Does raiding explain the negative returns to faculty seniority?
Bratsberg, Bernt ; Ragan, James F., Jr. ; Warren, John T. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Economists have studied various aspects of faculty mobility.
Research shows that turnover is greater among nonunion faculty (Rees
1994); female faculty average slightly more employers than male faculty
(Barbezat and Hughes 2001; Ginther and Kahn 2004) (1); the
responsiveness of turnover to relative pay diminishes with rank
(Ehrenberg, Kasper, and Rees 1991); and research productivity enhances
prospects for upward mobility (Ault, Rutman, and Stevenson 1979, 1982;
Coupe, Smeets, and Warzynski 2005). Still, questions remain unanswered:
Where do faculty go when they leave a university? How does faculty
turnover vary with time at a university? What percentage of faculty move
upward and what percentage move downward because of tenure denials or
the prospect of being turned down for tenure? The present article
contributes to our understanding of these issues, but its primary
objective was to use data on faculty mobility to provide insights on
another issue: returns to academic seniority.
The negative returns to seniority that many studies find are
commonly attributed to one of two factors. (2) The first view is that
negative returns reflect monopsony power on the part of universities.
Faculty with high mobility costs acquire high seniority and, because
they are unlikely to move, they are paid less than equally productive
faculty that employers view as more likely to leave. A competing
explanation is that highly productive faculty are "raided."
According to this story, returns to seniority are biased negatively
because faculty with high seniority tend to have low unmeasured
productivity. The best faculty are bid away, moving on to better jobs.
Those who remain are the faculty without outside offers, and the
negative returns estimated for senior faculty actually reflect a penalty
for low unmeasured productivity rather than a true penalty for
seniority.
The raiding story has several implications. First, estimated
returns to seniority should become less negative the more fully the
productivity is measured. Second, estimated returns should be less
negative once we control for faculty who are bid away. Finally, and of
particular importance, estimated returns to seniority should not be
negative for faculty who are bid away, the faculty for whom unmeasured
productivity is presumably high. With the right data set, these
hypotheses can be tested. Rejection of the raiding hypothesis would
provide tacit evidence of monoposony in academic markets. (3)
This article contributes to the literature in several ways. It is
the first research to directly test the raiding hypothesis. It provides
a detailed look at faculty mobility in one segment of the academic labor
market. It extends and improves Bratsberg, Ragan, and Warren (2003) in
the following ways: it expands the sample to cover three decades of
faculty pay records; it includes additional controls for productivity:
number and types of books, recent and prospective articles, and so
forth, resulting in the most complete specification of research
productivity to date; and it allows for heterogeneity in the seniority
penalty via PhD pedigree and direction of move. Finally, it tests for
the possibility that the academic job market does a better job of
matching faculty and universities in recent years, as might be expected
because of the information revolution.
The sample consists of five public, PhD-granting universities in
the Midwest. We track all tenure-track economics faculty employed in
these universities over a 30-yr period. We measure their productivity,
their pay, and their mobility. As such, the study provides a rich and
detailed investigation of one subset of economics programs. It is
possible that mobility may be greater in urban areas, where faculty can
more readily obtain alternative employment without relocating; and prior
research indicates that pay structures depend on the university's
stature and its relative emphasis on research and teaching. (4)
Therefore, the results of this or any other study of specific
universities cannot be generalized across institutions. Even so,
detailed evidence on one segment of the academic labor market can
provide new and important insights on faculty mobility, pay structures,
returns to seniority, and, of particular interest, whether the data
support the raiding story.
II. ACADEMIC PAY
For personal and scholarly reasons, economists are interested in
the process through which pay of economics faculty is determined. A long
literature has evolved, but the primary focus of recent research has
been the relationship between seniority (years at the current academic
institution) and pay. Many studies have found that, among nonunion
faculty at research universities, pay is inversely related to seniority
(Barbezat 1989; Brown and Woodbury 1998; Gordon, Morton, and Braden
1974; Ransom 1993). (5)
Moore, Newman, and Turnbull (1998) point out that most studies
provide few if any measures of research output and, prior to their work,
controlling for quality of research was rare. (6) Picking up on the
raiding theme, they find that, for their sample of 142 associate and
full professors in academic year 1993/1994, the coefficients of
seniority and experience become insignificant at the 5% level once
controls are added for quantity and quality of research (though the
coefficient of seniority remains negative and, in one of two
specifications, is significant at the 10% level). But in later research
that adds assistant professors to the original data set (Moore, Newman,
and Terrell 2007), the coefficient of seniority again emerges as
negative and significant. (7)
Bratsberg, Ragan, and Warren (2003) study 176 faculty over a 21-yr
period and find strong evidence of negative returns to seniority
regardless of specification. Arguing that match quality imparts a
positive bias to estimated returns to seniority, they then reestimate
their model using the two-step estimator of Topel (1991). As predicted,
the estimated seniority penalty increases once match quality is
accounted for. At 15 yr of seniority, the estimated penalty is 14.6% of
salary.
Why would returns to seniority be negative? Why would a newly hired
faculty member earn more than someone with the same experience and a
comparable research record? One argument is that, given difficulty in
measuring faculty productivity, the two faculty may not really be
comparable. Perhaps the faculty member with higher seniority has lower
unmeasured productivity. This interpretation is consistent with the
models of Harris and Holmstrom (1982) and Lazear (1986). The thesis is
that faculty potential is difficult to determine at the time of the hire
but is revealed as time passes. Faculty who turn out to be highly
productive are raided by other institutions, leaving behind faculty with
low unmeasured productivity.
According to the raiding story, seniority is not actually
penalized. Instead, the negative returns that are estimated for
seniority capture the inverse correlation between seniority and
unmeasured productivity. As better measures of productivity are added,
the estimated coefficient of seniority should become less negative. The
estimated seniority penalty should shrink further when we control for
faculty who are bid away. Finally, there is no reason that faculty who
are raided should be penalized for their time with the university. If
faculty who move to better or comparable jobs are subject to the same
penalty as faculty who remain with the university, the reason for the
negative seniority profile is not lower unmeasured productivity of those
who remain behind. The answer must lie elsewhere.
A competing explanation is that the penalty to seniority is real
and reflects monopsony power on the part of nonunion universities.
Ransom (1993) and Boal and Ransom (1997) present formal models of
monopsony that are based on differential mobility costs of faculty.
Faculty who are reluctant to move, whether because of family or other
considerations, fall behind otherwise similar faculty who are less
averse to moving. Faculty with high mobility costs tend to achieve
higher seniority and, because they are unlikely to leave, employers take
advantage of the situation when setting pay.
This view is consistent with the experience of Ronald Ehrenberg who
is not only a respected labor economist but also a former key
administrator at Cornell University. Ehrenberg (1999, 107) writes that
"our deans who allocate salary funds are ... exploiting the
monopsony power that they have over the least mobile faculty." In
contrast, other researchers (e.g., Monks and Robinson 2001; Moore,
Newman, and Turnbull 1998) favor the raiding explanation. Because there
has not yet been any formal test of raiding, alternative interpretations
are possible. The data of the present study make it possible to test for
raiding in the universities being studied.
III. FACULTY MOBILITY IN FIVE UNIVERSITIES
The data underlying this study come from the economics departments
of five Midwestern universities. The schools are Iowa State University,
Kansas State University, University of Kansas, University of Missouri,
and University of Nebraska. Based on research output, the universities
frequently are ranked between 50 and 100 or thereabouts. (8) All five
universities offer doctoral degrees in economics and are located in
communities whose populations range from 50,000 to 230,000. As such,
faculty who leave these universities for alternative employment within
the economics profession generally must relocate.
For each university, we collected annual pay records of all
tenure-track faculty with at least a 0.5 appointment in the department
of economics. Over the 30 years studied, 1975/1976 through 2004/2005, we
collected data for 238 faculty. (9) Given the panel nature of the data,
our sample has 2,698 observations of faculty salary. For each faculty
member, we also gathered detailed information on administrative
appointments, annual research productivity, date of doctoral degree,
institution conferring the degree, date of initial employment in the
department, and so forth.
