Optimal competitive balance in a season ticket league.
Fort, Rodney ; Quirk, James
There is no question the level of play has decreased. Now, do games
become more exciting? Are teams more evenly matched? No question. Is
that good for the game or not? I don't know. I really don't
know. I ask that question all the time.
--NFL Hall of Fame Quarterback Troy Aikman. quoted in Pedulla
(2003).
I think that margin of competition, that margin of the difference
between winning and losing in this league is very small, and I think
that is great for the fans because every team comes in with an
opportunity to win.
--NFL Commissioner Roger Goodell. quoted in Curran (2008).
I. INTRODUCTION
In this article, we lay out the basic welfare foundation of optimal
competitive balance for regular season play in a "closed"
sports league where season tickets dominate sales. This setting best
describes the National Football League (NFL), economically the most
important of the four major North American leagues (NALs). We handle the
case of single-ticket leagues like baseball in Fort and Quirk (2010).
Our chosen focus is on balance during the regular season and details of
all our modeling choices are given in the next section.
The quotes given above help to illuminate the policy issue
addressed by the theory. Is the NFL too balanced as Hall of Fame
Quarterback Troy Aikman's quote suggests? Or is the level of parity
on the field somehow "optimal" as suggested in Commissioner
Goodell's quote? Congressional hearings (U.S. Senate 2001) have
even been convened on the subject in the remaining NALs.
For the policy-oriented literature, it is implicitly taken that
more balance would be an improvement over the result generated by the
leagues themselves (comprehensive reviews are in Fort 2006a; Fort and
Quirk 1995; Szymanski 2003). This debate--among fans, reporters, and
economists--lacks anything remotely resembling any competitive balance
target, for example, an optimal level of competitive balance. From the
perspective of optimality constructs, this intuitive belief that
enhancing competitive balance would on net enhance general fan welfare
may simply be Pareto noncomparable advocacy.
Rottenberg (1956) was the first to detail the problems associated
with a lack of competitive balance. If outcomes on the field, court, or
ice become too predictable, as when there are only a few very dominant
teams, fans of perennially unsuccessful teams may stay away in droves
and some teams in the league may actually go under. Also, even the teams
that survive will have lower revenues if these disillusioned fans
forsake the sport altogether. Thus, leagues have a vested interest in
managing the level of competitive balance. The point of departure for
this article is how the league's profit-maximizing choice of
competitive balance deviates from one specification of the social
welfare-maximizing level of balance.
We address the question of optimal competitive balance comparing
decentralized league outcomes to the level of competitive balance that
maximizes the sum of consumers' and producers' surpluses. We
realize that other possible Pareto optimal outcomes might be developed,
but the surplus maximizing approach does have the virtue of utilizing
theoretical tools that are conceptually amenable to relatively
straightforward measurement and comparison in actual leagues. In
particular, our main result is that whether the decentralized league
result is too much or too little balance, relative to the
surplus-maximizing level, is an empirical matter. If the marginal
impacts of talent rearrangements are larger in smaller-revenue markets
than in larger-revenue markets, then welfare is enhanced by rearranging
talent to create more balance. But if the reverse is true, then less
balance enhances social welfare. The elements required to actually
assess this relationship, namely available data and careful empirical
analysis, can settle the issue.
We also are not blind to the fact that some advocacy of particular
mechanisms to enhance balance actually may be thinly veiled attempts to
redistribute wealth from players to owners and among owners. But that is
another virtue of our exercise. Future assessments of the distributional
consequences of various approaches to competitive balance can now
proceed with a firm grasp of the optimal target.
The article proceeds as follows. In Section II, we compare the
decentralized league model and planner's optimum for leagues that
heavily utilize season ticket sales. Our analysis identifies the
conditions that determine whether the planner would prefer more or less
balance than this type of league will produce in its decentralized
equilibrium. Section III lays out the policy implications. All our
findings suggest that whether more balance is preferred to less rests on
empirical questions that have yet to be assessed. Conclusions and
suggestions for future research are given in Section IV.
II. OPTIMAL COMPETITIVE BALANCE IN A "SEASON TICKET"
LEAGUE
In some leagues, season ticket sales dominate team revenue
functions. For example, the NFL has only eight home games and two
preseason games to sell. Team Marketing Report (2008) tabulates average
seat prices weighted by the proportions of different types of seats in
stadiums for all NFL teams. The highest of these is about $118 per game
suggesting a season ticket price of approximately $1,180. If the team
performs below expectations, fans have only lost the value of the few
games they then choose not to attend. So, football owners are able to do
what every owner would like to do, namely, transfer the risk that the
team performs below expectations to fans. Fans confronted primarily with
season ticket options must make their estimate of the value of that
purchase primarily on the quality of the home team. Further, in terms of
postseason chances, every game in the NFL is more important to fans,
even those against poorer opponents, dampening the importance of
visiting team quality in the fan purchase decision. Our first modeling
choice is to focus on a season ticket league and we will assume that
demand depends upon own ticket price and the team's own winning
percent.
For our second modeling choice, the season ticket league is
analyzed using the "closed league," competitive talent
equilibrium model (originally, El Hodiri and Quirk 1971). Members of a
closed league essentially face a completely inelastic supply of talent;
"open league" members might increase their talent by importing
it from some other league. The NFL, in particular, is distinguished on
the closed league basis from other world leagues (e.g., world football).
