2006 presidential address water markets in the west: prices, trading, and contractual forms.
Brewer, Jedidiah ; Glennon, Robert ; Ker, Alan 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Farmers in the American West use roughly 80% of the region's
water, often in low-value or subsidized crops, such as alfalfa, cotton,
or rice. Farmers typically pay only for the pumping or conveyance costs
for the water and not for its scarcity value. (1) Accordingly, much
water use in agriculture has less value than if it were used in the
West's rapidly growing urban areas and in many environmental and
recreational uses. As a result, significant allocative gains arise if
some water is moved from agriculture to other sectors.
For example, in 1992, Ronald Griffin and Fred Boadu reported that
the value of water used in agriculture, capitalized over 50 yr, was
$300-$2,300 per acre-foot (approximately 326,000 gallons) in the Rio
Grande Valley of Texas. In contrast, urban water values, capitalized
over the same period, ranged from $6,500 to $21,000 per acre-foot.
Griffin and Boadu estimated that the average reallocation of water
produced net benefits of $10,000 per acre-foot. (2) For more
contemporary evidence, in California, an acre-foot used in the
semiconductor industry produces $980,000 in gross state revenue; that
same acre-foot used to grow cotton and alfalfa generates $60. (3)
Groundwater for farming near Marana, Pima County, Arizona, costs
approximately $27 per acre-foot, whereas the same water supplied by
Tucson Water, with an increasing block rate structure, will cost
customers from $479 to $3,267 per acre-foot. (4) In recent efforts to
secure water from southeastern California's Imperial Irrigation District (IID), San Diego offered $225 per acre-foot for water that IID
farmers paid $15.50. (5) Even more dramatically, IID farmers paid $13.50
per acre-foot in 2001, while a development near the South Rim of Grand
Canyon National Park was prepared to spend $20,000 per acre-foot to
deliver the same Colorado River water. (6) Although the costs of
treating and distributing water for urban residents tend to be far
greater than for rural and explain some of these price differences, the
size of the differentials indicates the higher marginal benefits
received by many urban versus rural users for water.
These disparities in the value of water have occasioned calls for
reallocation of water from lower value to higher value activities
through water marketing. Such trades can benefit both parties: farmers
receive more for their water than they could earn in agriculture and
cities (7) secure additional water at a lower cost than available
alternatives, such as desalination. The need to develop water markets
for the smooth, incremental transfer of water across sectors with
minimum transaction costs has increased over the past 20 yr due to brisk population growth, urbanization, increased environmental concerns, and a
rise in the economic contribution of services simultaneous with a
relative decline in agriculture.
As the legal summary in Section II will make clear, water markets
are more complex than markets for other resources, such as land.
Property rights to water are less complete due to the mobile and
uncertain nature of water supplies, the incomplete adjudication of water
rights in many watersheds, and the fact that individuals have usufruct rights subject to state oversight. (8) Further, because water rights
often involve sequential users of the same water, water trades that
change the location, nature, and/or timing of use, as is the case with
most agriculture-to-urban transfers, are regulated by the states in
order to limit harm to third parties, who might be adversely affected.
Third-party objections to water transfers can and have slowed, limited,
or blocked water transfers. (9) Even though the interconnected nature of
water rights has the potential to drive up transaction costs, water
transfers are taking place.
This article addresses the extent and nature of western water
marketing. It documents trading activity, identifies the sectors and
states involved, describes the contractual forms used, and illustrates
the trends in water transactions over time. Water markets as we define
them involve three different types of voluntary transactions: sales of
water rights, 1-yr (short-term) leases, and multiyear (long-term)
leases. Water transfers are affected by the timing of the transaction,
location, quantity of water, and priority of water right (discussed
below). We are primarily interested in three types of water trades:
agriculture-to-agriculture, agriculture-to-urban, and urban-to-urban for
the 12 western states. Our objective was to provide a comprehensive
portrait of how water markets have developed in response to the price
differences noted above.
Our data reveal a number of important features regarding water
markets: (1) prices are higher for agriculture-to-urban trades relative
to within-agriculture trades. (2) Agriculture is the origin of the
majority of transactions. (3) The annual flow of water traded and the
amount of water committed for transfer in a given year through long-term
contracts (long-term leases and sales) reveal very different patterns
regarding the movement of water. As measured by the amount of water
contractually committed in a given year, the volume of water traded in
the West is increasing over time, whereas, if measured by the annual
flow of water traded, the amount is not rising. (4) The number of market
transactions is increasing over time primarily due to
agriculture-to-urban trades. (5) Sales and multiyear leases are growing,
while 1-yr leases are not. (6) Whether measured as annual flow or
committed water, Arizona, California, and Texas are among the top four
states in the quantity of water traded. (10) And, (7)
agriculture-to-urban trades involve the majority of the water moved in
most states when using the committed measure, whereas
agriculture-to-agriculture trades involve the majority of water in most
states when using the annual flow measure.
We report annual water transfers from 1987 through 2005 as listed
in the trade journal, Water Strategist, a monthly publication that
details transactions, litigation, legislation, and other water marketing
activities. Self-advertised as "the only source of published
information on water transactions in the West," (11) the Water
Strategist publishes each month a "Transactions" section that
lists, by state, each water transfer that occurred. From the
publication, we can learn all or a subset of the following: the year of
the transfer; the acquirer and supplier of the water (both labeled
variously as municipality, developer, company, irrigator, farmer,
rancher, conservancy district, irrigation district, state, federal
agency, etc.); the amount of water transferred; the proposed use of the
water; and, if applicable, the terms, such as the price and nature
(lease or sale) of the contract. Our data set only includes transactions
reported by the Water Strategist and no doubt misses some transactions.
These are most likely to include within-organization (within-irrigation
district) short-term trades. (12) Even so, Water Strategist listings are
the most comprehensive available and, hence, capture the general pattern
of water trading. (13)
In Section II, we offer an overview of water rights in the West and
consider some critical legal and regulatory issues that affect water
markets. Section III discusses issues raised in the economics literature
that relate to water transfers, while Section IV addresses general data
collection methodological issues and Section V explains how we measured
the volume of water traded using a "committed" variable.
Section VI presents price trends in western water markets, and Section
VII offers an overview of the markets with data on the contractual forms
used, the categories of trades, the number of transfers across time, the
changes in contract type over time, and differences in the markets
across states. Finally, Section VIII offers a summary of some key
findings.
II. APPROPRIATIVE WATER RIGHTS AND WATER MARKETS
To operate properly, any market requires reasonably secure property
rights. Unfortunately, water rights are weaker than those for most
resources due to water's physical characteristics and unique legal
status. Because water moves, surface water cannot be bounded or
partitioned easily across claimants and uses. Surface water often is
hydrologically connected to groundwater, which also migrates and is
unobserved. (14) Moreover, simultaneous and sequential users of water
make exclusion difficult and create numerous interdependencies.
Consequently, the trade of water can inadvertently affect multiple
parties.
In western states, individuals do not own water as they might own
land. The state owns the water, which it holds in trust for its
citizens. Individuals only hold usufruct rights to the water, subject to
the requirement that the use be beneficial and reasonable and to
oversight by the state in monitoring transfers to ensure that they are
consistent with the public interest. (15) Accordingly, water rights
appear to have less protection or be more fragile than most other
property rights. (16)
In general, western surface water rights are based on the prior
appropriation doctrine that allows rights holders to withdraw a certain
amount of water from a natural water course for private beneficial
purposes on land remote from the point of diversion. (17) Ownership of
water is allocated through the rule of first possession or priority of
claim. (18) Those with the earliest water claims have the highest
priority, and those with subsequent claims have lower priority or junior
claims. As such, there is a ladder of rights on a stream, ranging from
highest in priority to the lowest. This allocative mechanism ranks
competing claimants based on priority in order to ration water during
times of drought. Lower priority water rights carry greater risk in
water transfers because of possible shortfalls and accordingly are often
of less value in water markets.
Failure by rights holders to continue to use their water may result
in the rights being lost through the doctrines of abandonment or
forfeiture. (19) These doctrines create a perverse incentive for rights
holders to use all their water. In many states, farmers who conserve
water receive no benefit, as the water saved will go to the
next-priority user on the river. As a result, farmers are motivated to
devote large quantities of water to grow low-value crops. Until the
development of water markets and recognition by state legislatures that
conservation measures are consistent with beneficial use, farmers could
do little else with their excess water. California eliminated this
disincentive to conserve with a statute that provides that, when the use
of water is reduced through conservation, the conserved water may be
sold, leased, or transferred. (20)
Because appropriative rights can be separated from the land and
sold or leased, they can form the basis for private water trades. (21)
Even so, the process can be complicated. Appropriative rights are
measured in terms of diversion, but transfers of water that change the
point of diversion, timing, or nature of use are usually based on the
amount of water consumed. (22) Measuring transfers by consumption is
important because it protects the rights of subsequent downstream
diverters who have come to rely on the return flow from the first
diversion. Hence, limiting trades to consumptive use reduces third-party
effects on downstream diverters. However, calculating consumptive use is
more difficult, thus driving up the transaction costs of trade. (23)
Water markets also are affected by differential water quality,
especially cross-sector trades from agriculture to urban. Urban
utilities generally prefer and will pay more for high-quality water that
has less need for additional treatment. Within-sector trades may be
easier because the level of water quality demanded and supplied may be
more homogeneous. As we will see, municipalities and irrigators
routinely transfer water among themselves.
Water markets also depend on conveyance opportunities, and the lack
thereof can significantly reduce arbitrage possibilities. (24) This
requirement includes access to canals and aqueducts, as well as to
rivers or streams whereby water can be released by one diverter and
appropriated by another.
