Deconstructing the success of real business cycles.
Nakamura, Emi
I. INTRODUCTION
A major achievement of Real Business Cycle (RBC) models has been
their success at elegantly explaining a remarkably large fraction of
business cycle fluctuations in aggregate variables based solely on
exogenous variation in productivity. In particular, the RBC literature
has emphasized the ability of models driven by productivity shocks to
explain the historically observed paths of macroeconomic variables, a
method introduced by Plosser (1989). In a recent paper in the Handbook
of Macroeconomics, King and Rebelo (1999) remark on the
"dramatic" correspondence between simulations of the US
economy produced by the RBC model and the actual data when productivity
shocks are "remeasured" and the bare-bones model is augmented
with the assumptions of indivisible labor and variable capital
utilization. RBC models explain the comovement of a multiplicity of
macroeconomic variables consumption, output, labor supply, investment,
wages, productivity, etc.--with a single exogenous shock series. In
other words, they reduce a more than five-dimensional problem to one
dimension of unexplained variation.
The contribution of the RBC methodology to the business cycle
literature can be thought of in two parts. First, RBC models adopt a
basic dynamic stochastic general equilibrium framework that has now
become standard in the macroeconomics business cycle literature,
including New Keynesian models. Second, the RBC literature emphasizes
the importance of the productivity shock. This paper investigates the
question of how much of the success of RBC, according to standard RBC
evaluation techniques, arises from the basic form of the dynamic
stochastic general equilibrium model versus the specific role of the
productivity shock. The answer to this question says something both
about the nature of the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models
used in macroeconomics as well as about the standard RBC tests used to
evaluate these models.
The models considered in this paper all have the basic form of the
"high-substitution" RBC model developed by King and Rebelo
(1999). I consider both the original form of this model, as well as a
"Monetary Business Cycle" (MBC) version of the model augmented
with a Calvo Phillips curve and a standard Taylor rule specification of
monetary policy. I adopt the procedure of "remeasuring" the
business cycle shocks to perfectly match the observed output series by
King and Rebelo (1999). I consider the models' success at
explaining the behavior of macroeconomic variables given a variety of
specifications of shocks: productivity shocks, monetary shocks to the
Taylor rule, cost-push shocks, and preference shocks. This exercise
shows that any of the models with "remeasured" shocks is able
to successfully explain the empirical dynamics of the real variables.
The monetary model with remeasured shocks is, if anything, more
empirically successful than the RBC model, since it is also able to
explain the behavior of inflation and the nominal interest rate in the
Volcker-Greenspan era. Thus, this paper adds concreteness to work by
Hansen and Heckman (1996) and Fair (1992), suggesting that the RBC
standards for evaluating models may be too weak by showing that
important classes of business cycle models cannot be distinguished using
standard RBC evaluation techniques.
The MBC models considered in this paper have the same basic
structure as the model presented in Rotemberg and Woodford (1997). The
most closely related paper to the present work is perhaps the innovative
paper by Hairault and Portier (1993), which evaluates the performance of
a MBC model when presented with various combinations of estimated
monetary and productivity shocks. Unlike the present paper, however, the
success of the models is evaluated according to their second moment
properties.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section II presents the model, which
consists of a household sector, a firm sector and a central bank. Aside
from the assumptions relating to the price setting behavior of the firm
and the behavior of the central bank, the model is exactly the one
developed in King and Rebelo (1999), making the results as comparable as
possible to the RBC benchmark. In Section IV, I solve for the unique
rational expectations equilibrium of the model. Section V presents
simulation results. Section VI concludes. There are three appendices.
Appendix A describes the construction of the data series, Appendix B
describes the calibration of the model, and Appendix C provides a short
description of the model of indivisible labor used in the paper.
II. THE MODEL
I present only a brief description of the model, since its
components are standard in the business cycle literature. A more
detailed description of the basic RBC framework can be found in King and
Rebelo (1999). A detailed discussion of the monopolistic competition and
staggered price setting assumptions in the MBC model can be found in
Woodford (2003). The RBC model consists of a household sector and a firm
sector. The MBC model also incorporates a central bank.
A. Households
The representative household maximizes the expected discounted sum
of a utility function U([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t], [[eta].sub.t]), where Ct
denotes consumption of a composite consumption good, [L.sub.t] denotes
leisure and [[eta].sub.t] denotes a preference shock. Financial markets
are complete. All assets may therefore be priced using the stochastic discount factor
[M.sub.t,t+1] = [beta][U.sub.c]([C.sub.t+1], [L.sub.t+1],
[[eta].sub.t+1])/[U.sub.c]([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t], [[eta].sub.t])
where [beta] denotes the household's discount factor and
[U.sub.c]. denotes the partial derivative of U with respect to
[C.sub.t]. This implies that the short-term nominal interest rate,
[i.sub.t], and the real return on capital, [r.sub.t+1], are given by
familiar Euler equations
(1) [U.sub.c]([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t], [[eta].sub.t]) =
[beta][E.sub.t][[U.sub.c]([C.sub.t] + 1, [L.sub.t+1], [[eta].sub.t+1])
(1 + [r.sub.t+1])],
(2) [U.sub.c]([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t], [[eta].sub.t]) =
[beta][E.sub.t][[U.sub.c]([C.sub.t+1], [L.sub.t+1], [[eta].sub.t+1]) 1 +
[i.sub.t]/[[PI].sub.t+1]],
where [[PI].sub.t] denotes the rate of inflation. The labor market in the economy is perfectly competitive. The household's optimal
labor supply is given by
(3) [U.sub.l]([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t],
[[eta].sub.t])/[U.sub.c]([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t], [[eta].sub.t]) =
[W.sub.t]/[P.sub.t],
where [W.sub.t] denotes the wage rate.