Forty-five percent of the faculty worked elsewhere before joining
our sample. Their postdoctoral experience at the time of hire ranged
from 1 to 30 years, with a mean of 5.93 years. Whenever faculty left one
of the universities for another job, we determined the subsequent
employer. (10) Unfortunately, we do not know salaries except while the
person is in our sample (though we do know the research output of
faculty both before and after they are in our sample).
For faculty moving out of the sample, Table 1 shows the reason for
leaving, and for those who continued to work, the type of subsequent
employment. For faculty taking positions elsewhere, Figure 1 indicates
whether the move was upward, downward, or horizontal. About two-thirds
of the movers took another academic position. To determine the direction
of academic moves, research rankings of the new and former departments
were compared. Because rankings change over time, we used rankings at
the time of the move. (11)
When the new university was ranked at least 20 positions higher
than the university from which the faculty member moved, the move was
classified as upward. When the new university was ranked at least 20
positions lower, the move was classified as downward. When the two
universities were within 20 positions of one another, the move was
considered lateral. For moves to another unit in the same university
(another department, a research institute, or administration), the move
was classified as lateral unless we had information that the move was
involuntary. All moves to business and local government were labeled
downward. For jobs with the federal government or a nonacademic foreign
institution, moves were considered downward or lateral based on the
prestige of the new position. For example, a move to the board of
governors was considered lateral, and a move to a minor research
institute downward. Whenever a university in our sample was ranked in
the top 70, moves to government or nonacademic jobs were classified as
downward. (12)
Based on these classification rules, 23% of the moves were upward,
11% were lateral, and 66% were downward. (13) Assuming that faculty who
are raided because of their high productivity move upward or laterally,
no more than one-third of leavers appear to have been "bid
away." For the 100 faculty who moved (42% of the sample), Figure 2
shows the length of time the faculty stayed at the university. The most
common durations were 4, 5, and 6 years. For faculty who left after 4-7
years, we looked at direction of move. if the move for these faculty was
downward, the move was labeled a "tenure denial," (14) though
some readers may prefer milder terminology. Surely, some of the moves
were in anticipation of being denied tenure rather than formal
termination, and other motivations are possible. But given the timing
and direction of the moves, our measure can be viewed as a proxy for
negative outcomes of the tenure process. Upward moves occurred anywhere
between 2 and 23 years but were most frequent in the 5- to 7-years
period, indicating that labor market activity is most prevalent in the
period immediately preceding the tenure decision.
IV. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION OF THE WAGE EQUATION
Empirical models of academic pay are based on a human capital
specification in which the log of a faculty member's pay depends on
seniority, experience (age when experience is unavailable), gender, and
other control variables. This is the approach we adopt. In particular,
we estimate the following equation:
(1) ln [W.sub.ijt] = [[alpha].sub.1] [Sen.sub.it] + [[alpha].sub.2]
[Sen.sup.2.sub.it] + [[alpha].sub.3] [Exp.sub.it] + [[alpha].sub.4]
[Exp.sup.2.sub.it] + [beta][X.sub.it] + [[mu].sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.ijt],
where [W.sub.ijt] is the 9-mo salary of faculty member i at
university j in year t, Sen and Exp are years of seniority and
experience, X is the vector of control variables, [[mu].sub.i] is an
individual-specific term that captures unmeasured productivity
(estimated as a random effect), (15) and [[epsilon].sub.ijt], represents
white noise. (16) The control variables include gender (Female), current
service as department chair (Chair), number of years the person has
served as chair (Years Chair), past service as chair (Past Chair), past
service as dean (Past Dean), number of completed dissertations for which
the faculty member served as major professor (Advisees), academic year,
and institution.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Also included is a rich array of variables designed to capture
research productivity. First is Articles, the number of articles in
journals listed in EconLit. (17) We control for quality of articles in
several ways. First, we divide articles into four tiers. The first tier
consists of articles published in top 10 journals, as determined by
Moore, Newman, and Turnbull (1998). (18) The second tier comprised the
26 journals ranked by Scott and Mitias (1996) as being in the top 36
that are not already included in the top tier. Tier 3 is made up of
journals that were rated by department chairs as falling in the top 50
(Enomoto and Ghosh 1993) and that are not listed in tiers 1 or 2 plus 3
other journals that often are ranked highly: Journal of Economic
Perspectives, European Economic Review, and Economic History Review.
(19) Tier 4, the reference category, consists of articles in all
remaining journals listed in EconLit.
In one formulation, articles in the top three tiers are converted
to American Economic Review-equivalent pages and deflated by the number
of authors. These variables are labeled Pages Cat1, Pages Cat2, and
Pages Cat3. In another version of the model, the variables are adjusted
for neither page count nor number of authors. Instead, we simply count
number of articles in each tier (Articles Cat1, ..., Articles Cat3).
Quality is also proxied by a quadratic specification of the number
of times a faculty member's research is cited in the Social Science
Citation Index, which is a component of the Web of Science. The count is
number of publications to cite the faculty member, meaning that the
faculty member gets one hit whether one or more articles appear in the
bibliography.
In addition, we tabulate the number and type of books a faculty
member has authored. We have separate tallies for book chapters (Book
Chap), research books (Book Res), edited books (Book Ed), and textbooks
(Book Text). (20) To allow for differential returns to subsequent
editions of textbooks, we also count the number of revisions of the
original textbook (Text Revis). Research books and book chapters are
more closely related to scholarship than textbooks, but widely read
textbooks may enhance the visibility of the department to a greater
extent than research books, making it difficult to predict relative
returns to the different categories of books. Because most research on
pay has ignored books entirely, and those studies that do include books
do not differentiate among the various categories of books, prior
research does not offer guidance on the size of the relative parameters.
(21)
Prior research on faculty pay has focused exclusively on past
output, but it is possible that department chairs and evaluation
committees consider prospective research flows. Indeed, the faculty
member's evaluation portfolio (containing working papers, letters
of acceptances, letters inviting revisions and resubmissions, and the
like) provides a good basis for predicting publications in the near
future. Therefore, in one version of the model, we include not just
articles published through the end of the year in which a faculty member
is evaluated but also publications in the subsequent 3 years. The
variables capturing future publications are Prospective Articles,
Prospective Pages Cat1, Prospective Pages Cat2, and Prospective Pages
Cat3. The relative returns to prospective publications may be greater
than or less than that of past research, depending on a
department's faculty evaluation procedures.
In this more fully specified model, we also allow for differential
(added) returns to articles published in the past 5 years: Recent
Articles, Recent Pages Cat1, Recent Pages Cat2, and Recent Pages Cat3.
If senior faculty have published little in recent years and if older
publications are weighted less than recent publications, it is possible
that the seniority penalty picked up in previous research actually
captures a penalty to declining output flows of senior faculty. (22)
Some versions of the model also control for pedigree of the
institution from which the faculty member graduated. Based on the same
departmental rankings used to indicate whether a move was upward,
downward, or horizontal, doctoral-granting institutions were classified
as Top 10 if the university was rated as having one of the 10 best
doctoral programs in economics at the time the degree was conferred.
Siegfried and Stock (1999, 2004) find that graduates of top-tier
universities earn more than other graduates, but presumably, the primary
reason for the premium is the greater ability of graduates from elite
programs to find employment in higher rated and higher paying
departments. What we want to determine is whether, for a given academic
institution, graduates from top programs come in at a higher salary or
experience faster growth in compensation (a lower penalty to seniority).
Faculty from the top programs may be more marketable than other
faculty. Their degree may be more likely to generate subsequent job
interviews, and their network may also give them an edge in their job
search. Deans may be willing to pay more to keep someone from a top
program (to keep a Harvard or Chicago affiliation on the
department's Web page). If faculty from top programs are perceived
as more marketable, employers will be able to exert less monopsony power
against such faculty. Faculty from top programs may also experience
faster wage growth if, despite the large set of control variables,
faculty from top programs have higher unmeasured productivity than
faculty from lower rated institutions.
Finally, and of special interest, some specifications of the model
allow for differential effects for three classifications of faculty:
faculty who may have been raided--those who move upward or laterally
(Bid Away), faculty who apparently were denied tenure (Denial), and
other faculty who move (Other Move). Although our focus is on the first
category of movers, we predict that returns to seniority will be most
negative for faculty who are denied tenure, a proposition not previously
tested. A university is not likely to worry about losing faculty whose
productivity falls short of tenure standards, so why put much of a
department's salary-increment pool on faculty who are on their way
out?