Recently, there has been some international talent migration in the
other NALs.
The competitive talent market distinction is best portrayed by the
classical Walrasian tatonnement referee. Using all the information on
the impacts of one team's talent choice on the other teams in the
league, the referee's price comes to rest where no league member
would change their talent choice. While we find this competitive process
acceptable for our needs, especially for NALs, we note that the veracity
of the competitive talent market choice is currently under contention
(see Fort 2006b; Fort and Quirk 2007; Szymanski 2004; Szymanski and
Kesenne 2004). Fort and Quirk (2007) also provide an argument to the
effect that the common knowledge requirement of rational expectations
equilibrium is satisfied for closed, competitive talent market sports
leagues. Formulating our welfare problem in a rational expectations
framework would simply add more complications to what is a very
complicated problem (even in the present Walrasian case). Further, there
is no need to delve into any mechanisms used to alter the league
outcome, such as revenue sharing, in order to derive our comparisons
between the league and the planner. The impacts of revenue sharing in a
rational expectations equilibrium for this type of model are dealt with
in Fort and Quirk (2007).
We also model owners as choosing a single price, rather than as
price discriminators. As is well known from welfare economics, perfect
price discrimination would lead the planner and the league to choose the
same talent distribution, although the distribution of wealth would
likely be different in the two cases. In the NFL, suspicions of price
discrimination might be fueled by the presence of personal seat licenses
(PSLs), for example. A PSL is a lump-sum payment that guarantees its
holder the right to purchase a particular season ticket into perpetuity.
Thus, PSLs resemble two-part prices that might be devices extracting
consumers' surpluses. Additional suspicions are raised when PSLs
are auctioned since auctions also can be surplus extraction devices.
Recently, the New York Jets were able to auction front-row seats around
the 45 yd line for $82,000 each (Waszak 2008).
We ignore price discrimination for a number of reasons (and discuss
auctions shortly). First, the degree to which PSLs really are a price
discrimination mechanism is debatable. If selling rights to consecutive
season tickets really is an attempt at price discrimination then, just
as with magazine subscriptions, we would expect to see some form of
inter-temporal "two-for one deal" marketing approach, but we
do not.
Second, just as a season ticket sells a different product than a
single-game ticket, namely, rights to seat location for the entire
season, PSLs also sell a different product than a standard season
ticket. Under a PSL, the rights to a particular seat, in a particular
location, are lifetime rights. If the PSL replaces a lifetime-fights
season ticket, there is no additional value. But if the PSL adds a
lifetime fight (as it clearly did for the New York Giants, given
previous ticket-holder laments) then value is created. Further,
depending on the package, the PSL grants other access to food and
services.
Third, the variation in PSL prices across fans is based upon
willingness to pay for different locations, a different experience
altogether. The price of New York Giants' PSLs ranges from $1,000
to $20,000 per seat with more than half of the seats costing at least
$5,000 (Vacchiano 2008). The PSL does not include the price of the
tickets.
Fourth, it ends up that season tickets purchased under PSL rights
can be resold in the NFL's official "secondary ticket
market" created in 2007 (Veiga 2007). Indeed, PSLs themselves can
be completely unbundled from the associated season ticket and sold
separately, online (e.g., www.seasonticketrights.com). Preclusion of
resale is typically thought to be a prerequisite for successful price
discrimination.
The final reason for which we ignore price discrimination follows
from practical observation on owner choices to centralize significant
revenue portions, through their league, to be redistributed equally
among owners. Especially, in the season-ticket dominated NFL, television
revenues, branded team merchandise, and emerging electronic rights have
all been centralized through the league. We join Kahn (2007) in
observing that centralizing revenues at the league level limits the
degree to which surpluses can be captured.
As for auctions, the price discrimination idea is that buyers will
be lined up in order of willingness to pay so that surpluses are
extracted. In addition, a PSL auction makes resale of season tickets
different from the usual dissipation of consumer surplus; the surplus
may not go to the reseller who bought tickets at face value without
having to pay a PSL fee. Thus, if there is competition among resellers
bidding for the PSLs themselves, even if the season tickets are resold,
then the team, rather than the resellers, might still be capturing
consumers' surpluses.
This may occur but there are two offsetting features of PSL
auctions to date. First, the New York Jets' auction is the only one
to date so the surplus extraction, if it exists, cannot be general. More
typical is the simple setting of PSL rates by seat location as in the
New York Giants case mentioned above. Second, resale is
nationalized--the resale agreement is between the NFL (not individual
teams) and the reseller. As just mentioned, this type of choice by
owners reduces the chances for surplus extraction.
Our third modeling choice is to focus on regular season play. We
further assume a league at a given absolute level of play, the major
league level, and that all differences among teams at that level are
relative differences (extensions are in Kesenne 2000; Marburger 1997;
Rascher 1997). This builds Rottenberg's (1956) outcome uncertainty
observation into the model since fans care about relative competition.
The remaining modeling choices are as follows. We restrict our
attention to gate and attendance-related local revenue that can be
portrayed as proportional to ticket price (Heilmann and Wendling 1976).
This abstracts from local TV revenue but, at least for the NFL, local TV
is a relatively minor item in team revenues. We assume no team-specific
contributions to the value of talent (Vrooman 1996). Following the
observations in Fort and Winfree (forthcoming), the marginal product of
talent is assumed constant (constant returns to scale since talent is
the long-run choice of team owners) so that characteristics of the
underlying contest success function are essentially assumed away.
