Efficiency wages and subjective performance pay.
Yang, Huanxing
I. INTRODUCTION
How to design incentive schemes to motivate workers is an important
topic in economics. The shirking models of efficiency wages, such as
Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984), establish that firms need to pay a wage
premium (efficiency wages) to motivate workers, with unemployment
serving as a punishment device. However, one shortcoming of these models
is that performance pay plays no role. One justification for their
omission of performance pay is that individual performance may not be
verifiable. Nevertheless, if workers' performance is observable and
employment relationships are repeated, firms can use implicit bonuses or
relational contracts based on workers' subjectively assessed
performance to motivate workers. Since subjective performance pay cannot
be legally enforced, it has to be self-enforcing.
Given that both efficiency wages and subjective performance pay
motivate workers, what is the optimal wage contract from the firm's
perspective? Will different labor markets (occupations) use different
forms of wage contracts? What are the impacts of different forms of wage
contracts on unemployment and social welfare? To answer these questions,
this paper provides a theory of contract selection in a market setting.
In a seminal paper, MacLeod and Malcomson (1998, MM hereafter)
provided a model of contract selection between efficiency wages and
subjective performance pay. The driving force in their model is the
market condition. In a market with more workers than jobs, a firm can
always immediately and costlessly fill its vacancy after reneging on the
promised bonus. Therefore, no subjective performance pay is credible,
and firms have to use solely efficiency wages to motivate workers. On
the other hand, in a market with more jobs than workers, efficiency
wages are useless in providing incentives because a worker can find
another job immediately after being fired. As a result, firms use solely
subjective performance pay to motivate workers.
In MM, there are no exogenous turnover costs. Complementary to MM,
this paper provides a model of contract selection driven by exogenous
turnover costs in labor markets. We focus on the situation in which
unemployment always exists in labor markets, thus ruling out market
condition as a determinant of contract selection. It turns out that
turnover costs affect the amount of efficiency wages and performance pay
in optimal contracts. While in MM efficiency wages and subjective
performance pay cannot be used together to motivate workers, in our
model firms are able to use combinations of both methods of payments. By
affecting optimal contracts, turnover costs also have impacts on the
equilibrium employment level and social welfare. Finally, our model
generates rich empirical implications about the relationships among
turnover costs, forms of employment contracts, and levels of employment.
Our basic model studies how turnover costs borne by firms affect
contract selection. From the firm's point of view, subjective
performance pay is "cheaper" since efficiency wages entail a
wage premium. Thus, the optimal wage contract uses the maximum amount of
bonus to motivate workers. However, subjective performance pay may not
be credible due to the firm's moral hazard problem: in labor
markets with positive unemployment, a firm can immediately hire a new
worker after reneging on the implicit bonus. The presence of turnover
costs can alleviate this moral hazard problem. This is because a worker
can punish a reneging firm by quitting and the firm has to incur turnover costs in hiring new workers. Therefore, in the optimal
contract, the amount of bonus is increasing in turnover costs. Since
subjective performance pay is cheaper, as the turnover costs increase,
more subjective performance pay leads to a lower total wage payment.
After deriving the optimal contracts, we turn to study market
equilibrium, which is determined by firms' free entry condition. In
market equilibrium, the revenue product of labor equals the average
labor cost (ALC), which consists of the wage payment each period and the
average turnover costs incurred per period on the equilibrium path.
Interestingly, up to some threshold (when the wage premium is positive),
an increase in turnover costs reduces the ALC and leads to an increase
in the equilibrium employment level. Moreover, when the revenue product
of labor is elastic enough, an increase in turnover costs leads to
higher social welfare. This is a surprising result: a little bit
of(exogenous) friction in markets is beneficial for social welfare. The
main reason behind this result is that friction in markets alleviates
the firms' moral hazard problem and gives them commitment power,
which in turn grants firms more flexibility to alleviate the
workers' moral hazard problem. A general interpretation of this
result is that exogenous friction might be more efficient than
endogenously created friction (efficiency wages) in overcoming double
moral hazard problems in markets.
In an extended model, we incorporate workers' search costs.
Now, wage contracts should not only motivate workers to exert effort (IC
condition) but also induce unemployed workers to search (IR condition).
It turns out that inducing workers to search becomes more difficult as
the unemployment rate increases. The main result in the extended model
is that wages are increasing in the employment level only when
employment is high and are completely rigid when employment is low. This
implies that wage-unemployment relationship changes over the course of
business cycles: wages are procyclical in booms and rigid during
recessions.
Our model generates rich empirical implications. First, different
labor markets (occupations) will adopt different forms of wage
contracts. In particular, the efficiency wage component (wage premium)
is negatively related to and the amount of bonuses is positively related
to the turnover costs borne by firms in labor markets. Second, workers
paid by bonuses on average earn less than workers paid fixed wages
(efficiency wages). Third, occupations paid bonuses should have lower
unemployment rates than occupations in which bonuses are seldom used.
Fourth, wages are procyclical during booms and are either rigid or
countercyclical in recessions. Finally, the wage-unemployment elasticity
is decreasing in turnover costs in labor markets. All these predictions
are consistent with some empirical evidence. (1)
Relational contracts have been studied by Bull (1987), MM (1989,
1998), Baker, Gibbons, and Murphy (1994), and Levin (2003). However,
except for MM (1989, 1998), all the other papers study the
one-firm-one-worker setting; hence, both the firm's and the
worker's outside options are exogenously given. Moreover, these
papers do not study contract selection between efficiency wages and
subjective performance pay. MM (1989) offered a complete
characterization of the set of relational contracts that can be
implemented in a market setting, but it does not study the problem of
contract selection.
Akerlof and Katz (1989) incorporated a performance bond into a
shirking model of efficiency wages. They, however, assumed that firms
are able to commit: firms never forfeit a worker's bond if he does
not shirk. In contrast to their assumption, our model, following the
literature of relational contracts, assumes that firms are not able to
commit. The labor turnover models of efficiency wages, such as Salop
(1979) and Stiglitz (1974), treat the turnover rate as endogenous. They
derive the result that firms with higher turnover costs may pay higher
wages in order to reduce total turnover costs. This result is in direct
contrast to the prediction of our model.
The structure of the paper is as follows. Section II sets up the
basic model. Section III studies the optimal wage contracts. In Section
IV, first the stationary market equilibrium is derived and then
comparative statics and welfare analysis are conducted. In Section V, we
extend the basic model to incorporate search costs. Section VI presents
some empirical evidence. Section VII concludes the paper.
II. THE BASIC MODEL
Consider a labor market over time, with time t being discrete.
There are L workers and many firms which create J job vacancies in
total. While L is exogenously given, there is free entry on the
firms' side, thus J is endogenous. Both workers and firms are risk
neutral and share the same discount factor [delta]. Each job has the
same revenue product of labor p. Each firm takes p as given, but in the
aggregate, p is a decreasing function of the total employment E. At the
beginning of each period, unemployed workers and unfilled vacancies are
randomly matched. Note that agents on the long side of the market may
not get a match. At the end of each period, each existing match breaks
up with probability 1--[rho] for exogenous reasons. In any existing
match that survives this shock, the worker and the firm simultaneously
decide whether to continue the relationship next period. If either party
decides to leave, then the match is broken up endogenously. All the
agents without a match enter into the unmatched pool at the beginning of
the next period.
If employed, a worker gets utility [W.sub.t] - [ve.sub.t], where
[W.sub.t] is the total wage payment, v > 0 is the disutility of work,
and [e.sub.t] is effort in period t. For simplicity, we assume that a
worker can either work ([e.sub.t] = 1) or shirk ([e.sub.t] = 0). The
profit of a filled job vacancy in period t is [pe.sub.t] - [W.sub.t].
Workers without a job receive an unemployment benefit u > 0 per
period, which is exogenously given. Consistent with employment at will,
we assume that only spot contracts are legally enforceable. Following
the incomplete contract literature, we assume that et is observable but
not verifiable. (2) Therefore, spot contracts that are contingent on [e.sub.t] cannot be enforced by the court.
