Risk beliefs and smoking behavior.
Viscusi, W. Kip ; Hakes, Jahn K.
I. INTRODUCTION
More people die from smoking each year than from any other
consumption activity. These risks arise from consumer choices in a
market context. As a result, whether consumers are cognizant of the
attendant hazards is a central concern in assessing whether there is a
market failure and the extent of such a failure. Influencing
people's risk beliefs has been a primary focus of many government
interventions in this market, including warnings requirements and public
information campaigns.
Public opinion poll data provide some insight into general trends
in smoking risk beliefs but do little to resolve the more fundamental
concern of whether people underestimate the risks posed by cigarettes.
Typical questions ask respondents if cigarette smoking is "one of
the causes of lung cancer" or whether smoking is
"harmful." (1) These general measures of risk awareness
provide a useful historical perspective on smoking risk beliefs but do
not make it possible to determine whether the public perceives the risk
accurately. Recognizing that smoking is harmful does not imply that the
perceived risk level is as great as the actual risk.
The first exploration of the adequacy of risk beliefs was in
Viscusi (1990, 1992), which examined the adequacy of lung cancer risk
beliefs using a quantitative risk question. (2) The 1985 national survey
used in these studies asked respondents how many smokers out of 100
would get lung cancer because they smoke. People generally overestimate the risks of getting lung cancer due to smoking. These risk beliefs in
turn affect the decision to smoke in the expected manner. At least for
this risk component, which has been the most prominent smoking risk
since the 1964 Surgeon General report linking smoking and lung cancer,
the empirical evidence does not indicate a market failure.
Notwithstanding these results, a variety of puzzles remain. Do
smokers also perceive the other hazards of cigarettes, such as the total
mortality risk of smoking? If they understand the risk of death, do they
also properly assess how much life expectancy will be lost due to their
premature mortality?
Even if there is such a general understanding on average for the
population, are there major pockets of ignorance? The difference between
the smoking and the nonsmoking populations is striking. The current U.S.
smoking population is less well educated and has lower income levels
than the non-smoking population. A possible explanation for this
difference is that the higher education levels of nonsmokers enable them
to obtain a better understanding of the hazards of smoking, leading to
lower smoking rates among the better educated. Such differences in risk
beliefs have never been analyzed previously due to the absence of
smoking risk belief surveys that include such demographic information.
In this article, we exploit the more refined capabilities of two
large data sets: a 1997 national survey of smoking risk beliefs and a
1998 survey undertaken in Massachusetts. Each of these surveys includes
several quantitative risk perception measures as well as much more
comprehensive data on background characteristics than in the 1985 survey
analyzed in Viscusi (1990, 1992).
In Section II, we introduce the survey data and provide an overview
of smoking risk beliefs. Irrespective of the risk measure, there is a
pronounced tendency to overestimate the risk level compared to objective
scientific measures of the risk. These results contrast with the
frequently expressed claim in the literature that cigarette smokers are
the victims of companies' advertising. (3) According to this
alternative view, companies have allegedly designed their advertising
strategies to exploit potential irrationalities in order to foster
higher rates of smoking.
Section III explores the determinants of these risk beliefs,
yielding some intriguing results. Better educated respondents do have
more accurate beliefs, but because people generally overestimate the
risks of smoking, the greater accuracy is reflected in a lower
assessment of the risks. Some of the results are surprising, such as the
effect of state cigarette tax rates on the level of risk beliefs. How
these risk beliefs affect smoking behavior is the focus of Section IV.
The evidence reveals the expected negative relationship between smoking
and risk beliefs as well as the influence of other variables, such as
education, in accordance with economic predictions. Section V concludes
the paper.
II. SMOKING RISK BELIEFS
A. Data
Two data sources will serve as the basis for our analysis of
perceptions of the risks of smoking: a 1997 national survey and a 1998
Massachusetts survey. The 1997 national survey was administered by
Audits and Surveys Worldwide, and the 1998 survey was administered by
Roper Starch. Each of these surveys was a random digit dial probability
sample of all telephone households. However, the Massachusetts survey
oversampled the Medicaid population and is consequently less
representative than the U.S. sample. Both listed and unlisted numbers
were included, and there were multiple callbacks to complete the
interview. The selection of the respondent at the household was
randomized based on the most recent birthday of an adult household
member. Each of these surveys focused on respondents aged 18 yr or
older. (4)
The number of completed interviews was 1,013 for the 1997 U.S.
survey and 1,002 for the 1998 Massachusetts survey. The sample used in
the subsequent empirical analysis is usually 895 for the U.S. survey and
843 for the Massachusetts survey because we limit the analysis to
observations in which none of the key variables of interest have missing
values.
The structure of the Massachusetts survey is fairly similar to the
U.S. survey. The 1997 U.S. survey first inquired whether the respondent
had heard each of five different statements about cigarettes, such as
whether "smoking is not bad for a person's health." These
questions were intended to start respondents thinking about the main
topic of the survey: cigarettes. Responses do not serve as a measure of
risk belief but are simply indicators of the types of statements the
respondent may have heard regarding cigarettes. We use one of these
questions, which asks whether respondents had heard that "cigarette
smoking causes flat feet," as a separate variable below to identify
people who were confused or not attending to the survey task, or perhaps
willing to blame smoking for all physical ailments.
B. Risk Belief Questions
The survey then asked three quantitative smoking risk questions
about the lung cancer risk to a population of 100 smokers, the mortality
risk from smoking to 100 smokers, and smokers' life expectancy loss
by gender. The 1997 national survey first asked the total mortality risk
question, "Among 100 cigarette smokers, how many of them do you
think will die from lung cancer, heart disease, throat cancer, or any
illness because they smoke?" The next question on the survey was,
"Among 100 smokers, how many of them do you think will develop lung
cancer because they smoke?" (5) Thinking in terms of the risk for a
well-defined denominator, such as a population of 100 smokers, yields
more meaningful and well-behaved probability responses than asking
people to report the risk in percentage or decimal terms.
The life expectancy loss question provides information on the
normal life expectancy, so that the responses will isolate the perceived
incremental life expectancy loss. Otherwise, the response may be
confounded by misassessment of the base level of life expectancy. The
life expectancy loss question was worded, "As you may know, an
average 21-year-old male (female) would be expected to live to age 73
(80). What do you think the life expectancy is for the average male
(female) smoker?" with female respondents being asked the
parenthetical version of the question.
Not all individuals initially were able to give a response to each
of the risk belief questions. Just under 5% of the sample required a
probe after not giving a risk estimate when first asked. The probes were
of the following form, typified by the lung cancer question: "Just
your best estimate will do. How many out of 100 cigarette smokers do you
think will develop lung cancer because they smoke?" The subsequent
empirical analysis will incorporate a variable designated Probe to
indicate responses to the follow-up probe question rather than the
initial risk belief question. The Massachusetts survey also included the
same probe follow-up questions, queried respondents regarding whether
they had heard that smoking causes flat feet, and included a more
extensive set of other risk-related variables such as whether the
respondent uses a seat belt when a passenger in a car. These variables
will be discussed further below.