I follow the RBC literature in assuming that the household's
utility function takes a functional form that is consistent with a
balanced growth path,
(4) u([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t], [[eta].sub.t]) = [[eta].sub.t] 1/1 -
[sigma] {[[[C.sub.t]v([L.sub.t])].sup.1-[sigma]] - 1}.
I follow King and Rebelo (1999) in assuming that the household
works a fixed shift with some probability, and otherwise does not work
at all. This formulation of "indivisible labor" was originally
proposed by Rogerson and Wright (1988). King and Rebelo make use of the
indivisible labor assumption to increase the labor supply volatility of
the bare-bones RBC model and to increase the overall responsiveness of
the RBC model to productivity shocks. See Appendix C for a more detailed
discussion of this assumption and the functional form of v(Lt) that it
implies.
The composite consumption good, Ct, from which the household
derives utility, is a constant elasticity of substitution (CES)
aggregate of the differentiated goods produced by the firm sector.
Optimal household demand for each of these individual goods is therefore
given by
(5) [c.sub.t](z) =
[C.sub.t][[[p.sub.t](z)/[P.sub.t]].sup.-[theta]],
where [c.sub.t](z) denotes the consumption of individual good z,
[p.sub.t](z) denotes the price of this good, [P.sub.t] denotes the CES
price index that measures the minimum cost of purchasing one unit of
[C.sub.t], and [theta] denotes the elasticity of substitution of the
goods in [C.sub.t] as well as the elasticity of demand for each of the
goods [c.sub.t](z). The RBC version of the model corresponds to the
special case of perfect competition, where [theta] [right arrow]
[infinity].
B. Firms
The firm sector consists of a continuum of identical producers
selling differentiated goods (Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977). In the MBC
version of the model, the individual goods are imperfect substitutes in
household consumption. This implies that the firm has some monopoly
power and can therefore choose the price of the good it produces. In the
RBC version of the model, however, goods markets are perfectly
competitive. Firms act to maximize their expected profits. The
production function of the representative firm is [A.sub.t]F([K.sub.t],
[N.sub.t], [Q.sub.t]) = [A.sub.t][([Q.sub.t][K.sub.t]).sup.1-[alpha]]
[N.sup.[alpha].sub.t], where [K.sub.t] denotes capital, [N.sub.t]
denotes labor, [A.sub.t] denotes total factor productivity (TFP) and
[Q.sub.t] denotes capital utilization. I follow King and Rebelo (1999)
in assuming that the firm can vary its capital utilization rate and that
increased capital utilization leads to increased depreciation of the
capital stock. King and Rebelo (1999) make use of this assumption, like
indivisible labor, to increase the relative responsiveness of labor
supply to exogenous shocks.
Necessary conditions for cost minimization by firms are given by
(6) [W.sub.t] = [A.sub.t][F.sub.n]([K.sub.t], [N.sub.t],
[Q.sub.t])[S.sub.t],
(7) [[rho].sub.t] = [A.sub.t][F.sub.k]([K.sub.t], [N.sub.t],
[Q.sub.t])[S.sub.t],
(8) [P.sub.t][delta]([Q.sub.t])[K.sub.t] =
[A.sub.t][F.sub.Q]([K.sub.t], [X.sub.t], [Q.sub.t])[S.sub.t],
where [S.sub.t] denotes the firm's marginal cost,
[[rho].sub.t] denotes the firm's cost of capital and
[delta]([Q.sub.t]) denotes the depreciation rate of capital, which is
assumed to be a convex, increasing function of the utilization rate. The
first of these equations is the firm's labor demand equation. The
second equation is the firm's demand for capital. The third
describes optimal utilization of capital. As is standard in the
literature, I assume that there is a "gestation lag" of one
period between when the household trades off consumption in order to
invest and when the firm uses the newly acquired capital in production.
Thus, the producer's cost of capital is related to the real rate of
return on capital, [r.sub.t], by the equation,
(9) 1 + [r.sub.t] = [[rho].sub.t]/[P.sub.t] + (1 -
[delta]([Q.sub.t])),
where 1 - [delta] is the fraction of capital goods left
undepreciated at the end of each period.
I assume that the production function is linearly homogeneous. This
implies that every firm has the same capital-output ratio (despite
having different levels of production in the MBC version of the model),
so conditions (6) and (7) hold for the aggregate capital and labor
demands as well as for the demands of individual firms.
In the RBC version of the model, prices are flexible and [theta]
[right arrow] [infinity]. This implies that [p.sub.t](z) = [P.sub.t] =
[S.sub.t]. In the MBC version of the model I assume that firms change
their prices in a staggered manner as in Calvo (1983). As is well known,
this results in the rate of inflation evolving, up to a first-order
approximation, according to a New Keynesian Phillips curve,
(10) [[pi].sub.t] = [beta][E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t+1] +
[kappa][s.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t],
where [[pi].sub.t] denotes the log of the inflation rate
[[PI].sub.t], [s.sub.t] denotes percentage deviations of real marginal
costs [S.sub.t]/[P.sub.t] from their steady-state level and
[[epsilon].sub.t] is a "cost-push" shock. (1)
I also consider a "hybrid" Phillips curve similar to the
one proposed by Fuhrer and Moore (1995) in order to improve the fit of
the MBC model to nominal variables,
(11) [[pi].sub.t] = 0.5[beta][E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t+1] +
0.5[[pi].sub.t-1] + [kappa][s.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t],
This type of Phillips curve can be micro-founded by assuming that
some fraction of firms set prices according to a "rule of
thumb." (2)
Finally, in both the RBC and the MBC specifications of the model,
the equation for goods market equilibrium,
(12) [Y.sub.t] = [C.sub.t] + ([K.sub.t] + 1 - (1 -
[delta]([Q.sub.t])[K.sub.t])),
links the household and firm sectors of the economy. Here [Y.sub.t]
denotes aggregate output.