Nevertheless, since employment relationships have the potential to
be long term, firms may use implicit bonuses. In particular, [W.sub.t]
consists of a fixed wage [w.sub.t] [greater than or equal to] 0 that the
firm pays regardless of [e.sub.t] and a bonus [b.sub.t] [greater than or
equal to] 0 that the firm agrees to pay only if [e.sub.t] = 1. While
[w.sub.t] is legally enforceable, [b.sub.t] cannot be enforced by the
court; hence, it has to be self-enforcing.
Note that if an employed worker shirks, then his employer's
period profit is negative. Thus, firms have to motivate workers to exert
effort. To make sure there is positive employment, we assume that p(0)
> u + v/([delta][rho]). In addition, we assume that p(L) [less than
or equal to] u + v/([delta][rho]). This assumption ensures that J [less
than or equal to] L; that is, there is always unemployment and workers
are always on the long side of the market.
There are turnover costs in the labor market. Firms incur
recruiting costs in finding job candidates. (3) Workers incur search
costs in finding jobs. Moreover, each firm may require a skill which is
firm specific. (4) For simplicity, we assume that it takes one period
for a new employee to acquire the firm-specific skill. During that
period, the output of a new worker is less than that of an old worker by
[c.sub.F] [greater than or equal to] 0. (5) The parameter [c.sub.F]
captures the degree of firm specificity of jobs: the more firm specific
are jobs in the market, the larger the [c.sub.F]. We denote c =
[c.sub.F] + [c.sub.R] ([c.sub.R] represents recruiting costs) as the
turnover costs. For simplicity, we assume that c is borne by firms
alone. (6) Later on, we will discuss how relaxing this assumption
affects the results of the model. In the basic model, we ignore
workers' search costs, which will be studied in Section V. For
simplicity, we assume that if a worker is separated from a firm, his
skill which is specific to that firm degenerates immediately. Therefore,
all workers in the unmatched pool are homogeneous regardless of their
employment history.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
This is essentially an infinitely repeated game with some
employment relationships reshuffled in each period. The timing of a
typical period is shown in Figure 1. At the beginning of period t,
unemployed workers and unfilled job vacancies are randomly matched. In
each match, the firm offers the worker a contract. The worker can either
accept or reject the offer. If he rejects the offer, the worker is
unemployed for that period. Then, each employed worker chooses effort
and gets paid. After the payments have been made, a 1 - [rho] fraction
of existing matches exogenously break up. Then, in each surviving match,
the worker and the firm simultaneously decide whether to continue the
relationship into the next period. (7) All the unmatched agents enter
into the unmatched pool in the beginning of the next period.
The model is similar to MM but with two departures. First, we
introduce turnover costs in labor markets, which are not studied in
their model. Second, we only consider the case J [less than or equal to]
L, while in their model both cases J [less than or equal to] L and J
> L are studied. (8) Note that there are double moral hazard
problems: workers may want to shirk and collect the fixed wage
[w.sub.t], and firms may want to renege on the bonus [b.sub.t] after
workers exert effort. The concern for external reputation may mitigate the moral hazard problems. We rule out such a reputation effect. (9)
We are interested in equilibria in which employed workers exert
effort and firms do not renege in each period. There are many relational
contracts that can be supported as perfect equilibria, some of which may
involve complicated strategies. For simplicity, we restrict our
attention to trigger strategies. In particular, if a worker shirks, the
firm will fire him immediately. Similarly, if a firm reneges on a bonus
(pays less than [b.sub.t]), the worker quits immediately. (10)
III. THE OPTIMAL CONTRACTS
We are interested in stationary equilibrium, in which the
employment level, the fixed wage, and implicit bonus are constant over
time, so we can drop all the time subscripts. Denote [U.sup.N]
([U.sup.S]) as the expected discounted lifetime utility of an employed
nonshirker (shirker) and [bar.U] as the expected discounted lifetime
utility of an unemployed worker. Let [member of] be the number of
employed workers and a be the job acquisition rate. Note that both
[member of] and a are endogenous variables. The value function [U.sup.N]
is the following (supposing firms do not renege):
(1) [U.sup.N](w, b) = (w + b - v) + [delta][[rho][U.sup.N](w, b) +
(1 - [rho])[bar.U](w, b)].
The value of [U.sup.N] consists of two terms. The first term in
Equation (1) is a nonshirker's current period payoff. With
probability 1 - [rho], the current match breaks up exogenously so the
worker gets a continuation value [bar.U](w, b). With probability [rho],
the current match continues in the next period and the worker's
continuation value is [U.sup.N](w, b). Similarly, other value functions
are:
(2) [U.sup.S](w, b) = w + [delta][bar.U](w, b)
(3) [bar.U](w,b) = a x [U.sup.N](w, b) + (1 - a)[u +
[delta][bar.U](w, b)].
If an employed worker shirks, the current relationship breaks up
for sure, so the continuation value is [bar.U](w, b). For an unemployed
worker (at the beginning of a period) with probability a, he will find a
job in that period and his payoff is [U.sup.N](w, b); with probability 1
- a, he will stay unemployed and get u + [delta][bar.U](w, b).
Similarly, denote [V.sup.N] ([V.sup.R]) as the expected discounted
lifetime profit of a filled job vacancy if the firm does not renege
(reneges) (11) and [bar.V] as the expected discounted lifetime profit of
an unfilled job vacancy. The value functions are the following
(supposing workers do not shirk):
(4) [V.sup.N](w, b) = (p - w - b) + [delta][[rho][V.sup.N](w, b) +
(1 - [rho])[bar.V](w, b)]
(5) [V.sup.R](w, b) = (p - w) + [delta][bar.V](w, b)
(6) [bar.V](w, b) = [V.sup.N] - c.
The continuation value of [V.sup.N] has two components. With
probability 1 - [rho], exogenous separation occurs, so the firm gets a
continuation value [bar.V]; with probability [rho], the existing match
remains in the next period, and the firm's continuation value is
[V.sup.N]](w, b). [V.sup.R] is different from [V.sup.N] in continuation
values: after the firm reneges, the existing match breaks for sure so
the firm's continuation value is always [bar.V] x [bar.V] is the
firm's fallback position if it reneges. Since there is unemployment
in the market, the firm can immediately find a new worker to fill its
vacancy, by incurring turnover cost c. Therefore, [bar.V] (w, b) =
[V.sup.N] - c.
A. Programming Problem
Each firm offers a relational contract to maximize its profit,
taking the employment E (hence a) as given. The relational contract
should satisfy the following conditions. Unemployed workers should be
willing to accept the contract, and employed workers should have
incentives to exert effort. Firms should earn zero profit due to free
entry, and firms should not have incentives to renege. Note that
maximizing profit is equivalent to minimizing total wage payment W.
Mathematically, the programming problem is as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to
[U.sup.N] [greater than or equal to] [bar.U] (IRW) [bar.V] = 0
(IRF) [U.sup.N] [greater than or equal to] [U.sup.S]] (ICW) [V.sup.N]
[greater than or equal to] [V.sup.R] (ICF).
The IRF condition depends on the revenue product of labor p(E). For
the time being, we ignore this condition and discuss it in the next
section when we study market equilibria. Substituting Equations (1) and
(2), the no-shirking condition (ICW) becomes:
(7) [delta][rho]([U.sup.N] - [bar.U]) [greater than or equal to] (v
- b).
The left-hand side of Equation (7) is the rent of continued
employment enjoyed by an employed worker, and the right-hand side is the
current period gain from shirking. Note that efficiency wages (measured
by [U.sup.N] - [bar.U]) and performance pay b are substitutes in
motivating workers: either the bonus b should be big enough to reduce
the gain of shirking or the worker's rent from continued
employment, which is created by paying efficiency wages, should be big
enough. Note that firms can also use a combination of both.
Similarly, the no-reneging condition (ICF) can be simplified asy
(8) b [less than or equal to] [delta][rho]c.
The left-hand side of Equation (8) is the firm's current
period gain from reneging: the right-hand side is the expected cost of
reneging. Since it can always have a job vacancy filled immediately, the
firm's rent from continued employment comes solely from the fact
that retaining an old worker saves turnover costs c. (12) Therefore, any
credible b has an upper bound [delta][rho]c.
