Foreign direct investment and economic growth: the growth accounting perspective.
Wang, Miao ; Wong, M.C. Sunny
I. INTRODUCTION
During the past few decades, world foreign direct investment (FDI)
flows have increased dramatically, with an annual average growth rate of
over 20% in the 1980s and nearly 40% by the late 1990s (UNCTAD 2006).
Such a significant expansion of foreign capital flows has captured the
attention of both policy makers and researchers. Growth theories predict
that physical capital accumulation and technology improvement lead to
better economic growth performance (e.g., Aghion and Howitt 1992; Romer 1990; Solow 1956). This provides a promising prediction about the growth
effect of FDI in the host country, since FDI is considered to transfer
both physical capital and intangible assets such as better technology.
As a result, policy makers and governments of many host countries have
attempted to attract more inward FDI by giving special incentives, such
as tax breaks, to multinational corporations (MNCs). According to the
UNCTAD (2000), between 1991 and 1999, 974 FDI regulatory changes have
been made in over 100 countries to attract inward FDI.
However, the existence of an absolute growth effect of FDI is often
debated in the empirical literature (Carkovic and Levine 2005; Choe
2003). Recent researchers turn their attention toward whether FDI
promotes economic growth given certain social and/or economic
conditions. Two influential studies, Borensztein, De Gregorio and Lee
(1998) (hereafter, BDL [1998]) and Alfaro, Chanda, Kalemli-Ozcan and
Sayek (2004) (hereafter, ACKS [2004]), capture the positive effect of
FDI on economic growth under two conditions: a sufficient level of human
capital and a well-developed financial system, respectively. Based on
data from 69 countries over the period of 1970-1989, BDL (1998) find
that inward FDI promotes the host country's economic growth only
when the host country obtains a threshold level of human capital,
measured by average years of secondary schooling. ACKS (2004) argue that
FDI alone does not necessarily contribute to economic growth in the host
country. However, according to a sample of 71 countries between 1975 and
1995, the host country with a well-functioning financial system benefits
significantly from inward FDI.
While these important previous studies have determined the
conditions under which FDI will affect overall growth, there has not
been investigation into which components of growth (i.e., productivity
growth and capital stock growth) are affected by FDI. (1) Such evidence
is important for understanding the mechanisms by which FDI affects
growth and can better inform policy.
In this paper, we seek to shed light on the empirical literature of
FDI growth in the perspective of growth accounting. (2) Based on the
conjectures from BDL (1998) and ACKS (2004), which will be explained
later, we study the effect of FDI on different growth components and how
human capital and financial development affect the interaction between
FDI and components of growth. To our knowledge, although some
conjectures have been made in the FDI literature, there is no systematic
research on this issue. We also provide a possible connection between
the results in BDL (1998) and the results in ACKS (2004). Their
conditions can be fundamentally different catalysts for FDI to promote
economic growth. (3)
On the one hand, empirical results from BDL (1998) suggest the
existence of complementarity between human capital and FDI on economic
growth. The authors also find that FDI does not significantly simulate domestic investment. Hence, they conclude (page 118) that "... the
main channel through which FDI contributes to economic growth is by
stimulating technological progress, rather than by increasing total
capital accumulation in the host economy." They conjecture that FDI
drives technological progress only when there is a sufficient level of
human capital in the host country. The idea is later echoed by Xu
(2000), who tests the impact of FDI on technology transfer and finds
that U.S. MNCs contribute to total factor productivity (TFP) growth in
the host country when the country reaches a minimum human capital
threshold.
On the other hand, well-developed financial markets are crucial to
facilitating investments, by creating economies of scale for investors
and allocating capital to its most productive use. ACKS (2004) find that
well-developed financial markets can significantly enhance the growth
effect of FDI. They attribute the finding to two possible channels. They
argue that better development of financial markets can lead to higher
technological spillover effects of FDI. They also conjecture that
well-developed financial markets can efficiently create
backward-linkages between foreign firms and domestic firms in upstream industries in the host country. As a result, the existence of foreign
firms will increase the domestic investment in upstream industries. (4)
ACKS (2004) state that "[e]ven though backward linkages may allow
existing [domestic] firms, which already produce inputs in the industry,
to achieve economies of scale that may not have existed earlier, it also
can encourage the creation of new firms." (p. 92) This indicates
that FDI can stimulate capital accumulation under a well-functioning
financial system.
In the following paper, we empirically test two hypotheses: (1) the
positive growth effect of FDI given an adequate level of human capital
actually reflects the positive effect of FDI on productivity or TFP
growth given a certain level of human capital; and (2) the positive
growth effect of FDI given a well-developed financial system represents
the result of positive effect of FDI on capital accumulation, given the
adequate level of financial development.