Table 2 summarizes values of the key variables used in the
analysis, and Table 3 provides sample means separately for nonmovers,
faculty who are bid away, tenure denials, and other movers. The latter
table shows that the faculty who are bid away tend to be highly
productive (consistent with the findings of Ault, Rutman, and Stevenson
1979, 1982; Coupe, Smeets, and Warzynski 2005). They have more articles,
prospective articles, and citations than any other group. Although
nonmovers have more textbooks and pages in ranked journals, the average
experience is twice as high for non-movers as for faculty who are bid
away. At the other end of the spectrum, tenure denials have fewer recent
articles and prospective articles and fewer recent pages in ranked
journals than any other group.
Finally, females are disproportionately concentrated in the bid
away and denial categories. Although we are reluctant to make too much
of this point, given the small number of females in the sample (30
individuals, 193 observations), females are more likely to move out of
our sample (both upward and downward) than males. Higher mobility of
female faculty has been documented previously (e.g., Barbezat and Hughes
2001; Ginther and Kahn 2004). At least for this type of Institution, is
that females are more likely to be bid away (especially in recent years)
and also more likely to be denied tenure. (23)
V. EMPIRICAL ESTIMATES
A. Returns to Seniority and Productivity
In the stripped-down version of the model (Table 4, column 1), we
find negative returns to seniority, positive but diminishing returns to
experience, and no evidence of pay differences by gender. When controls
are added for administrative experience and graduate advising (column
2), we see that these activities appear to be rewarded highly, but the
estimated penalty for seniority is virtually unchanged--about 12.7% at
10 years of seniority. (24) Next, we include research productivity,
finding that faculty are compensated for both quantity and quality of
research (column 3). An unranked article is estimated to increase pay by
0.9%. The added returns to a 10-page, sole-authored article are 3.0% if
published in the American Economic Review (or other tier 1 journal),
1.0% if in a tier 2 journal, and 0.6% if in a tier 3 journal. Faculty
are compensated further if the article is cited.
Faculty are also rewarded for writing books and book chapters.
Estimated returns are greatest for textbooks--4.3% for a first edition
and 2.0% for each subsequent edition. Research books increase pay by an
estimated 2.0%, and the payoffs for editing a book or writing a book
chapter are 1.3% and 1.5%, respectively. The higher rewards for
textbooks may be because of their greater visibility. (25)
Alternatively, if faculty who write textbooks tend to be better teachers
or spend more time with students, part of the textbook premium may
reflect compensation for these other activities.
Interestingly, the coefficient of Advisees, which indicated a
reward of 1.0% per advisee in column 2, becomes zero and insignificant
once we control for research productivity. The implication is that
graduate advising is not rewarded directly. Students are drawn to major
professors with strong research records, and when research productivity
is not accounted for in the regression, number of doctoral dissertations
supervised serves as a proxy for research productivity. But when both
sets of variables are included, we see that it is actually the higher
research output of advisors that explains their higher pay.
The addition of research variables (column 3) reduces the penalty
to seniority by approximately 20%, which is consistent with the raiding
story. Therefore, there is evidence of a negative correlation between
productivity and seniority. As Moore, Newman, and Turnbull argue,
failure to account for research productivity does negatively bias
estimated returns to seniority. But of greater relevance, the estimated
penalty to seniority remains sizable and highly significant even when we
control richly for quantity and quality of research. Our interpretation
of these results is that, at least for our sample, the penalty for
seniority is real.
We also estimated faculty pay based on an alternative specification
of the research variables. Rather than adjusting for number of authors
and pages, we simply count the number of articles that a faculty member
has in each of the four journal tiers. We estimate that the return for
publishing in a tier 1 journal is 2.7% and that returns are 1.9, 1.4,
and 0.7%, respectively, for journals classified as tiers 2, 3, and 4.
These results demonstrate that faculty pay depends more strongly on
quality than quantity of publications and further suggest that there is
a recognizable hierarchy of journals in the economics profession.
Column 4 provides estimates for the specification that includes
impending publications and allows for differential returns to recent
articles (a positive coefficient for a "recent" publication
designates the added premium for articles published within the past 5
years). Returns to articles in ranked journals are modestly higher if
published recently. In particular, for a tier 1 journal, the reward to a
sole-authored, 10-page article is 0.6 percentage point higher if
published in the past 5 years. (26) For tiers 2 and 3 journals,
respectively, the added premiums are 0.5 and 0.1 percentage points. In
contrast, for unranked journals, returns appear to be 0.3 percentage
points higher for articles published more than 5 years ago. Publications
in unranked journals are valued, but apparently, a portion of the reward
is received with considerable delay.
The coefficients of all four variables capturing prospective
articles (those to be published in the next 3 years) are positive, and
two of the coefficients are statistically significant. But in all cases,
returns are lower for prospective articles than for published articles
and that is true for articles published more than 5 years ago as well as
for recent articles. Although faculty can expect to be rewarded for
future articles, those rewards will come primarily after the articles
are in print; pay depends more strongly on past publications than on
impending publications.
What really matters, however, is that including variables to
capture prospective publications and allowing for lags does not
appreciably affect estimated returns to seniority. The lower pay of
senior faculty is not the consequence of differences in impending
research flows or of a tendency to have dated publications whose value
has depreciated over time. Based on the specification of column 3, the
estimated penalty for 10 years of seniority is 9.8% of pay. When we add
prospective articles and allow for differential returns to articles
published in the past 5 years and those published earlier (column 4),
the estimated penalty is 9.3%. Finally, when we try a specification that
allows for differential returns to articles published in the past 5
years, the previous 5 years, and more than 10 yr ago and allows for
differences in returns to both number of articles published by quality
level and pages published by quality level, the estimated penalty to 10
years of tenure is 9.2%. As these numbers indicate, altering the
specification of the productivity variables has only a trivial effect on
the estimated penalty to seniority. (27) The lower pay of senior faculty
cannot be explained in terms of different patterns of publishing.
B. Returns to Seniority by Faculty Mobility
Next, we allow for differential returns to seniority of faculty
based on whether they move or stay and, if they leave the department,
the reason for the exit. (28) The raiding story implies that it is low
unmeasured productivity, and not seniority, that results in lower pay.
In contrast to senior faculty, who have low unmeasured productivity and
do not generate outside interest, faculty who are so marketable that
they move upward or laterally should have high unmeasured productivity.
There is no reason their pay should be inversely related to seniority,
even if productivity is not measured fully. If they are penalized for
seniority, and especially, if they are penalized as severely as faculty
who remain with the university, we can rule out raiding as the source of
negative seniority profiles.
The initial specification of Table 5, without controls for research
productivity, suggests that faculty who are bid away (move to better, or
at least comparable, positions) are penalized for their seniority but
that the penalty may be less severe. But, as previously noted, these
movers are more productive than other faculty. When controls are
included for research output (column 2), results indicate that the
penalty for faculty who are bid away is as severe as for faculty
overall. (29) Their pay may rise faster than that of other faculty but
not commensurately with their greater productivity. These findings are
inconsistent with raiding theory.
Next, we expand the model to allow for different seniority profiles
for all classifications of movers (Table 5, column 3). Based on the
differential intercepts, tenure denials are paid less than faculty who
stay with the university. Apart from the lower intercept, tenure denials
are penalized an additional 1.0% for each year of seniority relative to
faculty who remain with the university. But these results may be biased
by endogeneity of wages and mobility. If the department realizes that a
faculty member is on the way out, whether because of tenure denial or
some other reason, the department has an incentive to give the faculty
member a lower pay increment the final year (to reallocate the funds to
continuing faculty). In that event, keeping the last year's
observation on pay in the sample could bias downward returns to
seniority for movers.
One solution is to delete from the sample the final pay period for
faculty leavers. When we adopt this approach (column 4), all three
seniority interaction terms become more positive (less negative), and
the coefficient of Seniority x Denial becomes insignificant, though it
remains negative. Much of the wage penalty incurred by faculty who are
denied tenure is apparently paid in their final year in the department.