Finally, water markets are generally local or, at most, statewide
markets. There is little private water trading across state lines due to
a variety of state regulatory restrictions and to the costs associated
with transporting a heavy commodity (an acre-foot of water weighs 1,358
tons) to great distances. The price data bear out this situation by
revealing the large arbitrage opportunities that exist among neighboring states.
III. WATER MARKETING IN THE ECONOMICS LITERATURE
A large economics literature has addressed water reallocation and
the potential for water markets, and therefore, we only acknowledge
representative articles. It is generally accepted that sharp differences
in marginal water values among agricultural, urban, and environmental
uses exist. Some authors, however, express puzzlement regarding the
comparatively limited extent of voluntary exchange (Young 1986). One
response has been to focus on the special characteristics of water that
raise the costs of defining and enforcing water rights. These unique
attributes result in pecuniary and technological externalities when
water is transferred to a new location. Young and Haveman (1985) and
Hanemann (2005) pointed to the simultaneous and sequential use of water,
its mobility, its unobservability (groundwater), as well as the
variability and thus uncertainty of the supply. These factors link
parties so that an action by one likely impacts others, thus increasing
measurement and bounding costs (making it difficult to clearly assign
property rights) and thereby raising transaction costs.
Related third-party effects from water transfers arise from a
number of technological factors, including the hydrological and
geological connection between surface water and groundwater. If farmers
sell surface water and increase their groundwater withdrawal as a
substitute, it may increase pumping costs, cause subsidence, and lower
water quality (by salt water intrusion, e.g.) for other extractors
(Glennon 2002). Conversely, a farmer who invests in ditch-lining and
similar conservation actions may reduce groundwater recharge to the
detriment of other groundwater users (Knapp et al. 2003). Groundwater is
typically a common pool with very complex management requirements
(Provencher 1993; Provencher and Burt 1993).
Another technical externality arises from lost return flows when
water is shipped out of the watershed. This effect occurs not only with
reduced groundwater recharge but also when upstream sales diminish
downstream surface water. When a party diverts water from a stream, some
water will be consumed but much of it (perhaps 50% or more) will
percolate back to the stream for use by others. When the diverted water
is sold, however, this return flow may be blocked. Chang and Griffin
(1992) pointed out that water markets have formed where such effects are
small, either due to a limited number of potential third parties or to a
unique geography that makes return flow easy to quantify, track, and
measure. Johnson, Gisser, and Werner (1981) argued that restricting
transfers to consumptive use will limit these downstream effects. (25)
Besides technical externalities, there also can be pecuniary
effects if the agricultural economy is diminished from water transfers.
Hanak (2003) discussed both pecuniary and technological third-party
effects in examining county restrictions in California on water
transfers. Government tax revenues may shrink if farmers fallow land or
nonprofit entities (including municipalities) purchase water rights or
secure long-term water leases. Further, rural political influence may be
lost when large water transfers are made, populations migrate away, and
there is no clear mechanism for compensation. Political opposition to
water transfers over these issues can arise even when the actual costs
are likely to be fairly small. (26) Similar equity issues associated
with water trades are addressed by Charney and Woodard (1990), Howe,
Lazo, and Weber (1990b), Howitt (1994), and Howe and Goemans (2003).
(27) These distributional effects increase opposition to water markets
(Haddad 2000, 33-48).
To reduce the third-party effects of water trades, states have
established review processes for transfers. Regulatory requirements,
however, can impact trades. The analysis by Howe, Boggs, and Butler
(1990a) shows a wide range of transaction costs in nine case studies of
water transfers. They found that costs tend to be smaller if: (1) larger
amounts are involved, (2) there is less opposition to the transfer, and
(3) the water right has a higher priority. Similarly, Colby (1990) found
that regulatory review in some states could significantly delay the
process and raise transaction costs. (28)
While some institutional structures can retard trading, others can
promote it by reducing transaction costs. Notable is the Colorado-Big
Thompson Project (C-BT) and the associated Northern Colorado Water
Conservancy District (NCWCD) whose institutional structure facilitates
intertemporal and intersectional water trades. Carey and Sunding (2001)
compared the C-BT with the California Central Valley Project (CVP). With
a much larger service area, the CVP has multiple water districts with
differing regulations and procedures for transfers. Whereas internal
district water trades are customary and of low cost, interdistrict water
transfers within the CVP are more complicated with lengthy approval
processes. One issue involves environmental concerns when water is
shipped north to south through the Sacramento Delta. In part because of
these conditions, most trades are within CVP districts and involve
short-term leases. There are relatively fewer water sales or other
cross-district transactions. In contrast to the CVP, within the C-BT,
environmental conditions are more homogeneous, and there is an active
water sales market among irrigators and between agricultural and urban
users. Water allocations are uniformly defined and proportionally
adjusted as water supplies vary; trading rules are the same; and because
there is only a single water district within the C-BT, all return flow
effects are internalized within the organization, facilitating
adjustments to minimize any third-party losses from a trade. (29)
Despite problems of developing water markets, most of the economics
literature emphasizes the gains from expanding water trading. (30)
Anderson and Snyder (1997) summarized the overall benefits. Howitt
(1994) pointed to the role of the water bank established by California
during 1991 in mitigating the effects of drought. Colby, McGinnis, and
Rait (1991) examined the use of voluntary transfers to augment instream
flows and improve habitat in the Truckee-Carson drainage of Northern
Nevada. (31) Howe, Schurmeier, and Shaw (1986) outlined a range of
benefits of greater reliance on water markets.
Four recent papers use Water Strategist data to outline trends in
water market activity in the western United States (Brookshire et al.
2004; Brown 2006; Howitt and Hansen 2005; Loomis et al. 2003). (32)
Loomis et al. used price and quantity data from the trade journal for 5
yr (1995-1999) to evaluate the extent of water sales and leasing from
agriculture to accomplish environmental objectives in nine western
states. They concluded that water markets are more likely to be a means
of facilitating the smoother reallocation of water than reliance on
(nonvoluntary) regulatory reallocation.
Brookshire et al. used price data between 1990 and 2001 from 608
trades to compare the relative development of water markets in the
Central Arizona Water Conservancy District (CAWCD), the NCWCD, and the
Middle Rio Grande Conservancy District (MRGCD) in New Mexico. The
authors found that water trading is most active and routine in the
NCWCD, followed by the MRGCD and the CAWCD. Institutional details
regarding the nature of water rights and the associated transaction
costs of trading explain the differential roles of water markets across
the three regions. Howitt and Hansen examined transfers between 1999 and
2002 across 14 states to determine the relative volumes and prices for
water rights sales and water leases. They concluded that leases account
for 90% of the volume of transactions (as measured by annual flow) but
that sales prices are substantially higher than lease prices. They found
a mean implicit capitalization rate (ICR) for lease to sales prices at
6.6%, which is slightly below a standard commercial capitalization rate.
In examining this observation, the authors suggest that sales prices are
being driven up in order to mitigate the risk of water shortfalls during
drought.
Brown's study is most similar to the present one. He analyzed 1,380 water transactions between 1990 and 2003 in 14 states. (33) He
argued that more water is traded via leases than through sales.
According to his data, the number of leases grew over the 14-yr period,
roughly doubling in number, whereas the number of sales did not.
Further, leases involved larger amounts of water on average than did
sales. The most active lease transactions involved large
government-funded projects, such as the Central Arizona Project and the
State Water Project in California. Municipal leases of water grew
relative to those for agricultural and environmental uses after 1998. In
terms of sales, most purchases of water rights were by municipalities
from irrigators.
With regard to prices, Brown reported that lease prices for
municipal use were higher than those for agricultural and environmental
leases but that sales prices for municipal water were only slightly
higher than those for irrigation water. Both were greater than
environmental sales prices. Brown also computed ICRs, finding a median
ICR of 1.94%, well below that reported by Howitt and Hansen and any
standard commercial capitalization rate. He argued that the low ICR
reflects both low lease prices in agriculture and high prices paid by
water rights purchasers. Even so, Brown found that lease prices have
been rising in real terms since the late 1990s but sales prices have had
no clear trend. These studies describe an active water market,
especially through leasing water for trades within agriculture.
In the next section, we present more comprehensive data from 1987
to 2005 for 3,232 water transfers in 12 semiarid western states. Unlike
the above studies, we break leases into single- and multiyear
transactions and analyze them separately with respect to volumes and
prices. In comparing leases and sales amounts with respect to prices, we
focus on sales and 1-yr leases, rather than a composite of leases as has
been done in other studies. This is important because multiyear leases
can have much higher prices than 1-yr leases and thereby alter any ICR
calculations. In addition to examining the annual flow of water in each
transaction, we calculate the water committed through sales and
multiyear leases. This approach is important because the committed
measure substantially changes the assessment of the quantities conveyed
by contract type across sectors and across time.
For example, in our data, 79% of all leases are for 1 yr (771) and
they account for 91% of all leased water, measured by annual flow. If,
however, the amounts of water obligated through multiyear leases are
considered, the amounts involved in 1-yr leases fall to only 47% of the
total water transferred by leasing agreements. Accordingly, it is
important to consider the separate role of each contract type and how it
facilitates the movement of water from one party to another. Because of
the number of transactions included and the approach we adopt, our study
yields the most complete view of the development of water markets in the
American West.
IV. DATA COLLECTION METHODOLOGY
To assemble our water market data, we recorded every transfer
listed in the Water Strategist from January 1987 through December 2005
for Arizona, California, Colorado, Idaho, Montana, New Mexico, Nevada,
Oregon, Texas, Utah, Wyoming, and Washington. Two of the most important
variables were the original and the proposed use of each transfer. We
classified these uses as agriculture, urban (municipal and industrial),
or environmental. This classification system provided for nine possible
combinations. (34) Because we are particularly interested in water
reallocation, we focus on cross-sector trades, from agriculture-to-urban
and within-sector trades from agriculture-to-agriculture and
urban-to-urban.