Using data from BDL (1998), we find that inward FDI promotes TFP
growth only when the host country achieves a threshold of human capital
between 0.69 and 1.08 yr of secondary schooling. FDI promotes capital
growth only when the host country reaches a level of financial depth at
0.308, measured by liquidity liabilities of financial intermediaries as
a share of gross domestic product (GDP). In addition, we also observe a
quadratic effect of financial depth--the maximum effect of FDI on
capital growth occurs when financial depth in the host country is 0.684.
The paper is organized as follows: in Section II we present data
and variables; econometric results are presented and analyzed in Section
III; and we conclude the paper in Section IV.
II. DATA AND VARIABLES
Data on all control variables in our study come from BDL (1998). We
use this data set so that our results are comparable to previous
studies. Our sample includes 69 countries; all variables are averaged
over two decades: 1970-1979 and 1980-1989; Our methodology is similar to
BDL (1998), employing the seemingly unrelated regression (SUR)
technique. (5) A list of country names can be found in the Appendix. We
estimate the following model, which will be explained later. Table 1
presents descriptive statistics for the variables used in the empirical
analysis.
TFP [growth.sub.it] = [[beta].sub.0t] + [[beta].sub.FDI]
[FDI.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.FDI x H] [FDI X School).sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.H] [School.sub.it] +[[beta]'.sub.z][Z.sub.it] +
[[epsilon].sub.it] (1)
Capital [growth.sub.it] = [[??].sub.0,t] + [[??].sub.FDI]
[FDI.sub.it] [[??].sub.FDI] x FinDepth x [(FDI X FinDepth).sub.it] +
[[??].sub.FDI] x [FinDepth.sup.2] x [(FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]).sub.it] +
[[??]'.sub.z][Z.sub.it] + [V.sub.it]. (2)
The dependent variables, per capita TFP growth (TFP growth) and per
capita real capital growth (Capital growth) are calculated according to
the technique commonly used in the growth accounting literature. Per
capita real capital growth is calculated based on data from PennWorld
table 5.6 and the growth rate is averaged over the periods of 1970-1979
and 1980-1989. The TFP growth is calculated based on a Cobb-Douglas
production function: TFP growth = per capita real GDP growth - [alpha] x
Capital growth, where [alpha] represents the share of capital in the
production function. Gollin (2002) estimates labor share (l-[alpha]
across countries and finds that the labor share ranges between 0.47 and
0.72. Using the basic estimate of the labor share in Gollin (2002), we
calculate the TFP growth rate. (6) We include the interaction between
FDI and human capital (FDI x School), and the interaction between FDI
and financial depth (FDI x FinDepth). These interaction terms help to
catch any complementarity between FDI and these variables. To account
for possible quadratic effect of financial depth (Rioja and Valev 2004),
we also include the interaction between FDI and the square term of
financial depth (FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]). In addition, the set of other
control variables Z includes the following, with expected signs
consistent with the previous literature in parentheses: human capital
(+), financial depth (+), log value of initial GDP (-), government size
(-), black market premium (-), and inflation rate (-).
FDI (FDI) in the study is measured as FDI inflows divided by host
country's GDP; human capital (School) is measured as the average
years of secondary schooling in the male population over the age of 25;
financial depth (FinDepth) is measured as currency plus demand deposits
and other interest-bearing liabilities of banks and nonbank
intermediaries as a share of GDP. It is generally equal to M2/GDP and is
a measure of the overall liquidity in the financial sector. King and
Levine (1993) show that this measure of financial development is closely
related to long-run economic growth. The log value of initial GDP
ln/[GDP]) is the log value of real GDP in 1970 and 1980; government size
(Govt Expenditure) is measured as the government expenditure as a share
of host country's GDP; black market premium on foreign exchange
(Black Market Premium) is the relative difference between parallel
exchange market and official exchange market; and inflation rate
(inflation) is a measure of percentage change in the GDP deflator. (7)
Our key variables of interest are the interaction variables. For
example, a positive coefficient on FDI x School in TFP growth regression ([[beta].sub.FDO] x H > 0) indicates the complementarity between FDI
and human capital. In other words, FDI will contribute to productivity
growth when the host country reaches a certain level of human capital.
III. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
A. SUR Results
Table 2 reports SUR regression results. (8) First, we concentrate
on the results from TFP growth regressions. Human capital (School) in
the TFP regressions has a positive coefficient, though not statistically
significant in SUR7 and SUR8. Interestingly, the human capital measure
becomes less significant with the inclusion of the financial depth
variable. The coefficient on the stand-alone financial depth variable is
positive and significant in TFP regressions in SUR3-8 (.017-.025). Such
a positive effect of financial depth on TFP growth is consistent with
the results from Beck, Levine and Loayza (2000) as they find that
financial development contributes to both productivity growth and
physical capital growth.