Table 1 summarizes the risk perception responses to each of the
three risk questions. For the 1997 national survey, on average people
believe that 47 out of 100 smokers will develop lung cancer because they
smoke. (6) Although the selection of people into smoking behavior will
lead us to expect that smokers will have lower risk beliefs than
nonsmokers, even current smokers believe that 40 out of 100 smokers will
develop lung cancer. Former smokers have somewhat higher risk beliefs,
and never-smokers have the highest risk beliefs. The 1998 Massachusetts
survey yields similar results with respect to lung cancer mortality from
smoking, with the overall risk belief being 48 lung cancer deaths per
100 smokers, with current smokers assessing the risk as 41 per 100.
Although smokers consistently have lower risk beliefs than former
smokers and never-smokers, these comparisons do not imply that smokers
underestimate the risk. This result is what one would expect from
rational selection into smoking behavior. Other things being equal, the
people who engage in risky behaviors will always have lower risk beliefs
than those who do not. Moreover, the pertinent comparison from the
standpoint of market failure is how these risk beliefs compare to
scientific estimates of the risk, not how smokers' risk beliefs
compare to those of nonsmokers. Based on reports by the U.S. Surgeon
General and estimates of the size of the smoking population, the
estimated actual lung cancer fatality risk from smoking is 0.06-0.13,
with a midpoint estimate of 0.10. (7) Even smokers overestimate the lung
cancer risk by a factor of 4.
For all respondent categories in Table 1, the assessed total
mortality risk from smoking is somewhat greater than the perceived lung
cancer risk. Respondents overall believe that the risk per 100 smokers
is 51 in the 1997 U.S. data and 54 in the 1998 Massachusetts data.
Current smokers continue to have lower risk beliefs, with fatalities per
100 smokers equal to 44 in the 1997 U.S. survey and 46 in the 1998
Massachusetts survey.
These risk beliefs also exceed scientific estimates of the actual
smoking mortality risk, which is 0.18-0.36 based on evidence from the
U.S. Surgeon General combined with data on the size of the U.S. smoking
population. (8) Using results from more recent studies by researchers at
Johns Hopkins University and the Office on Smoking and Health of the
Centers for Disease Control generates estimates of a risk range of
0.15-0.30 and 0.13-0.26 depending on the study used. (9) All these
mortality risk reference points are below the perceived risk of smoking
but not to the same extent as lung cancer risk, which has been the most
highly publicized hazard of smoking.
The final risk belief questions pertain to life expectancy loss
from smoking. This value is 12.7 in the 1997 U.S. sample and 13.5 in the
1998 Massachusetts sample. Smokers assess a smaller life expectancy
loss. In the 1997 U.S. sample, these values for current smokers are 10.2
yr overall, with an assessed loss of 8.4 yr for men and 12.1 yr for
women. The 1998 Massachusetts results for current smokers likewise
indicate a gender gap, as the expected years of life lost is 11.3 yr
overall, with a loss of 8.7 for men and 13.8 for women. These gender
differences are not unexpected, given the greater life expectancy for
women.
These life expectancy loss perceptions also are in excess of the
scientific reference points. Coupling the mortality risk estimate with
the Surgeon General's estimate of the number of years of life lost
conditional on a smoking-related death leads to a life expectancy loss
estimate of 3.6-7.2 yr. (10) Evidence cited by the Institute of Medicine
(2001, 1-2) indicates a life expectancy loss of 6.6 yr, and an earlier
estimate by the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (1989, 206)
concludes that a pack-a-day smoker at age 30 would lose 6-8 yr of life.
Each of these risk reference points is exceeded by the perceived risk
levels.
Comparison of each of the three risk perception variables with the
scientific estimates of the risk fails to indicate any evidence of
market failure based on the average level of risk beliefs for the
different population groups. These results should not be entirely
surprising, as cigarettes have had on-product warnings since 1966. There
have been reports by the Surgeon General on smoking on almost an annual
basis since 1964, as well as a wide range of public health policies
directed at raising the public's assessment of the risks of
smoking.
III. REGRESSION ESTIMATES OF THE DETERMINANTS OF RISK BELIEFS
Although average risk beliefs are quite high, the awareness of
smoking risks may vary across the population in systematic ways, as does
smoking behavior. (11) A principal phenomenon that this article will
address is why the U.S. population is largely segmented into a
well-educated, high-income, white-collar nonsmoking population and a
less well-educated, lower income, blue-collar smoking population.
Whereas formerly there was a strong positive income elasticity for
cigarette demand in the United States, that is no longer the case,
though it remains true in other countries. (12) More generally, it will
be desirable to distinguish whether particular population segments, such
as the young, are especially ill informed. As in our discussion in
Section II, the reference point for whether people are ill informed is
whether people's risk perceptions are accurate given scientific
evidence on the levels of the risk.
Consider the following model of risk beliefs, using the mortality
risk of smoking as the example. Let RISK be the probability of death due
to smoking, which we assume can be characterized by a beta distribution.
The individual has available m different information sources, i = 1 to
m, each of which has an associated informational content [[delta].sub.i]
and an implied probability of death [q.sub.i]. This information source i
is equivalent to observing [[delta].sub.i] Bernoulli trials, of which a
fraction [q.sub.i] indicates death. The share of the total information
accounted for by information source i is
(1) [[delta]'.sub.i] = [[delta].sub.i] / [m.summation over (i
= 1)] [[delta].sub.i].
The various components i include the respondent's prior risk
beliefs, the effect of smoking experiences, the influence of education,
and other sources of information, such as cigarette warnings. Based on
these various information sources, the person forms a risk belief given
by the weighted average of these information sources or
(2) RISK = [m.summation over (i = 1)] [[delta]'.sub.i]
[q.sub.i].
The effect of the different variables on risk beliefs will reflect
the joint influence of the relative information weight and the implied
risk level.
The specific forms of equations estimated will reflect the survey
questions: ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions for the number of
lung cancer deaths per 100 smokers, the number of smoking-related deaths
per 100 smokers, and the expected number of years of life expectancy
loss.
The set of explanatory variables is quite extensive for our two
data sets. Here, we will present the empirical results in conjunction
with discussion of the hypothesized effects of the variables based on
Equation (2). Consider first the national regressions (United States,
1997) in Table 2 (Columns 1-3). Respondent Age in years should be
negatively related to risk beliefs, to the extent that older people were
raised prior to the antismoking movement and younger people who have
been raised in a stronger antismoking environment will have a higher
[q.sub.i.]. Note that the age variable in cross-sectional analyses such
as this is not a pure age effect but also embodies cohort effects. Age
has a negative but diminishing effect on risk beliefs. (13) There is no
clear-cut effect of being Female (0-1 dummy variable [d.v.]) in terms of
their smoking risk or available risk information, but Hakes and Viscusi
(2004) presented evidence that women often have higher risk beliefs with
respect to mortality risks generally. Women have higher smoking risk
beliefs, consistent with their higher risk beliefs generally. Nonwhite (0-1 d.v.) respondents may be less well informed about the risks, which
could imply either lower risk beliefs if they are ignorant of the risks
or higher risk beliefs if their lack of information leads to an
exaggerated perception of the risk. The observed effect in Table 2 (U.S.
survey) is positive and significant in two of the three instances.
The Education (in years of schooling) variable is of fundamental
interest. Education embodies the effects of schooling as well as
personal characteristics correlated with education, such as IQ and
parental background. More years of education should lead to a greater
information weight [[delta].sub.i] on risk levels [q.sub.i] that are
accurate reflections of the risk. Given the general overestimation of
smoking risks in the population, the hypothesized effect of Education is
negative, as is the case throughout the results in Table 2. The puzzle created by this result, and which will be explored below, is why smoking
is less prevalent among the well educated, given that they have lower
perceptions of the risk.
