Fixed revenue auctions: theory and behavior.
Deck, Cary A. ; Wilson, Bart J.
I. INTRODUCTION
There are numerous varieties of auction institutions used in
practice and studied in the economics literature. The four standard
mechanisms for selling a fixed quantity as in a single unit or lot are
the English, Dutch, first-price sealed bid, and second-price sealed bid
auctions. The widely known theoretical results are that the English and
second-price auctions are equivalent as are the Dutch and first-price
auctions. One of the most insightful theoretical results of private
value auctions is that under certain assumptions the expected revenue is
constant across the four mechanisms (see McAfee and McMillan 1987;
Milgrom 1987; Myerson 1981). But behavioral examinations of private
value auctions have consistently found that the relationships among the
formats are not so straightforward. English clock auctions generate
truthful revelation as predicted; however, second-price auctions, which
should also generate truthful revelation, do not reliably do so in a
laboratory setting (Harstad 2000; Kagel, Harstad, and Levine 1987).
Further, revenue equivalence does not hold between first-price and
second-price auctions (Coppinger, Smith, and Titus 1980). (1) In part,
this is due to the fact that many bidders in first-price auctions act as
if they are risk averse. Furthermore, Dutch auctions and first-price
sealed bid auctions are not behaviorally isomorphic; observed prices are
significantly lower in the Dutch clock auctions than in first-price
auctions (Cox, Roberson, and Smith 1982).
Almost exclusively, the focus of previous work has been on auctions
determining the selling price for a prespecified lot. (2) However, in
some situations, a seller may be more concerned about raising a fixed
amount of revenue. For example, a business may sell off just enough
inventory to gain the needed liquidity to undertake a particular
project. A person may pawn just enough items to secure money with which
to pay the monthly bills. Alternatively, in a procurement setting, a
buyer may desire to acquire as much as possible for some nonfungible
fixed budget. For example, a researcher whose grant is expiring may buy
as many supplies as possible with the remaining money or a firm may have
a fixed advertising budget with which to buy the most effective
campaign. Though not typically thought of in this way, auctions can be
used to solve these types of problems as well. (3) We define a fixed
revenue auction to be a bidding mechanism in which a prespecified total
payment is exchanged for a variable quantity of a good. (4) Wessen and
Porter (1997) developed a fixed revenue auction to cover the $326,000
cost of moving antennae for the Cassini mission to Saturn. The auction
allowed competing research teams to place bids in terms of the mass they
desired on the craft and the price per unit for the mass.
The goal of this paper is to understand the behavioral properties
of fixed revenue auctions utilizing the four standard mechanisms. To
enable comparisons with the extensive literature on auctions, the
environment is designed to allow the maximum similarity between auctions
in the two dimensions. This includes placing nontrivial restrictions on
buyer values to yield a theoretical equivalence between auction
dimensions. Given this, one might be inclined to suppose that the
behavioral properties are a forgone conclusion. This need not be the
case as evidenced by the aforementioned lack of isomorphism between
first-price and Dutch auctions and between English and second-price
auctions in the standard setting. Experiments have shown that even
simple changes in framing can impact behavior. (5) For example, framing
a lottery as a gain or a loss can change the value one places on the
lottery and framing the ultimatum game as a buyer-seller interaction can
lead to behavior more consistent with material self-interest. A change
in auction dimension, however, is more than a simple framing effect; it
is a change in the underlying decision problem. A priori, it is not
known how a dimensional change will influence behavior. If behavior
differs by dimension, the experiments could provide new insights into
how people approach these institutions. (6) If behavior is consistent
with previous results, then it provides greater confidence in the
robustness of previous work.
The next section presents a theoretical treatment of each mechanism
in a fixed revenue context. Separate sections discuss the design and
results of laboratory experiments investigating behavior in these
auctions. A final section contains concluding remarks. As a prelude to
our results, we find that under a generalization of the typical
assumption regarding values, the theoretical and behavioral properties
of the four standard auctions translate to a fixed quantity dimension in
a consistent and an intuitive way.
II. THEORETICAL MODEL
We begin by considering the standard, fixed quantity auction format
and then identify where and how fixed revenue auctions differ from the
familiar model. In the single (fixed)-unit, independent private value
auction, there are n bidders who value the lot up for auction. In the
English auction, the price starts low and increases until only one
bidder remains willing to purchase. The sole remaining bidder buys the
item at the final price. (7) The Dutch auction begins with a high price
that falls until a bidder agrees to purchase at that price. In contrast,
first- and second-price sealed bid auctions are both static in that
potential buyers submit sealed bids. For the first-price sealed bid
auction, the party submitting the highest bid wins the auction and pays
a price equal to his winning bid, whereas in the second-price sealed bid
auction, the party submitting the highest bid wins but pays a price
equal to the second highest bid.
Assuming a uniform distribution of values over the interval
[[v.bar], [bar.v]] and risk-neutral bidders, the following results for
the Nash equilibrium bid functions are well known:
(1) b(v) = [v.bar] + [(n- 1)/n](v - [v.bar]) for first-price sealed
bid and Dutch clock auctions
and
(2) b(v) = v for second-price sealed bid and English clock
auctions.
In the standard auction, the quantity q is set by the seller. To
consider fixed revenue auctions, we must generalize the notion of value
to be a function of quantity, v(q). Figure 1 shows various possible
value functions. Standard, fixed quantity auctions are vertical slice of
this figure, as in the dashed line. In a fixed revenue auction, q is the
amount of the bid.