Let us also define the following standard measure of TFP, the
"Solow residual,"
(13) [SR.sub.t], = [y.sub.t] - (1 - [[alpha].sub.sh])kt -
[[alpha].sub.sh][n.sub.t],
where lower case variables denote percentage deviations of the
corresponding upper case variable from their steady-state values and
[[alpha].sub.sh] is the labor income share. The Solow Residual is
defined here, as in King and Rebelo (1999), as the part of gross
domestic product (GDP) left unexplained by the Cobb-Douglas production
function. However, in the context of the high-substitution economy
described above, the Solow residual mismeasures productivity [A.sub.t]
even for the RBC case, since it does not take into consideration
variable capital utilization. The Solow residual further mismeasures TFP
in the MBC economy, since the labor share [alpha]sh underestimates the
Cobb-Douglas production function parameter [alpha].
C. The Central Bank
In the MBC version of the model, the central bank follows a
standard "Taylor rule" in setting the nominal interest rate.
According to the Taylor rule, the Federal Reserve predictably raises the
Federal Funds rate in response to high inflation and output and lowers
it when economic conditions reverse. In a seminal paper, Taylor (1993)
showed that the behavior of the U.S. Federal Reserve can be well
described by a Taylor rule in recent years. I use Taylor's original
policy rule, except for a slightly higher value of the constant term,
which fits the data better for the sample period I consider in the
simulation exercises,
(14) [i.sub.t] = 0.055 + 1.5([[pi].sub.t] - 0.02) + 0.5[y.sub.t] +
[v.sub.t],
where [v.sub.t] denotes a monetary policy shock. Notice that in
this equation [[pi].sub.t], refers simply to the inflation rate in the
present quarter, not the moving average of the previous year's
inflation (the variable used in some of the empirical literature).
III. REMEASURING THE SHOCKS
King and Rebelo argue that traditional measures of productivity are
likely to contain significant measurement errors. They
"remeasure" TFP as the sequence of TFP realizations that
perfectly matches their model to the data, in terms of the simulated and
empirical series for GDP. (3)
How does this approach relate to the more standard procedure of
using the Solow residual to estimate productivity? The key identifying
assumption in the RBC literature is that productivity shocks are the
only source of macroeconomic variation in the economy. Given this
premise, the productivity shocks are estimated by minimizing (in some
sense) the amount of approximation error. However, since the model is
only an approximation, there is a tradeoff between the model's
ability to fit the empirical GDP series and its ability to fit the
empirical productivity series. The difference between King and
Rebelo's estimation procedure and the more standard method is
simply that it minimizes the approximation error of the model in terms
of the output series rather than the Solow residual.
A similar type of mismeasurement argument could also be made for a
number of other types of shocks to the model: monetary shocks to the
Taylor rule, cost-push shocks to the Phillips curve, and preference
shocks to the Euler equations. The next section of the paper presents a
series of exercises in which each of these types of shocks is
"remeasured" according to the King and Rebelo (1999) procedure
in order to perfectly match the output series.
King and Rebelo assume that TFP follows a first-order
autoregressive process. They estimate the autoregressive parameter by
fitting the remeasured productivity series to an AR(1) process,
(15) [A.sub.t] = [[rho].sub.A][A.sub.t] - 1 + [e.sub.t],
where [A.sub.t] is TFP, [e.sub.t] is an independently and
identically distributed random variable and [[rho].sub.A] is the
autoregressive parameter.
Similarly, I assume that the monetary shocks evolve according to a
first-order autoregressive process,
(16) [v.sub.t] = [[rho].sub.v][v.sub.t-1] + [e.sub.t],
where [e.sub.t] is an independently and identically distributed
random variable; and [[rho].sub.v] is the autoregressive parameter.
Identical autoregressive shock processes are also postulated for the
cost-push shocks [[epsilon].sub.t] and the preference shocks
[[eta].sub.t]. However, it is important to remember that each of the
simulation exercises that follow considers only one of the shocks
described above at a time.
As in King and Rebelo (1999) I estimate the persistence parameters
in the following way. I first solve the model postulating a given value
of the autoregressive parameter. I then calculate the shocks implied by
the model solution, and calculate the persistence of this shock series.
I use this revised value of the persistence parameter to solve the
model, iterating this procedure until the postulated and actual values
of the persistence parameter are the same. (4) It is useful to note that
given the procedure used to remeasure the shocks, the simulation results
for the real variables in the RBC and MBC models are quite robust to
changes in the specification of the persistence parameters.
IV. SOLVING FOR A RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS EQUILIBRIUM
In the simulations that follow, I consider seven different versions
of the model presented in Section II. They differ according to the
exogenous shock generating the economic fluctuations and the
specification of the Phillips curve. I consider two versions of the RBC
model: a standard RBC model with a productivity shock (RBC1), and a
version of the RBC model with preference shocks (RBC2). In addition, I
consider five versions of the MBC model: the MBC model with monetary
shocks and a Calvo Phillips curve (MBC1), the MBC model with monetary
shocks and a hybrid Phillips curve (MBC2), the MBC model with cost-push
shocks and a Calvo Phillips curve (MBC3), the MBC model with preference
shocks and a Calvo Phillips curve (MBC4) and finally the MBC model with
productivity shocks and a Calvo Phillips curve (MBC5).
I apply a generalized version of the Blanchard and Kahn (1980)
approach, as formulated in Sims (2000), to solve for the unique bounded
rational expectations equilibrium of the log-linear approximation to the
model: The log-linear approximation is a first-order Taylor series
expansion around the non-stochastic steady state. The result is a system
of first-order linear difference equations, which gives the law of
motion for the economy. This system of equations can then be used to
construct simulations given hypothetical shock processes, as well as
theoretical means and variances.