For the majority of transfers, the Water Strategist explicitly
indicated both the original and the ultimate purpose of the water and
briefly described the details of each transaction. In cases where the
entry did not explicitly state the nature of use before or after the
transaction, it often was easy to determine the origination and
destination uses from the context of the description. For a few
transactions where the entry did not include the original and ultimate
uses and the transaction description was not informative, we developed
rules for classifying these transactions. (35)
According to our rules of thumb, we classified a use as
agricultural if the name of the lessor, lessee, seller, or buyer was an
irrigator, an irrigation district, a water district, a farmer, a ranch,
a canal company, a ditch company, or an individual. (36) Similarly, we
designated a use as agricultural if the description of the transaction
stated that the water was employed in agriculture, if the water was
provided by land fallowing, or if the description discussed widespread
farming in the district from which the water was supplied.
We classified a party as environmental if it was a state department
of fish and wildlife or a nature conservancy. The U.S. Bureau of
Reclamation, generally an agricultural water supplier, was labeled
environmental when it acted to improve or maintain instream flows, to
help fish stocks, or to preserve water quality levels or engaged in
other similar activities. When a party was a water conservation or
conservancy district, we designated the transfer as agricultural, urban,
or a combination agriculture and urban trade, not environmental. Most
water conservation or conservancy districts are primarily involved in
agricultural activities or in some cases urban and/or a combination of
agriculture and urban.
Last, in cases where either the Water Strategist did not explicitly
discuss the use of the water or its description was too vague, we
assigned urban when cities, townships, municipal water districts,
developers, manufacturing and mining companies, golf courses, and
landscape irrigators were involved.
Despite our best efforts to develop classification rules that would
reliably identify transactors, the information, in some cases, was
simply incomplete. These transfers lacking an identifiable origin or
destination use were relatively rare, accounting for 85 (2.6%) of the
3,317 transactions in our data set. They are excluded from our data set,
and thus, the tables and analyses provided below are based on the
remaining 3,232 observations. (37)
Finally, a single transaction occasionally involved multiple
transfers and sectors. For example, an entry might include an irrigator
and a city that transferred a combined 10,000 acre-feet of water to
another city. In this case, the destination of the transfer is clearly
urban, but the origination came from agriculture and urban. In many
instances, the description included a breakdown that allowed us to
identify the sectors. For example, if the irrigator and city each
transferred 5,000 acre-feet, we noted two transactions, one of 5,000
acre-feet provided from agriculture-to-urban and the other of 5,000
acre-feet from urban-to-urban. If the information did not allow use to
make such attributions, we classified the transfers as
"combination" transfers. Of the 3,317 transfers in our data
set, 161 (4.9%) were combination transfers. (38)
V. MEASURING THE VOLUME OF WATER TRADED
We measure and report the volume of water traded in two ways. The
measure used in the literature is the annual flow of water as listed in
the Water Strategist. Unfortunately, this annual flow measure reflects
only the amount of water transferred in the initial year of the
transaction. For example, a transaction in the Water Strategist
typically states that 1,000 acre-feet was leased for a specified number
of years or sold. The annual flow measure would only record the 1,000
acre-feet transferred in the year the transaction originated. By this
measure, a sale or multiyear lease of 1,000 acre-feet is identical to a
1-yr lease. This approach substantially biases downward the impact of
multiyear leases and sales on the volume of water traded. An alternative
and perhaps more intuitive measure would annually record water traded
through multiyear leases and sales for the duration of the contract (in
perpetuity for sales). This measure, however, would be misrepresentative in our sample, because any sales and multiyear leases consummated before
1987 (at the start of the data set) would necessarily be ignored, thus
possibly creating an artificial upward trend.
Accordingly, we introduce a committed water variable that avoids
the undercounting associated with the annual flow variable and any
downward bias early in the sample. The committed variable includes all
transfers that originated in a given year. It projects the annual flow
forward for the term of the transaction, that is, 5 yr for a 5-yr lease
or in perpetuity for a sale, and then discounts the flow by 5% per year
and sums the series to arrive at a single committed amount of water
analogous to a present value of a series of annual payments. (39) As we
show below, sales and multiyear leases are an important part of water
markets, and this procedure better reflects the actual amounts of water
involved than has been reported previously. (40)
VI. PRICE TRENDS: EVIDENCE OF REALLOCATION PRESSURES
Of the 3,232 transactions in our data set with information on the
transacting parties, amounts, and nature of use, a smaller number,
2,154, had price data. (41) Of these, 1,836 involved the three
classifications of primary interest: within-sector,
agriculture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban transactions and
across-sector, agriculture-to-urban trades.
We converted all prices into dollars per acre-foot of water for
comparison across time and contract type. Prices for 1-yr transactions
were easily presented in per acre-foot terms. For example, if 1,000
acre-feet of water was leased for 1 yr for a total price of $100,000,
then the per acre-foot price was $100. Prices for sales could be handled
in two ways. First, consider a sale of 1,000 acre-feet of water for a
total price of $2 million. The per acre-foot price is $2,000. This
price, however, is not directly comparable to the 1-yr lease price
because the sale commits a flow of water to the buyer in perpetuity.
Therefore, we construct a second price which is analogous to a 1-yr
lease price. By discounting quantity flows, using the same methodology
as for determining the present value of a perpetual bond, we calculate a
single committed quantity. With this discounted quantity, we convert the
total sales price into a per acre-foot price that is directly comparable
to a per acre-foot, 1-yr lease price. In the example of a sale of 1,000
acre-feet of water for a total price of $2 million, using 5% to discount
the quantity flows leads to discounted sales price of $100 per acre-foot
(multiyear lease prices are converted in the same manner one would use
to find the present value of a multiyear bond). Finally, rather than
assuming a discount rate, we took the mean (or median) sales and mean
(or median) 1-yr lease price and found the discount rate that equates
the two. This computed discount rate is termed the ICR.
Table 1 reports mean and median water prices for
agriculture-to-urban and agriculture-to-agriculture leases (1-yr and
multiyear combined) and sales. The prices are per acre-foot, and the
amounts are the annual flows during the first year of the contract as
described in the Water Strategist. As shown, the annual mean and median
sale and lease prices for agriculture-to-urban transactions are
significantly higher than are agriculture-to-agriculture trades (using a
Wilcoxon signed-rank test at a 5% level of significance). (42) This
condition in part indicates the benefits of out-of-sector water
transfers. (43) Other factors, such as more senior rights that may be
associated with agriculture-to-urban transfers and higher wheeling
costs, also explain the higher prices. Further, because sales involve
the transfer of water rights and a perpetual claim on water flows as
compared to leases, which involve a shorter term (often 1 yr) transfer
of the right to use water, sales prices will be higher than lease
prices. (44)
Figure 1 plots the annual median sales price per acre-foot from
1987 through 2005 for agricultural-to-agricultural and
agricultural-to-urban trades. As illustrated, the price differences
between agriculture-to-urban and agriculture-to-agriculture water sales
have been pronounced and growing since 1995. Using the paired annual
differences and calculating a Wilcoxon signed-rank test statistic, we
find that the annual median sales prices are statistically higher for
agricultural-to-urban trades relative to agricultural-to-agricultural
trades at a 5% significance level. Similar pricing patterns and test
results are revealed if committed water is used rather than annual flows
in calculating the per acre-foot prices.
Figure 2 plots the annual median combined lease price from 1987 to
2005. Consistent with sales prices, lease prices for urban uses are
significantly higher than are those for agricultural uses (using a
Wilcoxon signed-rank test at a 5% significance level). The low number of
leases explains the relatively noisy time series. We report the combined
(discounted) multiyear lease and 1-yr lease prices because the latter
dominate in agricultural transactions, whereas multiyear leases are
common in agriculture-to-urban transactions. (45)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Table 2 presents median prices by sector and contract type for each
of the 12 western states for 1-yr leases and sales. Also calculated is
the implicit conversion rate, ICR. The "*" denotes where the
number of sales or 1-yr leases with price data in the given state is
less than 10, whereas "n/a" denotes where there were no sales
and/or leases with price data for that given state. Because multiyear
leases would require discounting, which implies an ICR, and we are
interested in finding it, we only use 1-yr lease prices to compare to
the sales price. (46)
While the median prices vary across states and sectors for both
sales and 1-yr leases, there is significantly more variation across
states than across sectors. This phenomenon is illustrated by the ICRs.
Across states, ICRs for all-sector trades vary from a low of 0.5%
(Colorado) to a high of 8.1% (Montana). By contrast, the ICR for
agriculture-to-agriculture transfers is 0.9% compared to 1.6%
agriculture-to-urban transfers. The variation in price across the states
reflects differences in demand and supply characteristics, transaction
type, as well as transaction costs--all of which are primarily state
driven (e.g., population, weather, water endowments, conveyance
potential, political and legal institutions) and the regulatory
restrictions that prevent arbitrage across the states. (47)
To further explore price patterns, Table 3 presents the median
prices for 1-yr leases and sales and the corresponding ICRs over time.
As sales prices have risen and lease prices have fallen, the ICRs have
dramatically decreased over time. A sign test reveals that there is a
significant downward trend. Sales of water rights, which carry more
security and are used more in agriculture-to-urban trades, are in
growing demand relative to short-term leases, which are used more in
agriculture-to-agriculture transactions.