Household characteristics also may affect one's risk
attitudes. People who are Married (0-1 d.v.) or are members of a large
household, as reflected in the Household Size variable (number of people
in household), are less likely to be risk takers and would be expected
to have higher risk beliefs. To the extent that there are significant
effects for these variables, the influence is positive.
The Probe (0-1 d.v.) variable indicates risk responses made after
the follow-up question that probed for the risk beliefs. If people who
did not answer the risk perception question initially have less
prominent risk beliefs, one would expect this variable to have a
negative effect on each of the risk belief variables, which is in fact
the case. Respondents who required a probe to give a total cigarette
mortality estimate believe that almost ten fewer smokers out of 100 will
die from smoking-related causes than does the average respondent. The
Flat Feet variable is a 0-1 d.v. that indicates whether respondents have
heard that "cigarette smoking causes flat feet." Individuals
who indicate that smoking causes flat feet should be expected to
attribute a broad range of risks to cigarettes, but no such effect is
apparent in the national survey regression results in Table 2.
The Cigarette Tax variable (cents tax per pack by state in 1997)
(14) is of particular interest wholly apart from its effect on cigarette
prices. (15) States with high cigarette taxes tend to have much stronger
antismoking environments than states with low tax rates, such as the
tobacco-producing states of North Carolina, Virginia, and Kentucky. The
Cigarette Tax variable consequently serves in part as a proxy for state
antismoking information and should have a positive effect on risk
beliefs. It also provides a price signal to consumers of the
dangerousness of the product. The Cigarette Tax variable has a
significant positive effect on both lung cancer risk beliefs and total
mortality risk beliefs. Interestingly, the high-cigarette tax states, in
which one would expect the antismoking efforts to be most prominent,
have a strong effect in boosting smoking risk assessments. It also may
be the case that the presence of a high tax at the time of purchase is a
signal to those purchasing cigarettes that the product is risky. Thus,
one mechanism by which higher taxes may reduce smoking is by raising
risk beliefs. (16)
The final variables in the 1997 U.S. regressions are for whether
the respondent is a Current Smoker or a Former Smoker, each of which is
a 0-1 d.v. These variables will reflect the combined influence of
smokers' morbidity experiences with cigarettes, their greater
familiarity with on-product cigarette warnings, and their prior beliefs
that led to their initial selection into smoking behavior. Current
smokers consistently have much lower risk beliefs, and former smokers
have lower risk beliefs than do never-smokers except for lung cancer
risks.
The smoking status variables in the smoking risk belief equations
could potentially be simultaneously determined. If smoking status is
endogenous, then not only do one's experiences as a smoker or
nonsmoker inform risk beliefs, but high smoking risk perceptions
influence decisions on whether to start or stop smoking. When endogenous
variables are included in an OLS regression equation, estimates of
smoking risk beliefs would be biased and inconsistent. (17)
The parallel risk belief equations for the 1998 Massachusetts
survey reported in Table 2 (Columns 4-6) include a somewhat different
set of variables. There is, for example, no Cigarette Tax variable
because taxes within the state do not vary. Several additional variables
included in this survey also entered the regressions. The 1998
Massachusetts sample also was not representative of the state's
population, as it oversampled the poor. Two variables that reflect this
mix are whether the respondent is covered by Medicaid (0-1 d.v.) and
whether the respondent had health insurance coverage, which we denote as
Not Insured (0-1 d.v.). The omitted groups are those covered by a
private plan or by Medicare.
Unlike previous quantitative smoking risk belief surveys, the 1998
Massachusetts survey included occupational information. The personal
characteristic variables in Table 2 (Massachusetts survey) follow a
pattern similar to the national estimates: Female, Education, and
Married exhibit the same pattern as before, as does the Current Smoker
variable. The Age variables are not significant, perhaps due to the
unbalanced nature of the 1998 Massachusetts sample. Former Smoker risk
beliefs are not significantly different from those of never-smokers, but
they are higher than those of a Current Smoker.
People who have experienced a Job Injury have higher risk beliefs.
Apparently, the effect of physical injuries has increased the weight
respondents place on the possible risks of cigarettes, leading to
considerable overestimation of the risks. The magnitude of the effect
boosts lung cancer risk beliefs by 13 per 100 smokers and total
mortality risks by 11 per 100 smokers.
Blue Collar respondents perhaps surprisingly have higher estimates
of the expected years of life lost that are 2 yr more than white-collar
workers' beliefs. Their higher risk beliefs may reflect greater
personal contact with smokers who died. Note that the direction of the
effect is the opposite of what one would expect if higher smoking rates
among Blue Collar workers stemmed from risk underestimation.
The Medicaid and Not Insured variables each have significant
positive effects in two of the three equations. The people identified by
these policy variables, who are often poor and who are not covered by
standard health insurance, have higher risk beliefs. The extent of their
additional risk overestimation is especially great for the lung cancer
risk beliefs of the Not Insured, as they assess an additional 11 lung
cancer deaths per 100 smokers. As with the negative Education
coefficient, the segments of society who are least well informed tend to
have greater and less accurate risk beliefs than those who are better
informed.
Much the same type of educational background result is reflected in
the Massachusetts regressions by the Flat Feet variable. People who have
heard that smoking causes flat feet, which it does not, have higher risk
beliefs.
Finally, the Probe variable has a significant negative effect for
the first two equations. People who did not initially volunteer a lung
cancer risk estimate or a mortality risk estimate have lower risk
beliefs.
IV. SMOKING STATUS REGRESSIONS
Risk beliefs regarding the hazards of smoking can affect smoking
status in a variety of ways--influencing whether the person chooses to
smoke cigarettes, whether the person quits smoking after starting, how
many times the person tries to quit, and how much the person smokes.
Both the 1997 U.S. survey and the 1998 Massachusetts survey
elicited the smoking status of each respondent, making it possible to
construct categories of current smokers, former smokers, and
never-smokers. A person's current smoking status, however, is the
result of a sequence of two distinct but interrelated smoking decisions.
The first decision node is the initial never-smoker/ever-smoker decision
node. If the person chooses the ever-smoker path, there is a subsequent
decision node involving the choice to become a former smoker or remain a
current smoker. While each decision might be revisited many times in a
person's life, the first-stage decision on starting to smoke is
only appropriate for those who have never chosen "yes" to that
question before, and after a person has chosen "yes" at the
first stage, a subsequent second-stage decision must be made. One cannot
become a former smoker without first becoming an ever-smoker. The
first-stage decision, in short, selects those for whom the second
decision is relevant.
Excluding never-smokers from the analysis of the quit decision
makes the estimates conditional on the first-stage outcome. However,
following Heckman (1979), ignoring the initial ever-smoker/never-smoker
choice node in the second-stage estimates will lead to potentially
biased and inconsistent estimates of the coefficients from the
standpoint of the overall population's behavior. Because the
second-stage decision involves a binary outcome rather than a
continuously distributed choice, we will also report estimates using Van
de Ven and Van Pragg's (1981) adaptation of Heckman's model to
test for self-selection.
We begin our analysis of the pivotal discrete smoking choices with
full-sample estimates of the probability of being a never-smoker and the
probability of being a current smoker. For people who have ever been
smokers, we also estimate the probability of being a former smoker. This
is the individual choice analog of an equation for whether the person
has quit smoking, which is estimated for smoking populations.