Once we remove this observation, there is no longer evidence that this
group is penalized more for seniority than other groups of faculty. In
fact, based on the estimates of column 4, all categories of movers
receive seniority penalties comparable to those of nonmovers. (30) The
key finding of this section is that the penalty to seniority persists
even when we allow for different intercepts for faculty mobility status
(to permit higher unmeasured productivity of faculty who are bid away
and lower productivity of faculty who are denied tenure) and even when
we allow for differential seniority penalties.
C. Rewards for a PhD from a Top 10 Program?
As argued previously, faculty with degrees from top 10 programs may
experience a lower seniority penalty than other faculty for either of
two reasons: they may have higher unmeasured productivity or
universities may view them as more marketable and hence exert less
monopsony power against these faculty. Sixty-four of the faculty in our
sample (27%) graduated from a top 10 university. (31) Table 6 allows for
differential returns to seniority for such faculty. Estimates indicate
that these faculty, while still penalized for seniority, suffer a lower
penalty than other faculty. Comparing columns 1-2, we see that the
seniority advantage (lower penalty) for top 10 faculty shrinks once we
control for productivity, consistent with their slight productivity
advantage over other faculty. Based on the estimates of column 2, the
penalty to seniority is lower for top 10 faculty than for other faculty
(8.1% after 10 yr rather than 10.5%).
The remaining columns of Table 6 present the most comprehensive
specification of the model, first for the full sample (column 3) and
then after dropping final-year observations for faculty who leave
(column 4). As in Table 5, once we drop observations for faculty
leavers, seniority penalties do not differ significantly by mobility
status. According to the estimates of column 4, the overall seniority
penalty is approximately 0.9% per year for faculty who did not graduate
from top 10 programs (9.2% after 10 years). Faculty from top 10 programs
are also penalized for seniority but less severely than other faculty
(6.7% after 10 years). (32) For all categories of faculty studied,
returns to seniority are negative, substantial, and statistically
significant.
D. Allowing for Match Quality and Changes in the Reward Structure
Thanks to the information revolution (Internet, Web pages, posting
of information by the American Economic Association, etc.), the academic
job market operates more efficiently now than in the past. In this
section, we look at whether returns to seniority and experience have
changed in recent years, as might be expected because of greater
availability of information and perhaps fewer bad matches (where the mix
of faculty skills and attributes differs from that sought by the
university).
According to the literature, good matches between workers and
employers tend to last longer than poor matches and to be associated
with higher pay. (33) Unless match quality is accounted for, the
resulting correlation between seniority and the error term generates a
positive bias in the estimates of the returns to seniority. To allow for
the effect of match quality, we present estimates based in the two-step
procedure of Topel (1991) as well as random-effects estimates. We
provide estimates for two subperiods, 1975-1994, which can be thought of
as the pre-Internet period, and 1995-2004 (post-Internet). (34) In both
cases, we drop the last observation for movers and calculate cumulative
returns to seniority and experience at 15 yr, a value not far from the
mean for the sample (mean seniority is 14 yr, and mean experience is 16
yr). Results appear in Table 7.
There is no evidence that returns to experience have changed over
time. Regardless of estimation technique and time period, cumulative
returns to 15 years of experience are roughly 30%. In contrast,
random-effects and Topel estimators tell different stories about returns
to seniority. According to random-effects estimates (columns 3 and 5),
the seniority penalty has increased over time. But Topel estimates for
the two periods are comparable (columns 4 and 6), with no signs that the
penalty has increased. Instead, these estimates indicate that the role
of match quality bias has eroded over time.
Apparently, the correlation between (unobserved) match quality and
seniority was important in the early period, causing random-effects
estimates of the seniority penalty to be biased toward zero, as
Bratsberg, Ragan, and Warren (2003) found in their analysis of data from
1975 to 1995. (35) In the latter period, however, random-effects and
Topel estimates are not appreciably different, suggesting that
traditional estimation techniques are no longer biased. By implication,
recent hires are better matched with the universities than faculty hired
in the earlier era. This finding is consistent with both sellers and
buyers being better informed than in the past, perhaps as a consequence
of the Internet revolution, so that fewer truly bad matches occur.
Finally, the change in the market for economists has mixed
implications for mobility. The better quality of matches might reduce
turnover, but greater information makes it easier to move, which is an
offsetting effect. What we can conclude is that the nature of mobility
has changed. The share of mobility caused by poor matches is lower now
than in the past, and that is why match quality bias has eroded.
VI. SUMMARY
This study uses information on faculty mobility to address the
issue of why returns to faculty seniority are negative. The two
hypotheses that have been advanced are monopsony power by universities
and faculty raiding. According to the raiding story, senior faculty have
low unmeasured productivity, which creates a negative bias in estimated
returns to seniority. The raiding story has several implications: (1)
the bias should dissipate as better measures of research output are
added to the wage equation; (2) the estimated seniority penalty should
be lower if we control for faculty who are bid away--and presumably have
high unmeasured productivity; and (3) estimated returns to seniority
should not be negative for faculty who are bid away. To examine these
propositions, we collected the most detailed measures of productivity
used to date and we allowed the wage structure to differ for faculty who
move upward or laterally (presumably the targets of raids) and for other
categories of faculty.
We followed all tenure-track faculty at five universities over a
30-yr time period. As such, our analysis provides a detailed look at one
segment of the academic labor market: midlevel, doctoral granting
departments of economics in the Midwest. In our sample, about two-thirds
of faculty who leave for alternative employment move downward; less than
one-quarter moves upward. Faculty turnover is heaviest in the years
immediately preceding the tenure decision.
There is a substantial penalty for seniority with the university.
The penalty moderates when controls are added for research productivity,
pointing to an inverse relationship between seniority and
productivity--yet, in all specifications of the model, returns to
seniority are negative and significant. According to the random-effects
estimates of Table 7, after accounting for productivity, the penalty for
faculty overall is 8.9% at 10 yr of seniority and 12.2% at 15 yr. When
we switch to a Topel estimator, the estimated penalty rises modestly (to
14.6% at 15 yr). Loyalty may be rewarded in some quarters, but not in
academia.
The seniority penalty is little changed when we allow for
differential intercepts and differential returns to seniority by
mobility status. Faculty who end up moving to better or comparable
positions were penalized as severely for seniority while they were in
our sample as faculty who stay. These results are incompatible with the
raiding hypothesis.
Even faculty from top 10 universities receive negative returns to
seniority, though their penalty is less than that of faculty who
graduated from lesser ranked institutions. The better treatment of top
10 faculty could potentially reflect higher unmeasured productivity, but
it is also consistent with the model of monopsony if universities view
top 10 faculty as more likely to receive outside offers or to respond to
outside offers.
Faculty are rewarded highly for research productivity. According to
the baseline version of the model, returns to a sole-authored, 10-page
article are estimated to be 3.9% if published in a top 10 journal, 1.9%
if in a tier 2 journal, 1.5% if in a tier 3 journal, and 0.9% if in an
unranked journal. Books also increase faculty salary. The payoff appears
to be greatest for the first edition of a textbook, perhaps because of
the national visibility a textbook, can create. Subsequent editions of
the text, research books, edited books, and book chapters increase pay
by 1%-2% compared to the 4% return for a new textbook. Publications that
are cited generate additional compensation.
The lower pay of senior faculty cannot be attributed to differences
in impending research flows or a tendency to have dated publications
whose value has depreciated over time. Accounting for prospective
articles and for depreciation in returns to past publications, another
innovation of this study, does not appreciably alter any of the other
results, including the findings on seniority. Research is rewarded even
prior to publication, but returns are considerably greater once the
articles are in print. For articles in ranked journals, returns are
slightly higher for papers published in the past 5 years.
When research output is excluded from the analysis, faculty who
serve as major professor appear to be compensated for this activity, but
their higher pay is actually the consequence of their research output.
Students are drawn to faculty with strong research reputations, but
advising is not directly rewarded.
When we allow for a change in pay structures in the pre-Internet
and post-Internet periods, random-effects estimates suggest that the
seniority penalty has increased, but Topel estimates, which account for
match quality, indicate otherwise. The former period was characterized by correlation of match quality and seniority, which caused
random-effects estimates to understate the seniority penalty. In recent
years, there have been fewer poor matches, presumably the consequence of
greater availability of information. Now that match quality bias is no
longer important, traditional estimation techniques no longer understate
the penalty to seniority.