B. Optimal Contracts
With a positive c, firms have some freedom to choose b in
relational contracts. From the no-reneging condition (Equation 8), the
credible bonuses the firm can choose are in the range [0,
[delta][rho]c]. The bigger the c, the more freedom the firm has to
choose b. To facilitate analysis, we first prove a lemma.
LEMMA 1. If c [member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])), in the optimal
relational contract, the firm should set [b.sup.*] = [delta][rho]c. If c
[greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]), in the optimal relational
contracts, the firm can set any [b.sup.*] [member of] [v, [delta][rho]c]
subject to [w.sup.*] = u + v - [b.sup.*] [greater than or equal to] 0.
C. Proof See the Appendix.
The intuition for Lemma 1 is the following. There are two ways to
motivate workers: efficiency wages and performance pay. Performance pay
is less costly than efficiency wages from the firms' perspective.
This is because performance pay discourages shirking directly without
increasing total compensation, while efficiency wages require firms to
increase total compensation. However, performance pay is restricted by
the moral hazard problem on the part of the firm: it may renege on the
bonus if it is too high. This moral hazard can be alleviated by the
presence of turnover costs c: the firm will incur c in hiring a new
worker next period if it reneges on the bonus. The upper bound of
credible bonuses thus is increasing in turnover costs c. When
[delta][rho]c < v, the firm should set the highest credible bonus
[b.sup.*] = [delta][rho]c to reduce the necessary wage premium required
to motivate workers. When [delta][rho]c [greater than or equal to] v,
setting any b [member of] [v, [delta][rho]c] is enough to motivate
workers, and the firm does not need to pay wage premiums. But now the
IRW condition is binding, so the total wage payment cannot be reduced
further.
Define the wage premium [w.sup.p] as the extra utility per period
enjoyed by an employed worker relative to an unemployed worker. By Lemma
1, we can calculate [w.sup.p] in the optimal contracts.
(9) [w.sup.p] = ([b.sup.*] + [w.sup.*] - v) - u = {1/[(1 -
a)[delta][rho]] - 1}max{v - [delta][rho]c, 0}
From Equation (9), it is clear that the wage premium is decreasing
in c. Moreover, when c [greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]), the
wage premium equals to 0. On the other hand, when c = 0, [b.sup.*] = 0
and firms have to use solely efficiency wages to motivate workers. Note
that this case corresponds to the situation studied by Shapiro and
Stiglitz (1984). The following proposition summarizes the above results.
PROPOSITION 1. (a) Suppose c [greater than or equal to]
v/([delta][rho]). Then, the optimal contracts have the following form:
[b.sup.*] [member of] [v, [delta][rho]c] subject to [w.sup.*] = u + v -
[b.sup.*] [greater than or equal to] 0. Workers receive no wage premium,
and the optimal contract is purely in the form of performance pay. (b)
Suppose c [member of] (0, v/([delta][rho])). Then, the optimal contract
is the following: [b.sup.*] = [delta][rho]c and [w.sup.*] = u + (v -
[delta][rho]c)/[(1 - a)[delta][rho]]. Employed workers receive a
positive wage premium, which is decreasing in c. The optimal contract is
a combination of performance pay and efficiency wages. (c) Suppose c =
0. Then, the optimal contract has no performance pay component and is in
the form of pure efficiency wages.
D. Robustness
Note that the trigger strategies associated with the optimal
contract do constitute a subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium even when c
[member of] [0, v/([delta]p)) (so employed workers enjoy a positive wage
premium). This is because the worker and the firm make their separation
decisions simultaneously. Under this assumption, after one party's
deviation, the strategy profile (quit, fire) is optimal since unilateral deviation in separation decision would not change the outcome. (13)
So far, we have assumed that c is borne by firms solely. Now
suppose that the firm and the new worker share the turnover cost c
according to some bargaining rule, with the firm bearing cost [theta]c
and the new worker bearing (1 - [theta])c ([theta] [member of] (0, 1)).
We can go through the s[E.sup.*]e analysis again. Now, the firm can
enforce a credible bonus only up to [theta]([delta][rho]c), which is
less than [delta][rho]c in the basic model. However, now the worker has
less incentive to shirk since if he shirks, he will be fired and bear
the additional cost (1 - [theta])c in case he finds a new job later. The
amount of necessary efficiency wages is still decreasing in c if c
[member of] [0, v/ ([delta][rho])). Overall, the optimal bonus is
decreased, but the efficiency wage is more or less the same. The
qualitative results of the model remain the same.
Note that any severance pay has no value in overcoming the moral
hazard problems. Suppose employment contracts specify that firms pay
workers s whenever separation occurs. This severance pay s enables firms
to credibly enforce a bonus s. Under this circumstance, however, the
workers' moral hazard problem is not altered: though workers do not
receive the bonus s in the case of shirking, they receive a severance
pay s instead, thus there is no punishment for shirking.
IV. MARKET EQUILIBRIUM
In stationary market equilibria, all the firms in the market will
offer the same optimal contract derived in the previous section since
they face the same programming problem. Moreover, in equilibria, all
employed workers exert effort, all firms pay the implicit bonus (if
there is any), and employment relationships end only due to exogenous
separation. Denote [E.sup.*] as the employment level(s) in stationary
equilibria, which is determined by the firms' free entry condition:
(10) [bar.V]([w.sup.*], [b.sup.*], [E.sup.*]) = [p([E.sup.*]) -
[w.sup.*] - [b.sup.*] - [delta](1 - [rho])c]/ (1 - [delta]) - c = 0 =
[??] p([E.sup.*]) = [w.sup.*] + [b.sup.*] + (1 - [delta][rho])c.
The equilibrium job acquisition rate a is
(11) a = (1 - [rho])[E.sup.*]/(L - [rho][E.sup.*]).
Using Equation (11) and the results in Proposition 1, Equation (10)
can be written more explicitly. Specifically, for c [member of] [0,
v/([delta][rho])), Equation (10) becomes
(12) p([E.sup.*]) = u + v/([delta]p) + [v/([delta][rho]) - c] (1 -
[rho])[E.sup.*]/(L - [E.sup.*]).
For c [greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]), Equation (10)
can be rewritten as;
(13) p([E.sup.*]) = u + v/([delta][rho]) + (1 - [delta][rho])[c -
v/([delta][rho])].
The right-hand side of Equation (10) specifies the ALC per period
on the equilibrium path, with (1 - [delta][rho])c being the average
turnover costs incurred per period. Now, define
(14) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Thus, ALC(E) specifies an ALC curve. According to Equations (12)
and (13), market equilibria are determined by the intersection(s) of the
revenue product curve P(E) and the ALC curve ALC(E). It can be easily
seen from (14) that ALC is strictly increasing in [member of] if c
[member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])), and ALC is independent of [member of]
if c [greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]). On the other hand, the
revenue product curve p(E) is downward sloping. Therefore, the market
equilibrium must be unique. (14) Figure 2 illustrates the determination
of market equilibrium for the case c [member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])),
where point A denotes the market equilibrium.
A. Comparative Statics
We are interested in how changes in c affect the market
equilibrium.
PROPOSITION 2. For c [member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])), the
equilibrium employment level [E.sup.*] is increasing in c. For c
[greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]), [E.sup.*] is decreasing in
c.
Proof First consider the case c [member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])).
Differentiating Equation (12) with respect to c, we get
(15) [partial derivative][E.sup.*]/[partial derivative]c = (1 -
[rho])[E.sup.*](L - [E.sup.*]) /{[v/([delta][rho]) - c](1 - [rho])L -
p'([E.sup.*])(L - [E.sup.*]).sup.2]} > 0,
since [E.sup.*] [member of] (0, L) and p' ([E.sup.*]) < 0.
If c [greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]), then by Equation (13)
[partial derivative][E.sup.*]/[partial derivative]c = (1 -
[delta][rho])/p'([E.sup.*]) < 0.