In summary, the price data reveal that (1) state water markets are
quite different as reflected in the varying state prices and (2) there
are few arbitrage activities across the states to narrow those
differences. While state price variations can be explained in part by
sector-specific dominance in one state versus another, the variance of
prices across states is much greater than the variance across sectors
within a state. The price data also indicate a growing premium to
purchase water rights rather than lease water. Finally, the price data
demonstrate that urban users pay considerably more in purchasing and
leasing water relative to agricultural users.
VII. WESTERN WATER TRANSFERS
A. Contractual Form
As we have shown, in responding to opportunities to move water
within and across sectors in response to price differentials, various
contractual forms are possible: 1-yr leases, multiyear leases, and
sales. Although leases involve the right to use water and not the
transfer of the water right, some can be quite long as indicated in
Table 4, which lists leases by their duration. As shown, most leases
have short terms, with nearly 80% being 1 yr or less and over 85% being
5 yr or less. Some leases, however, approximate sales with terms of 50
or more years.
Table 5 provides additional information on the relative importance
of each type of contract in terms of number and amount of water moved
(committed and annual flow) for the three sectors. (48)
The data in Table 5 show that most agriculture-to-urban transfers
occur through sales that involve comparatively small amounts, 837
acre-feet on average as measured by the annual flow and 16,734 acre-feet
on average as measured by the amount committed. (49)
In part, as noted earlier, this pattern reflects the large number
of small transactions that take place in Colorado within the C-BT. Sales
occur less frequently for agriculture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban
transactions. Even if we omit Colorado sales and recalculate, average
sales size is 6,273 acre-feet (annual flow); sales transfers typically
are smaller than those for long-term or 1-yr leases in
agriculture-to-urban transactions. (50)
Within-sector, urban-to-urban transfers have more permanent sales
(269) than leases (146), but the average sale size is small, at 2,251
acre-feet, compared to the average size of 1-yr and multiyear leases, at
40,791 and 13,877 acre-feet, respectively. Over four times the amount of
water measured by annual flows is transferred between cities and from
businesses or mining companies by 1-yr leases than by multiyear leases
and sales. When committed amounts are considered, however, sales and
multiyear leases involve over ten times the amount of water traded
through short-term leases.
The data in Table 5 also reveal the importance of 1-yr leases for
balancing short-term water demand and supply conditions among
agricultural and urban users. One-year leases were used to temporarily
move 3,25 l, 123 acre-feet from agriculture to cities and 4,247,688
acre-feet to cities from other urban users. Transaction sizes (annual
flow) for 1-yr leases in agriculture-to-urban trades also are large,
averaging 19,704 acre-feet, more than double the size of multiyear
leases and almost 24 times the mean size of each sale. These
transactions may be large because they do not imply a permanent loss of
water in the watershed. Multiyear leases, which involve longer term
commitments of water, are less common than are 1-yr leases, 86 compared
to 165, and are smaller as measured by annual flow. Of the multiyear
leases, 18 are for less than 5 yr and 68 are for more than 5 yr.
Agriculture-to-agriculture trades usually occur (240) through a
lease, generally for 1 yr. Like cross-sector leases,
agriculture-to-agriculture leases involve much larger amounts of water
(28,628 acre-feet) than do water sales as measured by the annual flow.
Farmers trade water among themselves routinely using short-term leases
to meet temporary shortfalls or for other transitory market reasons.
Many of these transactions take place locally often within the
irrigation district to which both farmers belong. (51) As noted earlier,
these transactions can involve water of lower quality and with lower
priority appropriative water rights than required for
agriculture-to-urban transactions. Sales within agriculture are numerous
but generally involve small amounts of water with a mean transaction
size of 1,959 acre-feet (annual flow), although the average committed
size is much larger at 39,175 acre-feet.
Table 6 summarizes all water transfers from 1987 through 2005 by
contract type. Although sales account for 67% of all transactions, they
involve just 13% of the water traded as measured by annual flow.
Considering perpetual commitments, however, raises the amount of water
involved to 58% of the water traded. Leases account for only 30% of
transactions but transfer 83% of water as measured by annual flow.
Considering committed water, however, lowers the amount of water traded
by leases to 36%.
B. Aggregate Transfer Data by Category
Table 7 provides a comprehensive overview of 3,232 water transfers
in the 12 western states between 1987 and 2005. (52) Although we are
primarily interested in agriculture-to-agriculture,
agriculture-to-urban, and urban-to-urban trades, the table provides
information for all major sector transactions.
As shown in Table 7, agriculture is the origin of 78% of all trades
and 60% of all water traded, as measured by annual flows, and 54% of all
water committed. Agriculture-to-urban trades are by far the most
numerous, accounting for 56% of all transfers and involve 5.5 million
acre-feet or 18% of all water transferred as measured by annual flows
and 39.7 million acre-feet or 29% of committed water.
Agriculture-to-agriculture transactions represent 15% of all trades and
involve 23% of the water transferred as measured by annual flow and 12%
of the committed water.
The data reveal a significant movement of water out of agriculture
in response to the price differentials discussed earlier. Urban-to-urban
transactions account for 14% of the number of transfers and involve 18%
of annual flows and 19% of water committed. If these two major
within-sector categories are combined, they comprise 29% of water
trades, 41% of annual flows, and 31% of committed water. The difference
between the committed and the annual flow measures confirms what was
found in Table 5: within-sector trades rely more on 1-yr leases, while
out-of-sector trades rely more on sales and long-term leases. These
transfers, particularly agriculture-to-urban transactions, are more
numerous but comparatively small. These transfers typically involve
changes in the location, timing, and/or nature of water use, all of
which can have important effects on other users. These types of
transactions are significantly more controversial and generally require
state regulatory review. Because larger transfers are more likely to
affect third parties, agriculture-to-urban trades are smaller, roughly
one-fourth to one-fifth the size of agriculture-to-agriculture and
urban-to-urban transfers. Smaller transfers likely have fewer external
effects.
C. Water Transfers across Time
Figure 3 details water market activity across time. The figure
shows that: (1) the total number of water transfers is increasing
(statistically significant), (2) agriculture-to-urban trades are also
rising (statistically significant), and (3) neither
agriculture-to-agriculture trades nor urban-to-urban trades show a
discernable trend (statistically insignificant). Given that Colorado
dominates the number of transactions, we note that the trends remain the
same but are less pronounced when Colorado is removed.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 4 shows the quantities of water transferred across time.
Importantly, if we measure the total quantity of water transferred by
annual flow, there is no statistically significant upward trend, whereas
if we measure the water traded by total water contractually committed,
there is a statistically significant upward trend (at a 5% significance
level). (53) The rising trend of the committed measure is capturing the
fact that the number of sales is increasing over time (see Figure 7).
Figures 5 and 6 illustrate the water traded over the 19-yr period
by sector for annual flow and committed water measures, respectively.
With respect to Figure 5, we find no significant trend in
agriculture-to-urban trades, a significant downward trend in
within-agricultural trades, and no significant trend in urban-to-urban
trades. In Figure 6, however, where committed water is reflected, we
find a significant upward trend in agriculture-to-urban trades and no
significant trend for within-agricultural trades or urban-to-urban
trades. As shown, water is increasingly moving out of agriculture and
into urban uses over time reflecting the widening price differentials
between urban and agricultural uses (see Figure 1).
D. Contract Type over Time
Figure 7 describes how the total number of transfers moves over
time by contractual form. We find the following: (1) a significant
upward trend in total transactions, (2) a significant upward trend in
sales transactions, (3) a statistically significant upward trend in
multiyear leases, and (4) nonsignificant trend in 1-yr leases. (54) This
is consistent with the decreasing ICRs over time found in Table 3.
E. Analysis of Water Transfers by State
Table 8 outlines the number of water market transactions by state
and by contract form from 1987 through 2005. Colorado dominates in terms
of total market transactions, reflecting the institutional advantages of
the C-BT, where most of the transactions are sales. Other active market
states are California, Texas, Arizona, Nevada, and New Mexico. Within
California and Texas, short-term leases are the most prevalent contract
but multiyear leases and sales are also important. In Arizona, Nevada,
and New Mexico, sales are common, but, not surprisingly, Montana and
Wyoming, the least urban of the 12 western states, have the fewest water
sales.
Table 9 provides a detailed breakout of water transfer patterns for
agriculture-to-agriculture, agriculture-to-urban, and urban-to-urban
transactions within each of the western states. The table shows the
relative percentages of the amounts traded by origination and
destination classifications for both annual flow and committed measures
within the three categories. For example, within Arizona, 15% of the
annual flow of water transferred was in agriculture-to-urban trades,
while 46% and 39% were part of agriculture-to-agriculture and
urban-to-urban trades, respectively. Using the committed water measure,
31% of Arizona's traded water was part of agricultural-to-urban
trades, 37% in agriculture-to-agriculture trades, and 32% in
urban-to-urban transfers. By either measure, within-sector trades
clearly are the most common type of transaction in Arizona.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Using the annual flow measure, more water is traded within these
three categories in Arizona than in any other state. This may reflect
Arizona's reliance on groundwater and the clustering of agriculture
and urban areas near the same groundwater basins. With respect to the
committed measure, however, Texas trades the most water. While in most
states, the total committed water is usually double or triple the total
annual flow, in Texas the total committed is almost 15 times greater,
reflecting the importance of sales and multiyear leases in that state
for moving most water. In Texas, the establishment of the Edwards
Aquifer Authority in 1993 created an opportunity for urban interests,
particularly in the San Antonio area to purchase long-term rights to
water (Glennon 2002).
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Aside from Arizona and Texas, California accounts for the next
largest amount of water marketed in these categories. California has a
broad range of transactions with agriculture-to-urban trades the largest
activity. This situation reflects the efforts of Los Angeles and San
Diego, especially through the Metropolitan Water District of Southern
California, to secure agricultural water to meet growing urban demand.