Because of the conceptual overlaps and the empirical correlations
among our three smoking risk belief variables, we first explore the
effects of these variables on the different smoking status
probabilities, estimating them in pairs as well as collectively. The
different panels of Table 3 summarize the risk belief estimates only,
where each equation also includes the full set of explanatory variables
used below. Because of the high correlation of Lung Cancer Risk and
Total Mortality Risk beliefs, including all three risk variables in
Columns 4 and 8 creates multicollinearity problems. The strongest
consistent results are those in Columns 3 and 7, including the mortality
risk and life expectancy loss variables.
Consider the 1997 U.S. results in Column 3 of Table 3, which are
similar to the 1998 Massachusetts estimates in Column 7. An additional
10 expected deaths per 100 smokers boost the probability of being a
never-smoker by 0.02, decrease the probability of being a current smoker
by 0.02, and increase the probability of being a former smoker by 0.02.
An additional expected year of life lost raises the probability of being
a never-smoker by 0.01 and raises the probability of being a former
smoker by 0.01. These effects are in addition to the influence of
mortality risk beliefs.
The full set of regression results based on the two key risk belief
measures appears in Table 4. For the U.S. and Massachusetts samples, the
probability of being a never-smoker increases in a statistically
significant manner with Mortality Risk and, in the case of the U.S.
sample, with Expected Years of Life Lost as well. Education also has a
significant positive influence on being a never-smoker. In the U.S.
sample, being Nonwhite has a positive effect on being a never-smoker.
Age has a diminishing negative effect on being a never-smoker in
Massachusetts but no significant effect in the U.S. sample.
Cigarette Tax does not have a significant effect on the
never-smoker decision or on any of the other smoking choices in Table 4.
To the extent that cigarette taxes influence cigarette consumption
directly, it is through the tax's effect on the amount of
cigarettes demanded, not on the discrete smoking status decision. This
result in many respects parallels the finding with respect to the
inconvenience costs of smoking, as smoking restrictions have been found
to have a greater effect on the number of cigarettes smoked than on
smoking participation. (18) Note that Cigarette Tax does have an
indirect effect on smoking status by raising risk beliefs.
Three variables included in the 1998 Massachusetts survey but not
in the 1997 U.S. survey are influential as well. Blue Collar workers
have a 9% lower chance of being a never-smoker, as the blue-collar
orientation of the smoking population is independent of any correlation
of blue-collar status with informational deficits. Respondents who
undertake self-protective behaviors in other arenas by using seat belts
or being careful about their diet are much more likely to be
never-smokers. The decision to be a never-smoker reflects consistent
behavior to reduce health risks across different choice domains. (19)
The second set of full-sample estimates in Table 4 for whether the
person is a current smoker tends to reflect influences that are in the
opposite direction from what affects the probability of being a
never-smoker. For both samples, the total mortality risk and expected
years of life lost reduce the probability of being a current smoker, as
does years of education. Age has overall net negative effects on being a
current smoker, but the results are more mixed across the two samples.
Married respondents in the U.S. sample are less likely to be current
smokers.
Several distinctive Massachusetts survey data set variables are
influential. The blue-collar orientation of smoking is apparent with the
positive effect of the blue-collar variable on being a current smoker.
People who use seat belts (Uses Seatbelts) or are careful with their
diets (Diet Carefully) are more health conscious and are less likely to
be current smokers. One would expect that people who are not covered by
health insurance (Not Insured) are more likely to smoke for a variety of
reasons. Aside from income level, for which we have already controlled,
the primary influences captured by the Not Insured variable are that
these individuals are more willing to expose themselves to health risks
or that they have less access to medical care, possibly because they
have been denied coverage. That greater risk tolerance is borne out, as
those who are not insured have a 0.16 higher probability of being a
current smoker, controlling for a broad range of other influences.
The Model 3 estimates in Table 4 are for whether the respondent is
a former smoker. Conditional on being in the ever-smoker sample, has the
respondent quit smoking to become a former smoker? Both of the risk
belief variables have positive effects on transiting to the former
smoker state in each set of results. In the U.S. results in Table 4,
there is a diminishing negative effect of Age, a positive effect of
Education, and a positive effect of Married, as married smokers may be
more concerned about the effects of smoking on their family and on their
own health, which in turn will affect the family's well-being.
The estimated effects of the background variables in the
Massachusetts survey are somewhat different from the U.S. estimates
given the different mix of explanatory variables available for the
Massachusetts survey. Being averse to health risks, as reflected in Uses
Seatbelts, boosts the probability of being a former smoker by 0.13. The
most striking risk behavior result is the huge effect of the Not Insured
variable, which decreases the probability of becoming a former smoker by
0.31 controlling for a quite extensive set of personal characteristics.
The sequential smoking decision model incorporates the former
smoker equation from Table 4 as the second-stage quit decision but
includes a different first stage to account for selection into the
sample. Thus, we will be estimating the probit analog of Model 3 in
Table 4 for the ever-smoker subsample, as was also done in that table,
except that the probit equation will also include the appropriate
adjustment for being in the ever-smoker condition. (20)
The results for the Stage 2 equation in Table 5 are qualitatively
very similar to those in the "former smoker" model of Table 4,
as would be expected given their structural similarities. In the U.S.
sample, quitting is more likely for individuals who are older, more
educated, married, and who perceive smoking as being more dangerous,
while income, race, gender, and cigarette tax levels do not directly
affect quit choices. The Massachusetts sample also had the same pattern
of significant predictors of quit behavior as in Table 4, with education
here having no effect but with Not Insured individuals much less likely
to quit. The one qualitative difference between the tables is that Uses
Seatbelts is statistically insignificant in Table 5.
To model the first-stage equation in which individuals decide
whether or not to start smoking, we have altered some regressors so that
the structural equation is more appropriate to the context in which the
decision is taken. Most current smokers smoked their first cigarette
while teenagers. (21) As a consequence, the age of the sample members
who are age 18 and over at the time of the survey would likely provide
little information about the decision to become an ever-smoker.
Similarly, the person's ultimate education will not be completed at
the age most individuals decide whether to become smokers or abstain.
The only individuals for whom educational attainment will be
predetermined at the time of the ever-smoker/never-smoker decision are
those dropped out of school prior to high school graduation.
To incorporate these differences, the Stage 1 equations in Table 5
do not include the survey respondent's age, substitute the
respondent's eventual educational attainment with an indicator for
High School Dropout, and include an indicator as to whether the
respondent has heard that smoking is "not bad" for a
person's health.
Uptake of smoking as shown in the estimates in Table 5 depends upon
some of the same factors which predict never-smokers in Table 4. People
with higher smoking risk beliefs who have not dropped out of high school
and who are nonwhite are less likely to start smoking. While Married is
not statistically significant, a Household Head is more likely to have
smoked at some time, which might be picking up higher historical smoking
rates for men. The lower likelihood of smoking for people with higher
incomes is not surprising, but for this result to be meaningful
teenagers making the initial smoking decision must be acting on the
basis of their subsequent lifetime income.
The analogous regression of Stage 1 in Table 5 (Massachusetts
survey) shows the same effects for education and smoking risk
perceptions. Because people on Medicaid have low income levels, the
higher smoking initiation rates by those eventually on Medicaid are
consistent with the income coefficient for Stage 1 in Table 5 (U.S.
survey). Among the variables unique to the Massachusetts sample, we see
that Blue Collar workers are less likely to have abstained from smoking
and that seat belt users and those who eat carefully are less likely to
ever have smoked. These results suggest that individuals tend to be
consistent across health and safety decisions.
