pricing." Journal of Economic Theory, 13(3), 1976, 341-60.
SNA. System of National Accounts 1993, New York: United Nations,
1993.
Triplett, J. E., and B. P. Bosworth. Productivity in the U. S.
Services Sector: New Sources of Economic Growth. Washington DC:
Brookings Institution Press, 2004.
Wang, J. C. 2003. "Loanable Funds, Risk, and Bank Service
Output." Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper Series No.
03-4. Available at http://www. bos.frb.org/economic/wp/wp2003/wp034.htm.
Wang, J. C., and S. Basu. "Risk Bearing, Implicit Financial
Services, and Specialization in the Financial Industry." Working
paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 2007. Available at
http://www.bos.frb.org/ economic/ppdp/2006/ppdp063.pdf.
Wang, J. C., S. Basu, and J. G. Fernald. "A
General-Equilibrium Asset-Pricing Approach to the Measurement of Nominal
and Real Bank Output," in Price Index Concepts and Measurement.
Studies in Income and Wealth 70, edited by W. E. Diewert, J. S.
Greenlees, and C. R. Hulten. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2009,
273-320.
(1.) See, for example, Diewert (2008); Griliches (1992, 1994);
Inklaar, Timmer, and van Ark (2008); Triplett and Bosworth (2004).
(2.) For a discussion of the current method used in the United
States, see Fixler, Reinsdorf and Smith (2003).
(3.) See SNA (1993, 6.128).
(4.) Differences in systematic risk between industries can explain
differences in the internal rate of return; see Section II. However, our
loan risk premium estimates and stock market betas suggest that an 8%
risk premium is excessive.
(5.) WBF (2009) extend Wang's partial equilibrium model to a
general equilibrium setting, and demonstrate that all the qualitative
results in the study of Wang (2003) continue to hold. Interested readers
who wish to pursue the theoretical issues in greater detail are referred
to those studies.
(6.) For exposition of the theory, we focus on bank lending
services because the measurement problem is made harder by the fact that
the implicit revenue from services is bundled with risk-based asset
(i.e., loan) returns. See Wang (2003) for detailed accounting of
services to depositors. In the empirical application, we also measure
services to depositors.
(7.) Banks' role in resolving information asymmetry is well
recognized in the financial intermediation literature (e.g., see the
survey by Bhattacharya and Thakor 1993). More recently, Allen and
Santomero (2001) broaden the scope to recognize intermediaries'
role as providers of specialized financial expertise. This can be
interpreted as a form of transaction facilitation and thus encompassed
in our definition of bank value added.
(8.) This can be viewed as an extension to what is often referred
to as the "user-cost" framework. Diewert (1974) was one of the
first to introduce this framework and Barnett (1978) first applies it to
financial assets, introducing the concept of "user cost of
money." The key element of our extension is that it takes account
of risk, that is. in the real world where the reward to essentially all
investment is uncertain, the so-called "opportunity cost of
money" is comparable across securities only after adjusting for
risk.
(9.) Who famously cut Bill Clinton's hair on Air Force One at
Los Angeles International Airport (LAX).
(10.) These are all examples of the so-called relative approach to
asset pricing: the value of a specific risky investment is determined
taking the value of all the other assets as given. See Cochrane and
Saa-Requejo (2000) for other applications of this relative approach. One
prominent example is pricing options.
(11.) See WBF (2009) for a more detailed illustration in a
general-equilibrium framework.
(12.) The real-world analogy is a so-called special purpose
vehicle, which is a pure financing arrangement off the balance sheet of
the sponsoring institution. It involves virtually no operational
activities.
(13.) To the extent the portfolio is sufficiently diversified and
the persistence in aggregate shocks is accounted for, realized returns
averaged across firms should basically equal the conditional
expectation.
(14.) The mirror image of this over-counting of bank output is the
under-counting of borrowing firms' output--reduced on average by
([r.sup.A.sub.t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t]) simply because of the change in
accounting method.
(15.) Yields on bonds must be adjusted for the embedded option to
be comparable with those on option-free debt instruments. Bonds that
allow prepayment, such as MBS, essentially have an embedded call option.
(16.) They are typically considered risk-free in that they earn a
guaranteed return, [r.sup.F.sub.t], if the debt is held until maturity.
Note that even for this type of debt there is still interest rate risk,
that is, the holding-period return is almost surely uncertain if one
sells it prior to the maturity date.
(17.) In the consumption-capital asset pricing model, which can be
expressed as a specific case of Equation (1), this means assets with
payoff positively correlated with consumption growth have to pay a
positive return premium.