Colorado is heavily dominated by agriculture-to-urban trades, but the
overall amounts are less than in Arizona, California, or Texas.
Additionally, even though the amounts are smaller, agriculture-to-urban
trades are important in Montana, Nevada, Utah, and Washington, whereas
agriculture-to-agriculture trades are most important in Idaho, Oregon,
and Wyoming.
Table 10 provides a cross-state comparison of how much each state
contributed to the total amount of water transferred in each of the
three classifications for both measures. Notice that the committed water
measure only doubles the annual flow quantity in
agriculture-to-agriculture trades because of the prevalence of
short-term leases in agricultural trades, whereas in the other
classifications, the committed measures are almost five times the annual
flow quantities. With respect to agriculture-to-urban trades, Arizona,
California, and Texas lead the way. When using the annual flow measure,
California accounts for 45% of the water traded but falls to 13% when
using the committed measure, reflecting California's propensity to
engage in 1-yr leases. Conversely, Texas only accounts for 13% of the
water transferred when using the annual flow measure but increases to
36% when using the committed measure. With respect to
agriculture-to-agriculture trades, Arizona and California dominate using
either measure. Finally, Arizona, California, and Texas make up the
large majority of urban-to-urban trades. Note that when using the annual
flow measure, Texas makes up 12% of the water traded but increases to
44% when the committed measure is used, again reflecting the reliance
upon sales and long-term leases in the state.
VIII. CONCLUDING REMARKS
Relative price data reflect the growing pressure to move water from
traditional uses in agriculture to meet increased urban demand. This
paper has presented a new data set that documents the growth of water
trading between 1987 and 2005 for 12 western states in response to
shifting demand. Data for the analysis come from the Water Strategist, a
monthly publication that details transactions, litigation, legislation,
and other water market activities in the West. The data reveal a number
of important features regarding water market development.
First, the data confirm the widely held belief that prices are
higher for agriculture-to-urban trades versus within-agriculture trades,
in part, reflecting the differences in marginal values between the two
uses. Not only are prices higher for urban use but also they are growing
relative to agricultural use over time. Presently, approximately 80% of
the West's diverted water supply is employed in agriculture, part
at least, for comparatively lower use values than in urban areas. The
economically and statistically significant price differences reported
above suggest the potential for large economic gains from reallocating
water through a market mechanism. The data reveal that markets are
responding. Agriculture is the origin of the majority of trades, and the
number of agriculture-to-urban transactions is rising over time, whereas
the number of agriculture-to-agriculture transfers shows no such
pattern.
Second, there is a pronounced trend for the acquisition of water
for longer periods of time, either through multiyear leases or through
sales of the water right. Sales are the most often used contractual
form, and the number of sales is increasing over time. The number of
multiyear leases is increasing over time as well, while the number of
1-yr leases is not growing. This trend is likely due in part to the
security of water supplies long-term contracts provide. Buyers are
willing to pay a premium for water rights.
Third, the growing importance of sales and multiyear leases in
water transactions underscores the need to consider the amounts of water
obligated over time rather than examining only annual flows in assessing
the quantities of water traded as is commonly done in the literature.
Considering committed water, we find that more water is transferred and
the direction of trading is very different than if the focus is on
annual flows. While the latter suggests that most water is transferred
within agriculture, the committed variable reveals that more is
transferred from agriculture-to-urban and through urban-to-urban trades.
This difference arises because most agriculture-to-agriculture transfers
are through 1-yr leases, whereas agriculture-to-urban and urban-to-urban
transfers are primarily through sales and multiyear leases.
Finally, the data reveal considerable differences in water trading
across the states. Some of this pattern is due to differences in water
supply and demand characteristics. The states with the most rapidly
growing urban populations tend to exhibit the largest number and
greatest amounts of water in agriculture-to-urban transactions, and the
states with the smallest urban growth have the lowest amounts of water
traded. We have noted, however, that water rights are less secure than
for other assets and that, because of the interconnected nature of water
use and trading among parties, each state has a regulatory structure to
review and approve market transactions, especially those that involve
changes in the nature, timing, and location of use, as is the case for
most agriculture-to-urban transfers. The nature of property rights to
water and the regulatory review process varies across the states.
Accordingly, some of the interstate differences in observed water
transactions are due to differences in transaction costs associated with
varying property rights and regulatory requirements. Identifying and
quantifying those factors is an important next step in analyzing the
development of water markets in the West.
REFERENCES
Adams, J., D. Crews, and R. Cummings. "The Sale and Leasing of
Water Rights in Western States: An Update to Mid-2003." Working
Paper No. 2004-4, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State
University, 2004.
Anderson, T., and R. N. Johnson. "The Problem of Instream
Flows." Economic Inquiry, 24, 1986, 535-53.
Anderson, T., and P. Snyder. Water Markets." Priming the
Invisible Pump. Washington, DC: Cato Institute, 1997.
Brewer, J., R. Glennon, A. Ker, and G. Libecap. "Transferring
Water in the American West, 1897-2005." University of Michigan
Journal of Law Reform, 2007, forthcoming.
Brookshire, D. S., B. Colby, M. Ewers, and P. T. Ganderton.
"Market Prices for Water in the Semiarid West of the United
States." Water Resources Research, 40, 2004, W09S04.
Brown, F. L., C. D. Mars, M. Minnis, S. A. Smasal, D. Kennedy, and
J. A. Urban. "Transfers of Water Use in New Mexico," in The
Water Transfer Process as a Management Option .for Meeting Changing
Water Demands, Vol. II, Chapter 4, edited by L. J. MacDonnell.
Washington, DC: USGS, 1990.
Brown, T. C. "Trends in Water Market Activity and Price in the
Western United States." Water Resources Research, 42, 2006, W09402.
Carey, J. M., and D. L. Sunding. "Emerging Markets in Water: A
Comparative Analysis of the Central Valley and Colorado Big Thompson
Projects." Natural Resources Journal, 41, 2001, 283-328.
Carter, H. O., H. J. Vaux Jr, and A. F. Scheuring, eds. Sharing
Scarcity, Gainers and Losers in Water Marketing. Davis, CA: University
of California Agricultural Issues Center, 1994.
Chang, C., and R. C. Griffin. "Water Marketing as a
Reallocative Institution in Texas." Water Resources Research, 28,
1992, 879-90.
Charney, A. H., and G. C. Woodard. "Socioeconomic Impacts of
Water Farming on Rural Areas of Origin in Arizona." American
Journal of Agricultural Economics, December 1990, 1193.
Colby, B. G. "Transaction Costs and Efficiency in Western
Water Allocation." American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
December 1990, 1184-92.
Colby, B. G., M. A. McGinnis, and K. A. Rait. "Mitigating
Environmental Externalities Through Voluntary and Involuntary Water
Reallocation: Nevada's Truckee-Carson River Basin." Natural
Resources Journal, 31, 1991, 757-83.
Czetwertynski, M. "The Sale and Leasing of Water Rights in
Western States: An Overview for the Period 1990 2000." Working
Paper No. 2002-2, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State
University, 2002.
Epstein, R. "Possession as the Root of Title." 13 Georgia
Law Review, 1979, 1221.
Getches, D. H. Water Law in a Nut Shell. St. Paul, MN: West
Publishing Co., 1997.
Glennon, R. Water Follies. Groundwater Pumping and the Fate of
America's Fresh Waters. Washington, DC: Island Press, 2002.
--. "Water Scarcity, Marketing and Privatization." Texas
Law Review, 2005, 1873-1902.
Gould, G. A. "Recent Developments in the Transfer of Water
Rights, " in Water Law: Trends, Policies, and Practice, edited by
K. M. Carr and J. D. Crammond. Chicago: American Bar Association, 1995,
93-103.
Griffin, R. C., and F. O. Boadu. "Water Marketing in Texas:
Opportunities for Reform." Natural Resources Journal, 32, 1992,
265-88.
Haddad, B. M. Rivers of Gold: Designing Markets" to Allocate
Water in California. Washington, DC: Island Press, 2000.
Hanak, E. California's Water Market, by the Numbers. San
Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California, 2002.
--. Who Should be Allowed to Sell Water in California? Third-Party
Issues and the Water Market. San Francisco: Public Policy Institute of
California, 2003.
Hanemann, W. M. "The Economic Conception of Water," in
Water Crisis: Myth or Reality?, edited by P. Rogers, R. Llamas, and L.
Martinez Cortina. London: Taylor & Francis, 2005, 61-92.
Hansen, K., R. Howitt, and J. Williams. "An Econometric Test
of the Endogeneity of Market Structure: Water Markets in the Western
United States." Working Paper, Department of Agricultural and
Resource Economics, UC Davis, 2007.
Hirshleifer, J., J. C. DeHaven, and J. W. Milliman. Water Supply.
Economics, Technology, and Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1960.
Hogge, C. C., P. G. Hansen, J. Paul Riley, and R. J. Davis.
"Review of the Water Rights Transfer Process and Activity in
Utah," in The Water Transfer Process as a Management Option for
Meeting Changing Water Demands, Vol. II, Chapter 5, edited by L. J.
MacDonnell. Washington, DC: USGS, 1990.
Howe, C. W., C. S. Boggs, and P. Butler. "Transaction Costs as
Determinants of Water Transfers." University of Colorado Law
Review, 61, 1990a, 393-405.
Howe, C. W., and C. Goemans. "Water Transfers and their
Impacts: Lessons from Three Colorado Water Markets." Journal of
American Water Resources Association, 39, 2003, 1055-65.