It is surprising that the equilibrium employment level [E.sup.*] is
increasing in c when c is small. The intuition for this result is the
following. An increase in turnover costs by [DELTA]c can decrease the
total wage payment (or the wage premium) in every period by {l/[(1 -
a)[delta][rho]] - 1}[delta][rho][DELTA]c. On the other hand, the average
turnover costs per period on the equilibrium path increase by (1 -
[delta][rho])[DELTA]c. Overall, the first effect dominates the second
one. Intuitively, an increase in turnover costs reduces wage payment in
each period, while the increase in average turnover costs per period is
small since each job only incurs the turnover costs occasionally (with
probability 1 - [rho]) on the equilibrium path. Therefore, an increase
in c shifts the ALC curve downward, leading to an increase in [E.sup.*].
This result is reversed when c [greater than or equal to]
v/([delta][rho]). If c falls in this region, by Equation (14), an
increase in c shifts the ALC curve upward. This is because an increase
in c cannot reduce the wage payment further (the IRW condition is
binding), but it directly pushes up the average turnover costs per
period. Hence, the equilibrium employment level [E.sup.*] is decreasing
in c. By Equation (14), it can be easily seen that an increase in [rho]
or [delta] shifts the ALC curve down. Thus, as the exogenous separation
rate (1 - [rho]) decreases or the discount factor [delta] increases, the
equilibrium employment level [E.sup.*] increases.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Changes in c also affect the wage-employment relationship. For c
[member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])),
[partial derivative]([w.sup.*] + [b.sup.*])/[partial derivative]E =
[v/([delta][rho]) - c](1 - [rho])L /[(L - E).sup.2].
Thus, an increase in c reduces the wage-employment elasticity. This
is due to the fact that an increase in c reduces the required wage
premium, thus making wages less sensitive to the employment level.
B. Welfare Properties
Now, we study how changes in c affect social welfare. In the market
equilibrium, each firm's expected profit is 0 since p([E.sup.*]) =
ALC([E.sup.*]). The total social surplus S (per period) of the market
equilibrium with employment [E.sup.*] is
(16) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The first term is the social value of the total output or
consumers' total willingness to pay for the total output. The
second term is the total cost of labor, and the third term is the total
turnover cost incurred per period. Taking the derivative of Equation
(16) with respect to c,
(17) [partial derivative]S/[partial derivative]c = [p([E.sup.*]) -
(u + v) - (1 - [rho])c][partial derivative][E.sup.*]/[partial
derivative]c - (1 - [rho])[E.sup.*].
We first consider the case c [member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])).
Substituting [partial derivative][E.sup.*]/[partial derivative]c from
Equation (15) into Equation (17), we get
(18) [partial derivative]S/[partial derivative]c > 0 [??] v(1 -
[delta])/[delta] > - p'([E.sup.*])(L - [E.sup.*]).
Condition (18) is satisfied if [absolute value of
p'([E.sup.*])] is small enough. In other words, if the revenue
product of labor is elastic enough, then the social surplus is
increasing in turnover costs c. Intuitively, an increase in c has two
opposite effects on social welfare (see Equation 17). On one hand, it
directly increases the total turnover costs, thus reducing social
welfare. On the other hand, it increases the equilibrium level of
employment, thus increasing the social welfare. If the revenue product
of labor is elastic enough, a small increase in c can induce a big
increase in the equilibrium employment level, causing the positive
effect to dominate the negative effect and social welfare increases.
(15)
When c [greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]), the social
surplus is decreasing in c. This is because an increase in c reduces the
equilibrium employment [E.sup.*], thus both terms are negative in
Equation (17). Therefore, we have the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 3. If c [member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])) and Condition
(18) is satisfied (the revenue product of labor p(E) is elastic enough),
the social surplus is increasing in c. When c [greater than or equal to]
v/([delta][rho]), the social surplus is decreasing in c.
Proposition 3 is a surprising result: a little bit of (exogenous)
friction in markets can improve social welfare. Conventional wisdom
tells us that friction in markets is always bad, since it impedes the
smooth functioning of markets. However, our model shows that if there is
a double moral hazard problem in the market, a little bit of (exogenous)
friction in the market can actually make the market function more
effectively. The main reason is that without exogenous friction,
contingent contracts are not available; thus, to motivate one side of
the market (workers), a certain amount of matching friction has to be
created endogenously by using efficiency wages. The presence of some
exogenous friction alleviates the firms' moral hazard problem and
gives them commitment power, which makes contingent contracts
(performance pay) feasible. Contingent contracts not only reduce the
amount of endogenously created friction that is necessary to motivate
workers but also reduce the total amount of friction in the market that
is necessary to motivate workers. Broadly speaking, this result implies
that exogenous friction might be more efficient than endogenously
created friction in overcoming double moral hazard problems in markets.
C. Empirical Predictions and Policy Implications
Our model generates several testable empirical implications. The
first implication is about the forms of employment contracts. Our model
predicts that labor markets with different turnover costs will use
different forms of employment contracts. In particular, occupations with
high turnover costs are paid a high bonus, and those with low turnover
costs are paid a low bonus. The second implication is about total wage
payment. The model predicts that occupations with high turnover costs
are paid a low total wage, and those with low turnover costs are paid a
high total wage. This is because high turnover costs lead to high
bonuses, which reduce the wage premium. This also implies that workers
paid higher bonuses actually earn less than those paid low bonuses. (16)
The third implication is about the relationships among turnover
costs, bonuses, and unemployment. The model predicts that occupations
paid higher bonuses should have lower levels of unemployment. However,
the relationship between turnover costs and unemployment level is
nonmonotonic. Among the occupations with low turnover costs, the
occupations with higher turnover costs should have lower levels of
unemployment. On the other hand, among the occupations with high
turnover costs, the occupations with higher turnover costs should have
higher levels of unemployment. The final implication is about the
sensitivity of wage payment to employment levels. Specifically, wages
are less sensitive to the employment level in occupations with high
turnover costs than in occupations with low turnover costs.
By Proposition 4, if the existing turnover costs are small in
markets, it might be beneficial for the government to tax employers
(without compensating employees) whenever turnover occurs, thus
increasing the effective turnover costs. Actually, a government tax
always increases social welfare as long as the turnover costs c <
v/([delta][rho]). To see this, suppose c < v/([delta][rho]) and the
government imposes a turnover tax t with c + t < v/([delta][rho]).
Now, the social surplus becomes
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The equilibrium [E.sup.*] satisfies
p([E.sup.*]) = u + v/([delta][rho]) + [v/([delta][rho]) - c - t](1
- [rho])[E.sup.*]/(L - [E.sup.*]).
Note that [partial derivative][E.sup.*]/[partial derivative]t =
[partial derivative][E.sup.*]/[partial derivative]c > 0. Thus,
[partial derivative]S/[partial derivative]t = [p([E.sup.*]) - (u +
v) - (1 - [rho])c][partial derivative][E.sup.*]/[partial derivative]t
> 0.
Compared to Equation (17), the second term disappears because the
government collects the money. Therefore, the total social welfare is
always increasing in t as long as c + t [less than or equal to]
v/([delta][rho]). In fact, social welfare is maximized when t =
v/([delta][rho]) - c. Of course, the downside of a turnover[E.sup.*]ax
is that it may impede the free relocation of labor when firms have
different growth prospects, which is not modeled in the paper.
V. INCORPORATING SEARCH COSTS
In this section, we extend the basic model to incorporate
workers' search costs. Search costs are directly borne by workers.
More importantly, a worker incurs search costs as long as he has
actively searched for jobs, regardless of whether he finds one. Although
workers bear search costs directly, firms have to induce workers to
search for two reasons. First, firms need workers to fill vacancies
after exogenous separations occur. Second, to effectively discipline
shirkers, firms have incentives to reduce the effective job acquisition
rate by inducing workers to search.
We model the unemployed workers' search behavior as follows.
Anticipating the wage contracts that firms offer, in each period, each
unemployed worker decides whether and with what probability to search
(here, we allow workers to play mixed strategy regarding search). If a
worker searches, he incurs search costs [c.sub.s] > 0 in that period
regardless of the outcome. After unemployed workers make their search
decisions, the effective job acquisition rate a is determined, which is
the ratio of the number of unfilled vacancies to the population of
unemployed workers who search actively. Since the environment is
symmetric for all unemployed workers, we focus on symmetric strategies:
each unemployed worker searches with the same probability [sigma]
[member of] [0, 1]. Given [sigma], the stationary job acquisition rate
is
a = min{1, (1 - [rho])E/[[sigma](L - [rho]E)]}.