We adopt the following notation.
I = {1, ..., n}: an index of the set of teams in the league;
[w.sub.i]: win percent of team i;
p: market price per unit of win percent;
[t.sub.i]([w.sup.i]): ticket price at team i;
[D.sub.i]([t.sub.i]([w.sub.i]), [w.sup.i]): demand for tickets at
team i;
[MRP.sub.i]: marginal revenue product of a unit of win percent
given a revenue maximizing choice of [t.sub.i].
And our assumptions are as follows:
Measurement Assumption: Talent used to produce win percent is
measured so that adding one more unit of talent increases win percent by
one unit. This assumption has two implications. First, the price of a
unit of win percent, p, is also the price of a unit of talent. Second,
the marginal revenue product of win percent, [MRP.sub.i], is also the
marginal revenue product of talent, that is, the demand for talent.
Ticket Price Assumptions: [dt.sub.i]/[dw.sub.i] > 0; Fans are
willing to pay more for higher quality measured by win percent. Further,
for any choice of [w.sub.i], [t.sub.i]([w.sub.i]) is chosen to maximize
revenue for that [w.sub.i], implying ([partial
derivative][D.sub.i]/[partial derivative][t.sub.i])([t.sub.i]/[D.sub.i])
= -1. We use [t.sub.i]([w.sub.i]) to denote the revenue maximizing value
of [t.sub.i], given [w.sub.i]. It is to be noted that this is not the
same thing as maximizing revenue with respect to [w.sub.i].
Attendance Demand Assumptions: For any given [w.sup.i], [partial
derivative][D.sub.i]/[partial derivative][t.sub.i] < 0 SO that ticket
demand slopes downward for any [w.sup.i]; for any [t.sub.i], [partial
derivative][D.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sup.i] > 0 with [[partial
derivative].sup.2][D.sup.i]/ [partial derivative][w.sup.2.sub.i] < 0
so that increased quality shifts demand to the right, but at a
decreasing rate.
Talent Demand Assumption: For any [t.sub.i], [partial
derivative][MRP.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i] < 0, the demand
for talent slopes downward to the right.
Given all of the groundwork, above, the profit function for team i
is:
(1) [[pi].sub.i] =
[t.sub.i]([w.sub.i])[[D.sub.i]([t.sub.i]([w.sub.i]), [w.sub.i])] -
p[w.sub.i], i = 1, ..., n.
It has to be noted that, consistent with a season ticket league, we
assume that ticket demand depends upon own ticket price and the
team's own winning percent. At a maximum of profits, the
first-order conditions are:
(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Equation (2) shows that all team owners set the marginal revenue
product of talent equal to the marginal cost of talent. In Equation (2),
even though t is a function of w, our Ticket Price Assumption (t is
chosen to maximize revenue for any value of w so that ([partial
derivative][D.sub.i]/[partial derivative][t.sub.i])([t.sub.i]/[D.sub.i])
= -1) ends up canceling out all terms involving dt/dw.
Let [t.sup.*.sub.i] = [t.sub.i] ([w.sup.*.sub.i]), [D.sup.*.sub.i]
= [D.sub.i]([t.sub.i]([w.sup.*.sub.i]), [w.sup.*.sub.i]) and
[MRP.sup.*.sub.i] = [MRP.sup.i]([t.sub.i]([w.sup.*.sub.i]),
[w.sup.*.sub.i]), i = 1, ..., n, be the profit-maximizing ticket price,
and ticket demand and talent demand evaluated at that price,
respectively. There is a league profit-maximizing equilibrium at the
optimal ticket price vector, talent choice vector, and price of talent,
([t.sup.*], [w.sup.*], p), if:
(3) [MRP.sup.*.sub.i] - p = 0, i = 1, ..., n, and [n.summation over
(i=1)] [w.sup.*.sub.i] = n/2.
Equation (3) shows that, at a league profit-maximizing equilibrium,
marginal revenue product of talent is equalized across the league, that
is:
(4) [MRP.sup.*.sub.i] - [MRP.sup.*.sub.j] = 0, i, j = 1, ..., n.
For what follows, we observe two implications from Equation (4).
First, given our Ticket Price Assumption, this equilibrium also has
total revenue maximized for the league as a whole. We make use of this
observation in our specification of the planner's optimum shortly.
Second, in our model, it is possible for league revenues to be
maximized, consistent with Equation (4) and the Ticket Price Assumption,
at a constant vector [w.sup.*] = 0.500, that is, a perfectly balanced
league. However, Equation (2) makes it clear that this can only occur if
[MRP.sub.i] = [MRP.sub.j] for all i, j = 1, ..., n and for any common
equilibrium value of w. As long as there is variation in talent demand
itself, the league cannot be perfectly balanced. We make headway at this
point by imposing well-ordered variation in ticket demands across the
teams in the league:
Globally Invariant Drawing Power (GIDP) Assumption: Assume the set
of teams I = {1, ..., n} is listed in order of drawing power such that:
i. i [greater than or equal to] j, [w.sub.i] [greater than or equal
to] [w.sub.j] [??][D.sub.i](t, [w.sub.i]) > [D.sub.j](t, [w.sub.j])
for any common t [greater than or equal to] 0.
ii. Let [q.sub.D] be the number of tickets demanded. Then, i
[greater than or equal to] j, [w.sub.i] [greater than or equal to]
[w.sub.j] [??] [D.sub.i.sup.-1]([q.sub.D], [w.sub.i]) [greater than or
equal to] [D.sub.u.sup.-1]([q.sub.D], [w.sub.j]) for any common
[q.sub.D].
iii. i > j implies [t.sup.*.sub.i] > [t.sup.*.sub.j] in
equilibrium.