The one anomalous result in Stage 1 of Table 5 is that those in the
U.S. sample who have heard that smoking is not bad for people are less
likely to have begun smoking. This result, however, is likely due to the
fact that those individuals are also more likely to report having heard
that smoking is bad for people. (22) In the Massachusetts sample, where
people were asked the same set of questions, this anomalous result does
not occur.
The statistics at the bottom of Table 5 test the validity of the
functional and structural form. The Wald statistics indicate that all
the selection models explain a significant portion of the variation in
smoking decisions. The insignificant estimates for the error correlation
term (labeled atanh [rho]) and for the test of independent equations
suggest that selection is not affecting the second-stage results in the
U.S. sample. The corresponding estimates in the Massachusetts sample,
however, are less clear-cut. The estimate for the error correlation term
(atanh [rho]) is sufficiently high that the equations could be
considered linked at the 90% confidence level, although not at the 95%
level. At the 5% significance level, then, the Massachusetts sample
models give qualitatively similar results to those for the U.S. sample,
but the estimators are possibly not as efficient.
V. CONCLUSION
Examination of the 1997 U.S. smoking survey and the 1998
Massachusetts smoking survey revealed some expected results in line with
economic theory and general expectation but also yielded some surprises
as well. The smoking populations in these samples tend to be less
well-educated, blue-collar individuals. However, smokers are not
isolated from the considerable public information about the hazards of
cigarettes. They are very much aware of the risks. Indeed, they
overestimate the smoking-related risks of lung cancer, life expectancy
loss, and total mortality loss. Perception of these hazards affects the
decision to ever smoke, to be a current smoker, and to become a former
smoker in the expected manner. Moreover, there is evidence of consistent
risk-taking behavior, as people who use seat belts or exercise care in
their diets make risk-reducing choices in the smoking domain as well.
People who forego health insurance and place their well-being
substantially at risk by doing so are especially likely to smoke and not
to quit once they have begun. Cigarette smoking is a large risk that is
highly correlated with other risk-taking activities among the current
smoking population.
The effect of education is especially interesting. Those who are
better educated do have more accurate risk beliefs, but this greater
accuracy is reflected in lower risk beliefs, not higher risk beliefs, as
the better educated are less prone to risk overestimation. Yet, better
educated people are less likely to be smokers because of the larger
direct effect of education on the smoking status decision after
controlling for adjusted risk beliefs.
The effect of state cigarette taxes is also intriguing. Higher
cigarette taxes do not directly influence the various smoking status
decisions. However, people in the high cigarette tax states have higher
smoking risk beliefs, which in turn influence smoking behavior. Whether
the tax effect on beliefs is due to higher taxes signaling to cigarette
purchasers that the product is dangerous or due to the states with
higher taxes simply having a strong antismoking environment is unclear.
ABBREVIATIONS
LR: Likelihood Ratio
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
REFERENCES
Antonanzas, F., W. K. Viscusi, J. Rovira, F. J. Brana, F. Portillo,
and I. Carvalho. "Smoking Risks in Spain: Part I--Perceptions of
Risks to the Smoker." Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 21, 2000,
161-86.
DiCicca, P., D. Kenkel, and A. Mathios. "Racial Differences in
the Determinants of Smoking Onset." Journal of Risk and
Uncertainty, 21, 2000, 311-40.
Evans, W. N., M. C. Farrelly, and E. Montgomery. "Do Workplace
Smoking Bans Reduce Smoking?" American Economic Review, 89, 1999,
728-47.
Hakes, J. K., and W. K. Viscusi. "Dead Reckoning: Demographic
Determinants of the Accuracy of Mortality Risk Perceptions." Risk
Analysis, 24, 2004, 651-63.
Hanson, J., and D. Kysar. "Taking Behavioralism Seriously:
Some Evidence of Market Manipulation.'" Harvard Law Review,
112, 1999, 1420-1572.
Heckman, J. "Sample Selection Bias as Specification
Error." Econometrica, 47, 1979, 153-61.
Hersch, J. "Gender, Income Levels, and the Demand for
Cigarettes." Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 21, 2000, 263-82.
Institute of Medicine. Clearing the Smoke. Washington, DC:
Institute of Medicine, 2001.
Orzechowski, W., and Walker, R. C. The Tax Burden on Tobacco.
Arlington, VA: Orzechowski and Walker Consultants, 2005.
Rivers, D., and Q. H. Vuong. "Limited Information Estimators
and Exogeneity Tests for Simultaneous Probit Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 39, 1988, 347-66.
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. Reducing the Health
Consequences of Smoking: Twenty-Five Years of Progress, A Report of the
Surgeon General. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1989.
--. Youth and Tobacco, Preventing Tobacco Use among Young People, A
Report of the Surgeon General. Rockville, MD: U.S. Dept. of Health and
Human Services, 1994.
--. Reducing Tobacco Use, A Report of the Surgeon General.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2000.
Van de Ven, W. P. M. M., and B. M. S. Van Pragg. "'The
Demand for Deductibles in Private Health Insurance: A Probit Model with
Sample Selection." Journal of Econometrics, 17, 1981, 229-52.
Viscusi, W. K. "Do Smokers Underestimate Risks?" Journal
of Political Economy, 98, 1990, 1253-69.
--. Smoking: Making the Risky Decision. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1992.
--. Smoke-Filled Rooms: A Postmortem on the Tobacco Deal. Chicago,
IL: University of Chicago Press, 2002.
Viscusi, W. K., and J. Hakes. "Risk Beliefs and Smoking
Behavior." Paper presented at 2006 WEA Conference, NBER Working
Paper, forthcoming.
Viscusi, W. K., and J. Hersch. "Cigarette Smokers as Job Risk
Takers." Review of Economies and Statistics, 83, 2001, 269-80.
(1.) These and similar questions from Gallup polls are summarized
in Viscusi (1992). For example, the Gallup survey on July 18, 1990
(Question ID: U.S. Gallup 071890.R08), asked, "Do you think smoking
is or is not harmful to your health?"
(2.) Viscusi (1992) also presented exploratory results on other
risk measures using a North Carolina sample but did not include any
regression analyses for these data.
(3.) See Hanson and Kysar (1999) for articulation of this view.
(4.) Although the surveys were undertaken in response to
litigation, that aspect was never revealed to survey respondents. The
1997 survey was an attempt to replicate on a national basis the North
Carolina survey reported in Viscusi (1992), which had no external
funding. The senior author of this paper designed the 1998 survey with
no client involvement. The authors will make the data available to any
interested researcher for purposes of replication and verification of
our results.
(5.) In the 1998 Massachusetts survey, the wordings were quite
similar, although the order of the questions was reversed. The lung
cancer question was worded, "Out of 100 smokers, how many do you
think will die from lung cancer because they smoke?", while the
total mortality risk question followed in the form, "And out of
every 100 cigarette smokers, how many of them do you think will die from
lung cancer, heart disease, throat cancer, or any other illness because
they smoke?" Our results show that the ordering and wording
differences did not have any apparent effect on the results.
(6.) This estimate is a bit higher than the risk belief of 43 out
of 100 reported for a 1985 national survey in Viscusi (1992).
(7.) See Viscusi (1992) for derivation of this result.