The presence of search costs [c.sub.s] has two effects on wage
contracts. First, it can discipline employed workers: if a worker
shirks, he will be fired and has to incur search costs [c.sub.s] for
several periods to find another job. Second, firms now have to induce
workers to search, since search costs are directly borne by workers.
Specifically, with the presence of [c.sub.s], the value functions become
the following:
[U.sup.N] = (w + b - v) + [delta][[rho][U.sup.N] + (1 -
[rho])[bar.U]] [U.sup.S] = w + [delta][bar.U] [bar.U] = max{u +
[delta][bar.U], a x [U.sup.N] + (1 - a)(u + [delta][bar.U]) -
[c.sub.s]}.
Note that [bar.U] is the maximum of two payoffs: the payoff if a
worker searches and the payoff if he does not search, taking a as given.
Firms' value functions are still the same as those in the basic
model.
Unlike the basic model, here the effective job acquisition rate a
depends on unemployed workers' search behavior. It is easy to check
that a reaches its low bound when [sigma] = 1. Define this low bound as
[a.bar](E) [equivalent to] (1 - [rho])E/(L - [rho]E)
Specifically, a is determined by the following formulas:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
In the first case, each unemployed worker searches with [sigma] =
1. This is because the return of search is higher than the search costs
even if all unemployed workers search with [sigma] = 1. In the second
case, each unemployed worker does not search ([sigma] = 0) because the
return of search is too low. In the third case, neither Condition (C1)
nor Condition (C2) is satisfied. In this situation, only a mixed
strategy equilibrium exists: each unemployed worker searches with
[sigma] [member of] (0, 1) such that everyone is indifferent between
searching and not searching. More explicitly, Condition (C3) and a can
be written as:
(19) [c.sub.s](1 - [delta][rho]) [less than or equal to] (w + b) -
(u + v) [less than or equal to] (1 - [delta][rho])([c.sub.s]/[bar.a]
(20) a = [c.sub.s](1 - [delta][rho])/[(w + b) - (u + v)].
The new programming problem for each firm is as follows, taking the
job acquisition rate a as given:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to:
[U.sup.N] [greater than or equal to] [bar.U] (IRW1) a[U.sup.N] - (u
+ [delta][bar.U)] - [c.sub.s] [greater than or equal to] 0 (IRW2)
[bar.V] = [V.sup.N] - c = 0 (IRF) [U.sup.N] [greater than or equal to]
[U.sup.S] (ICW) [V.sup.N] [greater than or equal to] [V.sup.C] (ICF).
Compared to the programming problem in the basic model, the IRW2
condition is added because firms have to induce workers to search. Given
the IRW2 condition and the ICW condition, the IRW1 condition can be
rewritten as:
[U.sup.N] - (u + [delta][bar.U]) [greater than or equal to]
[c.sub.s]/(1 - a).
The IRW2 condition can be rewritten as:
[U.sup.N] - (u + [delta][bar.U]) [greater than or equal to]
[c.sub.s]/a.
Thus, the IRW1 condition is redundant. Getting rid of the value
functions, we can simplify the programming problem as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to:
w [greater than or equal to] u + V - b + (1 -
[delta][rho])[c.sub.s]/a (IRW2) w [greater than or equal to] u + (v - b
- [delta][rho][c.sub.s])\(1 - a)[delta][rho]] (ICW) b [less than or
equal to] [delta][rho]c (ICF).
Depending on parameter values, we have two possible scenarios. In
the first scenario, [delta][rho](c + [c.sub.s]) [greater than or equal
to] v, thus efficiency wages are not necessary. Without loss of
generality, firms set [b.sup.*] = v - [delta][rho][c.sub.s]. Now, the
ICW condition becomes w [greater than or equal to] u, and the IRW2
condition becomes
w [greater than or equal to] u + [delta][rho][c.sub.s] + (1 -
[delta][rho])[c.sub.s]/a.
Thus, the ICW condition is redundant if the IRW2 condition is
satisfied. In the optimal contract, the IRW2 is binding with a = 1. That
is,
[w.sup.*] = u + [delta][rho][c.sub.s] + (1 -
[delta][rho])[c.sub.s]/a = u + [c.sub.s].
Under the optimal contract, it can be easily seen that Equation
(19) is satisfied and a = 1 by Equation (20). This is because under the
optimal contract, unemployed workers will adjust their search behavior
such that the job acquisition rate a = 1. The ALC curve can be written
as:
(21) ALC(E) = [w.sup.*] + [b.sup.*] + (1 - [delta][rho])c = u + v +
(1 - [delta][rho])(c + [c.sub.s]).
which is independent of the employment level E.
In the second scenario [delta][rho](c + [c.sub.s]) < v, thus
efficiency wages are necessary. The optimal bonus is [b.sup.*] =
[delta][rho]c. Now, the IRW2 condition no longer implies the ICW
condition. The following lemma specifies the optimal [w.sup.*].
LEMMA 2. There is a cutoff [??] [member of] (0, L) such that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [??] is defined by
(23) v - [delta][rho]c + [c.sub.s](1 - [delta][rho])(L -
[rho][??]/[(1 - [rho])/[??]] = [v/([delta][rho]) - c - [c.sub.s]](L -
[[rho][??])/(L - [??]).
Proof See the Appendix.
The intuition for Lemma 2 is as follows. With the presence of
search costs, wage contracts need to serve two purposes: motivate
employed workers and induce unemployed workers to search. Both of them
require the wage to be high relative to unemployment benefit. Moreover,
both of them are affected by the employment level. When the employment
level is high, the resulting high job acquisition rate makes motivating
workers relatively more difficult. In this case, the wage should be set
just enough to motivate workers. On the other hand, when the employment
level is low, inducing search is relatively more difficult. However,
because unemployed workers will endogenously adjust their search
behavior, the wage is set just high enough to induce the job acquisition
rate [??] = (1 - [rho])[??]/(L - [rho][??]), at which both the ICW and
the IRW2 conditions are binding.
Following Lemma 2, the ALC curve ALC(E) can be easily derived, and
the equilibrium employment level [E.sup.*] is pinned down by firms'
free entry condition: p([E.sup.*]) = ALC([E.sup.*]).
We are interested in the wage-employment relationship. By Equation
(22), when E > [??], the total wage payment [w.sup.*] + [b.sup.*] is
increasing in the employment level E. On the other hand, when E <
[??], the total wage payment [w.sup.*] + [b.sup.*] is independent of E.
(17) This is an interesting result: the wage-employment relationship
changes over the course of business cycle. Specifically, wages are rigid
during recessions and are positively correlated with the employment
level during booms. The following proposition summarizes the above
result.
PROPOSITION 4. Suppose [delta][rho](c + [c.sub.s]) < v. Wages
are rigid during recessions and are positively correlated with the
employment level during booms. Specifically, the total wage payment is
increasing in E when E > [??] and is independent of E when E <
[??].
If unemployed workers play pure strategies regarding search, then
the total wagepayment is actually decreasing in E when E < [??]. This
is because when E < [??], the IRW2 condition is binding. A decrease
in E directly reduces the return to searching, as the job acquisition
rate a decreases. To induce every unemployed worker to search (with
probability 1), the total wage payment has to increase. As a result, the
wage-employment relationship now assumes a U-shape. This is a more
dramatic result: wages are procyclical during booms and countercyclical
during recessions. In reality, we believe that unemployed workers are
able to adjust their search behavior but not perfectly as our formal
model assumed (because it needs perfect coordination). Therefore, more
realistically wages are slightly countercyclical during recessions.
The existing theories usually predict a monotonic relationship
between wages and unemployment. The efficiency wage model of Shapiro and
Stiglitz shows that there is always a negative relationship between
wages and unemployment, while the migration model of Harris and Tadaro
(1970) predicts that there is always a positive relationship. In
contrast, our model predicts that the wage-unemployment relationship
might be different in different phases of business cycle.