Generally speaking, this is the well-known larger- and
smaller-revenue market distinction common in the analysis of sports
leagues. Under the GIDP Assumption, team 1 occupies the largest-revenue
market; team 2 is in the next largest-revenue market and so on down to
team n. This seems reasonable especially over any relevant team or
league planning horizon since the location of teams helps determine
their drawing power and team location is completely in the hands of the
league itself.
We first look at competitive balance in the decentralized
profit-maximizing equilibrium of the season ticket league (proofs of
propositions are in the Appendix):
PROPOSITION 1. In an n-team season ticket league, with a
competitive talent equilibrium, with GIDP among teams, league revenues
are maximized at ([t.sup.*], [w.sup.*]) satisfying Equation (4) where
[t.sup.*.sub.i] > [t.sup.*.sub.j] and [w.sup.*.sub.i] >
[w.sup.*.sub.j], for all i > j.
Proposition 1 shows that the decentralized league equilibrium
exhibits competitive imbalance with larger-revenue market teams winning
more than smaller-revenue market teams. As discussed earlier, the only
time this will not be true is if (removing the GIDP Assumption) there
are no larger- and smaller-revenue markets to begin with, that is,
talent demand is identical in all markets.
We next consider the planner's optimum. For simplicity, we
have the planner take the monopoly pricing power of each team as given.
Let [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] be fans'
surpluses and team's surplus in market i, respectively. [Correction
added on 20 May 2010 after first publication online on 25 February 2010:
in the preceding sentence, the expression [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and [R.sub.i] =
[t.sub.i]([w.sub.i])[[D.sub.i]([t.sub.i], ([w.sub.i]),[w.sub.i])] was
corrected to [R.sub.i] = [t.sub.i][D.sub.i]([t.sub.i],[w.sub.i]).] We
use revenues for team surpluses since (noted above) decentralized profit
maximization by owners in a season ticket league leads to maximization
of the league's total revenue anyway. The planner chooses the
vector w (the distribution of talent and, hence, competitive balance) to
maximize the sum of surpluses, accounting for the adding-up constraint.
The Lagrangean for this problem is:
(5) L = [n.summation over (i=1)] ([C.sub.i] + [R.sub.i]) + [lambda]
([n.summation over (i=1)] [w.sub.i] - n/2).
and the first-order conditions are:
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Let [t'.sub.i] = [t.sub.i]([w'.sub.i]), [D'.sub.i] =
[D.sub.i]([t.sub.i]([w'.sub.i]), [w'.sub.i]) and
[MRP'.sub.i] = [MRP.sub.i]([t.sub.i]([w'.sub.i]),
[w'.sub.i]), i = 1, ..., n, be the welfare-maximizing ticket price,
and ticket demand and talent demand evaluated at that price,
respectively. The two derivatives in the first-order condition with
respect to [w.sub.i] are:
(7) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [t'.sub.i] = [t.sub.i]([w'.sub.i]). [Correction
added on 20 May 2010 after first publication online on 25 February 2010:
Equation (7),[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(8) [partial derivative] [R.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i] =
[t'.sub.i] [partial derivative][D'.sub.i]/[partial
derivative][w.sub.i] = [MRP'.sub.i]
where [t'.sub.i] = [t.sub.i]([w'.sub.i]). [Correction
added on 20 May 2010 after first publication online on 25 February 2010:
Equation (8), [partial derivative][R.sub.i]/[partial
derivative][w.sub.i] = [partial derivative][t'.sub.i]/[partial
derivative][w.sub.i][D's.ub.i] + [t'.sub.i] [partial
derivative][D.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i] = [partial
derivative][t'.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i] [D'.sub.i]
+ [MRP'.sub.i], was corrected to [partial
derivative][R.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i] - [t's.sub.i]
[partial derivative][D'.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i] =
[MRP'.sub.i].]
In Equations (7) and (8), no terms containing [[partial
derivative][t'.sub.i]/[[partial derivative][w.sub.i] appear since
ticket revenues adjust optimally. Further, in Equation (7), regardless
of which demand function is determined by a particular [w.sub.i], the
quantity demanded at [t.sub.i] = [infinity] must be zero, that is,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], for any level of
team quality, if the owner charges an infinite price then zero tickets
are sold. Substituting Equations (7) and (8) into Equation (6), the
first-order conditions become:
(9) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[Correction added on 20 May 2010 after first publication online on
25 February 2010: the preceding paragraph has been amended in line with
the post-publication corrections for Equations (7), (8) and (9), and
Equation (9) was corrected.] Finally, Equation (9) implies the following
for the planner's equilibrium:
(10)[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
As our earlier observation on the league profit-maximizing outcome,
the first thing we observe here is that it is possible for welfare to be
maximized, consistent with Equation (9) and the Ticket Price Assumption,
at a constant vector [w.sup.*] = 0.500, that is, a perfectly balanced
league. Once again, identical demands allow this to happen since both
the fight-hand side of Equation (10) vanishes and [MRP'.sub.i] =
[MRP'.sub.j] for all i, j = 1, ..., n and for all values of w.