(8.) The procedures for this calculation and the data sources are
discussed in Viscusi (1992, 2002).
(9.) These studies are discussed in conjunction with the derivation
of these risk estimates in Viscusi (2002, 148-149).
(10.) See Viscusi (1992, 80) for documentation of this estimate.
(11.) For analysis of the effect on smoking of gender and income,
see Hersch (2000) and DiCicca, Kenkel, and Mathios (2000) for the effect
of race.
(12.) The data reported by Antonanzas et al. (2000) for Spain
indicate that education, which is strongly correlated with lifetime
wealth, is positively related to smoking status. In particular, the
average number of years of education is 11 for smokers, l0 for former
smokers, and 9 for never smokers.
(13.) This evidence is consistent with the 1985 age-related results
in Viscusi (1992) indicating that very young respondents who have been
raised in a strong antismoking environment tend to have higher risk
beliefs.
(14.) The source of this variable is Orzechowski and Walker (2005).
Data were formerly published by the Tobacco Institute.
(15.) Note that this variable and other policy variables are
potentially endogenous as levels of risk beliefs in the state may affect
smoking policies. The major determinants of tax rates, however, will
also include public finance considerations such as alternate revenue
sources, whether tobacco is commercially grown in the state, and so on.
Structural modeling of the determinants of each of the policy variables
is beyond the scope of this paper.
(16.) To explore whether this effect was due to taxes or cigarette
policies correlated with taxes, we included measures of tobacco
prevention spending in the risk belief models. Due to a lack of older
data, we use data released by Campaign for Tobacco-Free Kids on December
7, 2005, for fiscal year 2006 as these expenditure variables. The
measure used is state-level tobacco prevention spending as a percentage
of tobacco revenue, which closely correlates with state-level tobacco
prevention spending per capita. The auxiliary regressions, which we do
not report here, showed that prevention spending is not correlated
significantly with any of our risk belief measures.
(17.) We tested for this possibility using the two-stage
conditional maximum likelihood estimation technique of Rivers and Vuong
(1988), a technique that is closely related to the Hausman test but is
more appropriate for situations in which the second-stage equation has a
discrete dependent variable. The structural equation of smoking status
is estimated but includes both the actual risk perceptions variable and
a variable containing the residuals from a reduced-form risk perception
estimate. The test of significance for the coefficient on the residual
variable also addresses the null hypothesis of no simultaneity. The
Rivers-Vuong test coefficients fail to reject the null hypothesis that
smoking status is an independent variable, implying that the OLS
estimates in Table 2 are not biased due to endogeneity. For both data
sets (United States and Massachusetts) and each smoking status (current,
former, and never), we tested total mortality risk perceptions and
expected years of life lost perceptions using this test. None of the 12
resulting z scores were higher than 1.53 and only two exceeded 0.60,
where 1.96 is the critical value at the 95% confidence level.
(18.) For detailed analyses of responses to smoking restrictions,
see Evans, Farrelly, and Montgomery (1999) and the U.S. Department of
Health and Human Services (2000).
(19.) See Viscusi and Hersch (2001) for analysis of the
relationship of smoking to job risks and other personal hazards.
(20.) This adaptation of the Heckman (1979) selection model is
based on Van de Ven and Van Pragg (1981).
(21.) See the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (1994).
(22.) For the 273 people in our U.S. sample who reported having
heard that smoking is not bad for them, 53.8% also report having heard
that it was bad. Among the 610 people who had not heard smoking is not
bad, only 26.9% reported hearing that it was bad. It should be
emphasized that these questions pertain to statements that the
respondent has heard and are not measures of risk belief. Over 95% of
survey respondents also reported having heard that smoking was
"dangerous" and that smoking "shortens" life.
Moreover, Gallup polls since the 1970s have found that over 90% of the
public believe that smoking is harmful to one's health.
W. KIP VISCUSI and JAHN K. HAKES *
* Revision of paper (Viscusi and Hakes, 2006) prepared for July 1,
2006, Western Economic Association Meetings, President's Session.
Viscusi: University Distinguished Professor of Law, Economics, and
Management, Law School, Vanderbilt University, 131 21st Avenue South,
Nashville, TN 37203. Phone 615-343-7715, Fax 615-322-5953, E-mail
kip.viscusi@vanderbilt.edu
Hakes: Assistant Professor of Economics, Department of Economics
and Management, Albion College, 611 East Porter Street, Albion, MI
49224. E-mail jhakes@albion.edu
TABLE 1
Risk Beliefs, by Smoking Status and Gender
Lung Total
n Cancer Risk Mortality Risk
United States, 1997
All respondents 895 47.2 (28.7) 50.8 (28.6)
Male respondents 413 44.7 (29.1) 48.1 (29.4)
Female respondents 482 49.4 (28.1) 53.2 (27.7)
Current smokers 215 40.4 (28.3) 43.7 (28.5)
Male current smokers 111 41.7 (30.1) 44.4 (30.9)
Female current smokers 104 38.9 (26.3) 42.9 (25.8)
Massachusetts, 1998
All respondents 843 47.6 (29.5) 53.9 (29.1)
Male respondents 389 43.5 (29.2) 49.7 (29.0)
Female respondents 454 51.1 (29.3) 57.5 (28.8)
Current smokers 183 41.1 (29.5) 46.0 (30.7)
Male current smokers 89 39.4 (29.5) 43.5 (30.5)
Female current smokers 94 42.7 (29.6) 48.3 (30.9)
Expected Years
of Life Lost
United States, 1997
All respondents 12.7 (8.2)
Male respondents 10.1 (7.4)
Female respondents 14.8 (8.3)
Current smokers 10.2 (8.1)
Male current smokers 8.4 (7.6)
Female current smokers 12.1 (8.3)
Massachusetts, 1998
All respondents 13.5 (11.9)
Male respondents 10.4 (10.9)
Female respondents 16.1 (12.2)
Current smokers 11.3 (12.0)
Male current smokers 8.7 (11.8)
Female current smokers 13.8 (11.7)
Notes: For United States, 1997, sample limited to 895 observations
for which all explanatory variables in regression analysis have
values. For Massachusetts, 1998, sample limited to 843 observations
for which all explanatory variables used in regressions have values.
Standard deviations appear in parentheses.