The coefficient on FDI in the TFP regressions is negative, and
significant in SUR2-8. The interaction variable FDI x School has a
positive and significant coefficient in all regressions. The results
present a strong complementarity between FDI and human capital in terms
of promoting productivity growth. In other words, inward FDI alone does
not promote host country's productivity growth; FDI will have a
positive effect on productivity only when a threshold level of human
capital is reached. TFP regressions in SUR5-8 suggest that this
threshold is 0.69-1.08 yr of secondary education. This threshold
schooling is within the range of 0.52-1.13 yr estimated in BDL (1998).
For example, based on SUR7 specification, the effect of FDI on TFP
growth is [[beta].sub.FDI] + [[beta].sub.FDI x school] X School. As a
result, the threshold level of schooling for FDI to have a positive
effect on TFP growth is 1.781/ 2.424 = 0.73 yr. Intuitively, the host
country needs to have the ability to understand the technology embodied in inward FDI so that it can benefit from the technology. Among our
sample of 69 countries, 38 countries reached 0.73 yr of secondary
schooling over the whole sample period or over the period of 1980-1989.
Furthermore, it appears that the level of financial depth does not
positively interact with FDI in TFP regressions in a robust manner.
Although interaction between FDI and financial depth measures have
significant coefficients in SUR3, they become insignificant in SUR8 when
schooling interaction is included. The above results confirm our
hypothesis that the major factor linking FDI and productivity growth in
the host country is the human capital level, which also confirms the
conjecture by BDL (1998).
We also observe certain common results from capital growth
regressions. The coefficient on stand-alone financial depth is positive
in all regressions, which is again consistent with the results from
Beck, Levine and Loayza (2000). The magnitude of the significant
coefficient on financial depth ranges between .009 and .012. However,
the coefficient on schooling is not statistically significant at
conventional levels in capital growth regressions. Furthermore, SUR8
results indicate that there is no complementarity between FDI and
schooling in terms of affecting capital growth. It appears that
financial development is more crucial than human capital in terms of
promoting physical capital growth; and human capital level in the host
country does not seem to affect how inward FDI impacts capital growth.
Similar to the results in ACKS (2004), the coefficient on FDI is not
statistically significant. While the coefficient on the interaction
between FDI and financial depth alone in SUR2 and SUR4 is positive but
not statistically significant, we find that the coefficient on FDI x
FinDepth significantly positive and coefficient on FDI x
[FinDepth.sup.2] significantly negative in SUR3 and SUR5-8. The results
confirm our hypothesis that the host country needs to reach a certain
level of financial development for FDI to have a positive effect on
capital growth. Furthermore, the complementarity between financial depth
and FDI is quadratic. As financial depth increases, the effect of FDI on
capital growth increases; but it increases at a decreasing rate. For
example, according to SUR7 specification, the effect of FDI on capital
growth is calculated as [[beta].sub.FDI + [[beta].sub.FDI] x FinDepth x
FinDepth + [[beta].sub.FDI] x [FinDepth.sup.2] x [FinDepth.sup.2]. The
coefficient on FDI is -1.005; the coefficient on FDI x FinDepth is 4.206
and the coefficient on FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] is -3.074. So, the effect
of FDI on capital growth is -1.005+4.206 x FinDepth - 3.074 x
[FinDepth.sup.2]. FDI will positively affect capital growth only when
financial depth reaches the value of 0.308 in the host country and the
maximum positive effect of FDI occurs when financial depth is 0.684. In
other words, a country can benefit from inward FDI when the total liquid
liabilities of the financial system is above 30.8% of GDP. (9) We also
calculate the threshold level in ACKS (2004) based on their estimated
coefficients and find that the threshold level of financial depth in
their study is approximately 0.6. (10) Interestingly, our study suggests
that FDI can start to have a positive effect on capital stock growth at
a lower level of financial development. In our sample of 69 countries,
36 countries have obtained a financial depth threshold level of 0.308
over the whole sample period or over the second decade.
B. Control for Endogeneity
Potentially, cross-country study of FDI-growth can suffer from an
endogeneity problem. In other words, it can be true that better capital
growth rate or TFP growth rate also influences inward FDI in the host
country. To control for the potential endogeneity problem, we adopt
instrumental variables (IV) estimation. Ideally, instruments should be
highly correlated with FDI, but not with the error term. In reality,
perfect instruments are hard to obtain. Our instruments include log
value of land area of the host country, regional dummies for East Asia and South Asia, political institution variables, and other explanatory variables in the regressions. (11) As in BDL (1998), we apply
three-stage least square (3SLS) estimation to control for endogeneity.
Results are reported in Table 3. The IV estimation results are not
qualitatively different from the results from original SUR regressions.