V. SIMULATION RESULTS
King and Rebelo (1999) present the high correlations between the
simulated and empirical series for the RBC model as dramatic evidence
for the success of the RBC model driven by productivity shocks. Panel 1
of Table 1 shows that the simulation results for the MBC1-MBC5 models
(with both the Calvo and hybrid Phillips curves) are equally dramatic.
The correlations are at least .80 for consumption, .81 for investment,
.88 for labor, and .59 for the Solow residual. The MBC2 model also
explains the empirical series for inflation and the nominal interest
rate quite well. The correlations between the simulated and empirical
series are .91 for inflation and .74 for the nominal interest rate for
the MBC2 model. The correlations have a similar magnitude for the RBC2
model, though the correlation for the Solow residual is slightly lower.
Figure 1 plots the simulated and empirical time series for the MBC2
model with the hybrid Phillips curve. The solid lines represent the
empirical series, and the dashed lines represent the theoretical series.
The plots show that the simulated and empirical time series are very
similar, which is not surprising given the high correlations reported in
Table 1. As discussed in the previous section, the perfect fit between
the simulated and empirical output series is by construction--the
monetary shocks are chosen to perfectly match the simulated and
empirical output series. Similarly impressive plots could be constructed
for all of the models for the consumption, investment, labor, and Solow
residual variables. The success of the models at replicating the
observed paths of these variables is robust to almost any changes in the
parameters, given the procedure used to construct the shocks.
The simulations take as given the initial values of the state
variables, capital and productivity, as well as the sequence of
productivity shocks. I focus on the period spanning the third quarter of
1980 to the first quarter of 2000 in order to allow for a stable Taylor
rule: it seems unreasonable to assume that the Federal Reserve Bank
followed the same Taylor rule in earlier years. (6) For robustness,
Panel 2 of Table 1 also presents results for the period 1947-2000. The
results for the longer time series are broadly similar for the real
variables, though the MBC models are considerably less successful at
replicating the nominal variables over the longer time period. Following
Taylor (1993), I use the four-quarter moving average of quarterly
inflation as my empirical inflation series. As in RBC simulations, the
data series for the real variables are constructed by logging and HP
filtering the raw data, as described in Appendix A. The HP filter
removes low-frequency fluctuations in the time series, for the purpose
of isolating business cycle fluctuations. (7)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
An important caveat to the success of the models along this
dimension is, however, that the models' ability to explain the real
variables falls as their correlation with output drops. Table 1 shows
that the MBC2 model with the hybrid Phillips curve is far more
successful than the other models at explaining the nominal interest rate
and inflation (and has almost identical implications for the remainder
of the variables). (8) However, this result is somewhat fragile. In
particular, the MBC2 model's ability to replicate the nominal
variables is much less robust to changes in the model than its ability
to replicate the consumption, investment, labor, and Solow residual
variables. The simulations of the nominal variables depend on the
Central Bank's policy rule, whereas the simulations of the real
variables do not. As I note above, the MBC model replicates the real
variables almost equally well over the period 1947-2000, whereas the
ability of the MBC2 model to replicate the nominal variables diminishes
considerably over the longer time period. N one of the models succeeds
at all at explaining the real wage, which is least correlated with
output among the real variables. The correlations between the simulated
and empirical real wage series are close to zero or are negative.
Thus, the support provided by Table 1 for all of the business cycle
models considered in this paper has an important caveat. Looking
carefully at Figure 1, one can see that the simulated series for output,
consumption, labor supply, and the Solow residual are very similar. The
same is true of simulations of the RBC model. Table 2 shows that
consumption, the labor supply, and the Solow residual are highly
correlated with output in the long run. The success story of the RBC and
MBC models (with respect to the real variables) is that the models are
able to explain why certain variables covary so much over the business
cycle, and at what amplitudes-not their idiosyncratic movements.
Another common RBC approach to evaluating the fit of the model is
to compare the theoretical second moments of the model to the
relationships observed in the data. Table 2 gives cross-correlations
with output, and Table 3 gives the theoretical standard deviations
relative to output for the RBC and MBC models. I compare the theoretical
values to the corresponding empirical statistics for the periods
1947-2000 and 1980-2000. (9) Again, I find that the models have fairly
reasonable, and remarkably similar, properties for consumption,
investment, labor supply and the Solow residual.
Once again, the models differ in their implications for the nominal
interest rate, inflation and the real wage. The RBC1, MBC3, and MBC5
models imply the most reasonable levels of volatility for the real
wage--the real wage volatility for the other models is too low. (See
Table 3.) However, the volatility of the real wage in the RBC 1 model is
very sensitive to the persistence parameter for productivity: a small
reduction in this parameter causes a large reduction in the theoretical
variance of the real wage. (10)
The hybrid MBC model considerably underestimates the variance of
the nominal interest rate, though the correlation between the
theoretical and empirical series is quite high. (See Table 3.)
As noted above, the MBC2 model produces the most realistic
implications for the nominal variables. All of the other MBC models
imply correlations between the nominal variables and output that are
unrealistically large in magnitude. Basically, this is a consequence of
the use of the Calvo Phillips curve in the other MBC models. The lagged
inflation term in the hybrid Phillips curve prevents inflation from
moving in lockstep with output.
Impulse Response Functions
In order to provide some intuition for the results, Figures 2, 3,
and 4 plot the impulse response functions for the MBC and RBC models.