However, as long as there is variation in talent demand itself, the
league cannot be perfectly balanced since the fight-hand side of
Equation (10) cannot be zero.
However, unlike the league profit-maximizing outcome, adding the
GIDP Assumption to the Talent Demand Assumption does not settle
anything. Under these two assumptions (the latter has declining
[MRP.sub.i] with respect to [w.sub.i]), we can only find that i > j
implies ([partial derivative][D.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i])
< ([partial derivative][D.sub.j]/[partial derivative][w.sub.j]) in
equilibrium with [w.sup.*.sub.i]> [w.sup.*.sub.j]; the marginal
effect of an increase in talent on ticket demand is larger in the
smaller-revenue market j. But this is not enough to settle the issue
since the sign of the right-hand side of Equation (10) also rests on the
range of integration of these demand effects, that is, [t.sub.j] >
[t'.sub.j] and [t.sub.i] > [t'.sub.i]. Reasonably,
[t'.sub.i] > [t'.sub.j] by the GIDP Assumption, but the
sign of Equation (10) rests on the magnitude of this difference.
So, the difference between the league revenue-maximizing
equilibrium result in Equation (4) and the planner's optimum rests
on the right-hand side of Equation (10). On the right-hand side of
Equation (10), attendance for each team changes directly with a change
in that team's own talent level and surpluses follow suit. But it
is the size of the marginal fan surpluses with respect to talent, in the
smaller-revenue market compared to the larger-revenue market, which
determines whether an increase in balance is welfare enhancing. Without
assuming the problem away, and with the virtue of highlighting what
ultimately will be an empirical issue, the following can be shown.
PROPOSITION 2. In an n-team season ticket league, with a
competitive talent equilibrium, with GIDP among teams, with a planner
that maximizes the sum of consumers' and producers' surpluses,
if for [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] then welfare
is maximized at (t(w'), w') where (1) [t'.sub.i] >
[t'.sub.j] and [w'.sub.i] > [w'.sub.j], for all j [not
equal to] i and (2) [w'.sub.i] < [w'.sub.j] and
[w'.sub.j] > [w.sup.*.sub.j], for all j < i.
Proposition 2 shows that the planner's equilibrium is also
characterized by imbalance, but less so than the decentralized league
equilibrium, as long as the marginal fan surpluses with respect to
talent are larger in the smaller-revenue market than the larger-revenue
market [i.e., the right-hand side of Equation (10) is positive].
Otherwise, it could be the case that the league has chosen the welfare
maximizing level of balance [the right-hand side of Equation (10) is
zero], or that a decrease in balance could be welfare enhancing [the
right-hand side of Equation (10) is negative].
To us, the intuition behind the condition in Proposition 2
concerning the relationship between [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] goes as follows. In the last five seasons (2003-2007), Forbes
annual reports on NFL team finances show that the New England Patriots have been among the revenue leaders (second, four times; fifth, the
other) and the most successful team on the field among the revenue
leaders (14-2, 14-2, 10-6, 12-4, 16-0)(data can be checked in Fort
2010). The Arizona Cardinals were at the other end of the revenue
spectrum (among the bottom five revenue teams four times and dead last
three times) and equally unsuccessful (4-12, 6-10, 5-11, 8-8). In the
condition in Proposition 2, marginal surpluses would be lower in New
England (the larger-revenue team) because the much higher level of
success on the field would have their fans with a lower marginal
willingness to pay for additional winning. We emphasize that this occurs
at the margin--it is not that fans in smaller-revenue markets are
willing to pay more in total to see winners than fans in larger-revenue
markets. Of course, this is just an example and rigorous empirical work
is required to pass judgment on this theoretical construct.
We also note that the foregoing allows for the possibility that the
planner may choose balance in such a way that a dynasty team dominates.
Technically, this is a postseason issue beyond our regular season model.
However, there is a relationship since the winner of the regular season
could be that dynasty team. The planner's optimal level of balance
may result in the same team winning year after year, albeit at a lower
expected value if the planner would increase league balance. But from
the planner's perspective, this would occur because somehow the
presence of a dynasty team was also an important element determining fan
willingness to pay.
Of course, the ultimate value of Proposition 2 is that it states
the conditions under which an increase in balance will be welfare
enhancing in the form of a testable hypothesis. A suitable statistical
test is to determine whether the right-hand side of Equation (10) is
positive. Marginal impacts of winning percent on attendance can be
obtained from estimating attendance demand. Since ticket prices are also
available, the data required to do the test are observable.
III. POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Starting from this basic welfare theory foundation, what are the
implications for the policy issues detailed in Section I? For the season
ticket league, whether or not improved balance also improves welfare
(defined as the sum of fans' and owners' surpluses) depends on
the marginal impact on consumers' surpluses in larger-revenue and
smaller-revenue markets due to talent rearrangements in the two markets.
The verdict of empirical work on this ambiguity will determine whether
welfare will be improved by enhancing competitive balance, reducing it,
or simply leaving it alone. This finding suggests that settling the
debate over competitive balance requires knowledge of the relative sizes
of changes in fan surpluses and ticket prices, between larger- and
smaller-revenue markets, that accompany alterations in team qualities.