(18.) That is, the bank charges an implicit price for its
intermediation service, equal to a markup on the marginal cost of
producing that service. The cost is determined by a loan officer's
labor input in processing a loan, plus the amount of physical capital
and supplies used for that task.
(19.) For banks, additional distortions are introduced if deposit
insurance is not fully risk sensitive (see Wang 2003 for a detailed
treatment). Here, we assume that deposit insurance is fairly priced for
the banking industry as a whole, and ignore distributional effects.
(20.) The [d.sup.k.sub.t] equals the product of the probability of
default (PD) and the expected loss rate given default. If the latter is
near 100%, then [d.sup.k.sub.t] is close to the PD. Wang (2003) details
the distinction between promised yield and expected rate of return. The
equation here is exact only for instantaneous returns, and is used as an
approximation in discrete-time cases. See Duffle and Singleton (2003)
for continuous-time models of defaultable debt pricing.
(21.) The conditional estimate of [d.sup.M.sub.t], such as
KMV's expected default frequency, is procyclical.
(22.) See WBF (2009) for a detailed discussion of how the actual
value in each period still deviates from this average.
(23.) As is shown, the balance of loans exceeds that of deposits,
with bank equity making up the difference. This figure is a simplified
version of Figure 1 in Wang (2003), as it ignores risk premia on
deposits because of uninsured deposits. That is, for deposits it sets
[r.sup.M] = [r.sup.F], and overstates depositor services.
(24.) Specifically, it is a weighted average rate of return on all
U.S. Treasury securities held on banks' book. So it generally
exceeds what is commonly viewed as the risk-free rate--the 90-d Treasury
bill rate--as banks also hold longer term Treasury notes and bonds.
(25.) These correspond to the forms FFIEC 031-041; see
www.ffiec.gov for details.
(26.) Release H.15; see http://www.federalreserve.gov/
releases/hi5/. We use the constant-maturity series.
(27.) Release E.2; see http://federalreserve.gov/releases/ e2/. For
more information on banks' internal risk rating, see data reported
in Form FR2028a/s, available from 1997 onward:
http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/ report
forms/ReportDetail.cfm?WhichFormId=FR_2028a/s.
(28.) It is possible, but unlikely, that the systematic component
of risk, which determines the risk premium, is still the same for loans
and the matched securities.
(29.) This means that we estimate a market rate that would be the
theoretically correct reference rate if all the loans in the portfolio
had been (re)priced during the current period.
(30.) For coupon bonds, [r.sup.M] and [r.sup.F] should in fact be
matched by duration, not maturity. However, because we have no data on
the durations of private-sector market debt, we assume that the flow of
their coupon payments is such that each debt's duration is similar
to that of the maturity-matched Treasury.
(31.) "For a 180-d period, these risks are estimated to be
0.00% for P-1, 0.02% for P-2, 0.12% for P-3, and 0.43% for not prime
(NP)." www.moodyskmv.com/research/ whitepaper/60917.pdf.
(32.) It is possible that the loans covered in the survey are still
not representative of the banking industry as a whole, or at all times.
But this is the best micro data source available, and there is no reason
to suspect systematic bias.
(33.) The match is not improved by using asset-backed
commercial-paper (ABCP) which some would argue is a better reference for
secured bank loans. The yields on ABCP and on regular nonfinancial CP
are virtually the same until July, 2007, when the subprime-induced
financial turmoil broke out in the United States.
(34.) AA and BBB are bond ratings by S&P, equivalent to ratings
of Aa2 and Baa2 by Moody's. The mapping between long- and
short-term ratings can be found at
http://federalreserve.gov/releases/cp/about.htm.
(35.) For reference, the risk premium time series for each loan
category is reported separately in Figure A1.
(36.) We choose not to use a general index for the ABS market
because, between 2003 and the first half of 2007, a rapidly growing
share of the market comprised securities backed by subprime and Alt-A
mortgage loans--from less than 20% in 2003 to over 30% in 2006,
according to the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association.
(37.) Credit enhancement can be obtained in a variety of ways. It
can be purchased from third parties such as insurance companies, or
created "internally" by forming a sufficient loss-absorbing
cushion of junior claims within the tranche structure
"wrapped" around a pool of assets in a manner that enables the
issued ABS can obtain senior ratings.
(38.) Using securitization to save on capital requirements is a
form of regulatory arbitrage. This may not be a major concern; for
example, Calomiris and Mason (2004) find little evidence of this
motivation in banks that securitize credit card loans.
(39.) As these are indices for fixed-rate ABS, their average
maturity may exceed that of the underlying consumer loans, some of which
carry floating rates.