In conclusion, the results of this study help us understand better
the operation of academic labor markets by providing insights on faculty
mobility and pay structures. Most important, they lead us to reject the
raiding interpretation of the negative returns to faculty seniority.
REFERENCES
Abowd, J., F. Kramarz, and S. Roux. "Wages, Mobility and Firm
Performance: Advantages and Insights from using Matched Worker-Firm
Data." Economic Journal, 116, 2006, F245-85.
Abraham, K. G., and H. A. Farber. "Job Duration, Seniority,
and Earnings." American Economic Review, 77, 1987, 278-97.
Altonji, J. G., and R. A. Shakotko. "Do Wages Rise with
Seniority?" Review of Economic Studies, 54, 1987, 437-59.
Altonji, J. G., and N. Williams. "Do Wages Rise with
Seniority? A Reassessment." Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
58, 2005, 370-97.
Ault, D. E., L. G. Rutman, and T. Stevenson. "Mobility in the
Labor Market for Academic Economists." American Economic Review,
69, 1979, 131-36.
--. "Some Factors Affecting Mobility in the Labor Market for
Academic Economists." Economic Inquiry, 20, 1982, 104-32.
Axarloglou, K., and V. Theoharakis. "Diversity in Economics:
An Analysis of Journal Quality Perceptions." Journal of the
European Economic Association, 1, 2003, 1402-23.
Barbezat, D. A. "The Effect of Collective Bargaining on
Salaries in Higher Education." Industrial and Labor Relations
Review, 42, 1989, 443-55.
Barbezat, D. A., and J. W. Hughes. "The Effect of Job Mobility
on Academic Salaries." Contemporary Economic Policy, 19, 2001,
409-23.
Boal, W., and M. Ransom. "Monopsony in the Labor Market."
Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 1997, 86-112.
Bratsberg, B., J. F. Ragan Jr., and J. T. Warren. "Negative
Returns to Seniority: New Evidence in Academic Markets." Industrial
and Labor Relations Review, 56, 2003, 306-23.
Brown, B. W., and S. A. Woodbury. "Seniority, External Labor
Markets, and Faculty Pay." Quarterly Review of Economics and
Finance, 38, 1998, 771-98.
Burton, M. P., and E. Phimister. "Core Journals: A Reappraisal
of the Diamond List." Economic Journal, 105, 1995, 361-73.
Ciolek, M. T., and S. Whitfield. "The Past and Futures of
Scholarly Internet." Rzeczpospolita, 2000. Accessed April 5, 2006.
http://www.ciolek.com/PAPERS/ e-scholarship2000.html.
Coupe, T. "Revealed Performances: Worldwide Rankings of
Economists and Economics Departments, 1990-2000." Journal of the
European Economic Association, 1, 2003, 1309-45.
Coupe, T., V. Smeets, and F. Warzynski. "Incentives, Sorting
and Productivity Along the Career: Evidence from a Sample of Top
Economists." Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 22,
2005, 137-67.
Dustmann, C., and C. Meghir. "Wages, Experience, and
Mobility" Review of Economic Studies, 72, 2005, 77-108.
Ehrenberg, R. G. "Adam Smith Goes to College: An Economist
Becomes an Academic Administrator." Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 13(1), 1999, 99-116.
Ehrenberg, R. G., H. Kasper, and D. I. Rees. "Faculty Turnover
at American Colleges and Universities: Analyses of AAUP Data."
Economics of Education Review, 10, 1991, 99-110.
Enomoto, C. E., and S. N. Ghosh. "A Stratified Approach to the
Ranking of Economics Journals." Studies in Economic Analysis,
14(2), 1993, 74-93.
Ginther, D., and S. Kahn. "Women in Economics: Moving Up or
Falling Off the Academic Ladder?" Journal of Economic Perspectives,
18(3), 2004, 193-214.
Gordon, N., T. Morton, and I. Braden. "Faculty Salaries: Is
There Discrimination by Sex, Race, and Discipline?" American
Economic Review, 64, 1974, 419-27.
Graves, P., J. Marchand, and R. Thompson. "Economics
Departmental Rankings: Research Incentives, Constraints, and
Efficiency." American Economic Review, 72, 1982, 1131-41.
Hamermesh, D. S., G. E. Johnson, and B. A. Weisbrod.
"Scholarship, Citations and Salaries: Economic Rewards in
Economics." Southern Economic Journal, 49, 1982, 472-81.
Harris, M., and B. Holmstrom. "Theory of Wage Dynamics."
Review of Economic Studies, 49, 1982, 315-33.
Hirsch, B., R. Austin, J. Brooks, and B. Moore. "Economics
Departmental Rankings: Comment." American Economic Review, 74,
1984, 822-26.
Kalaitzidakis, P., T. P. Mamuneas, and T. Stengos. "Rankings
of Economics Journals." Journal of the European Economic
Association, 1, 2003, 1346-66.
Katz, D. A. "Faculty Salaries, Promotions, and Productivity at
a Large University." American Economic Review, 63, 1973, 469-77.
Lazear, E. P. "Raids and Offer Matching, in Research in Labor
Economics, Vol. 8, edited by R. G. Ehrenberg Greenwich, CT: JAI Press,
1986, 141-65.
Monks, J., and M. Robinson. "The Returns to Seniority in
Academic Labor Markets." Journal of Labor Research, 22, 2001,
415-27.
Moore, W. J., R. J. Newman, J. Raisian, and R. W. Thomas. "A
Quality Adjustment Model of the Academic Labor Market: The Case of
Economists." Economic Inquiry, 21, 1983, 241-54.
Moore, W. J., R. J. Newman, and D. Terrell. "Academic Pay in
the United Kingdom and the United States: The Differential Returns to
Productivity and the Lifetime Earnings Gap." Southern Economic
Journal, 73, 2007, 717-32.
Moore, W. J., R. J. Newman, and G. K. Turnbull. "Do Faculty
Salaries Decline with Seniority?" Journal of Labor Economics, 16,
1998, 352-66.
Ragan, J. F. Jr., and Q. N. Rehman. "Earnings Profiles of
Department Heads: Comparing Cross-Section and Panel Models."
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 49, 1996, 256-72.
Ragan, J. F. Jr., J. T. Warren, and B. Bratsberg. "How Similar
Are Pay Structures in 'Similar' Departments of
Economics?" Economics of Education Review, 18, 1999, 347-60.
Ransom, M. R. "Seniority and Monopsony in the Academic Labor
Market." American Economic Review, 83, 1993, 221-33.
Rees, D. I. "Does Unionization Increase Faculty
Retention?" Industrial Relations, 33, 1994, 297-321.
Scott, L. C., and P. M. Mitias. "Trends in Rankings of
Economics Departments in the U.S.: An Update." Economic Inquiry,
34, 1996, 378-400.
Siegfried, J. J., and W. Stock. "The Labor Market for New
Ph.D. Economists." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3), 1999,
115-34.
--. "The Market for New Ph.D. Economists in 2002."
American Economic Review, 94, 2004, 272-85.
Tolbert, P. S., T. Simons, A. Andrews, and J. Rhee. "The
Effect of Gender Composition in Academic Depart ments on Faculty
Turnover." Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 48, 1995, 562-79.
Topel, R. "Specific Capital, Mobility, and Wages: Wages Rise
with Job Seniority." Journal of Political Economy, 99, 1991,
145-76.
Tremblay, C. H., V. J. Tremblay, and B. Lee. "Field Publishing
Performance of U.S. Economics Departments." Atlantic Economic
Journal, 18, 1990, 37-48.
Tschirhart, J. "Ranking Economics Department in Areas of
Expertise." Journal of Eeonomic Education, 20(2), 1989, 199-222.
Zakon, R. H. "Hobbes' Internet Timeline." Zakon
Group LLC. 2005. Accessed April 5, 2006. http://www.
zakon.org/robert/internet/timeline/.