Fixed quantity English auctions start with a "low" price
that multiple buyers are willing to accept and gradually increase prices
thereby becoming less favorable to the bidders. For a fixed revenue
auction, a favorable starting position for the buyer would be a large
quantity. Making the trade less desirable to the buyer involves reducing
the quantity. Thus, in both dimensions, English auctions approach value
curves from below. Dutch auctions for a standard, fixed quantity start
with a "high" price which gradually decreases, becoming more
favorable to the bidders. The parallel for a fixed revenue auction would
be to start with an undesirable low quantity which increases to become
more favorable to buyers. Thus, in both dimensions, Dutch auctions
approach value functions from above.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The fixed revenue counterparts to the first-and second-price sealed
bid auctions would be the last- and penultimate-quantity sealed bid
auctions, respectively. In both the first- and the second-price sealed
bid auctions, the winner is the agent submitting the bid most favorable
to the seller. In the quantity dimension, the most favorable bids are
the ones for the smallest quantity. For the last-quantity auction, the
winner receives a quantity equal to her bid, while the winner of the
penultimate-quantity auction would receive a quantity equal to the
second lowest bid.
Before presenting a theoretical model of a fixed revenue auction,
we offer the following two comments. First, the fixed revenue auction is
a different allocative mechanism in which the bidders face a different
decision-problem than in the fixed quantity auction. In a traditional
Dutch auction, the price linearly (vertically) approaches an
individual's demand curve from above (at a fixed quantity). In a
Dutch version of the fixed revenue auction, the price per unit also
approaches an individual's demand from above but along a curve as
the quantity increases. (8) Second, in what follows, we purposively
select a set of assumptions that allows us to compare the theory and
behavior of fixed revenue auctions to previous work on standard
auctions. We consider this to be a prudent first step in understanding
the basic properties of fixed revenue auctions. We are not presuming that these assumptions are appropriate for all or even most
applications.
To determine equilibrium behavior in fixed revenue auctions, one
cannot simply translate the common assumption of uniform values
v(q)~U[[v.bar], [bar.v]] to q~U[[q.bar], [bar.q]] because bidders
consider the expected profit from each potential bid. For fixed quantity
auctions, a bid reduction of $1 results in an additional profit to the
bidder of $1, but in a fixed revenue auction, bidders need to know the
value function to determine how an increase of 1 unit impacts the
bidder's profits. Thus, as a means for comparing fixed revenue and
fixed quantity auctions, we make an additional assumption about the
value functions to determine optimal bidding behavior in a fixed revenue
auction. A simple functional form which generalizes the uniform
distribution assumption is that v = [alpha] + [beta]q, where
[alpha]~U[[[alpha].bar], [bar.[alpha]]]. While there are a plethora of
assumptions one could make on the form of the value functions, (9) this
form simultaneously allows the values associated with a specified
quantity to be distributed uniformly and the quantities associated with
a specified payment to also be distributed uniformly. Under this
assumption, bids are a function of [alpha]. With these value functions,
the optimal bids for a standard, fixed quantity auction (Equations 1 and
2) can be rewritten as:
(1') b([alpha]+ [beta]q) = [alpha]+[beta]q + [(n -
1)/n]([alpha] - [[alpha].bar])
and
(2') b([alpha] + [beta]q) = [alpha] + [beta]q.
To determine the optimal bid function in the last-quantity auction
with a payment p for a bidder with v = [alpha] + [beta]q, define the
breakeven quantity as [??] = (p - [alpha])/[beta]. (10) [??] is thus
bounded by [q.bar] = (p - [bar.[alpha]])/[beta] and [bar.q] = (p -
[[alpha].bar])/[beta]. Given the one-to-one mapping between [alpha] and
[??], let b([??]) be the bid function and [??](b) be the inverse bid
function. The probability that the other n - 1 bidders ask for a
quantity greater than b is [([bar.q] - [??])/ [[bar.q] -
[q.bar]].sup.n-1], and the expected profit from a bid of [bar.b] is
([alpha] + [beta]b - p)[([bar.q] - [??])/[[bar.q] - [q.bar]].sup.n-1].
The first-order condition for profit maximization by a bidder yields
Equation (3):
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Through standard manipulation, this yields
b' [beta][([bar.q] - [??]).sup.n-1] - (n - 1) [beta]b[([bar.q]
- [??]).sup.n-2] = (n -1)([alpha] - p)[([bar.q] - [??]).sup.n-2[,
which can be simplified to the following bid function:
(4) b = [bar.q] - [(n - a)/n]([bar.q] - [??]).
The similarities between Equations (4) and (1) are clear.
Taking into account that [bar.q] (p - [[alpha].bar])/[beta],
Equation (4) can be rewritten as:
b = (p - [[alpha].bar])/[beta] - [(n - 1)/n][([alpha] -
[[alpha].bar])/[beta]].
In a first-price, fixed quantity auction, a bidder wants to bid
below value to create a profit in the event the bidder wins the auction.
The parallel in a fixed revenue auction is to ask for a larger quantity.
For a fixed quantity auction, bidders under-reveal by v - b, which can
be rewritten as ([alpha] - [[alpha].bar])/n given that v = [alpha] +
[beta]q with q fixed. For a bidder with this value function in a fixed
revenue auction, the optimal amount of "over-revelation" is
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Equation (5) also yields the optimal stopping rule for the
increasing quantity in a Dutch clock fixed revenue auction. The
intuition of the isomorphism is the same in the quantity dimension as in
the price dimension.