The monetary shock would, all else equal, reduce the nominal interest
rate by half a percentage point in the MBC economy; the productivity
shock would, all else equal, increase aggregate output by 0.1% in the
RBC economy. The plots show that an economic boom in the MBC economy
(induced by an expansionary monetary shock) appears very similar to a
productivity-induced economic boom in the RBC economy. On the one hand,
according to the MBC story, an economic boom occurs when unexpectedly
low nominal interest rates lead to an expansion in demand, which is not
undone by inflation (due to sticky prices). The resulting economic
expansion leads to a measured increase in TFP, even though there is no
productivity shock. (I explain the intuition for the measured increase
in TFP below.)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
On the other hand, according to the RBC story, an economic boom
occurs when TFP is unusually high. The resulting increase in GDP leads
to a measured decrease in the Taylor rule residual even though there is
no monetary shock (holding fixed the nominal interest rate, which is
indeterminate in the RBC model). From an MBC perspective, procyclical
fluctuations in TFP are artifacts of a misspecified production function;
from an RBC perspective, countercyclical fluctuations in the Taylor rule
error are artifacts of a misspecified policy rule for the central bank.
In the MBC model, the shocks also generate fluctuations in the nominal
interest rate, inflation and the markup as depicted in Figure 4.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In the models without an assumed productivity shock (all of the
models except the RBC model), one might wonder about the source of the
observed procyclical variation in the Solow residual. There are two
sources of the observed variation in the Solow residual aside from
actual variation in TFP. The first is variable capital utilization,
which is not accounted for in the standard version of the Solow
residual. The second is a particular type of mismeasurement story that
was first noted by Hall (1988). (11) The story goes as follows. If
markets are monopolistic, then prices are no longer set equal to
marginal costs. The traditional argument for calibrating the parameter
[alpha] as the income share in the Cobb-Douglas production function
breaks down. Given that the firms are monopolists in the MBC model, the
correct calibration of the parameter [alpha] is as a markup over the
income share, rather than the income share itself. The Solow residual
thus underestimates the true contribution of labor to production. In the
MBC model, economic booms result from expansionary monetary shocks
rather than fluctuations in productivity. Since labor increases more
than capital in booms, the Solow residual is procyclical even though
productivity is constant. (12)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Finally, it is useful to provide some statistics on the assumed
exogenous shocks in the various models. Table 4 presents some summary
statistics for the remeasured shocks. In the case of the standard RBC
and the MBC models with monetary shocks (MBC1 and MBC2), it is possible
to derive a direct empirical measure of the exogenous shocks as well as
constructing the remeasured shocks investigated in this paper. As in
King and Rebelo (1999), the remeasured shocks generally do not have a
high correlation with the direct empirical measures of the shocks. The
lack of correlation is not surprising, given the small magnitude of the
shocks.
VI. CONCLUSION
The simulation exercises in this paper show that the success of the
RBC model according to standard RBC evaluation techniques arises
primarily from the basic structure of the stochastic dynamic general
equilibrium model, rather than from the specific role of the
productivity shock. According to standard RBC evaluation techniques,
there is a high degree of similarity between a broad variety of monetary
and real business cycle models driven by productivity, monetary,
cost-push, and preference shocks. These results emphasize the importance
of the basic structure of the RBC model--common to most modern business
cycle models in explaining the success of RBC models.
None of the models I consider provides a good explanation for
variables not highly correlated with output such as the real wage and
the real interest rate. Thus, as I discuss in Section V, the success
story of the RBC and MBC models (with respect to the real variables) is
that the models are able to explain why certain variables covary so much
over the business cycle, and at what amplitudes--not their idiosyncratic
movements. These results indicate strongly that a successful model of
these variables must embody either complicated nonlinear dynamics that
are able to generate shifting patterns of correlations across key
macroeconomic variables, or multiple shocks. The disparate implications
of the RBC and MBC models for the real wage and the interest rate
suggest that the dynamics of these variables are likely to be
particularly important in distinguishing between alternative sources of
variation in models with multiple shocks. The similar implications of
the RBC and MBC models in terms of standard RBC evaluation criteria also
underscores the importance of techniques that make use of additional
sources of data from micro-level studies, as well as more sophisticated
econometric approaches for comparing the model and data.
ABBREVIATIONS
DRI: Data Resources Inc.
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
MBC: Monetary Business Cycle
RBC: Real Business Cycle
TFP: Total Factor Productivity
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2008.00141.x
APPENDIX A: CONSTRUCTING THE DATA SERIES
This section describes the data series used in this paper.
All of the series are from the Data Resources Inc. (DRI) website
and span the period from the first quarter of 1947 through the third
quarter of 2000. I indicate whether the series are seasonally adjusted (SA), seasonally adjusted at an annual rate (SAAR), or not seasonally
adjusted (NSA).
All of the series are quarterly unless otherwise indicated.
For the monthly series, the average value over the quarter is used
to create a quarterly series. All of the series, except those that
correspond to nominal variables, are logged and then detrended by
subtracting the HP trend series for [lambda] = 1,600 (the standard value
for quarterly data). (13) The variables are:
Nominal GDP (in billions of dollars, SAAR): GDP. Real GDP (in
billions of 1992 chained dollars, SAAR): GDPQ. The HP-filtered version
of this series is the estimate for [y.sub.t].
Total Personal Consumption Expenditures (in billions of 1992
chained dollars. SAAR): GCQ. The HP filtered version of this series is
the estimate for c,. The quarterly data are not available on the DRI
website for the years prior to the fourth quarter of 1958 so annual data
are used. The variable name for the annual consumption series is GAE.
Total Fixed Investment (in billions of 1992 chained dollars. SAAR):
GIFQ. I use the data on investment to construct a series for the capital
stock using the definition,
(17) [I.sub.t] = [K.sub.t] - [K.sub.t+1] + [delta][K.sub.t],
where [I.sub.t] is fixed investment. The initial value in the
capital stock series is taken from the "Survey of Current
Business" estimate for 1947. The HP-filtered version of the capital
series is the estimate for [k.sub.t]. In order to construct a consistent
series for detrended investment, I apply the definition (17) to the
[k.sub.t] series. (Another approach would be to HP filter the investment
series, and then construct a capital stock series using Equation (17)).