BERNT BRATSBERG, JAMES F. RAGAN JR, and JOHN T. WARREN *
* The authors have benefited from the comments of Richard Edwards,
Ronald Ehrenberg, Dan Hamermesh, Derek Neal, Oddbjorn Raaum, Kjetil
Storesletten, Laura Ragan, Carol Tremblay, Vic Tremblay; seminar
participants at Claremont Graduate University, Oregon State University,
Kansas State University, the University of Nebraska, the University of
Puerto Rico-Bayamon, the Frisch Centre, the Missouri Economics
Conference; the co-editor: and two referees. We thank John Anderson,
Dave Mandy, Craig MacPhee, Peter Mueser, Peter Orazem, Mike Podgursky,
Jim Schmidt, and Joe Sicilian for assisting us in the collection of
certain data. Part of the project was completed while Ragan was a
visiting scholar at the Frisch Centre; he is grateful for the
Centre's support.
Bratsberg: Senior Research Fellow, Ragnar Frisch Centre for
Economic Research, Gaustadalleen 21, 0349 Oslo, Norway. Phone +47 2295
8818, Fax +47 2295 8825, E-mail bernt.bratsberg@frisch.uio.no
Ragan, Jr.: Professor, Department of Economics, Kansas State
University, Waters Hall, Manhattan, KS 66506-4001. Phone 785-532-4582,
Fax 785-532-6919, E-mail jfrjr@ksu.edu
Warren: Adjunct Professor, Department of Economics, Kansas State
University, Waters Hall, Manhattan, KS 66506-4001. Phone 785-532-7357,
Fax 785-532-6919, E-mail jomega@ksu.edu
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00220.x
(1.) Related research shows that faculty turnover varies with
gender composition of the department (Tolbert et al. 1995).
(2.) See Bratsberg, Ragan, and Warren (2003) for a review of this
research. A more recent study is Moore, Newman, and Terrell (2007).
(3.) If one can come up with a third explanation for why returns to
seniority are negative (other than raiding and monopsony power) then
rejection of the raiding hypothesis would not imply acceptance of the
monopsony model, but we are unaware of a compelling alternative to these
two models. As one referee observed, administrative constraints on pay
increases of existing faculty coupled with growing demand for PhD
economists may have reduced the relative pay of senior faculty. But we
interpret this story in terms of the monopsony model: faculty must move
to realize their market salary; universities reap rents from faculty who
are tied down.
(4.) For example, Ransom (1993) found a greater seniority penalty
for faculty from "high-quality universities" than for faculty
in general.
(5.) This finding is at odds with the positive returns to seniority
often found for other professions (e.g., see Ransom 1993). One
explanation may be the tenure system in academia. Once a faculty member
is tenured, the list of available alternative jobs shrinks considerably,
limiting mobility and increasing potential monoposony power. Moreover,
the incentive effects of seniority-based pay, found in other sectors of
the economy, are based on the threat of dismissal, which effectively
disappears with academic tenure. Finally, in nonacademic professions, an
employee who leaves may take along clients with whom the employee has
cultivated a professional relationship. To deter such exits, firms in
the financial sector, law, accounting, and so forth have an incentive to
reward seniority.
(6.) The exceptions are Katz (1973), Hamermesh, Johnson, and
Weisbrod (1982), and Ragan, Warren, and Bratsberg (1999). These studies
show that research quality is a more important determinant of pay than
quantity of research.
(7.) The coefficient is -0.0064 (se = 0.0026) or -0.0082 (se =
0.0023), depending on the specification.
(8.) Among U.S. universities, the departments in our sample are
ranked between 42 and 102 by Tschirhart (1989) and between 51 and 101 by
Coupe (2003). Four of the departments appear between 69 and 86 in the
ranking of the top 88 U.S. universities by Kalaitzidakis, Mamuneas, and
Stengos (2003). Tremblay, Tremblay, and Lee (1990) place four of the
universities in the 51 92 range.
(9.) Although 1975/1976 is the initial year of the sample (the
first year for which we have pay data), we include faculty whose
employment at the university began prior to 1975/1976.
(10.) Data on faculty mobility were typically obtained from vitae
posted on the Web. When vitae were missing, we searched the American
Economic Association directory, googled the faculty name, or called the
person's former department to solicit information. Through the same
sources and university Web pages, we determined the year in which a
person received the doctoral degree and the school conferring it.
(11.) The time period and source of the rankings are 1974-1978
(Graves, Marchand, and Thompson 1982), 1978-1983 (Hirsch et al. 1984),
1984-1993 (Scott and Mitias 1996), and 1990-2000 (Coupe 2003).
(12.) In all cases, classifications were based on a thoughtful a
priori discussion of the move, but there are so few moves in our data
set whose direction is debatable that we are confident that empirical
estimates are not sensitive to the classification system adopted.
(13.) These data are consistent with the findings of Ault, Rutman,
and Stevenson (1979, 1982) that the average academic move is downward.
(14.) Although "tenure denial" is defined in terms of
seniority of 4-7 years, empirical results are not sensitive to this
classification. If tenure denial is alternatively defined as downward
mobility of faculty with experience of 4-7 years, results are similar.
Likewise, our conclusions are unchanged when we define tenure denial
more broadly as downward mobility for faculty with seven or fewer years
of seniority.
(15.) For individual faculty, changes in seniority and experience
are perfectly correlated, which precludes estimation of [[mu].sub.i] as
a faculty fixed effect. An advantage of random effects over ordinary
least squares is that it allows for individual heterogeneity, and
Breusch-Pagan tests overwhelmingly favor the random-effects
specification over ordinary least squares for our sample.
(16.) In supplemental regressions, we add the term [[eta].sub.ij]
to account for match quality of faculty member i at university j and use
the Topel (1991) two-step estimator.
(17.) EconLit covers the period 1969 to present. Earlier data were
obtained from the American Economic Association, Index of Economic
Articles. Our measure of articles excludes book reviews, papers in
conference proceedings, and articles in journals not covered by EconLit.
(18.) These journals are American Economic Review, Econometrica,
Economic Journal, Economica, International Economic Review, Journal of
Economic Theory, Journal of Political Economy, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Review of Economic Studies, and Review of Economics and
Statistics.
(19.) Axarloglou and Theoharakis (2003) and Kalaitzidakis,
Mamuneas, and Stengos (2003) rank Journal of Economic Perspectives and
European Economic Review among the top 15 journals. Burton and Phimister
(1995) have Economic History Review number 10 based on their application
of data envelope analysis to citation data.
(20.) Data on books were obtained from EconLit from 1988 to present
and from WorldCat for earlier years (prior to EconLit coverage). Only
original book chapters were included, not reprints.
(21.) An exception is Ragan and Rehman (1996) who estimate returns
to textbooks and research books across faculty from multiple departments
at one university. They report larger returns for research books than
textbooks.
(22.) We thank Derek Neal for pointing out that if past
publications are heavily discounted and prospective publications
rewarded, misspecification of the reward structures could potentially
explain the negative returns to seniority found in the literature. By
allowing for lower returns to older publications and positive returns to
prospective publications, we are able to test for this possibility.
(23.) Mobility patterns may have shifted favorably for females over
the sample period. During the period 1990-2004, six females were
"bid away" and four were denied tenure. In the period before
1990, only one female was bid away (in 1989), while four were denied
tenure. For males, the patterns of being bid away and being denied
tenure did not change between subperiods.
(24.) Based on the estimates of column 2, the penalty for 10 yr of
seniority is exp(-0.01392 x 10 + 0.0000288 x 100) 1 = exp(-0.1363) 1 =
0.1274. The negative returns to seniority are not driven by a subset of
our sample. When we allow returns to seniority to differ by university,
results point to significant and negative returns at each university.
(25.) One scholar confided to one of the authors that his research
book sold only 50 copies. More generally, textbooks sell at higher
levels than research books. The relative rewards to the different
categories of books may also depend on the relative importance of
teaching at the institution, in which case the returns to textbooks are
likely to be lower at more elite institutions.
(26.) The 0.6 premium is the sum of the coefficients of Recent
Pages Cat1/10 and Recent Articles (0.0090-0.0031).
(27.) When we allow for two sets of lags, we find that the return
to articles is lowest for articles published more than 10 yr ago, but
articles published 6-10 yr ago are not discounted relative to those
published in the past 5 yr. One reason may be that the effect of any
depreciation in the value of articles published in the 6- to 10-yr
timeframe is offset by the fact that the returns to recent articles are
not fully received until years after the publication (because of budget
pressures in any given year) or because of departmental policy to
explicitly value past publications (e.g., by rewarding research
reputation).