Howe, C. W., J. K. Lazo, and K. R. Weber. "The Economic
Impacts of Agriculture to Urban Water Transfers on the Area of Origin: A
Case Study of the Arkansas River Valley in Colorado." American
Journal of Agricultural Economics, December 1990b, 1200-9.
Howe, C. W., D. R. Schurmeier, and W. D. Shaw Jr. "Innovative
Approaches to Water Allocation: The Potential for Water Markets."
Water Resources Research, 22, 1986, 439-45.
Howitt, R. E. "Effects of Water Marketing on the Farm
Economy," in Sharing Scarcity: Gainers and Losers in Water
Marketing, edited by H. O. Carter, H. J. Vaux Jr, and A. F. Scheuring.
Davis, CA: Agricultural Issues Center, 1994, 97-132.
Howitt, R., and K. Hansen. "The Evolving Western Water
Markets." Choices, 20, 2005, 59-63.
Johnson, R. N., M. Gisser, and M. Werner. "The Definition of a
Surface Water Right and Transferability." Journal of Law and
Economics, 24, 1981, 273-88.
Knapp, K. C., M. Weinberg, R. Howitt, and J. F. Posnikoff. Water
Transfers, Agriculture, Groundwater Management: A Dynamic Economic
Analysis." Journal of Environmental Management, 67, 2003, 291-301.
Koehler, C. L. "Water Rights and the Public Trust Doctrine:
Resolution of the Mono Lake Controversy." 22 Ecological Law
Quarterly, 1995, 541-89.
Livingston, M. L., and T. A. Miller. "A Framework for
Analyzing the Impact of Western Instream Water Rights on Choice Domains:
Transferability, Externalities, and Consumptive Use." Land
Economics, 62, 1986, 269-77.
Loomis, J. B., K. Quattlebaum, T. C. Brown, and S. J. Alexander.
"Expanding Institutional Arrangements for Acquiring Water for
Environmental Purposes: Transactions Evidence for the Western United
States." Water Resources Development, 19, 2003, 21-8.
Lueck, D. "The Rule of First Possession and the Design of the
Law." Journal of Law and Economics, 38, 1995, 393-436.
--. "First Possession," in The New Palgrave Dictionary of
Economics and the Law, edited by P. Newman. Macmillan Press, 1998,
132-44.
MacDonnell, L. J. The Water Transfer Process as a Management Option
for Meeting Changing Water Demands, Vol. I, Washington, DC: USGS, 1990.
MacDonnell, L. J., C. W. Howe, and T. A. Rice. "Transfers of
Water Use in Colorado," in The Water Transfer Process as a
Management Option for Meeting Changing Water Demands, Vol. II, Chapter
3, edited by L. J. MacDonnell. 1990.
National Research Council. Water Transfers in the West: Efficiency,
Equity, and the Environment, Committee on Western Water Management,
Water Science and Technology Board, Commission on Engineering and
Technical Systems, with the Assistance of the Board on Agriculture.
Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 1992.
Provencher, B. "A Private Property Rights Regime to Replenish a Groundwater Aquifer." Land Economics, 69, 1993, 325-40.
Provencher, B., and O. Burr. "The Externalities Associated
with the Common Property Exploitation of Groundwater." Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 24, 1993, 139-58.
Rose, C. M. "Possession as the Origin of Property."
University of Chicago Law Review, 52, 1985, 73-87.
Sax, J. L. "The Constitution, Property Rights and the Future
of Water Law." University of Colorado Law Review, 61, 1990, 257-82.
Simms, R. A. "A Sketch of the Aimless Jurisprudence of Western
Water Law," in Water Law: Trends, Policies, and Practice, edited by
K. M. Carr and J. D. Crammond. Chicago: American Bar Association, 1995,
320-29.
Squillace, M. "Water Rights Transfers in Wyoming," in The
Water Transfer Process as a Management Option for Meeting Changing Water
Demands, Vol. II, Chapter 6, edited by L. J. MacDonnell. Washington, DC:
USGS, 1990.
Thompson, B. H. "Institutional Perspectives on Water Policy
and Markets." California Law Review, 81, 1993, 673-764.
Woodard, G. C., and C. S. McCarthy. "Water Transfers in
Arizona," in The Water Transfer Process as a Management Option for
Meeting Changing Water Demands, Vol. II, Chapter 1, edited by L. J.
MacDonnell. Washington, DC: USGS, 1990.
Young, R. A. "Why are there so Few Transactions Among Water
Users?" American Journal of Agricultural Economics, December 1986,
1143-51.
Young, R. A., and R. H. Haveman. "Economics of Water
Resources: A Survey," in Handbook of Natural Resource and Energy
Economics, Vol. II, edited by A. V. Kneese and J. L. Sweeney. New York:
Elsevier, 1985, 465-529.
ABBREVIATIONS
CAWCD: Central Arizona Water Conservancy District
C-BT: Colorado-Big Thompson Project
CVP: California Central Valley Project
ICR: Implicit Capitalization Rate
IID: Imperial Irrigation District
MRGCD: Middle Rio Grande Conservancy District
NCWCD: Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District
JEDIDIAH BREWER, ROBERT GLENNON, ALAN KER and GARY LIBECAP *
We are grateful to Ellen Hanak who provided extremely detailed,
very valuable comments on our last draft and to Chuck Howe who offered
his insights on an earlier set of data. We also thank Tom Brown and Ron
Cummings for providing access to their water transfer data sets. Support
for this research was provided by National Science Foundation Grant
0317375; the Robert Wesson Fellowship at the Hoover Institution,
Stanford; the Julian Simon Fellowship at the Property and Environment
Research Center, Bozeman, Montana; the Earhart Foundation; the
International Center for Economic Research, Turin, Italy; the Rogers
College of Law, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, and
the Anheuser-Busch Chair, McGuire Center, Eller College, University of
Arizona.
Brewer: Department of Economics, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ
85721. E-mail jwbrewer@email.arizona.edu
Glennon: Rogers College of Law, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ
85721. E-mail glennon@law.arizona.edu
Ker: Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University
of Arizona, Tucson, AZ 85721. E-mail aker@ag.arizona.edu
Libecap: Bren School of Environmental Science and Management and
Economics Department, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA;
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA; Hoover Institution,
Stanford, CA 93106. E-mail glibecap@bren.ucsb.edu
(1.) Glennon (2005, 1883-1885). As pointed out by Hanemann (2005,
note 29), this also is historically true for urban areas where metering
did not become common until well into the 20th century.
(2.) Griffin and Boadu (1992, 274-5).
(3.) See Peter Gleick, Pending Deal Would Undermine State's
Water Solutions, Sacramento Bee, February 25, 2005, at B7. There are
other inputs in production, of course, but this example demonstrates the
potential marginal gains possible from water reallocation.
(4.) Based on personal communication with Paul Wilson, professor of
agricultural economics at the University of Arizona; Ken Seasholes,
director of the Arizona Department of Water Resources, Tucson Active
Management Area; and Christopher Avery, Esq., Tucson City
Attorney's Office. See Tucson City Code [section]27-33.
(5.) Dean E. Murphy. "Pact in West will Send Farms' Water
to Cities." New York Times.com, 17 October 2003.
(6.) See Glennon, Water Follies (2002, 207).
(7.) This analysis applies as well to securing water for
environmental and recreational uses.
(8.) Sax (1990, 260). For more detailed discussion of water rights
and regulation, see Brewer et al. (2007).
(9.) We do not object to the regulation of water transfers where
significant third-party effects may occur. Rather, we note that the
regulatory process can raise transaction costs because of additional
time and resources required to secure regulatory approval for water
transfers. Where there are important physical externalities, the added
transaction costs, in part, reflect effort to more completely
internalize those effects and thereby may reduce the number of water
trades.
(10.) In terms of annual flow, California (11,058, 161 acre-feet),
Arizona (8,375,767 acre-feet), Idaho (4,960,527 acre-feet), and Texas
(2,559,140 acre-feet) are the leaders, and in terms of water committed
for transfer over 19 yr, California (36,761,948 acre-feet), Texas
(31,099,884 acre-feet), Arizona (21,889,597 acre-feet), and Colorado
(14,913,506 acre-feet) are the leaders. These committed amounts are
discounted as discussed later in the text.
(11.) http://www.waterstrategist.com
(12.) Brown (2006), who also used the Water Strategist data,
pointed to some missing transactions. We compared our California
transactions drawn from the Water Strategist with those reported by
Hanak (2002) for the time period 1987-2001 for a sense of the
completeness of the Water Strategist data. Hanak reported data collected
from a variety of primary sources including the State Water Resources
Control Board, the California Department of Water Resources, the U.S.
Bureau of Reclamation as well as transfer records from within the
Metropolitan Water District, the Westlands Water District, and other
major organizations. For 1987 1996, the two data sets track closely, but
for 1996-2001, our transaction volumes are lower than hers, suggesting
some undercounting. We have no way of determining whether this problem
also occurs in other western states. Nevertheless, we conclude that the
Water Strategist data appear to be generally representative of water
transactions.
(13.) Besides Brown (2006), other authors who have used the Water
Strategist include Howitt and Hansen (2005), Brookshire et al. (2004),
Adams, Crews, and Cummings (2004), Loomis et al. (2003), and
Czetwertynski (2002). See discussion below.
(14.) Glennon (2002, 35-50).
(15.) Gould (1995, 94), Simms (1995, 321).
(16.) Sax (1990, 260), and Koehler (1995, 555).
(17.) Getches (1997, 74-189). California has a hybrid system that
combines the prior appropriation doctrine with riparianism, a doctrine
associated with the eastern United States that grants owners of land on
rivers and streams rights to water. Glennon (2002, 14-15).
(18.) See discussion of first possession in Epstein (1979), Rose
(1985), and Lueck (1995, 1998).
(19.) Getches (1997, 176-180).