Total Hours of Employment of All Persons in the Nonfarm Business
Sector (in billions of hours. SA): LBMNU. The HP-filtered version of
this series is the estimate for [N.sub.t].
Total Capacity Utilization Rate in Manufacturing (percent of
capacity, SA): IPXMCA (monthly series). The HP filtered version of this
series is the estimate for [Q.sub.t].
Compensation per Hour in the Nonfarm Business Sector, (Scaled 1982
= 100, SA): LBCPU. The HP-filtered version of this series is the
estimate for [w.sub.t].
Federal Funds Rate: (Percentage per Annum, NSA). FYFF (monthly
series). This series, transformed to give quarterly rates, is the
estimate for [i.sub.t].
Price Index: I infer the price index series from the nominal and
real GDP series. (14) I use the price index series to construct an
inflation series, which is the estimate for [pi]t. Solow residual
(18) [y.sub.t] - (1 - [[alpha].sub.sh])[k.sub.t] -
[[alpha].sub.sh][n.sub.t].
APPENDIX B: CALIBRATING THE MODEL
A. Households
I set the real return on capital and the real interest rate to 6.5%
and steady-state depreciation at 10% per annum. Following King and
Rebelo (1999), I specify [sigma] = 3 in the utility function (4).
The parameterization of [theta] determines the degree of monopoly
power of the firms in the market. I chose a value [theta] = 7.88, which
implies a steady-state average markup of 15% over the marginal cost.
(15)
B. Firms
In the RBC framework, [alpha] is simply the steady-state labor
income share. On the other hand, in a model with monopolistic
competition, [alpha] is the labor income share scaled by the
steady-state markup. The implied value of is 0.7705, given a labor share
of two-thirds.
I follow King and Rebelo (1999) in specifying the steady-state
labor supply as n = 0.2, which they present as the fraction of available
time engaged in work in the U.S. in the post-war period.
I set the steady-state value of capital utilization Q = 1.
However, a different choice for Q would simply define different
units for capital.
The degree of amplification in the high substitution economy is
very sensitive to the parameterization of the elasticity of
[delta]([Q.sub.t]) with respect to [Q.sub.t]. I follow King and Rebelo
(1999) in calibrating this elasticity to be 0.1.
Let [gamma] denote the probability that a firm is able to change
its prices in a given period (according to the Calvo assumption). Gali and Gertler (1999) report estimates of 7 between .803 and .866. I use
[gamma] = .6 because this parameter implies a more realistic amount of
high-frequency variation in the inflation series.
The remainder of the parameters in the model can be derived by
exploiting the relationships among variables in the steady state.
APPENDIX C: INDIVISIBLE LABOR
Rogerson and Wright (1988) suggest the following approach to
modelling indivisible labor. Suppose that the labor force of the economy
consists of a continuum of identical households. Each one has
probability p of working a shift of H hours, and probability 1 - p of
not working at all. As in Section II, the households seek to maximize
their expected utilities. In this scenario, it seems natural for the
households to enter into an efficient risk-sharing agreement think of it
as an Unemployment Insurance system. The Unemployment Insurance system
allocates consumption in the two states to solve the problem,
(19) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
s.t.
(20) p[C.sub.u] + (1 - p)[C.sub.e] = C,
where [C.sub.u] is consumption in the unemployed state, [C.sub.e]
is consumption in the employed state, and C is the expected consumption
over the two states.
If household utility takes the CES form,
(21) u(C, L) = 1/1 - [sigma]{[[C[??](L)].sup.1-[sigma]] - 1}.
then expected utility is given by
(22) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where L is average leisure, defined as L = 1 - pH.
Thus, we can incorporate indivisible labor into the model simply by
taking household utility to be (22). (16) See King and Rebelo (1999) for
the details of the derivation.
REFERENCES
Bernanke, B. S., and M. L. Parkinson. "Procyclical Labor
Productivity and Competing Theories of the Business Cycle: Some Evidence
from Interwar U.S.
Manufacturing Industries." Journal of Political Economy, 99,
1991, 439-59.
Blanchard, O. J., and C. Kahn. "The Solution of Linear
Difference Equations under Rational Expectations."
Econometrica, 48, 1980, 1305-11.
Calvo G. A. "Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing
Framework." Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 1983, 383-98.
Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan. "Can Sticky
Price Models Generate Volatile and Persistent Real Exchange Rates?"
Review of Economic Studies, 69, 2002, 533-63.
Dixit, A. K., and J. E. Stiglitz. "Monopolistic Competition
and Optimum Product Diversity." American Economic Review, 67, 1977,
297-308.
Evans, C. "Productivity Shocks and the Real Business
Cycle." Journal of Monetary Economics, 29, 1992, 191-208.
Fair, R. "The Cowles Commission Approach, Real Business Cycle
Theories, and New Keynesian Economics," in The Business Cycle:
Theories and Evidence, edited by M. T. Belongia and M. R. Garfinkel.
Boston: Kluwer Academic, 1992, 191-208.
Fuhrer, J. C., and G. R. Moore. "Inflation Persistence."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 1995, 197-230.
Gali, J., and M. Gertler. "Inflation Dynamics: A Structural
Econometric Analysis." Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 1999,
195-222.
Hairault, J., and F. Portier. "Money, New-Keynesian
Macroeconomics and the Business Cycle." European Economic Review,
37, 1993, 1533-63.
Hall, R. E. "The Relationship Between Price and Marginal Cost
in US Industry." Journal of Political Economy, 96, 1988, 921-47.
Hansen, L. P., and J. J. Heckman. "The Empirical Foundations
of Calibration." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, 1996,
87-104.