As in the price dimension, truthful revelation is the dominant
strategy in the English quantity clock and penultimate-quantity
auctions, b = [??] = (p - [alpha])/[beta]. Intuitively, in the
penultimate-quantity auction, asking for a larger quantity lowers the
likelihood of winning but does not change the amount of the payoff
conditional on winning. If asking for a smaller quantity causes a bidder
to win that would not have won with truthful revelation, then the bidder
would be worse off than having not won the auction. If the bidder would
have won anyway, then lowering the bid would not change the payoff. This
is also true for the English clock auction.
The familiar expected price in a standard, first-price fixed
quantity auction is [v.bar] + [(n - 1)/(n + 1)]([bar.v] - [v.bar]) or
replacing v with [alpha] + [beta]q is ([[alpha].bar]+bq)+ [(n - 1)/(n +
1)]([bar.[alpha]]- [[alpha].bar]). The translated calculation for the
last-quantity fixed revenue auction gives an expected quantity of
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (6)
Taking into account that [bar.q] (p - [[alpha].bar])/[beta], the
right hand side of Equation (6) can be rewritten as [bar.q] - [(n -
1)/(n + 1)]([bar.q] - [q.bar]). The translation of revenue equivalence
holds as well. That is, given the form of the value function and the
uniform distribution of the [alpha]'s, each of the four auction
mechanisms generates the same expected quantity conditional on payment.
Further, the expected payment in an auction where the quantity is fixed
at the level expected in a fixed revenue auction with payment [p.sup.*]
is [p.sup.*]. That is E(p|q = E(q|[p.sup.*])) = [p.sup.*]. Similarly,
E(q|p = E(p|[q.sup.*]))=[q.sup.*].
III. EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN AND PROCEDURES
Given that observed behavior in laboratory experiments with fixed
quantity auctions sometimes differs from the theoretical predictions, we
conducted a series of laboratory auctions to explore how people behave
in fixed revenue auctions. We designed this experiment to determine
what, if any, behavioral differences arise when the dimension of the
auction is changed. Because the ordering of observed prices in standard
auctions is well established, our experiment seeks to determine if this
ordering is maintained when it is the revenue that is prespecified.
As detailed by Cox, Roberson, and Smith (1982), maintaining similar
message spaces and expected payoffs across treatments is imperative in
an auction experiment. Here, this entails comparability not only across
institutions but also across the dimension of the auction, fixed revenue
versus fixed quantity dimension. It is straightforward to calculate that
the expected profit of a bidder in the fixed quantity auction is
([bar.[alpha]] - [[alpha].bar] /[n(n + 1)], while the expected profit to
a bidder in the fixed revenue auction is ([bar.[alpha]] -
[[alpha].bar])/[[beta]n(n+ 1)]. To maintain similarity, the slope
parameter 13 is set equal to 1. With this slope for the value functions,
[bar.v] - [v.bar] = [bar.q] - [q.bar] so that the vertical distance
between value-curves is the same as the horizontal distance.
The other parameters in the experiments were as follows. Each
auction had n = 5 bidders. The random components of the values
functions, the [alpha]'s, were distributed U[-10, 5], which was
public information among the bidders. With these parameters, the
risk-neutral expected profit of the winner was $2.50 per auction. This
choice of distribution also gives symmetry in the expected price and
quantity. In the standard price auctions, the quantity is fixed at 13,
thus yielding an expected price ([[alpha].bar]+bq) + [(n - 1)/(n +
1)]([bar.[alpha]] - [[alpha].bar]) = 13. Similarly, the price is set at
13 in the fixed revenue auction, which according to Equation (6) gives
an expected quantity of 13. (11) With these parameters, maximum
willingness to pay is distributed U[3, 18] and minimum acceptable
quantity is distributed U[8, 23].
The English and Dutch auctions require additional parameterization
in the form of clock increments and starting and stopping amounts. All
clock increments were set at 0.1, which was also the discreteness
allowed for bids in the sealed auctions, (12) thereby maintaining an
identical message space in each treatment. In a fixed quantity auction,
the natural starting price for the English auction and natural stopping
price for the Dutch auction are zero. (13) However, there does not
appear to be a natural starting price for the Dutch auction or stopping
price for the English clock. This ambiguity problem does not occur in
the quantity dimension. When it is the revenue that is fixed, zero
serves as a natural starting quantity for the Dutch auction and a
natural stopping quantity for the English auction. The seller's
total inventory is a natural starting quantity for the English clock and
stopping quantity for the Dutch clock. (14) To maintain parity between
the dimensions of the auction, it is important that the starting point be as far from the expected termination point in both cases. That is,
the Dutch price should start as far above the expected price as the
Dutch quantity starts below the expected quantity. Since the natural
starting place of 0 for the Dutch quantity auction is 13 units below the
expected quantity of 13, the appropriate starting price for the Dutch
auction is 13 units above the expected price of 13 which is 26. The
natural stopping point for the Dutch price is 0, which is 13 units below
the expected price, and thus, the appropriate stopping point for the
Dutch quantity is 13 units above the expected quantity; hence, the lot
size is set at 26. For the English auction, the natural starting price
is 0, which is 13 units below the expected price of 13. Therefore, in
the English quantity auction, the appropriate starting point is 13 units
above the expected quantity of 13 which is 26. Similarly, the natural
ending point for the English quantity auction is 0, and thus, for the
English price auction, it is 26. See Figure 2 for a graphic
representation of this parallelism in the experimental design. These
parameters also have the desirable feature that all four clock auctions
should on average take the same amount of time to determine a winner as
the expected price and quantity are 13. For consistency, sealed bids
also had to be between 0 and 26.