(20.) California Water Code, [section]1011.
(21.) Getches (1997, 156-60), Hirshleifer, DeHaven, and Milliman
(1960).
(22.) MacDonnell (1990, Vol. I, p. 11).
(23.) Anderson and Johnson (1986) and Johnson, Gisser, and Werner
(1981). Johnson et al. described how specifying a property right in
water in terms of consumptive use with options for third-party
grievances can be an effective method for promoting transfers. Howitt
and Hansen (2005, 60) pointed to both transaction costs through property
rights and regulatory differences and often high costs of transporting
water.
(24.) Conveyance costs can be high. Hansen, Howitt, and Williams
(2007, 3) reported that 55% of the $250 that the Metropolitan Water
District of Southern California paid in 2002 for water from Northern
California was for the cost of conveying it.
(25.) See also Livingston and Miller (1986).
(26.) Hanak's survey of the literature (2003. 81) points out
that effects of fallowing irrigated farmland is likely to have not more
than a 1% effect on overall county economic activity, even when payments
for economic adjustments are not included.
(27.) See the readings included in National Research Council (1992)
and the volume edited by Carter. Vaux, and Scheuring (1994). Brewer et
al. (2007) introduced water market data and discussed regulatory issues.
(28.) Various state regulations regarding transfers are outlined in
Hogge et al. (1990): MacDonnell (1990) for Utah; Brown et al. (1990) for
New Mexico: MacDonnell, Howe, and Rice (1990) for Colorado: Woodard and
McCarthy (1990) for Arizona. and Squillace (1990) for Wyoming.
(29.) See also discussion of the C-BT institutional structure in
Howitt and Hansen (2005, 60).
(30.) See the summary of benefits in Haddad (2000, 19-.32).
(31.) Instream flow rights have particular problems because they
require relaxing beneficial use requirements in appropriative water
rights and because they are costly to enforce from downstream diversion.
See Anderson and Johnson (1986).
(32.) See also Adams, Crews, and Cummings (2004), Czetwertynski
(2002). and the recent working paper by Hansen, Howitt, and Williams
(2007).
(33.) Because he was concerned about very active C-BT trading
overwhelming the summary statistics, Brown combined all C-BT
transactions for a simple purpose for a given month into a single case.
This reduces the overall number of transactions from 2,450 to 1,729 in
his data set. Another 349 are dropped because of missing information,
leaving 1,380.
(34.) The nine classifications are: agricultural-to-agricultural,
agricultural-to-urban, agricultural-to-environmental,
urban-to-agricultural, urban-to-urban, urban-to-environmental,
environmental-to-agricultural, environmental-to-urban, and
environmental-to-environmental.
(35.) In selected cases where the description of the transfer
contained in the Water Strategist was ambiguous, we relied upon Robert
Glennon's knowledge of water institutions in the West (aided by
Google searches). These transfers primarily occurred in Arizona and
California and consisted of approximately 55 of the 3,317 transfers in
the data set.
(36.) One could potentially argue that an individual should be
classified as an urban user instead of an agricultural user, but we
decided that it was more likely that an individual (not a city, a
corporation, or another entity reflecting municipal or industrial use)
was an agricultural user, especially if the individual was a seller. The
Water Strategist described an individual as a seller of water 88 times
and as the buyer 9 times. The total water that was transferred when
either the buyer or the seller was listed as an individual was 22,467
acre-feet. This amount is less than 0.01% of the total water transferred
in our data set. One transfer by an individual accounted for 15,000
acre-feet of the total 22,467 acre-feet transferred.
(37.) These unknown transfers account for 798,932 acre-feet of
water, about 2.5% of the total in our data set. Our data set is
available on the web page of Donald Bren School of Environmental Science
and Management, Water Policy Program, University of California Santa
Barbara.
(38.) Combination transfers account for 4,939,997 acre-feet, about
15.5% of the total in our data set.
(39.) To illustrate the differences between the annual flow and the
committed variables, consider a 5-yr lease of 1,000 acre-feet per year
beginning in 1990. The annual flow metric would record 1,000 acre-feet
in 1990 only. The committed variable instead would discount the 1,000
acre-feet transacted annually across the 5 yr of the contract at 5% and
sum the total. In so doing, 4,329 acre-feet would be recorded for 1990,
rather than 1,000 acre-feet.
(40.) For example, see the annual flow measures used by Brown
(2006) and Howitt and Hansen (2005). We recognize that during dry years,
the actual amount of water available may be substantially less than the
contractual amount if sales or leases involve very junior priority
rights. For example, dry-year contingencies in long-term contracts may
allow for reduced volumes to flow by specifying that up to a certain
amount would be traded or that the transfer would be between two
amounts. Unfortunately, in our data set, we do not observe the actual
amounts transferred. To account for potential biases when contingent
transfers were involved, we created three separate measures for both the
annual flow and the committed variables calculated in our data set:
minimum, maximum, and the mean amount transferred. For a 2-yr lease of
up to 1,000 acre-feet annually, the minimum annual flow (committed)
amount was 0 acre-feet (0 acre-feet), the maximum annual flow
(committed) was 1,000 acre-feet (1,859 acre-feet), and the average
annual flow (committed) was 500 acre-feet (930 acre-feet). The results
reported in this paper use the mean annual flow and mean committed
amounts. Because there are relatively few contingent contracts in our
data set, the results and conclusions do not change in any meaningful
way if either the minimum or the maximum amounts are used instead.
(41.) In our data set, 2,189 transfers had price information, but
35 of these were "unknown" transfers, those where we could not
determine the sector where they originated or ended. For that reason, we
use 2,154 transfers where we had such information. Overall, there were
85 unknown transfers in our data set and 50 of them did not have price
data. The disparity between the overall number of transfers in the data
set, 3,232 and 2,189, is due to cases in which the Water Strategist did
not provide price information or the entry coupled the sale of land and
water into one price and we had no way of disentangling the two in order
to determine the price of the water.
(42.) The Wilcoxon signed-rank test is similar to the standard
difference-in-means t-test. However, its nonparametric nature allows
additional flexibility, as it does not require a priori assumptions on
the distribution of its components.
(43.) Because our sample covers the years 1987-2005, prices were
converted into real dollars to compare prices across years. All prices
where converted into 1987 dollars using the consumer price index--all
urban consumers average from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The
patterns shown in the table hold if median prices are used instead of
mean values although the differences are narrowed. Further, if
transactions in the very active water market state of Colorado are
removed, the price differences remain but the number of observations is
reduced.
(44.) As we have noted earlier, sales prices may also be higher if
the priority of the water right is higher for water sold than for water
leased.
(45.) There are more 1-yr agriculture-to-agriculture leases (222)
than 1-yr agriculture-to-urban leases (165), but fewer
agriculture-to-agriculture multiyear leases (18) than
agriculture-to-urban multiyear leases (86). Although we combine short-
and long-term leases in Figure 2, the price trends for median lease
prices are similar for both short-term and long-term leases.
(46.) Brown (2006) also calculated ICRs. His price data are for
1990-2003, while ours are for 1897-2005. Nevertheless, the calculations
are quite similar if we use his time period (Brown's categories).
Brown, Our Calculations,
1990-2003 1990-2003
Urban (municipal) 2.64% 2.73%
Agriculture (irrigation) 0.65 0.87
Environment 5.37 6.78
All states 1.94 2.00
(47.) In other work, we are examining the effects of state
regulatory and property rights regimes on observed water transfers,
controlling for economic, political, water supply, and infrastructure
characteristics.
(48.) Eighty-six transfers were neither leases nor sales and are
not included in Table 4. An example of such a transfer would be an
exchange for service between two parties. For example, a developer might
give his water right to the city free of charge in return for a service.
(49.) The Water Strategist sometimes referred to transactions as
sales that transferred the water but not necessarily the water right. In
our data set, these are referred to as short-term sales. Short-term
sales can be thought of in a similar manner as a 1-yr lease and are thus
included in all 1-yr leases categories. Of the 110 short-term sales that
occurred over the 19 yr in our data set, 80 were in California. There
were 71 permanent sales in California.
(50.) Dropping Colorado transactions leaves 566 sales transactions
for 3,550,415-acre-feet annual flows.
(51.) Irrigation districts are political subdivisions of the state
that supply farmers with irrigation water. Elected governing boards run
irrigation districts. For discussion, see Thompson (1993, 687-701).
Internal district water transactions may not be included in our data set
from the Water Strategist because they may not be reported.
(52.) Less 85 unknown transfers. For more complete discussion of
the legal issues involved in water transfers, see Brewer et al. (2007).
(53.) A Wilcoxon signed-rank test is used to test trend by first
differencing more recent realizations with early realizations and then
second proceeding with a simple Wilcoxon signed-rank test. A 5%
significance level is used in all tests.
(54.) All tests for trend are undertaken by differencing the data
and then undertaking a simple Wilcoxon signed-rank test at a 5%
significance level.