Hodrick, R. J., and E. C. Prescott. "Post-war U.S. Business
Cycles: An Empirical Investigation." Working Paper, Carnegie-Mellon
University, 1980.
King, R. G., and S. T. Rebelo. "Resuscitating Real Business
Cycles, " in Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, edited by J. B.
Taylor and M. Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V., 1999.
Plosser, C. I. "Understanding Real Business Cycles."
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 1989, 51-78.
Rogerson, R., and R. Wright. "Involuntary Unemployment in
Economics with Efficient Risk Sharing." Journal of Monetary
Economies, 22, 1988, 501-15.
Rotemberg J. J., and L. H. Summers. "Inflexible Prices and
Procyclical Productivity." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105,
1990, 851-74.
Rotemberg, J. J. and M. Woodford. "An Optimizing-Based
Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy," in
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, edited by B. S. Bernanke and J. J.
Rotemberg, Massachusetts, MA: MIT Press, 297-346.
Sims, C. A. "Solving Rational Expectations Models."
Unpublished paper, Princeton University, 2000.
Sims, C. A., and T. Zha. "Were there Regime Switches in US
Monetary Policy." American Economic Review, 96, 2006, 54-81.
Steinsson, J. "Optimal Monetary Policy in an Economy with
Inflation Persistence." Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 2003,
1425-56.
Taylor, J. B. "Discretion Versus Policy Rules in
Practice." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
39, 1993, 195-214.
--. "A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules."
edited by Monetary Policy Rules, edited by J. B. Taylor. Chicago and
London: The University of Chicago Press, 1999, 319-47.
Woodford, M. Interest and Prices. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 2003.
(1.) I have not been explicit about the microfoundations of this
cost-push shock. It has been microfounded in various ways in the
literature. For example, it can arise due to a time-varying tax rate on
firm sales, or time variation in the elasticity of substitution, 0, as
shown by Steinsson (2003).
(2.) See Steinsson (2003) and Gali and Gertler (1999).
(3.) In practice, King and Rebelo (1999) target a linear
combination of the output and capital series. This procedure yields
almost identical results to the simpler procedure described above.
(4.) There is a slight mechanical difference between my estimation
approach and the one used by King and Rebelo (1999). To be consistent
with the filtering procedure used for the other variables, I use the
Hodrick-Prescott (HP)filtered output series to estimate the stochastic
process for the Taylor rule errors. King and Rebelo (1999) use linearly
detrended data to estimate the autoregressive parameter in the
productivity process rather than the HP-filtered data that are used in
the remainder of their paper.
(5.) See Sims (2000) for a description of the Gensys program that I
use to solve the model.
(6.) See Taylor (1999) for a discussion of the shift in monetary
policy since the 1980s. Note, however, that there is some debate on
whether, aside from the Volcker deflation, the changes in monetary
policy were small relative to changes in the shock process. See, for
example, Sims and Zha (2006).
(7.) RBC models generally attribute long-term growth to trend
growth in productivity. This assumption could also be made in the MBC
model.
(8.) The MBC2 model has some difficulty in capturing low-frequency
movements in the nominal interest rate. One reason may be the HP
filtering of the real variables: nominal interest rates fell over almost
the entire period 1980-2000. According to the MBC2 model, low frequency
variations in the nominal interest rate lead to low frequency variations
in output. However, in the simulations, low frequency variations in the
output series are removed by the HP filter.
(9.) The standard deviations presented here are calculated directly
from the unconditional second moments of the model.
(10.) As the productivity shocks become less permanent, the
incentives for intertemporal substitution rise. Therefore, a smaller
change in the real wage is required to produce a given change in labor
supply.
(11.) Hall (1988) shows that, with imperfect competition, movements
in aggregate demand lead to changes in the Solow Residual. Rotemberg and
Summers (1990) and Bernanke and Parkinson (1991) follow up on
Hall's original contribution.
(12.) Evans (1992) shows that the Solow residual is Granger caused
by the nominal interest rate and the money supply.
(13.) See Hodrick and Prescott (1980) for the details of the HP
filter.
(14.) The GDP deflator is appropriate, since, in the model, I make
the simplifying assumption that the prices of durable and consumption
goods are the same.
(15.) This is the value for [theta] estimated in Rotemberg and
Woodford (1997), although the assumptions in this paper are different
from the ones we make here, so the parameter estimate should only be
taken as a rough guide. A standard value in the literature is [theta] =
10. For example, see Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2002).
(16.) To be consistent in interpretation, [C.sub.t], [L.sub.t],
[B.sub.t], and [k.sub.t] (as used in Section I) must be expected values
over employment states and likewise for the household's budget
constraint.
EMI NAKAMURA, I would like to thank Michael Woodford for numerous
and inspiring conversations. I would also like to thank Robert Barro, W.
Erwin Diewert, Gauti B. Eggertsson, Dale Jorgenson, Robert King, David
Laibson, Gregory Mankiw, Alan Manning, Alice Nakamura, Jim Nason, Julio
Rotemberg, Jon Steinsson, James Stock, the editor Dennis Jansen, and two
anonymous referees for valuable comments.