(40.) Non-investment-grade bond indices have yields much higher
than the average rate received on consumer loans, most likely because of
the high default premium (i.e., [d.sup.M.sub.t] above).
(41.) None of the conforming residential mortgages that back the
agency MBS carry prepayment penalties; this amounts to an implicit call
option. The option is most likely to be exercised when the current
period mortgage rate falls below the loan's contractual interest
rate. See, for example, Dunn and McConnell (1981) or Kau et al. (1992)
for the magnitude and determinants of prepayment risk.
(42.) There are, of course, timing issues regarding when the
screening or monitoring is done versus when the implicit revenue is
recognized. See WBF (2009) for an in-depth discussion.
(43.) As mentioned before, the NIPA methodology uses the return on
bank Treasury portfolios as their reference rate, see Fixler et al.
(2003). The comparison we make in Figure 1 is based on similar reasoning
though.
(44.) Among the loan categories covered in the Call Reports, we
consider only those for which reasonably similar reference securities
can be found in the market. So, lease financing receivables are
excluded. Moreover, we include only loans and deposits made in
banks' domestic offices, because activities in foreign offices do
not contribute to U.S. GDP. In sum, the four categories in Table 1
account for 90% of the total balance of loans and leases in 2007.
(45.) By excluding these, we further reduce our measure of bank
output relative to the NIPA methodology, which includes other financial
assets and liabilities. However, as shown by Fixler et al. (2003), these
sources of imputed output are quantitatively unimportant.
(46.) We infer the former from total services related to real
estate loans, based on the simplifying assumption that the share of
services to commercial customers is proportional to the share of
commercial loan balances in total real estate loans.
(47.) Table A1 in the Appendix lists the specific data items used
in calculating the average interest rate on each category of securities,
loans, and deposits. Table A2 summarizes major changes, in terms of
reporting requirements and variable definitions, in the Call Reports
between 1997 and 2007 and the way they are handled to arrive at
harmonized time series.
(48.) See also Berlin and Mester (1999) on interest rate smoothing
as a feature of relationship banking.
(49.) in practice, the BEA uses the average return on Treasuries on
bank balance sheets as their overall reference rate. However, these
Treasuries on average have longer maturities than deposit accounts.
(50.) Figure A2 shows the service spread separately for the three
loan categories.
(51.) "Loan services" in the figure corresponds to
[y.sup.A] in Equation (6), and "Deposit services" to [y.sup.D]
in Equation (8). "Default risk compensation" corresponds to
the term [r.sup.A] A in Equation (7). "Term risk compensation"
denotes the return because of maturities longer than 3 mo.
(52.) Using our risk-adjusted reference rates, the average interest
spread on loans and deposits over this period is 1.5 percentage points
with a standard deviation of 0.5 percentage points, while using a
risk-free reference rate the average is 2.4 percentage points with a
standard deviation of 0.2 percentage points.
(53.) The standard deviation of the annual growth rate of bank
output is compared with standard deviation of the annual growth rate of
industry gross output based on the BEA "GDP by Industry"
dataset, both covering the same period of 1998-2007 at an annual basis.
The standard deviation of bank output growth was 14%: the standard
deviation of output growth in the "securities, commodity contracts,
and investments" industry was 16%.
(54.) Operating surplus is defined as value added net of labor
compensation and indirect taxes. As explained above, part of the
"excess" bank operating surplus should be reallocated to
nonfinancial firms that purchase bank services, while the remainder
should be reallocated to interest payments and receipts of households.
(55.) See, for example, Jorgenson, Gollop, and Fraumeni (1987).
(56.) Data are from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
(57.) Note that we exclude the trading-income elements of
noninterest income, as we argue that it is also not output but transfer
of property income; see Inklaar and Wang (2007) for further discussion.
(58.) This industry (NAICS 521 and 522) comprises commercial banks,
the Federal Reserve, savings banks, and credit unions. Commercial banks
account for more than half of the employment. Savings banks, the second
largest category, tend to have a larger share of real estate loans than
commercial banks. Although the risk premium on real estate loans tends
to be somewhat lower than on other loans, a robustness check that
applies the same interest rate margin by loan category to savings banks
leads to similar estimates of overstatement.
(59.) Lower bank operating surplus also means lower operating
surplus for the overall private sector. But taking this into account has
only a minimal effect on the values reported in Table 2 for the private
sector. It is also important to note that we are in all likelihood
underestimating the risk premium, and this means the true capital share
of the banking industry is lower than 42%.
(60.) The BEA counts only software and a few intangibles as
capital. Corrado, Hulten, and Sichel (2006), among others, argue that
the scope of capital should be expanded to cover organizational capital,
brand capital, etc.