In essence, estimates of the impact of changes in quality on
attendance actually measure the empirical importance of
Rottenberg's (1956) uncertainty of outcome hypothesis; how does
attendance respond to increases in a team's own quality? Estimates
of these impacts to date have been somewhat clumsy and not clearly
directed to the issues raised in Proposition 2, but they are evolving
[the review in Szymanski (2003) covers their findings while the review
in Fort (2006a) covers the shortcomings of the approaches]. The analysis
here dictates that these estimates are required before making any
attempt to alter competitive balance.
To make these observations a bit more concrete, as mentioned
earlier, some worry that the NFL may be too balanced. This view rejects
Proposition 2 so that less balance would enhance fans' welfare. But
this type of rejection is intuitive; only a careful econometric analysis
of the direct effects stated in Proposition 2 would actually decide the
issue.
While identification of mechanisms to either enhance or reduce
competitive balance is out of place given our findings, our examination
of optimal competitive balance does offer the following observation. In
the event that league choices are judged suboptimal, owners in NALs
cannot be expected to violate their profit-maximizing choices of their
own volition. Also, there is no external regulatory agency to enforce
the talent redistribution in an NAL that would have to occur. To date,
there has only been Congressional brow-beating of the variety cited in
Section I (U.S. Senate 2001). Thus, there is a regulatory structure
hurdle to leap in order to move decentralized league decision making
toward the welfare improvements under the planner's optimum.
From this perspective, one policy prescription--breaking up NALs
into competitive separate leagues--has two attractive features to
recommend it (see Horowitz 1976; Noll 1976; Quirk and Fort 1999; Ross
1989, 1991). First, the structure for this type of intervention already
exists under the antitrust laws. Fort (2007) lists the references in the
argument over practical, case-by-case antitrust intrusions into sports,
but the first important observation is that the structure for antitrust
intervention is in place and breaking up production units has been
accomplished in the past (e.g., the AT&T break up into seven
"baby Bells," finalized in 1982).
The second attractive feature of an antitrust move to break up
sports leagues involves the chances for a Pareto improvement in
fans' welfare. Proponents cited above have developed the argument
that, if two competing leagues were created from an existing league, the
result would unleash competitive forces so that a team would exist in
every economically viable location without sacrificing the goodwill
investment that the owners have already made in existing teams. If the
result of such a break up approaches the competitive distribution of
teams, Pareto optimality would reign over the distribution of talent
among these teams with the sum of producers' and consumers'
surpluses maximized. This would be the planner's outcome with
optimal competitive balance detailed in this article. Competition would
distribute teams so that any remaining smaller- and larger-revenue
potential among the franchises would approximate the optimal
distribution of talent in the planner's outcome in Equation (10)
for the season ticket league.
Other impacts of the imposition of competition have been covered in
detail in the references cited above. For example, well-known from basic
welfare analysis, moving from an inefficient outcome to the
planner's surplus-maximizing optimum, it will be the case that the
distribution of talent changes because there will be more teams in more
cities. As a result, teams that had more talent may now have less. But
if this redistribution truly is a welfare improvement, then gains in
under-served markets will more than offset.
To conclude our policy discussion, we are not so naive as to
believe that the sum of fan and owner welfare matters in the policy
process. Indeed, public choice analysis often reveals that social
welfare may matter little in the policy process. Every move away from
any league's profit-maximizing choice will have distributional
consequences on players, owners, and fans. Indeed, leagues have a
variety of mechanisms for attaining their own ends and the ones chosen
and favored by leagues must have favorable distributional consequences
for them. But identifying the optimal level of competitive balance is
important because doing so sets the stage for the analysis of the
distributional consequences relative to welfare maximization; it is
possible to know the cost in terms of fan welfare of violating the
planner's optimum.
IV. CONCLUSIONS AND SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH
We attempt to seek remedy for the absence of considerations of the
optimal level of competitive balance in North American pro sports
leagues. We devise a planner's optimal talent distribution for
regular season play that maximizes the sum of fans' and teams'
surpluses. This outcome is compared to decentralized, profit-maximizing
outcome for a closed league where season ticket sales dominate team
revenues (like in the NFL).
As long as owners in different locations face variation in demand
functions, the profit-maximizing outcome yields competitive imbalance.
The balance that the season ticket league has depends on the marginal
surpluses created in larger-revenue markets relative to smaller-revenue
markets following a planner's alteration in the distribution of
talent. Theoretically, the possibility remains that the league's
profit-maximizing distribution of talent also maximizes fan welfare.
For policy implications, first, only careful empirical tests can
determine whether enhancing or reducing balance is welfare improving for
our season ticket league. Careful estimates of impacts of talent choice
on attendance demand for all teams are required in order to choose
intervention mechanisms that effectively hit the optimal level of
competitive imbalance. To date, this type of careful assessment is
missing in the debate over competitive balance. Second, unless it also
maximizes profits, we do not expect that owners will choose the optimal
level themselves. Currently, there is no external regulatory structure
governing NALs that could impose the planner's optimum using the
variety of mechanisms that are capable of changing competitive balance.