Contractual approaches to wage determination predict that wages are
history dependent. Based on the implicit contract approach of Harris and
Holmstrom (1982), Beaudry and DiNardo (1991) showed that wages are
downward rigid and are bid up if the market condition improves
sufficiently to ensure that workers do not quit. (18) Thus, wage
payments depend on the most favorable labor market condition observed
since one has begun his job. MM (1993) and Malcomson (1997) studied the
dynamics of fixed wage contracts in the presence of holdup problems.
They show that wages are rigid with respect to shocks of small
magnitudes. When the cumulative shock reaches sufficient magnitude, the
wages are renegotiated either upward or downward to reflect the current
market condition. Though related, our prediction is different from those
implications. Specifically, in our model, wages are flexible(both upward
and downward) in booms (E > [??]) but are rigid in recessions (E <
[??]). On the other hand, the history-dependent wage-employment
relationships predicted by the above papers do not depend on whether the
economy is in recession or boom.
We are also interested in how changes in turnover costs affect the
wage rigidity region. From Equation (23), we can see that an increase in
c or [c.sub.s] reduces [??]; thus, the wage rigidity region expands.
Intuitively, an increase in c or [c.sub.s] reduces the efficiency wage
that is necessary to motivate workers, thus inducing workers to search
becomes relatively more difficult. As a result, the job acquisition rate
[??] (hence [??]) at which both the ICW and the IRW2 conditions are
binding increases. By Equation (22), an increase in c or [c.sub.s] makes
wages in the wage-procyclical region less sensitive to the employment
level. This is simply because the required wage premium is smaller.
VI. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Tables 1 and 2 summarize the empirical predictions of the basic
model and the extended model, respectively. Note that all these
predictions are essentially comparative statics results.
A. Forms of Contracts
There are only a few empirical works on the relationships between
occupation and bonuses. (19) And in available data, only the frequency
of bonuses is reported but not the amount of the bonuses. Note that the
prediction of our model is about different amounts of merit pay in
different occupations. To proceed, we simply make the assumption that
the frequency of bonuses and the amount of bonuses are positively
correlated.
Table 3 is excerpted from table 3B of MacLeod and Parent (1999),
which is based on the NLSY data (1988-1990). From the table, managers
have the highest bonus payment, food and cleaning service workers have
the lowest bonus payment, and professionals and secretaries are paid
with medium-sized bonuses. A similar pattern holds when bonus plus
promotion is used as the measure of discretionary pay. (20) This pattern
is largely consistent with the predictions of our model. This is because
managers usually have high turnover costs, service workers low turnover
costs, and professionals and secretaries medium turnover costs.
The turnover costs for managers are usually high for two reasons.
First, some firm-specific knowledge is needed for a manager to be
effective in a firm, and it takes time for a new manager to acquire this
knowledge. Second, each managing job may require a different combination
of skills and personality, so finding appropriate candidates for a
vacancy takes a long time and requires substantial effort. As a result,
the recruiting costs for managers are relatively high. On the other
hand, the jobs for food service and cleaning workers are fairly standard
across firms. Therefore, their turnover costs are usually low. It is
also reasonable to think that the turnover costs for professionals and
secretaries are lower than those of managers and higher than those of
service workers, since their jobs usually have a firm-specific component
which is smaller than managers' but bigger than service
workers'.
A similar pattern emerges from the 1990 British Workplace
Industrial Relations Survey (WIRS), which is reported in Table 4. Manual
workers have the smallest bonus, while managers have the highest bonus.
Moreover, among manual workers, the incidence of bonuses is decreasing
in their skills. This is also largely consistent with our model, since
turnover costs in an occupation are roughly increasing in required
skills: the more skills a job requires, the more firm-specific skills
are involved, hence the higher the turnover costs.
Though this empirical evidence is largely consistent with our
model, it is not a test of our theory. (21) We hope that some carefully
designed empirical work can be done in the near future to directly test
our model.
B. Wage Differentials and Unemployment
Using data from the Industrial Wage Survey, Brown (1992) conducted
an empirical study on the relationship between wage levels and methods
of pay. He found that workers paid by standard rates on average earn a
higher wage than those with merit pay. Standard rates and merit pay
correspond to efficiency wages and subjective performance pay,
respectively, in theoretical models. This empirical evidence is
consistent with the prediction of our model: merit pay can reduce the
amount of efficiency wages, so workers paid by standard rates enjoy a
higher wage premium, hence earn more than workers with merit pay. (22)
One implication of our model is that the level of equilibrium
unemployment is a decreasing function of the usage of bonuses. Based on
the 1990 British WIRS data, MM found that there is a negative
correlation between the percentages of workers with merit pay and
unemployment rates among occupations. The study by MacLeod and Parent
(1999) further supports this result. Using data from the NLSY 1988-1990,
they showed that there is a strong negative relationship between the use
of discretionary bonuses and local unemployment.
C. The Wage Curve
As in Solon, Barsky, and Parker (1994), most of the empirical works
just test whether the real wage is procyclical but do not estimate the
whole wage curve. Fortunately, a small but important literature
initiated by Blanchflower and Oswald (1994, BO hereafter) does estimate
the whole wage curve. Using the U.S. General Social Survey (GSS) data
(1974-1988), they estimated the industry wage curve (wage as a function
of the unemployment rate in industries) and the regional wage curve
(wage as a function of the regional unemployment rate). Figure 3, copied
from BO (p. 107), illustrates their estimation result. Both curves are
initially downward sloping and then become upward sloping. Both wages
are minimized at an unemployment rate of approximately 6%-8%. These wage
curves are consistent with the empirical predictions of our extended
model. The upward-sloping portion of the wage curve suggests that
unemployed workers are not able to adjust perfectly their search
behavior.
BO also estimated the wage curve based on the U.S. Current
Population Surveys (1964-1991). The results are slightly different from
those from the GSS: the wage curve is significantly downward sloping
when the unemployment rate is low, and it flattens out as the
unemployment rate increases, but there is no upward-sloping portion of
the wage curve. A similar estimation result holds for data from the
British Social Attitude Surveys (1983-1989): the wage curve flattens out
when the unemployment rate is greater than 13%. Using the General
Household Surveys' data (1973-1977) from Britain, BO found that the
wage curve has a U-shape with the turning point occurring around an
unemployment rate of 4.5%. Based on the International Social Survey
Program data (1986-1991) from West Germany, the estimation of BO shows
that the wage curve flattens out around an unemployment rate of 11%.
Bratsberg and Turunen (1996) estimated the U.S. wage curve for young
workers using the 1979-1993 waves of the NLSY. According to their study,
the wage curve based on annual earnings flattens out when the
unemployment rate is higher than 12% and the wage curve based on hourly
wage exhibits a U-shape with the minimum wage reached at an 11.5%
unemployment rate.
Though there are some minor differences, all the above estimation
results show that the wage curve either flattens out or becomes upward
sloping at fairly high unemployment rates. They are largely consistent
with our empirical prediction that wages are procyclical during booms
and either rigid or countercyclical in recessions.
D. Wage-Unemployment Elasticity
BO also estimated the wage-unemployment relationship for different
occupations using data from the 1990 British WIRS. The results are
reported in Table 5. Unskilled manual workers have the largest
wage-unemployment elasticity, supervisors the lowest elasticity, and
clerical workers some medium elasticity. As we argued before, turnover
costs are increasing in the order of unskilled manual workers, clerical
workers, and supervisors. Therefore, the pattern of wage-unemployment
elasticity is largely consistent with the predictions of our model.
Unskilled manual workers have the lowest turnover costs; hence, their
methods of pay are mainly efficiency wages. As a result, their wages are
more procyclical. On the other hand, supervisors (managers) have high
turnover costs; thus, their methods of pay are mainly subjective
performance pay, which leads to low wage-unemployment elasticity.