We conducted experimental sessions for each of the four mechanisms
in a fixed revenue setting. For calibration, we also conducted auctions
with a fixed quantity. But given the large literature on sealed bid,
single-unit (lot) auctions, we investigated only the English and Dutch
price clock auctions. The total number of laboratory sessions was 24:
four replications of each treatment in the 2 x 2 design of
{FixedRevenue, FixedQuantity} x {Dutch, English} and four replications
of each of the two sealed bid fixed revenue institutions.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In each treatment, subjects were shown their random a. In the fixed
quantity auctions, a subject's screen indicated that her value
equaled her random component plus 13. A subject's screen also
displayed the current clock price and the profit that the subject would
receive if she bought at the current clock price. Subjects in the fixed
revenue auctions were shown that the price was always 13. In the fixed
revenue clock auctions, the subjects were shown the component of their
value that came from the clock and what their total value would be if
they were to buy at the current clock quantity. In the sealed bid
auctions, subjects were told that they could type a quantity component
bid. After a subject entered such a bid, his value and profit
conditional on winning were updated on the screen. As explained to the
subjects, these numbers were a lower bound on profit and value in the
penultimate-quantity auction. Unlike in the clock auctions, subjects
confirmed their bids in the sealed auctions. Subjects received feedback
after each period in terms of the market price or quantity. This
information along with their private information and bids was displayed
in a table on the subject's screen.
In each session, subjects first read written instructions and then
participated in eight unpaid practice periods. (15) After the practice
rounds, the experiments continued for an additional 15 periods. (16)
Hence, the data set includes 120 subjects and 360 auctions. Subjects
were randomly recruited from classes at the University of Arkansas and
only participated in one auction mechanism with either the fixed revenue
or the fixed quantity dimension. The laboratory sessions lasted less
than 1 h, and subjects were paid $5.00 for showing up on time plus their
salient earnings which averaged approximately $5.01 across all
treatments.
IV. RESULTS
In what follows, we report our results as a series of six findings.
The careful construction of the experimental environment allows for a
direct comparison between dimensions even though the participants bid
prices in one case and quantities in the other. Given the random draw,
[alpha], a bidder's value curve was a line with slope [beta] = 1
that is parallel to the extreme cases shown in Figure 2. For each
subject, one observes a bid for the fixed quantity or payment and how
much this deviates from the point on the bidder's value curve
associated with the fixed quantity or payment. Being further below the
curve results from a lower bid in the fixed quantity auction, but in the
fixed revenue auctions, it is the consequence of a higher bid.
Comparisons across dimensions are thus measured relative to a line with
slope 1. While any such line would work, it is natural to think of the
fixed quantity auction as a standard and bids in such auctions as a
distance above 0, the minimum possible bid. For fixed revenue auctions,
one needs the distance below the maximum bid of 26. We define the
variable [Transaction.sub.ijs] as the standardized transaction of
subject s in session i and auction j. For the fixed quantity auction,
[Transaction.sub.ijs] = [Price.sub.ijs], which is the observed price. If
the session is a fixed revenue auction, then [Transaction.sub.ijs] = 26
- [Quantity.sub.ijs], where [Quantity.sub.ijs] is the observed
transaction quantity for a fixed revenue of 13. (18)
We begin by comparing the transactions in the fixed revenue and
fixed quantity versions of the Dutch and English clock auctions. We
employ a linear mixed-effects model as the basis for the quantitative
support for this and other findings. The treatment effects (Dutch vs.
English auctions and FixedRevenue vs. FixedQuantity) and an interaction
effect from the 2 x 2 design are modeled as (0-1) fixed effects, while
the 16 independent sessions and winning bidders within the sessions are
modeled as random effects [e.sub.i] and [[zeta].sub.is] respectively. As
a control for the across-auction variation of the realizations of the
[alpha]'s, we include deviations of the relevant kth highest
realization from their theoretical expected values, denoted by
[a.sub.k]. (19) We do this because the predicted standardized
transactions in each round are conditioned on the observed [alpha]
realizations; so, the location of the second highest [alpha] should not
matter in a first-price or last-quantity auction but should identify the
transaction amount in a second-price or penultimate-quantity auction.
For [alpha] ~ U[-10, 5], the expected values of the highest and second
highest realization of five draws are 2.5 and 0, respectively.
Specifically, the model that we estimate via maximum likelihood is:
[Transaction.sub.ijs] = [mu] + [e.sub.i] + [[zeta].sub.is] +
[[beta].sub.1][Dutch.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.2][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.3][Dutch.sub.i][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[phi].sub.1][a.sub.1,ij] + [[phi].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij] +
[[gamma].sub.1][a.sub.1,ij][Dutch.sub.i] +
[[gamma].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij][Dutch.sub.i] +
[[delta].sub.1][a.sub.1,ij][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[delta].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[eta].sub.1][a.sub.1,ij][Dutch.sub.i][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[eta].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij][Dutch.sub.i][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.ijs],
where [e.sub.i] ~ N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.1]), [[zeta].sub.is] ~
N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.2]) and [[epsilon].sub.ijs] ~ N(0,
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.3])
FINDING 1. Consistent with previous work, standardized transactions
in a Dutch clock auction are greater than standardized transactions in
an English clock auction for both fixed revenue and fixed quantity
mechanisms. There is no difference in the standardized transactions in
the fixed revenue and fixed quantity mechanisms.