FDI itself does not necessarily promote either productivity growth or
capital growth. The interaction between FDI and human capital has a
positive and significant coefficient in TFP growth regression. Again,
the coefficient on FDI x FinDepth is significantly positive, and the
coefficient on FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] is significantly negative in the
capital growth regression.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
Many countries', especially developing countries',
governments give MNCs favorable treatment such as a tax break. The
purpose is to encourage more inward FDI. As mentioned above, the
empirical results indicate that more attention is needed for the
research on FDI and growth. We should clearly understand exactly how FDI
affects physical capital growth and TFP growth. While there are a number
of studies that look at the final effect of FDI on economic growth and
many argue that FDI promotes economic growth given certain conditions in
the host country, few papers compare the channels through which FDI
impacts economic growth. Studying these channels--through physical
capital growth and TFP growth can provide better policy guidance to
policy makers. For example, if a host country needs to achieve a certain
level of education for FDI inflows to have a positive effect on TFP, the
government's first priority should be allocating more resources to
education instead of a monetary incentive to MNCs.
Based on data from 69 countries over two decades, we find that FDI
promotes capital growth when a certain level of financial depth is
reached, and FDI contributes to productivity growth when a certain level
of human capital is reached in the host country. Interestingly, the
interaction between FDI and human capital is not significant in capital
growth regressions; and the interactions between FDI and financial depth
measures are not significant in TFP growth regressions. The results
suggest that human capital is the major factor linking FDI and
productivity growth and financial depth is the major factor linking FDI
and capital growth.
ABBREVIATIONS
3SLS: Three-Stage Least Square
FDI: Foreign Direct Investment
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
IV: Instrumental Variables
MNCs: Multinational Corporations
SUR: Seemingly Unrelated Regressions
TFP: Total Factor Productivity
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2008.00133.x
APPENDIX
List of Countries
Algeria
Benin
Botswana
Cameroon
Central African Republic
Congo, Rep.
Gambia, The
Ghana
Kenya
Lesotho
Malawi
Mali
Mauritius
Mozambique
Niger
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
Swaziland
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Congo, Dem. Rep. (Zaire)
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Barbados
Costa Rica
Dominican Republic
El Salvador
Guatemala
Haiti
Honduras
Jamaica
Mexico
Trinidad and Tobago
Argentina
Bolivia
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Ecuador
Guyana
Paraguay
Peru
Uruguay
Venezuela
Bangladesh
Myanmar
Hong Kong, China
India
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic Rep.
Israel
Jordan
Korea, Rep.
Malaysia
Pakistan
Philippines
Singapore
Sri Lanka
Syrian Arab Republic
Taiwan, China
Thailand
Yemen, Rep.
Cyprus
Greece
Malta
Turkey
Papua New Guinea
REFERENCES
Abramovitz, M. "Resource and Output Trends in the United
States since 1870." American Economic Review, 46, 1956, 5-23.
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. "A Model of Growth Through Creative
Destruction." Econometrica, 60, 1992, 323 51.
Alfaro, L., A. Chanda, S. Kalemli-Ozcan, and S. Sayek. "FDI
and Economic Growth: The Role of Local Financial Markets." Journal
of International Economics, 64(1), 2004, 89-112.
Barro, R. Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country
Empirical Study. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1997.
Barro, R., and J.-W. Lee. "International Comparisons of
Educational Attainment." Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 1993,
363-94.
Beck, T., R. Levine, and N. Loayza. "Finance and the Sources
of Growth." Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 2000, 261-300.
Borensztein, E., J. De Gregorio, and J.-W. Lee. "How does
Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?" Journal of
International Economics, 45(1), 1998, 115-35.
Carkovic, M., and R. Levine. "Does Foreign Direct Investment
Accelerate Economic Growth?" in Does Foreign Direct Investment
Promote Development?, edited by T. Moran, E. Graham, and M. Blomstrom.
Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2005, 195-220.
Choe, J.-I. "Do Foreign Direct Investment and Gross Domestic
Investment Promote Economic Growth?" Review of Development
Economics, 7, 2003, 44-57.
Denison, E. F. Trends in American Economic Growth. 1929-1982.
Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1985.
Frankel J. A., and D. Romer. "Does Trade Cause Growth?"
American Economic Review, 89, 1999, 379-99.
Ghani, E., and V. Suri. "Productivity Growth, Capital
Accumulation, and the Banking Sector." Working Paper, World Bank,
2000.
Gollin, D. "Getting Income Shares Right." Journal of
Political Economy, 110, 2002, 458-74.
Jorgenson, D. W. "Productivity and Postwar U.S. Economic
Growth." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(4), 1988, 23-41.
Jorgenson, D. W., and K. J. Stiroh. "Raising the Speed Limit:
U.S. Economic Growth in the Information Age." Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 1, 2000, 125-211.
King, R. G., and R. Levine "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter
might be right." Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 1993, 717-38.
Markusen, J. R., and A. J. Venables "Foreign Direct Investment
as a Catalyst for Industrial Development." European Economic
Review, 43, 1999, 335-56.