Table 6 reports the results of two other studies: BO on the British
General Household Surveys 1973-1977 and Kennedy and Borland (2000) on
the Australian Bureau of Statistics Income Distribution Survey
1982-1994. Again, managers have the lowest wage-unemployment elasticity,
and manual workers or clerks have the highest elasticity.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
VII. CONCLUSIONS
We studied contract selection between efficiency wages and
subjective performance pay to motivate workers in a labor market
setting. Though subjective performance pay is cheaper than efficiency
wages, it is limited by the firms' incentive to renege. The
presence of turnover costs borne by firms reduces firms' incentives
to renege, thus making implicit bonuses credible to some extent. In the
optimal contracts, the amount of the bonus is positively correlated and
the amount of wage premium negatively correlated with the turnover costs
borne by firms. Up to some threshold, an increase in turnover costs
effectively reduces the total wage payment and total labor costs, thus
increasing the equilibrium employment level and social welfare.
The extended model incorporates workers' search costs. In this
setting, the wage-unemployment relationship turns out to be different
during booms and recessions: wages are procyclical in booms and are
either rigid or countercyclical in recessions. Our model generates rich
empirical implications. The forms of wage contracts and total wage
payments are different in occupations with different turnover costs.
Occupations using more bonus payments have lower total wage payments and
lower unemployment rates. Occupations with high turnover costs have low
wage-unemployment elasticity. Some empirical evidence is consistent with
these predictions.
Though our model is couched in a labor market setting, it can also
be applied to other markets where both parties in a relationship have
moral hazard problems and both are able to change partners in markets.
For example, consider buyer-seller relationships in a market setting, in
which the quality of goods is observable but not verifiable. To
motivated sellers, buyers can either offer higher fixed prices
(analogous to efficiency wages) or post some bonuses (which have to be
self-enforcing), tying payments to the quality of goods. Turnover costs
will generally affect the optimal contracts and have welfare
implications, similar to those shown in the labor market model.
The model can be extended in several directions. First, in the
model, we have assumed that the turnover costs are exogenous. When firms
are able to choose turnover costs within some range, they might have
incentives to choose the level of turnover costs that minimizes their
ALCs. Second, in the model, we have assumed that workers are
homogeneous. Yang (2005) studied relational contracts with heterogeneous workers. Now moral hazard interacts with firms' learning about
workers' types, which results in nonstationary relational
contracts. This helps to explain why contractual terms change as the
length of a relationship increases. Third, it is also interesting to
model relational contracts in a setting where the demand for labor is
fluctuating over time. Such a model enables us to see more explicitly
how wages and contract forms change during the course of business
cycles. This is left for future research.
ABBREVIATIONS
ALC: Average Labor Cost
BO: Blanchflower and Oswald
GSS: General Social Survey
MM: MacLeod and Malcomson
NLSY: National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth WIRS: Workplace
Industrial Relations Survey
APPENDIX
Proof of lemma 1.
After some algebra, the programming problem can be simplified as
the following:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(24) w + b [greater than or equal to] u + v (IRW)
(25) w [greater than or equal to] u + k(v-b) (ICW)
(26) b [less than or equal to] [delta][rho]c (ICF)
where k = l/[(1 - a)[delta][rho]] > 1. Condition (25) can be
further reformulated as:
(27) w + b [greater than or equal to] u + v + (k - 1)(v - b).
From Equation (27), we see that if b < v, then only Equation
(25) is binding and the total compensation w + b is decreasing in b; so
b should be set as high as possible subject to condition (26). Condition
(24) is binding if and only if b [greater than or equal to] v. Actually,
Condition (24) specifies the low bound of the total wage payment, u + v.
Therefore, when c < v/([delta][rho]), the optimal contract is
[b.sup.*] = [delta][rho]c and [w.sup.*] = u + k(v - [b.sup.*]). When c
[greater than or equal to]v/([delta][rho]), the optimal contracts are
[b.sup.*] [member of] [v, [delta][rho]c] subject to [w.sup.*] = u + v -
[b.sup.*] >0.
Proof of lemma 2.
Note that the right-hand side of the IRW2 condition is decreasing
in a and goes to infinity as a goes to 0. On the other hand, the
right-hand side of the ICW condition is increasing in a and goes to
infinity as a goes to 1. Thus, there is an a [member of] (0, 1) such
that the right-hand sides of both conditions are equal. That is,
(28) v - [delta][rho]c + (1 - [delta][rho])[c.sub.s]/[??] = (v -
[delta][rho]c - [delta][rho][c.sub.s])/[(1 - [??])[delta][rho]]
Therefore, if a > [??], then the IRW2 condition is redundant and
the ICW condition is binding. If a [less than or equal to] [??], then
the ICW condition is redundant and the IRW2 condition is binding.
Moreover, the fixed wage w is minimized when a = [??]. Define [??] such
that
(29) (1 - [rho])[??]/(L - [rho]>[??]) [equivalent to] [??].
Note that [??] is unique and {??] [member of] (0, L). Combining
Equations (28) and (29) gives rise to Equation (23). First, consider the
case E > [??]. Then,
[a.bar](E) = (1 - [rho])E/(L - [rho]E) > (1 - [rho])[??]/ (L -
[rho][??]) = [??].
Thus, the binding condition is the ICW condition, and firms will
induce unemployed workers to search with probability 1 with the
effective a equaling the low bound [a.bar](E). As a result, the optimal
[w.sup.*] is given by:
[w.sup.*] = u + [v- [delta][rho](c + [c.sub.s])](L -
[rho]E)/[[delta][rho] (L - E)].
Now, consider the case E [less than or equal to] [??]. In this
case, firms will just induce [??] by paying the following wage:
[w.sup.*] = u+v-[delta][rho]c+(1 - [delta][rho])[c.sub.s] (L -
[rho][??])/[(1 - [rho])[??]].
With the wage specified above, it can be verified that Equation
(19) is satisfied and that from Equation (20), the effective a is
a = [c.sub.s](1 - [delta][rho])/[[w.sup.*] + [delta][rho]c) - (u +
v)] = (1 - [rho])[??]/(L - [rho][??]) = [??].
HUANXING YANG, I wish to thank two anonymous referees, Ken Burdett,
Bill Dupor, Jan Eeckhout, Paul Evans, Rafael Rob, and the participants
at the Fall 2003 Midwest Theory Conference for helpful comments and
discussions. I am truly indebted to Steven Matthews for his invaluable
advice and guidance. The usual disclaimers apply.
Yang: Assistant Professor of Economics, Ohio State University, 405
Arps Hall, 1945 N. High Street, Columbus, OH 43210. Phone 614-292-6523,
Fax 614-292-3906, Email yang. 1041@osu.edu
REFERENCES
Akerlof, G., and L. Katz. "Workers' Trust Funds and The
Logic of Wage Profiles." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 1989,
525-36.
Baker, G., R. Gibbons, and K. Murphy. "Subjective Performance
Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts." Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 109, 1994, 1125-56.
Beaudry, P., and J. DiNardo. "The Effects of Implicit
Contracts on the Movement of Wages over the Business Cycle: Evidence
from Micro Data." Journal of Political Economy, 99, 1991, 665-88.
Blanchflower, D., and A. Oswald. The Wage Curve. Boston, MA: The
MIT Press, 1994.
Bratsberg, B., and J. Turunen. "Wage Curve Evidence from Panel
Data." Economics Letters, 51, 1996, 345-53.
Brown, C. "Wage Levels and Method of Pay." Rand Journal
of Economics, 23, 1992, 366-75.
Bull, C. "The Existence of Self-Enforcing Implicit
Contracts." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 1987, 147-59.
Farrell, J., and E. Maskin. "Renegotiation in Repeated
Games." Games and Economic Behavior, 1, 1989, 327-60.
Green, F., A. Felstead, K. Mayhew, and A. Pack. "The Impact of
Training on Labor Mobility: Individual and Firm-Level Evidence from
Britain." British Journal of Industrial Relations, 38, 2000,
261-75.
Harris, M., and B. Holmstrom. "A Theory of Wage
Dynamics." Review of Economic Studies, 49, 1982, 315-33.
Harris, J., and M. Tadaro. "Migration, Unemployment and
Development: A Two-Sector Analysis." American Economic Review, 60,
1970, 126-42.