Table 1 reports the estimates for the above model. The benchmark
for the treatment effects is the fixed quantity English auction. The
point estimate for the average standardized transaction in this
treatment, [??] = 13.07, is nearly identical to the expected theoretical
standardized transaction of 13. From this, we can infer that the bidders
are following their dominant strategy to bid until the price exceeds
their value. The Dutch clock institution has significantly higher
standardized transactions, increasing the standardized transaction
amount by [[??].sub.1] = 0.74 (p value = .0130). This result is
consistent with risk-averse bidding and with previous work. However,
none of the terms involving FixedRevenue are statistically significant,
individually or jointly (Likelihood Ratio statistic = 2.46, p value =
.8729). Hence, we conclude that transaction amounts in fixed revenue
auctions are equivalent to those in fixed quantity auctions when the
settings are directly comparable.
FINDING 2. The dimension of the auction, fixed revenue or fixed
quantity, does not affect efficiency in the Dutch clock auction but does
(marginally) affect efficiency in the English auction.
All four clock auctions were highly efficient. Average efficiency
in the Dutch quantity clock and Dutch price clock auctions was 99.1% and
97.5%, respectively. Average efficiency in the English quantity clock
and English price clock auctions was 97.2% and 99.5%, respectively.
Figure 3 plots the average efficiency over the 15 periods for each
session (by treatment). Efficiency is defined as the winning
bidder's surplus divided by the maximum possible surplus. Using the
average efficiency in a session as the unit of observation, we cannot
reject the null hypothesis that the Dutch quantity clock and Dutch price
clock auctions are equally efficient based upon the Wilcoxon rank-sum
test ([U.sub.4,4] = 8, p value = 1.0000). There is marginal evidence to
reject the null hypothesis that the English quantity clock and English
price clock auctions are equally efficient ([U.sub.4,4] = 15,p value =
.0571). The magnitude of this difference is relatively small as the
"poorer" performing English quantity clock auction was 97.2%
efficient.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
FINDING 3. Consistent with previous work, Dutch clock fixed revenue
auctions are not behaviorally isomorphic to last-quantity sealed bid
auctions.
Cox, Roberson, and Smith (1982) reported the same result for fixed,
single-unit auctions. Table 2 reports the estimates of a linear
mixed-effects model that tests the theoretical isomorphism between Dutch
clock and last-quantity sealed bid auctions. This data set includes four
sessions of Dutch clock auctions and four sessions of last-quantity
sealed bid auctions. The dependent variable is the transaction quantity,
and the treatment effect of interest is the institution. (20) Since we
expect ex ante that the bids are a function of the highest
[[alpha].sub.i], we also include the [[alpha].sub.1] variable as a
control for variation of the [alpha] draws. The average quantity in the
Dutch clock fixed revenue auctions is [??] = 12.17 which is less than
risk-neutral prediction of 13 and consistent with risk-averse bidding.
(Recall that the Dutch quantity starts at 0 and increases until the
first bidder accepts the quantity on the clock.) Last-quantity sealed
bid auctions have even more risk-averse outcomes, lowering transaction
quantities by [[??].sub.1] = -0.47 (p value = .0460). In the Dutch
auctions, the estimated slope of the quantity bid function is
[[??].sub.1] = -0.87, which is very close to the slope of the bid
risk-neutral function of -(n - 1)/ n = -0.80. There is no evidence that
last-quantity bid functions are steeper [[??].sub.1] = 0.02 (p value =
.6981). Cox, Smith, and Walker (1983) concluded that this difference is
the result of bidders improperly updating their priors as opposed to the
"excitement" of watching the clock to continuing tick. Panel
(A) of Figure 4 plots the winning quantity bids against the winning
bidder's value for that quantity along with the risk-neutral
prediction. Panel (B) of Figure 4 plots the same information in manner
more consistent with previous auction experiments; the x-axis has the
bidder's value parameter and the y-axis is the actual bid. For the
familiar fixed quantity auction, the risk-neutral prediction would be
upward sloping since a higher value for the fixed number of units would
lead to a higher price bid and risk-averse bidders would bid above that
prediction. For fixed revenue auctions, a higher a leads to a lower
quantity bid, so the risk-neutral bid function is downward sloping and
risk-averse bidders would bid below this prediction.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
FINDING 4. Dutch clock and last-quantity sealed bid auctions are
equally and highly efficient.
There are only 11 auctions out of 120 that are less than 100%
efficient: 5 Dutch clock and 6 last-quantity sealed bid. The average
efficiency is 99% over the 60 auctions for each institution (see Figure
3). Using a Wilcoxon rank-sum test, we cannot reject the null hypothesis
that the two institutions are equally efficient ([U.sub.4,4] = 8.5, p
value =.8857).
FINDING 5. Consistent with previous work, English clock fixed
revenue auctions are not behaviorally isomorphic to penultimate-quantity
sealed bid auctions.
Kagel and Levin (1993) found that in single-unit, second-price
sealed bid auctions, bidders consistently bid higher than the dominant
strategy prediction, even with experience in the auction mechanism. They
speculated that bidders fall to the illusion that bidding higher is a
low-cost means of increasing the probability of winning. We also find
that bidders in the penultimate-quantity sealed bid auction similarly
over-reveal (by submitting quantities less than their dominant strategy
prediction). Because English auctions are conducted in real time, they
provide immediate and overt feedback as to what a bidder should and
should not bid, and so bidders adopt the strategy very quickly. Sealed
bid auctions do not offer such feedback.