Neuhaus, M. The Impact of FDI on Economic Growth: An Analysis for
the Transition Countries of Central and Eastern Europe. Heidelberg:
Springer, 2006.
Oliner, S. D., and D. E. Sichel. "The Resurgence of Growth in
the Late 1990s: Is Information Technology the Story?" Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 14(4), 2000, 3-22.
Page, J. M. "The East Asian Miracle: An Introduction."
Worm Development, 22, 1994, 615-25.
Rioja, F., and N. Valev. "Does One Size Fit All?: A
Reexamination of the Finance and Growth Relationship." Journal of
Development Eeonomics, 74, 2004, 429-47.
Romer, P. "Endogenous Technological Change." Journal of
Political Economy, 98, 1990, 71-102. Solow, R. M. "A Contribution
to the Theory of Economic Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
70, 1956, 65-94.
--. "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production
Function." Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, 1957, 312-20.
United Nations. World Investment Report 2000. UNCTAD, United
Nations, New York, 2000.
World Investment Report 2006. UNCTAD, United Nations, New York,
2006.
Xu, B. "Multinational Enterprises, Technology Diffusion, and
Host Country Productivity Growth." Journal of Development
Economics, 62, 2000, 477-93.
Young, A. "The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical
Reality of the East Asian Growth Experience." Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 110, 1995, 641-80.
(1.) We will use the terms "capital stock growth,"
"capital accumulation," and "physical capital
growth" interchangeably in this paper.
(2.) Pioneered by Abramovitz (1956) and Solow (1957), the
components of growth, namely capital accumulation and productivity
growth, have been widely studied in the growth accounting literature.
For example, Young (1995) argues that the rapid growth in East Asian
countries (Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan) is mainly due
to better utilization of labor and capital, not productivity growth
(Page 1994). See also Denison (1985), Jorgenson (1988), Jorgenson and
Stiroh (2000) and Oliner and Sichel (2000) for further discussion.
(3.) Some recent studies also turn their attention to the impacts
of FDI in the perspective of growth accounting. These studies discuss
the effects of FDI on capital accumulation and technological growth and
in turn the effect of FDI on economic growth. For example, Neuhaus
(2006) shows theoretically FDI not only raises the level of physical
capital (capital accumulation or capital widening), but also improves
the quality of physical capital (technological change or capital
deepening). On the other hand, Ghani and Suri (2000) examine the impacts
of FDI and bank-lending on economic growth in Malaysia. The authors
conclude that capital accumulation is the key driver of economic growth
in Malaysia. Bank-lending is positively associated with capital
accumulation, but not with TFP growth, while FDI is positively
associated with TFP growth. Our paper builds upon previous important
studies in the aspect that we discuss the channels through which FDI
affects physical capital growth and TFP growth. In other words, we
estimate empirically economic conditions necessary for FDI to positively
affect physical capital growth and TFP growth.
(4.) See Markusen and Venables (1999) for detailed theoretical
argument on backward linkages with the existence of foreign firms.
(5.) This SUR technique allows unobserved factors to affect TFP
growth and capital growth at the same time. It is commonly used in the
literature of economic growth (See also Barro and Lee 1993 and Barro
1997). Similar to BDL (1998), we estimate the regressions of TFP growth
and capital growth simultaneously and constrain the coefficients in each
regression to be equal across the two decades except the constant. We
also run a pure cross-sectional regression by averaging variables across
two periods. The cross-sectional regression provides qualitatively
similar results to the SUR regression. Results from the cross-sectional
regression are not provided, but available upon request.
6. Assume a Cobb-Douglas production function of Y = [AK.sup.[alpha]
[L.sup.1-[alpha]], where A represents total factor productivity level; K
and L represent capital and labor, respectively; [alpha] represents the
share of capital input used in the production. We use the basic measure
of labor share in table 2 of Gollin (2002, p. 470) for the estimation of
capital growth and TFP growth. Furthermore, we employ the alternative
adjustments of labor share in Gollin (2002) to estimate capital growth
and TFP growth. The results do not change substantially, which can be
obtained upon request.
(7.) See BDL (1998) for the detailed discussion on the measurement
of all variables and data.
(8.) Regional dummy and institutional factors included in the
regressions are also from BDL (1998). The institutional factors include
number of wars during the sample period, political rights, and number of
assassinations.
(9.) According to the quadratic expression, we find that the
expression equals 0 when FinDepth are 0.308 and 1.05. Recall that the
level of financial depth is defined as M2/ GDP, which should not exceed
one theoretically. It implies that the growth effect of FDI is always
positive when FinDepth is greater than 0.308. In our sample of 69
countries, Malta is the only country whose values of FinDepth are
greater than 1.
(10.) ACKS (2004) do not explicitly calculate the threshold level
of financial depth. Our calculation is based on their results of
regression (3) in table 4 (p. 100).