TABLE 2
Risk Belief Regression Equations
United States, 1997
Model 1: Lung Model 2: Total
Cancer Risk Mortality Risk
1 2
Age -0.804 *** (0.266) -0.638 ** (0.266)
Age squared 0.0073 *** (0.003) 0.0052 * (0.003)
Female 4.311 ** (1.881) 4.499 ** (1.881)
Nonwhite 6.953 ** (2.930) 1.879 (2.930)
Education (yr) -1.164 *** (0.353) -0.960 *** (0.353)
Married 2.416 (2.068) 4.422 ** (2.068)
Household Size 1.400 ** (0.667) 0.768 (0.667)
Job Injury
Medicaid
Not Insured
Blue Collar
Probe -6.352 (4.465) -9.286 ** (4.465)
Flat Feet 4.498 (5.952) -6.683 (5.951)
Cigarette Tax 0.106 ** (0.053) 0.122 ** (0.053)
Current Smoker -10.988 *** (2.370) -11.565 *** (2.370)
Former Smoker -3.160 (2.282) -5.035 ** (2.281)
Constant 72.524 *** (8.278) 69.734 *** (8.277)
[R.sup.2] 0.087 0.083
United States, 1997 Massachusetts, 1998
Model 3: Expected Model 1: Lung
Years of Life Lost Cancer Risk
3 4
Age -0.154 ** (0.072) 0.112 (0.300)
Age squared 0.0011 (0.001) -0.0012 (0.003)
Female 4.563 *** (0.513) 7.111 *** (2.018)
Nonwhite 1.412 ** (0.799) 1.117 (2.759)
Education (yr) -0.309 *** (0.096) -0.748 ** (0.332)
Married -0.687 (0.564) 1.702 (2.095)
Household Size 0.387 ** (0.182)
Job Injury 13.238 *** (4.415)
Medicaid 3.908 * (2.250)
Not Insured 10.556 ** (4.862)
Blue Collar -0.270 (2.603)
Probe -0.231 (1.217) -18.493 *** (3.778)
Flat Feet -0.093 (1.622) 10.542 ** (5.304)
Cigarette Tax -0.003 (0.014)
Current Smoker -3.779 *** (0.646) -9.842 *** (2.673)
Former Smoker -1.038 * (0.622) -0.063 (2.292)
Constant 20.108 *** (2.256) 52.891 *** (9.137)
[R.sup.2] 0.158 0.097
Massachusetts, 1998
Model 2: Total Model 3: Expected
Mortality Risk Years of Life Lost
5 6
Age -0.110 (0.299) -0.017 (0.117)
Age squared 0.0007 (0.0027) 0.0002 (0.0011)
Female 7.608 *** (2.011) 5.389 *** (0.790)
Nonwhite -1.925 (2.749) 5.689 *** (1.081)
Education (yr) -0.196 (0.331) -0.295 ** (0.130)
Married 0.477 (2.088) -0.327 (0.821)
Household Size
Job Injury 11.460 *** (4.399) 0.792 (1.729)
Medicaid 2.697 (2.242) 3.067 *** (0.881)
Not Insured 8.223 * (4.843) 1.956 (1.904)
Blue Collar 0.493 (2.593) 2.125 ** (1.019)
Probe -18.275 *** (3.765) 0.331 (1.480)
Flat Feet 2.291 (5.285) 4.657 ** (2.078)
Cigarette Tax
Current Smoker -11.487 *** (2.663) -3.790 *** (1.047)
Former Smoker -1.476 (2.283) -0.262 (0.898)
Constant 58.308 *** (9.103) 13.140 *** (3.579)
[R.sup.2] 0.081 0.154
Notes: The U.S. sample contains 895 observations. Indicators for
Northeast, North Central, and West regions were included in models
as control variables, but the coefficients are not reported. The
Massachusetts sample contains 843 observations.
Standard errors are in parentheses.
* Significant at 90% confidence level.
** Significant at 95% confidence level.
*** Significant at 99% confidence level.
TABLE 3
Effects of Risk Beliefs on Smoking Status
United States, 1997
1 2
Panel A: Never-smokers
Lung Cancer Risk 0.0007 (0.0009) 0.0018 *** (0.0006)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0023 *** (0.0009)
Expected Years of 0.0095 *** (0.0024)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.0514 0.0590
LR [chi square] 63.79 73.15
Panel B: Current smokers
Lung Cancer Risk -0.0014 * (0.0007) -0.0018 *** (0.0005)
Total Mortality Risk -0.0014 * (0.0007)
Expected Years of -0.0095 *** (0.0020)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.0854 0.1051
LR [chi square] 84.24 103.73
Panel C: Former smokers
Lung Cancer Risk 0.0026 * (0.0014) 0.0022 ** (0.0009)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0005 (0.0014)
Expected Years of 0.0122 *** (0.0037)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.0973 0.1154
LR [chi square] 60.49 71.75
United States, 1997
3 4
Panel A: Never-smokers
Lung Cancer Risk 0.0002 (0.0009)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0024 *** (0.0006) 0.0022 ** (0.0009)
Expected Years of 0.0094 *** (0.0024) 0.0094 *** (0.0024)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.0641 0.0641
LR [chi square] 79.47 79.52
Panel B: Current smokers
Lung Cancer Risk -0.0009 (0.0007)
Total Mortality Risk -0.0019 *** (0.0005) -0.0013 * (0.0007)
Expected Years of -0.0097 *** (0.0020) -0.0094 *** (0.0020)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.1066 0.1081
LR [chi square] 105.18 106.73
Panel C: Former smokers
Lung Cancer Risk 0.0017 (0.0014)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0018 ** (0.0009) 0.0006 (0.0014)
Expected Years of 0.0129 *** (0.(1036) 0.0122 *** (0.0036)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.1132 0.1157
LR [chi square] 70.37 71.92
Massachusetts, 1998
5 6
Panel A: Never-smokers
Lung Cancer Risk -0.0003 (0.0010) 0.0011 * (0.0006)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0017 * (0.0011)
Expected Years of 0.0024 (0.0016)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.0913 0.0909
LR [chi square] 104.85 104.35
Panel B: Current smokers
Lung Cancer Risk -0.0006 (0.0008) -0.0021 *** (0.0005)
Total Mortality Risk -0.0017 ** (0.0008)
Expected Years of -0.0047 *** (0.0013)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.1216 0.1328
LR [chi square] 107.24 117.10
Panel C: Former smokers
Lung Cancer Risk 0.0008 (0.0015) 0.0029 *** (0.0008)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0022 (0.0014)
Expected Years of 0.0061 *** (0.0020)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.1118 0.1235
LR [chi square] 72.07 79.62
Massachusetts, 1998
7 8
Panel A: Never-smokers
Lung Cancer Risk -0.0004 (0.0010)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0015 ** (0.0006) 0.0018 * (0.0011)
Expected Years of 0.0025 (0.0016) 0.0025 (0.0016)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.0933 0.0934
LR [chi square] 107.08 107.20
Panel B: Current smokers
Lung Cancer Risk -0.0007 (0.0008)
Total Mortality Risk -0.0022 *** (0.0005) -0.0017 ** (0.0008)
Expected Years of -0.0046 *** (0.0013) -0.0046 *** (0.0013)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.1366 0.1374
LR [chi square] 120.50 121.17
Panel C: Former smokers
Lung Cancer Risk 0.0009 (0.0015)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0031 *** (0.0008) 0.0023 (0.0014)
Expected Years of 0.0061 ** (0.0020) 0.0061 *** (0.0020)
Life Lost
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.1271 0.1276
LR [chi square] 81.92 82.28
Notes: All models included controls for Age, Age squared, Female,
Nonwhite, Education (yr), Married, Income (thousands), Income
unreported, Income top-code, Household Head, Total Mortality Risk,
and Expected Years of Life Lost. For the U.S. sample, models in
Panels A and B have 895 observations and models in Panel C have 449
observations, as those who had never smoked were excluded. For the
Massachusetts sample, models in Panels A and B have 843 observations
and models in Panel C have 487 observations, excluding those who had
never smoked. Models including only one risk belief were also
estimated, with results similar to Columns 1-3. LR=likelihood ratio.
Coefficients represent dF/dx for unit changes at the mean.
Standard errors are in parentheses.
* Significant at 90% confidence level.