(28.) Although we cannot identify which faculty remain with the
university after receiving an outside offer and then a counteroffer,
counteroffers soften the seniority penalty. If we excluded faculty who
receive counteroffers, the seniority penalty of nonmovers would be even
greater. Because those with positive pay shocks are less likely to move,
we may underestimate the seniority penalty for nonmovers. Ideally, we
would like to allow for endogeneity of faculty mobility, both upward and
downward, but that requires instrumental variables that affect mobility
but not pay. Although we have been unable to come up with plausible
instruments, another way to address endogeneity is to delete
observations in the final year or two that movers are in the department,
when low pay could plausibly result from knowledge by the department
chair that such faculty are leaving. This approach is adopted in the
following section.
(29.) If we alternatively define mobility in terms of upward,
lateral, and downward moves (rather than bid away, tenure denials, and
other moves), we find that faculty who move to better universities are
penalized at least as severely as faculty overall, which is at odds with
the raiding hypothesis.
(30.) Results are similar if we drop the final two observations for
movers.
(31.) The heavy concentration of faculty from top 10 universities
is consistent with the finding of Moore et al. (1983) that "most
academic appointments follow a 'downstream' pattern."
(32.) As one might expect, mobility patterns differ by pedigree of
PhD degree: Faculty in our sample are more likely to be bid away and
less likely to be denied tenure if they graduated from a top 10 program.
Nonetheless, when we relax the specification of Table 6 to allow a
different pattern of coefficients for top 10 and other faculty, our
conclusions still hold. The finding that top 10 faculty who are bid away
are penalized as severely as faculty who remain is especially difficult
to reconcile with the raiding interpretation of the observed negative
seniority profiles.
(33.) See, for example, Abraham and Farber (1987), Altonji and
Shakotko (1987), Altonji and Williams (2005), and Topel (1991). Recent
studies point to substantial heterogeneity in returns to seniority
across different segments of the labor market (Abowd, Kramarz, and Roux
2006; Dustmann and Meghir 2005).
(34.) The Internet had become an important tool by 1995. Zakon
(2005) reports that 1995 was characterized by WWW, search engines, and
the introduction of JAVA. That year, the NSF linked supercomputing
centers to create "the very high speed Backbone Network Service" and the "main U.S. traffic [was] now routed through
interconnected network providers." The Internet had become very
important on university campuses, with edu second only to corn in the
ranking of domains by host numbers. Ciolek and Whitfield (2000) concur,
noting that "In the mid-1990s as it finally entered most scholarly
institutions and became genuinely accessible to all, some scholars
immediately mounted home pages, published electronic articles and sought
funds for online projects."
(35.) Bratsberg, Ragan, and Warren (2003) report that the penalty
to 15 yr of seniority was 8.0% when estimated with the random-effects
model and 14.6% when estimated with the Topel model. Based on our more
elaborate specification and an additional 9 yr of data, our estimates
are 12.2% and 14.6%, respectively.
TABLE 1
Faculty Status after Leaving the Sample
Status Frequency %
Retirement 49 32.0
Death/illness 4 2.6
Business 6 3.9
Federal government 10 6.6
State government 6 3.9
Foreign university 16 10.5
Foreign other 4 2.6
Other U.S. university 51 33.3
Other unit in university 7 4.6
Total 153 100.0
TABLE 2
Sample Descriptive Statistics
Variable Mean SD Minimum Maximum
In (salary) 10.568 0.248 9.923 11.365
Move 0.232 0.422 0 1
Bid Away 0.082 0.274 0 1
Denial 0.062 0.242 0 1
Other Move 0.088 0.283 0 1
Top 10 0.249 0.432 0 1
Seniority 13.900 10.358 0 42
Experience 16.001 10.335 0 42
Female 0.072 0.258 0 1
Chair 0.049 0.217 0 1
Years Chair 0.527 1.755 0 15
Past Chair 0.069 0.253 0 1
Past Dean 0.003 0.051 0 1
Advisees 2.134 3.763 0 41
Articles 7.307 8.488 0 93
Pages Cat l 8.578 14.977 0 106.506
Pages Cat2 13.181 22.282 0 181.288
Pages Cat3 11.237 28.313 0 285.063
Recent Articles 2.312 3.154 0 23
Recent Pages Catl 1.975 5.360 0 55.493
Recent Pages Cat2 4.088 9.636 0 98.522
Recent Pages Cat3 3.087 9.338 0 96.289
Prospective Articles 1.670 2.508 0 39
Prospective Pages Catl 1.078 3.370 0 31.059
Prospective Pages Cat2 2.764 6.871 0 52.616
Prospective Pages Cat3 2.176 6.542 0 69.771
Book Text 0.181 0.519 0 3
Text Revised 0.145 0.760 0 9
Book Research 0.269 0.852 0 10
Book Edited 0.182 0.829 0 13
Book Chapter 0.493 1.529 0 22
Citations 33.285 61.705 0 837
Notes: Sample consists of 2,698 observations of 238 faculty.
TABLE 3
Sample Means by Mobility Status
Variable Nonmovers Bid Away Denial Other Move
In (salary) 10.605 10.526 10.271 10.494
Top 10 0.269 0.253 0.173 0.118
Seniority 16.218 6.167 2.393 9.004
Experience 18.403 8.538 3.226 11.013
Female 0.047 0.217 0.190 0.063
Chair 0.056 0.068 0 0.013
Years Chair 0.644 0.276 0 0.110
Past Chair 0.083 0 0 0.063
Past Dean 0.003 0 0 0
Advisees 2.534 0.432 0.060 1.696
Articles 7.794 8.584 1.161 6.207
Pages Cat] 9.331 7.311 0.993 8.554
Pages Cat2 14.095 13.791 1.352 13.013
Pages Cat3 12.546 11.210 0.526 7.413
Recent Articles 2.224 3.819 0.958 2.633
Recent Pages Cat] 1.834 3.414 0.504 2.911
Recent Pages Cat2 3.845 8.373 1.233 4.238
Recent Pages Cat3 3.273 3.728 0.498 2.695
Prospective Articles 1.466 3.434 1.060 2.241
Prospective Pages Catl 0.894 2.391 0.742 1.700
Prospective Pages Cat2 2.219 8.189 2.335 2.772
Prospective Pages Cat3 2.224 3.134 1.285 1.492
Book Text 0.217 0.113 0 0.051
Text Revised 0.186 0.018 0 0
Book Research 0.285 0.443 0.030 0.139
Book Edited 0.204 0.204 0 0.097
Book Chapter 0.577 0.425 0.036 0.139
Citations 36.681 41.489 1.857 18.224
Observations 2,072 221 168 237
Faculty 138 34 35 31
TABLE 4
Random-Effects Estimates for Faculty Pay Structures
Independent Variable (1) (2)
Seniority -.0139 *** (.0023) -.0139 *** (.0021)
[Seniority.sup.2]/100 .0104 ** (.0050) .0029 (.0047)
Experience .0392 *** (.0025) .0365 *** (.0022)
Experience 2/100 -.0543 *** (.0051) -.0485 *** (.0047)
Female .0124 (.0274) .0126 (.0245)
Chair .0862 *** (.0113)
Years Chair .0100 *** (.0021)
Past Chair .0456 *** (.0140)
Past Dean .2837 *** (.0386)
Advisees .0107 *** (.0008)
Articles
Recent Articles
Prospective Articles
(Pages Catl)/10
(Recent Pages Catl)/10
(Prospective Pages Catl)/10
(Pages Cat2)/10
(Recent Pages Cat2)/10
(Prospective Pages Cat2)/10
(Pages Cat3)/10
(Recent Pages Cat3)/10
(Prospective Pages Cat3)/10
Book Text
Text Revised
Book Research
Book Edited
Book Chapter
Citations/100
[Citations.sup.2]/10,000
Independent Variable (3) (4)
Seniority -.0120 *** (.0018) -.0113 *** (.0018)
[Seniority.sup.2]/100 .0169 *** (.0040) .0157 *** (.0041)
Experience .0234 *** (.0019) .0231 *** (.0019)
Experience 2/100 -.0416 *** (.0041) -.0412 *** (.0041)
Female .0376 * (.0207) .0417 ** (.0203)
Chair .0765 *** (.0092) .0801 *** (.0092)
Years Chair .0164 *** (.0017) .0163 *** (.0017)
Past Chair .0305 *** (.0117) .0311 *** (.0118)
Past Dean .3925 *** (.0317) .3892 *** (.0316)
Advisees -.0003 (.0008) -.0001 (.0008)
Articles .0085 *** (.0007) .0093 *** (.0007)
Recent Articles -.0031 ** (.0012)
Prospective Articles .0005 (.0010)
(Pages Catl)/10 .0295 *** (.0032) .0308 *** (.0036)
(Recent Pages Catl)/10 .0090 ** (.0038)
(Prospective Pages Catl)/10 .0156 *** (.0057)
(Pages Cat2)/10 .0104 *** (.0018) .0083 *** (.0022)
(Recent Pages Cat2)/10 .0079 *** (.0028)
(Prospective Pages Cat2)/10 .0040 (.0028)
(Pages Cat3)/10 .0060 *** (.0013) .0046 *** (.0015)
(Recent Pages Cat3)/10 .0039 (.0028)
(Prospective Pages Cat3)/10 .0065 ** (.0033)
Book Text .0418 *** (.0077) .0413 *** (.0077)
Text Revised .0198 *** (.0045) .0195 *** (.0046)
Book Research .0201 *** (.0037) .0196 *** (.0037)
Book Edited .0129 ** (.0051) .0099 * (.0052)
Book Chapter .0147 *** (.0022) .0150 *** (.0023)
Citations/100 .0406 *** (.0118) .0462 *** (.0125)
[Citations.sup.2]/10,000 -.0141 *** (.0014) -.0149 *** (.0014)
Notes: Dependent variable is the natural logarithm of annual pay.