(11.) To make our results more comparable to previous influential
studies, we adopt the same instrumental variables used in BDL (1998).
The land area of host countries is obtained from Frankel and Romer
(1999).
MIAO WANG and M. C, SUNNY WONG *
* We would like to thank Bruce Blonigen, Brian Brush, David Clark,
Joseph Daniels, Jim Granato, two anonymous referees, and the
participants at the Midwest Economics Association Meeting 2007 for their
helpful comments and suggestions. This research is supported by the
Miles Research Grant from the College of Business Administration,
Marquette University, and the Marquette University Regular Research
Grant. All errors and omissions are our own.
Wang. Assistant Professor, Marquette University, Department of
Economics, 606 N. 13th Street, Milwaukee, WI 53233. Phone
1-414-288-7310, Fax 1-414-288-5757, E-mail grace.wang@mu.edu.
Wong: Assistant Professor, University of San Francisco, Department
of Economics, 2130 Fulton Street, San Francisco, CA 94117. Phone
1-415-422-6194, Fax 1-415-422-6983, E-mail mwong11@usfca.edu
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics
Capital-Growth TFP-Growth FDI
70-79 80-89 70-79 80-89 70-79 80-89
Mean 0.015 0.005 0.018 0.000 0.003 0.002
Max 0.049 0.035 0.064 0.065 0.026 0.039
Min -0.016 -0.022 -0.051 -0.052 -0.002 -0.004
Standard
deviation 0.013 0.012 0.026 0.026 0.004 0.005
Initial-Income School Government-Size
70-79 80-89 70-79 80-89 70-79 80-89
Mean 7.335 7.596 0.647 0.905 0.174 0.183
Max 8.937 9.327 3.680 2.920 0.365 0.344
Min 5.958 6.107 0.010 0.060 0.060 0.057
Standard
deviation 0.728 0.811 0.644 0.671 0.077 0.069
Financial-Depth Inflation Black MarkPremium
70-79 80-59 70-79 80-89 70-79 80-89
Mean 0.319 0.394 0.155 0.237 0.253 0.340
Max 1.586 1.327 0.834 1.682 1.673 2.709
Min 0.104 0.124 0.057 0.021 -0.004 -0.006
Standard
deviation 0.220 0.256 0.141 0.339 0.367 0.481
TABLE 2
Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) Results
Panel A SUR1 School Interaction Term only
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.1497 (0.3164) -0.8424 (0.6261)
FDI x School 0.4604 * (0.2518) 1.5777 *** (0.5290)
School 0.0033 (0.0021) 0.01 *** (0.0040)
FDI x FinDepth
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]
FinDepth
Ln (GDP) -0.0022 (0.0018) -0.0061 * (0.0034)
No. of Obs 69 69
R-Squared .05 .18
.12 .16
SUR2 Financial Interaction
Panel A Linear Term only
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.0845 (0.4604) -1.3768 * (0.8277)
FDI x School
School
FDI x FinDepth 0.2272 (0.5737) 2.0595 * (1.1945)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]
FinDepth 0.0058 (0.0056) 0.0179 (0.0114)
Ln (GDP) -0.0007 (0.0016) -0.0026 (0.0029)
No. of Obs 66 66
R-Squared .02 .14
.07 .06
Panel A SUR3 Financial Interaction Terms
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -1.2112 * (0.7030) -3.03 ** (1.2711)
FDI x School
School
FDI x FinDepth 4.677 ** (2.1845) 8.6435 ** (3.9468)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -3.27 ** (1.5391) -4.8089 * (2.6764)
FinDepth 0.0098 * (0.0058) 0.0259 ** (0.0120)
Ln (GDP) -0.0014 (0.0016) -0.0035 (0.0029)
No. of Obs 66 66
R-Squared .09 .17
.06 .06
SUR4 Financial Interaction and
Panel A School Interaction
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.09 (0.4595) -1.4084 ** (0.6708)
FDI x School 2.053 *** (0.7580)
School 0.0035 (0.0022) 0.0072 * (0.0039)
FDI x FinDepth 0.4435 (0.5746)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]
FinDepth 0.0033 (0.0056) 0.0198 ** (0.0097)
Ln (GDP) -0.0022 (0.0019) -0.0067 ** (0.0033)
No. of Obs 66 66
R-Squared .01 .21
.1 .13
SUR5 Financial Interactions and
Panel B School Interaction
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -1.1162 (0.6967) -1.5372 ** (0.6787)
FDI x School 2.2179 *** (0.7664)
School 0.0032 (0.0022) 0.0073 * (0.0039)
FDI x FinDepth 4.3951 ** (2.0957)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -2.8865 ** (1.4540)
FinDepth 0.0066 (0.0058) 0.0189 ** (0.0097)
Ln (GDP) -0.0025 (0.0019) -0.0068 ** (0.0033)
Govt Expenditure
Black Market Premium
Inflation
Regional and No No
institutional factors?