TABLE 1 Water Transfer Prices (per Acre-Foot) by Sector
Agriculture-to- Agriculture-to-
Urban Leases Agriculture Leases
Mean price ($) 114 29
Median price (S) 40 10
Number of observations 189 178
Agriculture-to- Agriculture-to-
Urban Sales Agriculture Sales
Mean price ($) 4,366 1,747
Median price (S) 2,643 1,235
Number of observations 1,013 169
TABLE 2 Prices by State and by Sector
All Sectors
1-yr
Leases ($) Sales ($) ICR (%)
Arizona 43.12 786.16 5.5
California 44.53 641.45 6.9
Colorado 12.54 2,693.38 0.5
Idaho 4.43 59.70 7.4
Montana 8.14 100.22 8.1 *
New Mexico 28.94 1,250.00 2.3
Nevada 23.77 1,992.28 1.2 *
Oregon 7.49 111.37 6.7 *
Texas 18.87 461.79 4.1
Utah 4.63 356.22 1.3
Washington 20.21 289.93 7.0 *
Wyoming 27.27 1,073.22 2.5 *
All 27.69 1,752.06 1.6
Agriculture-to-Agriculture
1-yr
Leases ($) Sales ($) ICR (%)
Arizona 33.03 721.65 4.6 *
California 39.11 864.35 4.5 *
Colorado 13.67 1,488 0.9 *
Idaho 4.43 59.76 7.4 *
Montana 3.49 n/a n/a
New Mexico 13.69 1,150 1.2 *
Nevada n/a n/a n/a
Oregon 4.88 n/a n/a
Texas 17.42 217.29 8.0 *
Utah 4.29 681.87 0.6 *
Washington 10.30 n/a n/a
Wyoming 2.38 121.85 2.0 *
All 10.68 1,235 0.90
Agriculture-to-Urban
1-yr
Leases ($) Sales ($) ICR (%)
Arizona 54.81 182.57 30.0 *
California 83.41 641.45 13.0
Colorado 28.70 3,687.12 0.8
Idaho 2.40 106.37 2.3 *
Montana 17.60 n/a n/a
New Mexico n/a 1,592.86 n/a
Nevada 23.77 1,952.55 1.2 *
Oregon 6.49 n/a n/a
Texas 18.82 465.41 4.0
Utah 92.15 331.29 27.8 *
Washington 25.01 417.85 6.0 *
Wyoming 45.10 1,440.41 3.1 *
All 41.00 2,642.70 1.6 *
Number of sales or 1-yr leases with price data in the given
state is less than 10; n/a, no sales and/or leases with price
data for the given state.
TABLE 3
Median Prices by Year across All States and Sectors
1-yr Leases ($) Sales ($) ICR (%)
1987 60.76 1,200.00 5.10
1988 50.41 960.27 5.30
1989 41.23 1,112.44 3.70
1990 39.11 1,432.79 2.70
1991 91.75 1,752.45 5.20
1992 18.22 1,656.23 1.10
1993 11.79 1,411.66 0.80
1994 29.13 1,450.94 2.00
1995 13.69 1,680.55 0.80
1996 29.69 2,389.29 1.20
1997 17.59 2,818.40 0.60
1998 19.51 3,902.82 0.50
1999 14.72 3,550.23 0.40
2000 26.39 7,586.53 0.30
2001 31.37 7,171.72 0.40
2002 31.57 8,299.21 0.40
2003 29.02 10,905.56 0.30
2004 30.07 10,624.32 0.30
2005 27.34 8,912.00 0.30
Median 27.69 1,752.06 1.60
TABLE 4
Leases by Lease-Length
Frequency Average
Duration (yr) Number (%) Size
1 771 79 30,416
2-5 65 7 12,088
6-9 4 0 6,287
10-19 40 4 8,759
20-29 39 4 5,558
30-39 12 1 7,699
40-49 18 2 14,718
50-74 10 1 50,086
75 13 1 2,126
100 9 1 14,632
Total 981 100 26,347
TABLE 5
Water Transactions by Contract Type and Category, 1987-2005
Agriculture- Agriculture- Urban-
to-Urban to-Agriculture to-Urban
Number of Transfers
Sale 1,543 215 269
Lease
One-year 165 222 97
Multiyear 86 18 49
Total Quantities: Committed (acre-foot)
Sale 25,821,328 8,422,685 12,109,620
Lease
One-year 3,251,123 6,355,338 4,247,688
Multiyear 8,794,128 990,393 9,961,049
Committed Average Size (acre-foot)
Sale 16,734 39,175 45,017
Lease
One-year 19,704 28,628 43,791
Multiyear 102,257 55,022 203,287
Agriculture- Agriculture- Urban-
to-Urban to-Agriculture to-Urban
Number of Transfers
Sale 1,543 215 269
Lease
One-year 165 222 97
Multiyear 86 18 49
Total Quantities: Annual Flow (acre-foot)
Sale 1,291,066 421,134 605,481
Lease
One-year 3,251,123 6,355,338 4,247,688
Multiyear 729,732 90,659 679,996
Annual Flow Average Size (acre-foot)
Sale 837 1,959 2,251
Lease
One-year 19,704 28,628 43,791
Multiyear 8,485 5,037 13,877
TABLE 6
Water Transactions by Contract Type 1987-2005
No. of Frequency
Transfers (%)
One-year leases 771 24
Multiyear leases 210 6
All leases 981 30
Sales 2,165 67
Miscellaneous (a) 86 3
All transfers 3,232 100
Committed
Amount Frequency
(acre-foot) (%)
One-year leases 23,450,450 17
Multiyear leases 26,759,628 19
All leases 50,210,078 36
Sales 79,496,161 58
Miscellaneous (a) 8,353,065 6
All transfers 138,059,304 100
Annual Flow
Amount Frequency
(acre-foot) (%)
One-year leases 23,450,450 76
Multiyear leases 2,395,430 8
All leases 25,845,880 83
Sales 3,974,808 13
Miscellaneous (a) 1,143,890 4
All transfers 30,964,578 100
(a) Miscellaneous transfers are listed as "exchanges"
and "storages" in the Water Strategist.
TABLE 7
Water Transfers by Sector, 1987-2005
No. of Frequency
Classification Transfers (%)
Agriculture-to-Agriculture 471 15
Agriculture-to-urban 1,825 56
Agriculture-to-environment 233 7
Urban-to-agriculture 38 1
Urban-to-urban 440 14
Urban-to-environment 54 2
Environment-to-agriculture 0 0
Environment-to-urban 1 0
Environment-to-environment 6 0
Combination 164 5
Total 3,232 100
Committed
Amount Frequency
Classification (acre-foot) (%)
Agriculture-to-Agriculture 16,241,925 12
Agriculture-to-urban 39,747,584 29
Agriculture-to-environment 18,186,143 13
Urban-to-agriculture 2,549,986 2
Urban-to-urban 26,600,020 19
Urban-to-environment 8,925,447 6
Environment-to-agriculture 0 0
Environment-to-urban 62 0
Environment-to-environment 4,171,200 3
Combination 21,636,938 16
Total 138,059,303 100
Annual Flow
Amount Frequency
Classification (acre-foot) (%)
Agriculture-to-Agriculture 7,138,480 23
Agriculture-to-urban 5,533,394 18
Agriculture-to-environment 6,014,228 19
Urban-to-agriculture 326,440 1
Urban-to-urban 5,657,591 18
Urban-to-environment 1,054,031 3
Environment-to-agriculture 0 0
Environment-to-urban 62 0
Environment-to-environment 284,560 1
Combination 4,955,791 16
Total 30,964,577 100
TABLE 8
Water Transactions by Type and State
Number Number Number of Number of
of All of Short-Term Long-Term
Transactions Sales Leases Leases
Arizona 175 118 41 12
California 481 71 305 60
Colorado 1,707 1,599 60 31
Idaho 105 27 74 2
Montana 23 2 10 11
New Mexico 118 64 36 15
Nevada 126 112 4 3
Oregon 77 12 44 17
Texas 253 82 119 50
Utah 75 56 15 3
Washington 45 16 24 5
Wyoming 47 6 39 1
Total 3,232 2,165 771 210
TABLE 9
Share of Each Transfer's Classification to a
State's Total Quantity Transferred
Annual Flow
Agriculture- Total
Agriculture- to-Agriculture Urban-to- (million
to-Urban (%) (%) Urban (%) acre-foot)
Arizona 15 46 39 8.34
California 41 32 27 5.04
Colorado 51 29 20 0.59
Idaho 39 55 6 1.59
Montana 55 45 0 0.02
New Mexico 15 78 7 0.10
Nevada 84 0 16 0.22
Oregon 0 100 0 0.10
Texas 48 15 37 1.75
Utah 38 32 29 0.31
Washington 49 36 15 0.16
Wyoming 37 63 0 0.10
Committed
Agriculture- Total
Agriculture- to-Agriculture Urban-to- (million
to-Urban (%) (%) Urban (%) acre-foot)
Arizona 31 37 32 21.72
California 37 32 31 12.60
Colorado 75 8 17 5.88
Idaho 29 67 5 2.36
Montana 95 5 0 0.22
New Mexico 36 55 10 0.91
Nevada 72 0 28 2.39
Oregon 0 100 0 0.29
Texas 50 3 47 25.30
Utah 53 3 44 4.05
Washington 79 3 18 1.93
Wyoming 38 62 0 0.41
TABLE 10
Relative Percentage of State to Each Classification's
Total Transfer Amount
Annual Flow
Agriculture- Agriculture- Urban-to-
to-Urban to-Agriculture Urban (%)
(%) (%)
Arizona 20 53 58
California 45 23 24
Colorado 5 2 2
Idaho 10 12 2
Montana 0 0 0
New Mexico 0 1 0
Nevada 3 0 1
Oregon 0 1 0
Texas 13 4 12
Utah 2 1 2
Washington 1 1 0
Wyoming 1 1 0
Million acre-feet 6.23 7.13 5.66
Committed
Agriculture- Agriculture- Urban-to-
to-Urban to-Agriculture Urban (%)
(%) (%)
Arizona 19 49 26
California 13 25 14
Colorado 13 3 4
Idaho 2 10 0
Montana 1 0 0
New Mexico 1 3 0
Nevada 5 0 3
Oregon 0 2 0
Texas 36 5 44
Utah 6 1 7
Washington 4 0 1
Wyoming 0 2 0
Million acre-feet 35.21 16.24 26.60