(61.) Specifically, 34% versus 26% of total investment.
SUSANTO BASU, ROBERT INKLAAR and J. CHRISTINA WANG *
* We would like to thank Barry Bosworth, Erwin Diewert, John
Fernald, Alice Nakamura, Marshall Reinsdorf, Paul Schreyer, Kevin
Stiroh, Jack Triplett, Frank Wykoff, participants at the 2006 NBER/CRIW
Summer Institute workshop and two anonymous referees, for helpful
conversations and comments on the issues addressed in this paper. The
views expressed in this paper are solely those of the authors and are
not those of the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston.
Basu: Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Boston
College, 140 Commonwealth Avenue, Chestnut Hill. MA 02467; Research
Associate, NBER. Phone +1 617-552-2182, Fax +1 617-552-2308, E-mail
susanto.basu@bc.edu
Inklaar: Assistant Professor, Faculty of Economics and Business,
University of Groningen, PO Box 800, 9700 AV Groningen, The Netherlands.
Phone +31 50 363 4838, E-mail r.c.inklaar@rug.nl
Wang: Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Economic
Research, 600 Atlantic Avenue, Boston, MA 02210. Phone +1 617-973-3209,
Fax +1 617-973-3957, E-mail: christina.wang@bos.frb.org
TABLE 1
The Effect of Risk Adjustment: Imputed Output
of U.S. Commercial Banks at Current Prices
in 2007:Q4 ($billions)
Annualized
Average Interest Interest
Balance Flow Rate (%)
Deposits in 5,504 152 2.8
domestic offices
Demand deposits 486 0.0 0.0
Time and savings 5,018 152.2 3.0
deposits
Loans in domestic 5.471 395 7.2
offices
Real estate loans 3,545 235.3 6.6
Consumer loans 804 80.9 10.1
Commercial and 1,123 78.8 7.0
industrial loans
Total 10,975 547 6.6
Reference Rate
Default
Risk-Free Term and
(%) (%) Term (%)
Deposits in 3.5 3.5 3.5
domestic offices
Demand deposits 3.5 3.5 3.5
Time and savings 3.5 3.5 3.5
deposits
Loans in domestic 3.5 4.0 5.7
offices
Real estate loans 3.5 4.3 5.8
Consumer loans 3.5 3.5 4.9
Commercial and 3.5 3.5 6.0
industrial loans
Total 3.5 3.8 4.6
Imputed Output
Default
Risk-Free Term and Term
Deposits in 39.0 42.5 42.5
domestic offices
Demand deposits 16.9 16.9 16.9
Time and savings 22.1 25.6 25.6
deposits
Loans in domestic 205.0 177.0 83.7
offices
Real estate loans 112.2 84.3 31.5
Consumer loans 53.0 52.9 41.1
Commercial and 39.8 39.8 11.1
industrial loans
Total 244.0 219.5 126.2
Notes: "Average balance" is the average of the balance
reported on December 31, 2007 and September 30, 2007.
"Interest flow" is the actual interest received or paid
within the quarter. "Annualized interest rate" is the
interest flow divided by the average balance and then
annualized. The risk-free reference rate is the average
3-mo Treasury yield, the term-adjusted reference rate is the
Treasury yield corresponding to the average maturity of the
loans or deposits, and the default-and term-adjusted rate
also includes the default-risk premium. See Tables Al and A2
in the Appendix for details of the Call Report data items
used in constructing these variables.
TABLE 2
The Impact of Risk Adjustment on Labor
Share and Internal Rate of Return, 1997-2006
Average
Internal
Capital Rate of
Share in Return on Fixed
Value Added Assets
Financial
intermediation
Risk-free 59 17.8
Risk-adjusted 41 6.8
Private economy 42 9.3
Notes: "Financial intermediation" refers to North American
Industrial Classification System (NAICS) industries 521 and
522 in the Bureau of Economic Analysis's (BEA) GDP by
Industry Account. "Risk-free" and "risk-adjusted" denote the
two measures of bank output that use the risk-free and the
risk-adjusted reference rates (corresponding to the "risk
free" and "default and term" output columns in Table l),
respectively. "Private economy" is as defined in the GDP by
Industry Account. The "capital share in value added"
includes an estimate of the labor compensation of self
employed, assuming they earn the same average wage as
employees. The "internal rate of return on fixed assets" is
the shadow rental rate on the gross capital stock at current
prices that would generate the actual capital compensation
(defined as value added minus labor compensation). All fixed
assets as covered by the Bureau of Labor Statistics are
included, that is, fixed reproducible assets, land and
inventories. The industry-level capital and income data are
available annually for the 1997-2006 period.