Threshold value (no. of 32.21% (33) 0.6930 yr (39)
countries reaching
threshold)
No. of observations 66 66
R-squared .08 .21
.09 .14
SUR6 Financial Interactions and
Panel B School Interaction (w/ Control Variables)
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.7653 (0.6027) -1.3409 ** (0.6587)
FDI x School 1.8975 ** (0.7619)
School 0.0019 (0.0019) 0.0069 * (0.0037)
FDI x FinDepth 3.7227 ** (1.8437)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -2.8012 ** (12862)
FinDepth 0.0106 * (0.0056) 0.0199 ** (0.0099)
Ln (GDP) -0.0045 *** (0.0017) -0.0082 *** (0.0033)
Govt Expenditure -0.0764 *** (0.0144) -0.0579 ** (0.0275)
Black Market Premium -0.0066 *** (0.0022) -0.0091 * (0.0049)
Inflation -0.006 * (0.0032) -0.0104 (0.0085)
Regional and Yes Yes
institutional factors?
Threshold value (no. of 25.42% (43) 0.7066 yr (39)
countries reaching
threshold)
No. of observations 66 66
R-squared .38 .34
.31 .11
SUR7 Regional Dummy and
Panel B Institutional Factors
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -1.0058 * (0.6013) -1.7818 *** (0.6462)
FDI x School 2.4249 *** (0.7452)
School 0.0007 (0.0019) 0.0036 (0.0037)
FDI x FinDepth 4.2064 ** (1.8446)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -3.0749 ** (1.2933)
FinDepth 0.0111 ** (0.0057) 0.0171 * (0.0098)
Ln (GDP) -0.0038 ** (0.0019) -0.0113 *** (0.0036)
Govt Expenditure -0.0684 *** (0.0151) -0.028 (0.0281)
Black Market Premium -0.006 *** (0.0022) -0.0053 (0.0047)
Inflation -0.0066 ** (0.0032) -0.0163 ** (0.0076)
Regional and Yes Yes
institutional factors?
Threshold value (no. of 30.88% (36) 0.7347 yr (38)
countries reaching
threshold)
No. of observations 66 66
R-squared .4 .41
.34 0.36
Panel B SUR8 All Regressors
Capital Stock
Variables Growth TFP Growth
FDI -1.0988 * (0.6091) -2.4814 ** (1.1966)
FDI x School 0.0165 (0.5525) 2.2923 ** (1.1443)
School 0.0007 (0.0020) 0.0031 (0.0036)
FDI x FinDepth 4.5678 ** (2.1987) 3.6513 (4.5614)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -3.352 ** (1.4131) -2.9419 (2.7239)
FinDepth 0.0116 ** (0.0057) 0.0257 ** (0.0118)
Ln (GDP) -0.0041 ** (0.0019) -0.0119 *** (0.0036)
Govt Expenditure -0.0695 *** (0.0154) -0.0323 (0.0279)
Black Market Premium -0.0058 *** (0.0022) -0.0057 (0.0047)
Inflation -0.0066 ** (0.0032) -0.0143 * (0.0078)
Regional and Yes Yes
institutional factors?
Threshold value (no. of 31.19% (35) 1.0824 yr (26)
countries reaching
threshold)
No. of observations 66 66
R-squared .40 .41
0.33 0.36
Note. Standard errors in the parentheses. *** significant at 1%;
** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%.
TABLE 3
Instrumental Variables Regression (3SLS) Results
SUR1 School Interaction
Panel A Term only
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.2594 (0.4780) -1.6108 * (0.9541)
FDI x School 0.5308 (0.3383) 2.0765 *** (0.7061)
School 0.0031 (0.0022) 0.0087 ** (0.0042)
FDI x FinDepth
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]
FinDepth
Ln (GDP) -0.0021 (0.0018) -0.0058 * (0.0034)
No. of Observations 69 69
R-Squared .05 .18
.12 .14
SUR2 Financial Interaction
Panel A Linear Term only
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.477 (0.6394) -1.5869 (1.1524)
FDI x School
School
FDI x FinDepth 0.6672 (0.7540) 2.3043 (1.5499)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]
FinDepth 0.0049 (0.0057) 0.0173 (0.0120)
Ln (GDP) -0.0007 (0.0016) -0.0026 (0.0029)
No. of Observations 66 66
R-Squared .01 .14
.08 .07
SUR3 Financial
Panel A Interaction Terms only
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -1.1198 (0.7558) -3.1361 ** (1.3556)
FDI x School
School
FDI x FinDepth 4.4284 ** (2.3164) 8.9255 ** (4.1599)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -3.1198 ** (1.6096) -4.9614 * (2.7843)
FinDepth 0.0097 * (0.0058) 0.0259 ** (0.0120)
Ln (GDP) -0.0013 (0.0016) -0.0036 (0.0029)
No. of Observations 66 66
R-Squared .09 .17
.06 .06
SUR4 Fin. Interaction and
Panel A School Interaction
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.5907 (0.6046) -1.6229 ** (0.8081)
FDI x School 2.2385 *** (0.8559)
School 0.0(134 (0.0022) 0.007 * (0.0039)
FDI x FinDepth 1.0075 (0.7185)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2]
FinDepth 0.0022 (0.0056) 0.0201 ** (0.0097)
Ln (GDP) -0.0022 (0.0019) -(1.0067 ** (0.0032)
No. of Observations 66 66
R-Squared -.01 .22
.11 .13
SUR5 Financial Interactions and
Panel B School Interaction
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -1.0519 (0.7390) -1.4716 ** (0.6896)
FDI x School 2.1586 *** (0.7740)
School 0.0032 (0.0022) 0.0073 * (0.0039)
FDI x FinDepth 4.2334 ** (2.1982)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -2.7942 * (1.5075)
FinDepth 0.0065 (0.0058) 0.0189 ** (0.0097)
Ln (GDP) -0.0025 (0.0019) -0.0068 ** (0.0033)
Govt Expenditure
Black Market
Premium
Inflation
Regional and No No
Institutional
Factors?
Threshold value 31.32% (35) 0.6817 yr (39)
no. of countries
reaching threshold)
No. of Observations 66 66
R-Squared .08 .21
.09 .14
SUR6 Financial Interactions and
School Interaction
Panel B (w/ Control Variables)
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.6811 (0.6399) -1.2799 ** (0.6690)
FDI x School 1.8389 *** (0.7694)
School 0.0019 (0.0019) 0.007 * (0.0037)
FDI x FinDepth 3.4967 * (1.9344)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -2.6673 ** (1.3334)
FinDepth 0.0105 * (0.0056) 0.02 ** (0.0099)
Ln (GDP) -0.0045 *** (0.0017) -0.0082 *** (0.0033)
Govt Expenditure -0.0766 *** (0.0145) -0.0585 ** (0.0275)
Black Market -0.0066 *** (0.0022) -0.0091 * (0.0049)
Premium
Inflation -0.006 * (0.0032) -0.0104 (0.0085)
Regional and Yes Yes
Institutional
Factors?
Threshold value 23.79% (46) 0.6960 yr (39)
no. of countries
reaching threshold)
No. of Observations 66 66
R-Squared .38 .34
.31 .11
SUR7 Regional Dummy and
Panel B Institutional Factors
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -0.9554 (0.6408) -1.731 *** (0.6574)
FDI x School 2.3757 *** (0.7539)
School 0.0007 (0.0019) 0.0037 (0.0037)
FDI x FinDepth 4.0716 ** (1.9414)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -2.995 ** (1.3443)
FinDepth 0.011 ** (0.0057) 0.0171 * (0.0098)
Ln (GDP) -0.0039 ** (0.0019) -0.0113 *** (0.0036)
Govt Expenditure -0.0686 *** (0.0151) -0.0286 (0.0281)
Black Market -0.006 *** (0.0022) -0.0053 (0.0047)
Premium
Inflation -0.0066 ** (0.0032) -0.0163 ** (0.0076)
Regional and Yes Yes
Institutional
Factors?
Threshold value 30.15% (36) 0.7286 yr (38)
no. of countries
reaching threshold)
No. of Observations 66 66
R-Squared .4 .41
.34 .36
Panel B SUR8 All Regressors
Capital
Variables Stock Growth TFP Growth
FDI -1.0605 * (0.6507) -2.4086 * (1.2755)
FDI x School 0.0204 (0.5532) 2.3065 ** (1.1511)
School 0.0007 (0.0020) 0.0031 (0_0036)
FDI x FinDepth 4.4566 ** (2.3008) 3.419 (4.7781)
FDI x [FinDepth.sup.2] -3.2853 ** (1.4697) -2.807 (2.8368)
FinDepth 0.0116 ** (0.0057) 0.0256 ** (0.0119)
Ln (GDP) -0.0041 ** ((1.0019) -0.0119 *** (0.0036)
Govt Expenditure -0.0696 *** (0.0154) -0.0325 (0.0279)
Black Market -0.0058 *** (0.0022) -0.0057 (0.0047)
Premium
Inflation -0.0066 ** (0.0032) -0.0143 * (0.0078)
Regional and Yes Yes
Institutional
Factors?
Threshold value 30.78% (36) 1.0442 yr (27)
no. of countries
reaching threshold)
No. of Observations 66 66
R-Squared .4 .41
.33 .36
Note: Standard errors in the parentheses. *** significant at 1%;
** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%.