** Significant at 95% confidence level.
*** Significant at 99% confidence level.
TABLE 4
Probit Regression Estimates for Smoking Status
United States, 1997
Variable Model l: Model 2:
Never-Smoker Current Smoker
1 2
Age 0.001 (0.005) 0.008 (0.005)
Age squared -0.00003 (0.00005) -0.00011 ** (0.00005)
Female 0.029 (0.037) -0.005 (0.030)
Nonwhite 0.098 * (0.052) -0.032 (0.041)
Education (yr) 0.023 *** (0.007) -0.032 *** (0.006)
Married 0.046 (0.038) -0.070 ** (0.031)
Income (1000s) 0.00096 (0.00077) -0.00103 (0.00065)
Income unreported 0.096 ** (0.048) -0.082 ** (0.035)
Income top-code -0.046 (0.195) 0.001 (0.189)
Household Head -0.133 ** (0.055) 0.036 (0.043)
Cigarette Tax 0.0001 (0.0008) 0.0002 (0.0007)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0024 *** (0.0006) -0.0019 *** (0.0005)
Expected Years 0.0094 *** (0.0024) -0.010 *** (0.002)
Life Lost
Medicaid
Not Insured
Blue Collar
Uses Seatbelts
Diet Carefully
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.064 0.107
United States, 1997 Massachusetts, 1998
Variable Model 3: Model 1:
Former Smoker Never-Smoker
3 4
Age -0.013 * (0.008) -0.010 * (0.005)
Age squared 0.00022 *** (0.00008) 0.00008 * (0.00005)
Female -0.020 (0.053) 0.015 (0.038)
Nonwhite -0.051 (0.082) 0.054 (0.051)
Education (yr) 0.039 *** (0.010) 0.031 *** (0.006)
Married 0.093 * (0.053) 0.038 (0.040)
Income (1000s) 0.0015 (0.0011) 0.00089 (0.00099)
Income unreported 0.083 (0.074) 0.077 (0.051)
Income top-code -0.0003 (0.3185) 0.147 (0.100)
Household Head 0.082 (0.0091)
Cigarette Tax -0.0001 (0.0012)
Total Mortality Risk 0.0018 ** (0.0009) 0.0015 ** (0.0006)
Expected Years 0.0129 *** (0.0036) 0.0025 (0.0016)
Life Lost
Medicaid -0.067 (0.043)
Not Insured 0.008 (0.089)
Blue Collar -0.089 * (0.046)
Uses Seatbelts 0.156 *** (0.038)
Diet Carefully 0.110 ** (0.042)
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.113 0.093
Massachusetts, 1998
Variable Model 2: Model 3:
Current Smoker Former Smoker
5 6
Age -0.012 *** (0.004) 0.028 *** (0.007)
Age squared 0.00010 *** (0.00004) -0.00022 *** (0.00006)
Female 0.033 (0.030) -0.050 (0.049)
Nonwhite -0.031 (0.036) 0.047 (0.064)
Education (yr) -0.013 ** (0.005) 0.003 (0.009)
Married -0.027 (0.031) 0.028 (0.053)
Income (1000s) 0.00025 (0.00075) 0.00029 (0.00125)
Income unreported -0.063 (0.035) 0.069 (0.067)
Income top-code -0.065 (0.063) -0.012 (0.138)
Household Head
Cigarette Tax
Total Mortality Risk -0.0022 *** (0.0005) 0.0031 *** (0.0008)
Expected Years -0.0046 *** (0.0013) 0.0061 *** (0.0020)
Life Lost
Medicaid 0.048 (0.035) -0.040 (0.055)
Not Insured 0.158 ** (0.083) -0.312 ** (0.117)
Blue Collar 0.070 * (0.039) -0.054 (0.060)
Uses Seatbelts -0.139 *** (0.033) 0.133 *** (0.049)
Diet Carefully -0.077 ** (0.036) 0.074 (0.053)
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.137 0.127
Notes: For the U.S. sample, 895 observations in Models 1 and 2 and 449
observations in Model 3 (nonsmokers excluded). For the Massachusetts
sample, 843 observations in Models 1 and 2 and 487 observations in
Model 3. Coefficients represent dF/dx for unit changes in continuous
variables at the mean, or for discrete changes of d.v. from 0 to 1.
Standard errors are in parentheses.
* Significant at 90% confidence level.
** Significant at 95% confidence level.
*** Significant at 99% confidence level.
TABLE 5
Two-Stage Probit Selection Model for Smoking Decisions
United States, 1997
Stage 1: Stage 2:
Variable Start Smoking Quit Smoking
Age -0.034 * (0.020)
Age squared 0.00056 *** (0.00021)
Female -0.087 (0.092) -0.060 (0.138)
Nonwhite -0.249 * (0.136) -0.154 (0.226)
Education (years) 0.098 *** (0.029)
High School Dropout 0.642 *** (0.181)
Married -0.123 (0.093) 0.231 * (0.138)
Income (1000s) -0.00411 ** (0.00184) -0.00369 (0.00317)
Income unreported -0.201 (0.123) 0.221 (0.204)
Income top-code 0.267 (0.496) 0.008 (0.810)
Household Head 0.373 *** (0.141) 0.236 (0.277)
Cigarette Tax -0.0003 (0.0021) -0.0001 (0.0031)
Medicaid
Not Insured
Blue Collar
Uses Seatbelts
Diet Carefully
Total Mortality Risk -0.0061 ** (0.0016) 0.0048 (0.0031)
Expected Years of
Life Lost -0.023 *** (0.006) 0.033 *** (0.012)
Heard smoking "not bad" -0.257 *** (0.099)
Heard smoking causes
flat feet -0.313 (0.289)
Constant 0.681 *** (0.235) -2.165 *** (0.582)
Wald [chi square]
(16 d.f.) 50.31 ***
atanh [rho] -0.266
LR test of independent 0.00
Equations, [chi square]
(1 d.f.)
Massachusetts, 1998
Stage 1: Stage 2:
Variable Start Smoking Quit Smoking
Age 0.049 *** (0.017)
Age squared -0.00040 *** (0.00015)
Female -0.040 (0.097) -0.133 (0.107)
Nonwhite -0.200 (0.126) -0.017 (0.147)
Education (years) -0.017 (0.017)
High School Dropout 0.462 *** (0.141)
Married -0.060 (0.097) 0.039 * (0.113)
Income (1000s) 0.00080 (0.00245) 0.00055 (0.00271)
Income unreported -0.203 (0.126) 0.222 (0.154)
Income top-code -0.397 (0.249) -0.200 (0.288)
Household Head
Cigarette Tax
Medicaid 0.273 ** (0.111) 0.021 (0.120)
Not Insured 0.012 (0.220) -0.646 ** (0.274)
Blue Collar 0.213 * (0.119) -0.026 (0.130)
Uses Seatbelts -0.467 *** (0.103) 0.015 (0.131)
Diet Carefully -0.283 ** (0.112) -0.011 (0.126)
Total Mortality Risk -0.0047 *** (0.0016) 0.0037 * (0.0021)
Expected Years of
Life Lost -0.006 (0.004) 0.008 * (0.005)
Heard smoking "not bad" -0.072 (0.090)
Heard smoking causes
flat feet 0.071 (0.220)
Constant l.014 *** (0.199) -1.579 *** (0.586)
Wald [chi square]
(16 d.f.) 27.19 **
atanh [rho] 1.457 *
LR test of independent 3.50 *
Equations, [chi square]
(1 d.f.)
LR=likelihood ratio. See Table for sample sizes.
Standard errors are in parentheses.
* Significant at 90% confidence level.
** Significant at 95% confidence level.
*** Significant at 99% confidence level.