Table 3 reports the estimates of a linear mixed-effects model that
tests the theoretical isomorphism between English clock and
penultimate-quantity sealed bid auctions. This data set includes four
sessions of English clock auctions and four sessions of
penultimate-quantity sealed bid auctions. The model includes the
[a.sub.2] variable as a control on the variation of the second highest
[alpha]. The average quantity in the English fixed revenue auction is
[??] = 13.23, which compares quite favorably to the theoretical
prediction of 13. The penultimate-quantity sealed bid auctions have
lower transaction quantities by [[??].sub.2] = -0.58 (p value = .0344).
As predicted, the relationship between the second highest a and the
transaction quantities is almost exactly -1 ([[??].sub.2] = - 0.97,p
value <.0001). Figure 5 plots bids against the second lowest [alpha]
along with the dominant strategy prediction. Again, as opposed to the
more familiar fixed quantity setting in which a higher value curve leads
to a higher "price" bid, in the fixed revenue auction a higher
[alpha] leads to a lower "quantity" bid. In Panel (A), only
the quantity-setting bids are plotted against that bidder's
[alpha]. This panel clearly displays the Kagel and Levin observation of
over-revelation in the penultimate-quantity sealed bid auctions. Just as
Cox, Roberson, and Smith (1982) reported, subjects also "throw
away" bids in the English auctions when they receive a very low at
and do not expect to win the auction. Hence, they exit nearly
immediately.
FINDING 6. We cannot reject the null hypothesis that
penultimate-quantity sealed bid auctions are as efficient as English
clock auctions.
As Figure 3 indicates, three of the penultimate-quantity sealed bid
auctions are rather inefficient; a full 10 percentage points below the
minimum efficiency observed in any of the other conditions. The fourth
session, however, is highly efficient. As a result, we cannot reject the
null hypothesis that the two institutions are equally efficient
([U.sub.4,4] = 13, p value = .2000).
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
V. CONCLUSIONS
The Dutch price, English price, first-price sealed bid, and
second-price sealed bid auctions are all commonly used institutions that
have been studied extensively both theoretically and empirically. This
paper establishes the theoretical and behavioral properties of these
standard auction mechanisms employed to raise a fixed amount of revenue
for the seller. While this represents a shift in how auctions can be
used, under one generalization of the standard assumptions regarding
values, the predictions are similar to standard theory. Not
surprisingly, with this assumption, a bidder in the English quantity or
penultimate-quantity sealed bid auction should truthfully reveal her
value, while a bidder in the Dutch quantity or the last-quantity auction
does not. However, if values are not linear in quantity, the complexity
of the auction is dramatically increased. Our choice of value functions
is restrictive to enable a direct behavioral comparison with previous
research and is not held to be a general description of bidder values.
This is an area deserving further study. A related issue pertains to
mechanism design: when is a fixed revenue auction optimal? The answer to
this can depend on a variety of factors including the cost structure of
the seller, the distribution of buyer value functions, and the
transactions and contracting costs associated with conducting the
auction and the resulting trades. While these are important issues to be
resolved, they are beyond the scope of this paper. Our goal is to
understand the basic properties of such an auction. We take as given
that the seller is attempting to receive a fixed payment for the least
quantity (cost) while dealing with a single buyer.
The results of our experiment indicate that auction outcomes are
not affected by the dimension of the auction. Bidders truthfully reveal
in the English auction but not in the penultimate-quantity sealed bid
auction. Bidders attempting to game this sealed bid institution
nominally lower efficiency relative to the English auction. As in the
price dimension, the last-quantity auction and the Dutch clock auction
are not behaviorally isomorphic. The sealed bid institution leads to
lower quantities (analogous to higher prices in a fixed quantity
auction). However, the two institutions are equally and highly
efficient. Quantity equivalence does not hold across institutions, just
as revenue equivalence has regularly been found not to hold in the
standard setting. In fact, the dimension of the auction does not change
the magnitude or ordering of the differences between auction
institutions. These findings suggest that auction behavior is extremely
robust and thus lends additional credence to previous work.
REFERENCES
Coppinger, V., V. Smith, and J. Titus. "Incentives and
Behavior in English, Dutch and Sealed Bid Auctions." Economic
Inquiry, 18, 1980, 1-22.
Cox, J., B. Roberson, and V. Smith. "Theory and Behavior of
Single Object Auctions," in Research in Experimental Economics,
Vol. 2, edited by D. Grether. Greenwich: JAI Press, 1982, 537-79.
Cox, J., V. Smith, and J. Walker. "A Test that Discriminates
between Two Models of the Dutch-First Auction Non-Isomorphism."
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 4, 1983, 205-19.
Dastidar, K. "On Procurement Auctions with Fixed
Budgets." Working Paper, Jawaharlal Nehru University, 2006.
Hansen, R. "Empirical Testing of Auction Theory."
American Economic Review, 75, 1985, 156-59.
--. "Sealed Bid Versus Open Auctions: The Evidence."
Economic Inquiry, 24, 1986, 125-42.
Harstad, R. "Dominant Strategy Adoption and Bidders'
Experience with Pricing Rules." Experimental Economics, 3, 2000,
261-80.
Kagel, J., R. Harstad, and D. Levine. "Information Impact and
Allocation Rules in Auctions with Affiliated Private Values: A
Laboratory Study." Econometrica, 55, 1987, 1275-304.