Hashimoto, M., and B. Yu. "Specific Capital, Employment
Contracts, and Wage Rigidity." Bell Journal of Economics, 11, 1980,
536-49.
Kennedy, S., and J. Borland. "A Wage Curve for
Australia." Oxford Economic Papers, 52, 2000, 774-803.
Lang, K. "Persistent Wage Dispersion and Involuntary Unemployment." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 1991, 181-202.
Levin, J. "Relational Incentive Contracts." American
Economic Review, 93, 2003, 835-57.
MacLeod, B., and J. Malcomson. "Implicit Contracts, Incentive
Compatibility, and Involuntary Unemployment." Econometrica, 57,
1989, 447-80.
--. "Investments, Holdup, and the Form of Market
Contracts." American Economic Review, 83, 1993, 811-37.
--. "Motivation and Markets." American Economic Review,
88, 1998, 388-411.
MacLeod, B., and D. Parent. "Job Characteristics and the Form
of Compensation." Research in Labor Economics, 18, 1999, 177-242.
Malcomson, J. "Contracts, Holdup, and the Labor Markets."
Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 1997, 1916--57.
Salop, S. "A Model of the Natural Rate of Unemployment."
American Economic Review, 69, 1979, 117-25.
Shapiro, C., and J. Stiglitz. "Equilibrium Unemployment as a
Worker Discipline Device." American Economic Review, 74, 1984,
433-44.
Solon, G., R. Barsky, and J. Parker. "Measuring the
Cyclicality of Real Wages: How Important is Composition Bias."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 1994, 1-25.
Stiglitz, J. "Alternative Theories of Wage Determination and
Unemployment in LDCs: The Labor Turnover Model." Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 88, 1974, 194-27.
Yang, H. "Nonstationary Relational Contracts." Working
Paper, Ohio State University, 2005.
(1.) See Section VI for details.
(2.) An alternative setting would be that, while [e.sub.t] is not
observable, the performance is observable but not verifiable, and et
determines the worker's performance with some noise. The only
difference this alternative setting makes is that shirking cannot be
detected for sure. Since workers are risk neutral, the qualitative
results of the paper still hold under this alternative setting.
(3.) For some jobs, Lang (1991) found that firms are willing to pay
employment agencies large sums for finding workers.
(4.) See Hashimoto and Yu (1980) for the issue of firm-specific
human capital.
(5.) [c.sub.F] can be interpreted as the training cost to acquire
firm-specific skills.
(6.) This assumption is not unrealistic. An empirical study by
Green et al. (2000) shows that even expenses on most transferable
training are paid by employers.
(7.) Alternatively, it is also possible that endogenous separation
decisions are made before exogenous separation occurs. But whether
exogenous separation occurs before or after endogenous separation
decisions are made does not matter, since a match breaks up if either
separation occurs.
(8.) Another minor difference is that in MM, there is a job
creation cost. Incorporating a job creation cost would not change the
qualitative results of our paper.
(9.) External reputation may not work for two reasons. First,
outsiders do not know exactly whether a separation occurs due to
exogenous reasons or cheating. Second, even if a separation is known to
be due to cheating, outsiders do not know exactly which party is at
fault.
(10.) The trigger strategies are appealing in practice: if at least
one party violates the relational contract, the informal relationship
sours and is unlikely to continue.
(11.) Given that workers are playing trigger strategy, for a
reneging firm, paying 0 instead of any positive bonus less than b is the
most profitable deviation.
(12.) In MM, a firm's rent from continued employment comes
from the fact that the firm may not have its vacancy filled immediately,
which is possible only when J > L. This rules out the use of
performance pay when J [less than or equal to] L.
(13.) Note that since any endogenous separation results in welfare
loss (turnover costs c have to be incurred), the equilibria derived
under trigger strategies are not renegotiation proof. In the previous
version, we show that the optimal contract derived under trigger
strategies can be supported as the optimal contract in a strongly
renegotiation proof equilibrium in the sense of Farrell and Maskin
(1989). The proof is available upon request.
(14.) For c [member of] [0, v/([delta][rho])], the existence of
equilibrium [E.sup.*] c (0, L) is guaranteed if p(0) > u +
v/([delta][rho]). For c [greater than or equal to] v/([delta][rho]), the
existence of equilibrium [E.sup.*] [member of] (0, L) is ensured if p(L)
< u + v/([delta][rho]) + (1 - [delta][rho])[c - v/([delta][rho])]
< p(0).
(15.) Condition (18) depends on the endogenous variable [E.sup.*].
A more primitive condition cannot be derived unless we impose a specific
functional form on p(E). This is because [E.sup.*] cannot be explicitly
solved with a general p(E), which is evident from Equation (12). To
derive a more primitive condition, we assume
p(E) = u + v/([delta][rho]) + k(L - E),
with k [greater than or equal to] 0 being some constant. Note that
the smaller the k, the more elastic is the revenue product of labor.
Now, Condition (18) can be written as:
[v.sup.2](1 - [delta]).sup.2]/[[delta].sup.2] + (1 -
[rho])[v/([delta][rho]) - c](1 - [delta])/ [delta] > kL(1 -
[rho])[v/([delta][rho]) - c].
The above condition is valid if k is small enough or the exogenous
turnover rate 1 - [rho] is close to 0.
(16.) of course, this result crucially depends on the risk
neutrality of workers.
(17.) Note that without search costs, the total wage payment is
always increasing in E when efficiency wages are necessary.
(18.) In a model of long-term implicit contracts, Harris and
Holmstrom (1982) showed that wages are downward rigid and are bid up
when workers' perceived ability increases. These results crucially
depend on firms' ability to commit to long-term contracts.
(19.) Throughout this section, both merit pay and bonuses refer to
subjective performance pay. They are not objective performance pay,
which is conditional on contractible performance.
(20.) Promotion, which usually is associated with a permanent wage
increase, as a deferred compensation can also motivate workers to exert
effort.
(21.) One may think that the pattern given in Table 3 is also
consistent with firms using bonuses to select more able workers, which
may matter more in managerial occupations and for professionals.
However, bonuses cannot be enforced by the court. Therefore, how much
bonus will be posted does not only depend on how much bonus firms are
willing to post but also depend on how much firms can credibly post.
(22.) Combined with the information given in Table 3, the
prediction that occupations receiving higher bonuses would have a lower
level of total compensation implies that managers would have lower total
compensation on average than cleaning service workers. This seems to
contradict the fact that managers earn more than cleaning service
workers. However, in Brown's empirical analysis, he controlled for
human capital. The fact that managers earn more than cleaning workers is
simply because the former have more human capital. After controlling for
human capital, cleaning workers actually earn more than managers.
TABLE 1
Empirical Predictions
Low Turnover High Turnover
Costs Costs
Contract form Mainly efficiency Big bonuses
wages
Total wage payment High Low
Unemployment High Low
Wage-unemployment High Low
elasticity
TABLE 2
Empirical Predictions II
Procyclical in booms,
rigid in recessions
The wage Low Turnover High Turnover
curve Costs Costs
The wage Big Small
rigidity region
Wage-unemployment High Low
elasticity
TABLE 3
Bonuses across Occupations I
Bonus +
Occupations Bonus (%) Promotion (%)
Managers 28.46 47.37
Professionals 15.46 29.22
Secretaries 11.60 25.60
Food service workers 7.49 18.66
Cleaning service workers 7.43 17.33
TABLE 4
Bonuses across Occupations II
Occupations Incidence of Bonus (%)
Professional and managerial 35
Supervisors 32
Clerical, administrative, 30
and secretarial
Skilled manual 22
Semiskilled manual 16
Unskilled manual 11
TABLE 5
Wage-unemployment Elasticities I
Occupations Coefficient
Unskilled manual -0.0916
Skilled manual -0.0325
Clerical -0.0434
Supervisors -0.0048
TABLE 6
Wage-unemployment Elasticities II
Occupations British GHS data ABS IDS data
Manual -0.0721
Clerks -0.0896
Professionals -0.0631 -0.0224
Managers -0.0497 -0.0198
Notes: GHS = General Household Survey; ABS IDS =
Australian Bureau of Statistics Income Distribution
Survey.