Nakamura: Columbia Business School and Department of Economics,
3022 Broadway, New York, NY 10027. Phone 212-854-8162, Fax 212-662-8474,
E-mail enakamura@columbia.edu
TABLE 1
Sample Correlations Between Simulated and Empirical Series
MBC1 MBC2 MBC3 MBC4 MBCS
RBC1 RBC2 Calvo Hybrid Calvo Calvo Calvo
Panel A: 1980-2000
Consumption 0.81 0.80 0.80 0.81 0.80 0.81 0.81
Investment 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82
Labor 0.89 0.89 0.88 0.88 0.89 0.89 0.88
Real wage 0.10 0.06 -0.08 -0.02 0.06 0.20 0.03
Inflation 0.21 0.90 0.27 0.26 0.30
Nominal interest rate 0.27 0.73 0.01 -0.01 0.07
Output 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Solow residual 0.62 0.65 0.63 0.64 0.65 0.60 0.62
Panel B: l947-2000
Consumption 0.76 0.75 0.76 0.76 0.75 0.75 0.76
Investment 0.76 0.76 0.76 0.76 0.76 0.76 0.76
Labor 0.88 0.87 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.85 0.86
Real wage 0.07 0.00 0.08 0.08 0.06 -0.01 0.07
Inflation 0.16 0.14 -0.11 -0.13 -0.11
Nominal interest rate -0.01 -0.08 -0.11 -0.01 -0.12
Output 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Solow residual 0.64 0.15 0.68 0.71 0.51 0.06 0.60
Notes: RBC1: Real Business Cycle model with remeasured Productivity
Shocks; RBC2: Real Business Cycle Model with remeasured Preference
Shocks; MBC1: Monetary Business Cycle model with remeasured Monetary
Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve; MBC2: Monetary Business Cycle model with
remeasured Monetary Shocks, Hybrid Philips Curve; MBC3: Monetary
Business Cycle model with remeasured Cost Push Shocks, Calvo Philips
Curve; MBC4: Monetary Business Cycle model with remeasured Preference
Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve; MBCS: Monetary Business Cycle model with
remeasured Productivity Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve. In all cases,
the shocks are "remeasured" so that the theoretical output series
perfectly matches its empirical counterpart.
TABLE 2
Correlations with Output-Empirical Statistics versus Theoretical
Predictions
1947g1- 1980g1- MBC1
Model 2000g3 2000g3 RBC1 RBC2 Calvo
Consumption 0.07 0.81 1.00 1.00 1.00
Investment 0.75 0.81 1.00 1.00 1.00
Labor 0.89 0.89 1.00 1.00 1.00
Real wage 0.08 -0.18 0.10 -0.80 0.24
Inflation 0.12 -0.15 0.57
Nominal interest rate 0.13 0.01 0.58
Output 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Solow residual 0.64 0.57 0.97 0.80 0.78
MBC2 MBC3 MBC4 MBCS
Model Hybrid Calvo Calvo Calvo
Consumption 1.00 0.99 1.00 1.00
Investment 1.00 0.99 1.00 1.00
Labor 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.98
Real wage 0.17 0.27 -0.99 0.10
Inflation 0.22 -1.00 -1.00 -0.99
Nominal interest rate 0.33 -0.99 -0.99 -0.98
Output 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Solow residual 0.91 0.68 0.67 0.93
Notes: RBC1: Real Business Cycle model with remeasured Productivity
Shocks; RBC2: Real Business Cycle Model with remeasured Preference
Shocks; MBC1: Monetary Business Cycle model with remeasured Monetary
Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve; MBC2: Monetary Business Cycle model with
remeasured Monetary Shocks, Hybrid Philips Curve; MBC3: Monetary
Business Cycle model with remeasured Cost Push Shocks, Calvo Philips
Curve; MBC4: Monetary Business Cycle model with remeasured Preference
Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve; MBCS: Monetary Business Cycle model with
remeasured Productivity Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve. In all cases, the
shocks are "remeasured" so that the theoretical output series
perfectly matches its empirical counterpart.
TABLE 3
Relative Standard Deviations of Macroeconomic Series--Empirical
Statistics versus Theoretical Predictions
1947g1- 1980g1- MBC1
Model 2000g3 2000g3 RBC1 RBC2 Calvo
Consumption 0.76 0.80 0.56 0.52 0.61
Investment 4.13 4.32 2.74 2.91 3.74
Labor 1.07 1.12 1.00 1.09 1.02
Real wage 0.41 0.63 0.04 0.11 0.07
Inflation 1.40 1.48 0.80
Nominal interest rate 2.04 2.49 0.75
Output 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Solow residual 0.51 0.48 0.36 0.73 0.30
MBC2 MBC3 MBC4 MBCS
Model Hybrid Calvo Calvo Calvo
Consumption 0.60 0.55 0.39 0.52
Investment 3.80 4.23 5.26 4.33
Labor 1.02 1.02 1.07 0.90
Real wage 0.03 0.09 0.15 0.10
Inflation 0.96 0.76 0.80 0.75
Nominal interest rate 0.95 0.66 0.70 0.64
Output 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Solow residual 0.26 0.50 0.77 0.43
Notes: RBC1: Real Business Cycle model with remeasured Productivity
Shocks; RBC2: Real Business Cycle Model with remeasured Preference
Shocks; MBC1: Monetary Business Cycle model with remeasured Monetary
Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve; MBC2: Monetary Business Cycle model with
remeasured Monetary Shocks, Hybrid Philips Curve; MBC3: Monetary
Business Cycle model with remeasured Cost Push Shocks, Calvo Philips
Curve; MBC4: Monetary Business Cycle model with remeasured Preference
Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve; MBCS: Monetary Business Cycle model with
remeasured Productivity Shocks, Calvo Philips Curve. In all cases, the
shocks are "remeasured" so that the theoretical output series
perfectly matches its empirical counterpart.
TABLE 4
Descriptive Statistics for the Remeasured
Shocks
MBC1 MBC2
Model RBC1 Calvo Hybrid
Standard deviation 0.03 0.76 0.37
Mean 0.01 0.09 0.04
Notes: RBCI: Real Business Cycle model with remeas
ured Productivity Shocks; MBCI: Monetary Business
Cycle model with remeasured Monetary Shocks, Calvo
Philips Curve; MBC2: Monetary Business Cycle model
with remeasured Monetary Shocks, Hybrid Philips Curve.
The descriptive statistics for the productivity shocks are
multiplied by 100. The descriptive statistics for monetary
shocks are given in units of annualized percentage points.