Kagel, J., and D. Levin. "Independent Private Value Auctions:
Bidder Behavior in First-, Second-, and Third-Price Auctions with
Varying Numbers of Bidders." Economic Journal, 103, 1993, 868-79.
Kamecke, U. "Dominance or Maximin: How to Solve an English
Auction." International Journal of Game Theory, 27, 1998, 407-26.
Lucking-Reiley, D. "Using Field Experiments to Test
Equivalence between Auction Formats: Magic on the Internet."
American Economic Review, 89, 1999, 1063-80.
Maskin, E., and J. Riley. "Auction Theory with Private
Values." American Economic Review, 75, 1985, 150-55.
McAfee, R. P., and J. McMillan. "Auctions and Bidding."
Journal of Economic Literature, 25, 1987, 699-738.
McCabe, K., S. Rassenti, and V. Smith. "Auction Institutional
Design: Theory and Behavior of Simultaneous Multiple-Unit
Generalizations of the Dutch and English Auctions." American
Economic Review, 80, 1990, 1276-83.
Milgrom, P. "Auction Theory," in Advances in Economic
Theory." Fifth Worm Congress, edited by Truman F. Bewley.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987, 1-32.
Myerson, R. "Optimal Auction Design." Mathematics of
Operations Research, 6, 1981, 58-73.
Riley, J. "Expected Revenue from Open and Sealed Bid
Auctions." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 1989, 41-50.
Wessen, R., and D. Porter. "A Management Approach for
Allocating Instrument Development Resources." Space Policy, 13,
1997, 191-201.
(1.) See Lucking-Reiley (1999) and Hansen (1985, 1986) for tests of
revenue equivalence with naturally occurring field data. Maskin and
Riley (1985) and Riley (1989) discussed possible explanations for the
failure.
(2.) There is also a class of market auctions that serve to
determine both price and quantity. The double auction and the Walrasian
auction are two examples of this type of auction. McCabe, Rassenti, and
Smith (1990) provided a description of other institutions such as the
double Dutch auction.
(3.) Transaction costs can explain why a buyer or seller might want
to hold a single auction for a set of items even though it might not
achieve as much revenue as auctioning items off separately. Auctions for
surplus equipment are often structured such that a bidder has to
purchase an entire pallet of used items rather than a single item. Vast
tracts of land are rarely auctioned off in square foot parcels.
Similarly, transaction costs could explain why someone would prefer to
hold a fixed revenue auction, thus guaranteeing a single transaction.
(4.) Dastidar (2006) also considered such auctions.
(5.) A framing effect is the observation that people make different
decisions for the same available actions over same outcomes when they
(presumably) conceive the decision-making problem as being different.
For example, the visual electronic interface of an online English
auction is a different decision-frame than an oral English auction with
a live auctioneer and bidding paddles.
(6.) Given the complexity of the mathematical optimization problem,
it seems doubtful that most bidders actually construct the equilibrium
bid function.
(7.) There are two different formats of English auctions, an outcry
version in which bids come from the floor and jump bidding is possible
and a clock version in which the bid price is controlled by the
auctioneer. Our paper focuses on the latter, and the interested reader
is referred to Kamecke (1998) for a discussion of the theoretical
differences between the two.
(8.) While multiunit variations of standard auctions, such as the
double Dutch (McCabe, Rassenti, and Smith 1990), endogenously determine
quantity, in those auctions each bidder is deciding if she should trade
a fixed unit for the bid price.
(9.) See Dastidar (2006) for a more generalized discussion of
auctions in which the bids are in terms of quantities.
(10.) At q = [??], v = p. In the standard, fixed quantity auction,
a bidder's value is the breakeven price.
(11.) The parameters were selected so that the expected price and
quantity were not focal points.
(12.) Note that with n = 5 bidders, the slope of the bid function
is 0.8 = (n - 1)/n which can be realized with an increment of 0.1.
(13.) Stopping price refers to a price at which the auction is
ended. In a Dutch price auction, the seller's reserve price might
also serve as a stopping price.
(14.) Not having a stopping quantity in a Dutch quantity auction
exposes the seller (experimenter) to the possibility of an infinite
loss. The same would be true in a Dutch price auction if the price were
allowed to become negative and fall indefinitely.
(15.) A copy of the instructions is available from the authors upon
request.
(16.) The sealed bid auctions ran much more quickly than the clock
auctions, so as many as 15 additional auctions were also conducted. The
results do not differ in any meaningful way when including these
auctions, so for the sake of parsimony, the analysis focuses only on the
first 15 auctions in each session.
(17.) Recall that the expected profit to the winner was $2.50 each
round. The observed average payoff is the result of aggressive,
risk-averse bidding behavior which is detailed in the next section.
Risk-averse behavior implies saliency in the rewards, that is, subjects
are earnestly engaged in the bidding task.
(18.) For example, a price of 17 which is 4 units above the
expected price of 13 is the same deviation as a quantity of 9 which is 4
units below the expected quantity of 13. Formally, we take transaction
amount = expected price + (expected quantity--observed quantity), which
is 26-observed quantity. In the example, 26-9 = 17. This is related to
the over-revelation of Equation (5).
(19.) A priori, we expect that the standardized transaction in the
Dutch auction is dependent upon the highest realization of [alpha],
while it is dependent upon the second highest realization in the English
auction.
(20.) Findings 3 and 5 focus only on fixed revenue auctions and
thus rely upon the actual quantity rather than the standardized
transaction amount used in Finding 1 for comparing behavior in different
dimensions.