Third, the antitrust remedy of breaking up the leagues does already have
the requisite legal structure and precedence. Also, if the forces of
competition can drive a Pareto result, then the optimal level of balance
that maximizes the sum of fans' and teams' surpluses, detailed
in this article, would be achieved.
There are many avenues for future work suggested by this analysis.
We utilize the competitive talent market model most applicable to NALs.
But initial investigations by Szymanski (2004), Szymanski and Kesenne
(2004), and Easton and Rockerbie (2005) suggest that other leagues
around the world may be better treated with noncooperative models. Also,
extensions beyond gate demand to include local TV will no doubt prove
insightful, for example, beyond the NFL (a league that sells all games
in a national contract). For that matter, different owner objectives
would produce different decentralized league outcomes for comparison to
the planner's optimum [most recently, Fort and Quirk (2004) and
Kesenne (2005)]. Further, we do not address the case where a league
might be dominated by single-game ticket sales (more likely for, say,
Major League Baseball). Finally, ours is an assessment of optimal
balance during the regular season. While regular season balance bears
directly on playoff accessibility, models of optimal playoff balance
remain for future work.
APPENDIX: PROOFS OF PROPOSITIONS
PROPOSITION 1. By assumption, based on simple observation [item
(iii) under our GIDP Assumption], [t.sup.*.sub.i] > [t.sup.*.sub.j]].
We seek to show that in equilibrium, [w.sup.*.sub.i] >
[w.sup.*.sub.j].
For [w.sup.*.sub.i] > [w.sup.*.sub.j], the GIDP Assumption has
[MRP.sub.i] > [MRP.sub.j] for any 0 [less than or equal to] w [less
than or equal to] 1 and for all j [not equal to] i. Since our Talent
Demand Assumption has [partial derivative][MRP.sub.i]/[partial
derivative][w.sub.i] < 0, then [MRP.sub.i] > [MRP.sub.j] for any 0
[less than or equal to] w [less than or equal to] 1 and for all j [not
equal to] i implies [w.sup.*.sub.j].
PROPOSITION 2. Again, item (iii) under the GIDP Assumption suggests
[t'.sub.i] > [t'.sub.j]. We seek o show that if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] [the right-hand side
of Equation (10) is positive] then (1) [w'.sub.i] >
[w'.sub.j], for all j < i and (2) [w'.sub.i] <
[w*.sub.i] and [w'.sub.j] > [w.sup.*.sub.j] for any j < i.
For any j < i, [w'.sub.i] > [w'.sub.j] follows
lines similar to the proof of Proposition 1, using the additional
assumption that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. For
[w'.sub.i] > [w'.sub.j], the GIDP Assumption has
[MRP.sub.i] > [MRP.sub.j] for any 0 < w < 1 and for all j <
i. Since our Talent Demand Assumption has OMRPi/Owi < 0, MRPi >
MRPj for any 0 [less than or equal to] w [less than or equal to] 1 and
for all j [not equal to] i implies [w'.sub.i] > [w'.sub.j].
For [w'.sub.i] < [w.sup.*.sub.i], it has to be noted that
first our Talent Demand Assumption has [partial
derivative][D.sup.*.sub.i]/[partial derivative][w.sub.i] > 0 and
[partial derivative][D.sub.j]/[partial derivative][w.sub.j] > 0 so
that and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. If we
evaluate the planner's optimum depicted in Equation (10) at
[w.sup.*], the decentralized league equilibrium, then the planner's
optimum is the same as the league profit-maximizing equilibrium if and
only if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. But for the
planner to rearrange talent so that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], the planner would have to move talent toward the
smaller-revenue market, j, implying that (locally, at least)
[w'.sub.i] < [w.sup.*.sub.i]. Then
[[summation].sup.n.sub.i=1][w.sub.i] = n/2 implies [w'.sub.j] >
[w.sup.*.sub.j], for all j < i. Moving from the league profit-
maximizing equilibrium to a planner's optimum would be in the
direction of more competitive balance.
ABBREVIATIONS
GIDP: Globally Invariant Drawing Power
NAL: North American League
NFL: National Football League
PSL: Personal Seat Licenses
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00264.x
REFERENCES
Curran, T. E. "Is Parity Making NFL Games Less
Watchable?" nbcsports.msnbc.com, September 25. 2008. Accessed
October 7, 2008. http://nbcsports.msnbc.com/id/26894728.
Easton, S.T., and D. W. Rockerbie. "Revenue Sharing,
Conjectures, and Scarce Talent in a Sports League Model." Journal
of" Sports Economics, 6, 2005, 359-78.
El-Hodiri, M., and J. Quirk. "'An Economic Model of a
Professional Sports League." Journal of Political Economy, 70,
1971, 1302-19.
Fort, R. "Competitive Balance in North American Professional
Sports," in Handbook of Sports Economics Research. edited by J.
Fizel. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 2006a, 190-208.
--. "Talent Market Models in North American and World
Leagues," in Sports Economics after Fifty Years: Essays in Honour
of Simon Rottenberg, edited by P. Rodriguez, S. Kesenne, and J. Garcia.
Oviedo, Spain: Oviedo University Press, 2006b, 83-106.
--. "Sports Leagues and the Antitrust Laws," in Industry
and Firm Studies, edited by V. J. Tremblay and C. H. Tremblay. Armonk,
NY: M. E. Sharpe, Inc., 2007, 245-68.