The regressions contain dichotomous variables to control for
university and academic year. The sample consists of 2,698
observations of 238 faculty.
* Statistically significant at the .10 level; ** statistically
significant at the .05 level; *** statistically significant at
the .01 level (two-tailed test).
TABLE 5
Differential Returns to Seniority for Movers
Independent Variable (1) (2)
Bid Away .0145 (.0239) .0013 (.0201)
Denial
Other Move
Seniority x Bid Away .0033 * (.0018) -.0020 (.0016)
Seniority x Denial
Seniority x Other Move
Seniority -.0142 *** (.0021) -.0110 *** (.0018)
[Seniority.sup.2]/100 .0035 (.0047) .0152 *** (.0041)
Control for Research? No Yes
Sample Full Full
Independent Variable (3) (4)
Bid Away -.0237 (.0204) -.0293 (.0201)
Denial -.0707 *** (.0212) -.0757 *** (.0211)
Other Move -.0158 (.0208) -.0234 (.0206)
Seniority x Bid Away -.0018 (.0016) .0001 (.0017)
Seniority x Denial -.0106 *** (.0035) -.0059 (.0046)
Seniority x Other Move -.0019 * (.0010) -.0002 (.0011)
Seniority -.0092 *** (.0018) -.0093 *** (.0018)
[Seniority.sup.2]/100 .0136 *** (.0041) .0119 *** (.0041)
Control for Research? Yes Yes
Sample Full Drops last
observation for movers
Notes: Dependent variable is the natural logarithm of annual
salary. Regressions control for experience, gender,
administrative experience, advising, university, year, and
faculty random effects. The estimates of columns 2-3 include all
research productivity variables (those listed in Table 4, column
4). The full sample used for columns 1-3 consists of 2,698
observations of 238 faculty, and the restricted sample for column
4 of 2,568 observations of 238 faculty.
* Statistically significant at the .10 level; *** statistically
significant at the .01 level.
TABLE 6
The Effect of a Top 10 Degree
Independent Variable (1) (2)
Top 10 -.0197 (.0197) -.0040 (.0165)
Bid Away
Denial
Other Move
Seniority x Top 10 .0042 *** (.0006) .0027 *** (.0006)
Seniority x Bid Away
Seniority x Denial
Seniority x Other Move
Seniority -.0161 *** (.0021) -.0129 *** (.0018)
[Seniority.sup.2]/100 .0073 (.0047) .0180 *** (.0041)
Control for Research? No Yes
Sample Full Full
Independent Variable (3) (4)
Top 10 -.0105 (.0156) -.0091 (.0152)
Bid Away -.0218 (.0203) -.0274 (.0199)
Denial -.0692 *** (.0211) -.0739 *** (0210)
Other Move -.0174 (.0207) -.0244 (.0205)
Seniority x Top 10 .0026 *** (.0006) .0027 *** (.0006)
Seniority x Bid Away -.0015 (.0016) .0005 (.0017)
Seniority x Denial -.0106 *** (.0035) -.0060 (.0046)
Seniority x Other Move -.0012 (.0010) .0006 (.0011)
Seniority -.0109 *** (.0018) -.0110 *** (.0018)
[Seniority.sup.2]/100 .0156 *** (.0041) .0139 *** (.0041)
Control for Research? Yes Yes
Sample Full Drops last
observation for movers
Notes: Dependent variable is the natural logarithm of annual
salary. Regressions control for experience, gender,
administrative experience, advising, university, year, and
faculty random effects. The estimates of columns 2-3 include all
research productivity variables. The full sample used for columns
1-3 consists of 2,698 observations of 238 faculty, and the
restricted sample for column 4 of 2,568 observations of 238
faculty.
* Statistically significant at the .10 level;; **statistically
significant at the .05 level; ***statistically significant at the
.01 level.
TABLE 7
Returns to Seniority and Experience by Subperiod--Comparing
Random-Effects and Topel Estimates
Full Sample
Random Effects Topel
Independent Variable (l) (2)
Seniority -.0107 *** (.0018) -.0151 *** (.0035)
Seniority 2/100 .0134 *** (.0041) .0308 *** (.0112)
Experience .0230 *** (.0019) .0267 *** (.0039)
Experience 2/100 -.0404 *** (.0041) -.0537 *** (.0113)
Seniority penalty -.1302 *** (.0225) -.1575 *** (.0354)
at 15 yr
Cum returns .2527 *** (.0237) .2800 *** (.0385)
to experience at 15 yr
1975-1994
Random Effects Topel
Independent Variable (3) (4)
Seniority -.0088 *** (.0024) -.0204 *** (.0053)
Seniority 2/100 .0243 *** (.0056) .0546 *** (.0160)
Experience .0253 *** (.0025) .0306 *** (.0056)
Experience 2/100 -.0513 *** (.0054) -.0734 *** (.0156)
Seniority penalty -.0767 *** (.0297) -.1828 *** (.0536)
at 15 yr
Cum returns .2643 *** (.0305) .2933 *** (.0562)
to experience at 15 yr
1995-2004
Random Effects Topel
Independent Variable (5) (6)
Seniority -.0139 *** (.0028) -.0083 ** (.0038)
Seniority 2/100 .0143 ** (.0072) -.0063 (.0131)
Experience .0226 *** (.0032) .0209 *** (.0045)
Experience 2/100 -.0374 *** (.0078) -.0179 (.0141)
Seniority penalty -.1756 *** (.0340) -.1390 *** (.0417)
at 15 yr
Cum returns .2551 *** (.0379) .2731 *** (.0479)
to experience at 15 yr
Notes: Regressions control for gender, research productivity,
university, and academic year (see specification reported in
Table 4, column 4), and sample drops the last observation for
movers. The sample in columns 1-2 consists of 2,598 observations
of 238 faculty, columns 3-4 have 1,771 observations of 177
faculty, and columns 5-6 have 827 observations of 142 faculty.
Standard errors in columns 2, 4, and 6 are adjusted for sampling
errors in first-step estimates.
* statistically significant at the .01 level; ** statistically
significant at the .05 level; *** statistically significant at
the .01 level.
FIGURE 1
Direction of Move for Those Leaving the Sample
Downward (66%)
Laterally (11%)
Upward (23%)
Note. Data are limited to faculty who obtain alternative employment.
Note: Table made from pie chart.