CARY A. DECK and BART J. WILSON, We wish to thank seminar
participants at CIRANO and the University of Alaska Anchorage as well as
two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Financial support from the
Walton College of Business is gratefully acknowledged.
Deck: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of
Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR 72701. Phone 1-479-575-6226, Fax
1-479-575-3241, E-mail cdeck@walton.uark.edu
Wilson: Associate Professor, Interdisciplinary Center for Economic
Science, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030. Phone
1-703-993-4845, Fax 1-703-993-4851, E-mail bwilson3@gmu.edu
TABLE 1
Estimates of the Linear Mixed-Effects Model of Standardized
Transactions for Fixed Revenue versus Fixed Quantity
[AuctionsTransaction.sub.ij] = [mu] + [e.sub.i] + [[zeta].sub.is]
+ [[beta].sub.1][Dutch.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.2]
[FixedRevenue.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.3][Dutch.sub.i]
[FixedRevenue.sub.i] + [[phi].sub.1][a.sub.1,ij] +
[[phi].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij] + [[gamma].sub.1][a.sub.1,ij]
[Dutch.sub.i] + [[gamma].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij][Dutch.sub.i]
+ [[delta].sub.1][a.sub.1,ij][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[delta].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij][FixedRevenue.sub.i] + [[eta].sub.1]
[a.sub.1,ij][Dutch.sub.i][FixedRevenue.sub.i] +
[[eta].sub.2][a.sub.2,ij][Dutch.sub.i][FixedRevenue.sub.i]
+ [[epsilon].sub.ijs]
Standard Degrees of
Estimate Error Freedom (a)
[mu] 13.07 0.18 151
Dutch 0.74 0.25 12
FixedRevenue -0.26 0.25 12
Dutch x FixedRevenue 0.25 0.36 12
[a.sub.1] -0.06 0.08 151
[a.sub.2] 0.98 0.07 151
[a.sub.1] x Dutch 0.85 0.12 151
[a.sub.2] x Dutch -0.93 0.09 151
[a.sub.1] x FixedRevenue 0.12 0.13 151
[a.sub.2] x FixedRevenue -0.09 0.10 151
[a.sub.1] x Dutch x FixedRevenue -0.16 0.17 151
[a.sub.2] x Dutch x FixedRevenue 0.07 0.13 151
LR: [[beta].sub.2] = [[beta].sub.3] =
[[delta].sub.1] = [[delta].sub.2] =
[[eta].sub.1] = = [[eta].sub.2] = 0
238 observations (b)
t Statistic p Value
[mu] 74.18 <.0001
Dutch 2.91 .0130
FixedRevenue -1.05 .3153
Dutch x FixedRevenue 0.71 .4905
[a.sub.1] -0.66 .5093
[a.sub.2] 14.77 <.0001
[a.sub.1] x Dutch 7.13 <.0001
[a.sub.2] x Dutch -10.13 <.0001
[a.sub.1] x FixedRevenue 0.96 .3401
[a.sub.2] x FixedRevenue -0.90 .3706
[a.sub.1] x Dutch x FixedRevenue -0.94 .3487
[a.sub.2] x Dutch x FixedRevenue 0.58 .5659
2.46 .8729
238 observations (b)
(a) The linear mixed-effects model for repeated measures treats
each session as of one degree of freedom with respect to the
treatments in the 2 x 2 design: Dutch, FixedRevenue, and Dutch x
FixedRevenue variables. Hence, the degrees of freedom for the
estimates of these fixed effects are 12 = 16 sessions - 4
parameters. The linear mixed-effects model is fit by maximum
likelihood with 16 groups. For brevity, the session random
effects are not included in the table.
(b) In two Dutch clock price auctions, a subject inadvertently
clicked on the Buy button nearly immediately after the auction
started. Omitting any one of 238 included data points does not
change the above estimates in any discernable way. However, these
two outliers exert undue influence on the estimates, i.e., bias
the estimates, and are excluded.
TABLE 2
Test of Dutch Clock and Last-Quantity
[IsomorphismQuantity.sub.ijs] = [mu] + [e.sub.i] +
[[zeta].sub.is] + [[beta].sub.1][Sealed.sub.i] + [[phi].sub.1]
[a.sub.1,ij] + [[gamma].sub.1][a.sub.1,ih][Sealed.sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.ijs]
Degrees
Estimate Standard Error of Freedom
[mu] 12.17 0.14 79
Sealed -0.47 0.19 6
[a.sub.1] -0.87 0.04 79
[a.sub.1] x Sealed 0.02 0.05 79
t Statistic p Value
[mu] 87.78 <.0001
Sealed -2.51 .0460
[a.sub.1] -21.32 <.0001
[a.sub.1] x Sealed 0.39 .6981
TABLE 3
Test of English Clock and Penultimate-Quantity
[IsomorphismQuantity.sub.ijs] = [mu] + [e.sub.i] +
[[zeta].sub.is] + [[beta].sub.1][Sealed.sub.i] + [[phi].sub.2]
[a.sub.2,ij] + [[gamma].sub.2][a.sub.2,ih][Sealed.sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.ijs]
Degrees of
Estimate Standard Error Freedom
[mu] 13.23 0.11 80
Sealed -0.58 0.21 6
[a.sub.2] -0.97 0.04 80
[a.sub.2] x Sealed 0.01 0.08 80
120 observations
t Statistic p Value
[mu] 124.96 <.0001
Sealed -2.73 .0344
[a.sub.2] -23.00 <.0001
[a.sub.2] x Sealed 0.13 .8983
120 observations