--. Rodney Fort's Sports Business Data Pages. 2010. Accessed
January 26, 2010. http://www.rodneyfort.com/SportsData/BizFrame.htm.
Fort, R., and J. Quirk. "Cross-Subsidization, Incentives, and
Outcomes in Professional Team Sports Leagues." Journal of Economic
Literature, XXXIII, 1995, 1265-99.
--. "Owner Objectives and Competitive Balance." Journal
of Sports Economics, 5, 2004, 30-42.
--. "The Competitive Talent Market Model: Rational
Expectations in Pro Sports Leagues.'" Scottish Journal of
Political Economy, 54, 2007, 374-87.
--. "Optimal Competitive Balance in Single-Game Ticket Sports
Leagues." Journal of Sports Economics, 2010. Early View: DOI:
10.1177/1527002509359906.
Fort, R., and J. Winfree. "Sports Really Are Different: The
Contest Success Function and the Supply of Talent." Review of
Industrial Organization, 34, 2009, 69-80.
Heilmann, R. L., and W. R. Wendling. "A Note on Optimum
Pricing Strategies for Sports Events," in Management Science in
Sports, edited by R. E. Machol, S. P. Ladany, and D. G. Morrison.
Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland Publishing Company, 1976.
Horowitz, I. Testimony on Inquiry into Professional Sports, Select
Committee on Professional Sports, House of Representatives, 94th
Congress, 2d Session, part 2, September 1976, 131-36.
Kahn, L. M. "Sports League Expansion and Consumer
Welfare." Journal of Sports Economics, 8, 2007, 115-38.
Kesenne, S. "Revenue Sharing and Competitive Balance in
Professional Team Sports." Journal of Sports Economics, 1, 2000,
56-65.
--. "Revenue Sharing and Competitive Balance: Does the
Invariance Proposition Hold?" Journal of Sports Economics, 5, 2005,
98-106.
Marburger, D. R. "Gate Revenue Sharing and Luxury Taxes in
Professional Sports." Contemporary Economic Policy, XV, 1997,
114-23.
Noll, R. G. Testimony on Inquiry into Professional Sports, Select
Committee on Professional Sports, House of Representatives, 94th
Congress, 2d Session, part 2, September 1976, 131-36.
Pedulla, T. "NFL Dynasties Go 'Way of the
Dinosaurs.'" USAToday.com, January 23, 2003. Accessed October
9, 2006. http://www.usatoday.com/sports/football/
super/2003-01-23-1acover-dynastiesx.htm.
Quirk, J., and R. Fort. Hard Ball: The Uses and Abuses of Market
Power in Professional Sports. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
1999.
Rascher, D. "A Model of a Professional Sports League," in
Advances in the Economics of Sport, Vol. 2, edited by W. Hendricks.
Greenwich, CT: JAI, 1997, 27-76.
Ross, S. F. "Monopoly Sports Leagues." Minnesota Law
Review, 73, 1989, 643-761.
--. "Break Up the Sports League Monopolies," in The
Business of Professional Sports, P. D. Staudohar and J. A. Mangan.
Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press, 1991, 152-74.
Rottenberg, S. "The Baseball Players' Labor Market."
Journal of Political Economy, 64, 1956, 242-58.
Szymanski, S. "The Economic Design of Sporting Contests."
Journal of Economic Literature, XLI, 2003, 1137-87.
--. "Professional Team Sports Are Only a Game: The Walrasian
Fixed-Supply Conjecture Model, Contest-Nash Equilibrium, and the
Invariance Principle." Journal of Sports Economics, 5, 2004,
111-26.
Szymanski, S., and S. Kesenne. "Competitive Balance and
Revenue Sharing in Team Sports." Journal of Industrial Economics,
52, 2004, 165-77.
Team Marketing Report. "National Football League Fan Cost
Index." 2008. Accessed October 7.
http://www.teammarketing.com/fancost/nfl.
U.S. Senate. "Baseball's Revenue Gap: Pennant for Sale?
Hearing before the Subcommittee on Antitrust, Business Rights, and
Competition of the Committee on the Judiciary," United States Senate, 106th Congress, 2nd session, November 21, 2000, 2001.
Vacchiano, R. "Giants Release Cost of Personal Seat Licenses
in New Stadium." Daily News online. 2008. Accessed February 19,
2009. http://www.nydailynews.com/sports/football/giants/2008/07/17/2008-07-17_ giants_release_cost_of_personal_seat_lic.html.
Veiga, A. "Ticketmaster, NFL Ink Ticket Resale Deal."
USAToday, online. 2007. Accessed February 19, 2009.
http://www.usatoday.com/tech/products/2007-12-18868452254_x.htm.
Vrooman, J. "The Baseball Players' Labor Market
Reconsidered." Southern Economic Journal, 63, 1996, 339-60.
Waszak, D., Jr. "Jets' PSL Auction Nets $16 Million:
Owner Calls It 'Absolutely Amazing.' "New York Post,
online. 2008. Accessed February 19, 2009.
http://www.nypost.com/seven/10282008/sports/jets/jets_psi_
auction_nets_16_million_135733.htm.
Fort: Sport Management. School of Kinesiology, University of
Michigan, 1402 Washington Heights, Rm. 3150, Ann Arbor. MI 48109-2013.
E-mail rodfort@umich.edu
Quirk: Division of Humanities and Social Science, California
Institute of Technology (Retired)