Is the price elasticity of money demand always unity?
Evans, Paul ; Wang, Xiaojun
I. INTRODUCTION
For much of history, money largely consisted of monetary metals. In
particular, during late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, many
countries adopted gold standards and gold served as money--either
directly as coins held by the public or as claims on bullion held by
commercial and central banks. At the same time that large stocks of gold
were being held for monetary uses, even larger stocks were being held
for nonmonetary uses owing to gold's superior luster, reflectivity,
malleability, conductivity, ductility, and resistance to corrosion. (1)
In its monetary uses, it was valued only in terms of its ability to
purchase consumption goods. As a result, asset holders demanded real
gold balances, that is, the nominal stock deflated by an appropriate
index of prices for goods. By contrast, in its nonmonetary uses, it was
valued in terms of its physical units, that is, its undeflated nominal
stock. These dual uses of gold imply that the demand for monetary gold
should not be expected to be unit-elastic with respect to the price
level, a result that we demonstrate formally in the next section. (2)
Empirical researchers have not noticed that money demand behaves
differently under commodity standards from how it behaves under fiat
standards. Since the available historical data are dominated by
observations from fiat standards, the characteristics of money demand
under commodity standards are largely concealed when the researchers use
data that span both commodity and fiat standards. More specifically, the
hypothesis of long-run price homogeneity is usually not rejected. For
example, Meltzer (1963) used U.S. data from 1900 to 1958 to estimate
money demand functions formulated in both nominal and real terms and
found little evidence against price homogeneity. Laidler (1971) carried
out a similar test using both U.K. and U.S. data over the period of
1900-1965 and obtained a similar result notwithstanding a different
specification. Friedman and Schwartz (1982) also found support for price
homogeneity for both United Kingdom and United States over the period of
1867-1975 using the method of phase averaging to extract the long-run
correlation between nominal money demand and the price level. Hendry and
Ericsson (1991) applied cointegration methods to the annual U.K. data
from Friedman and Schwartz (1982) to confirm price homogeneity. Applying
the same approach to annual U.S. data from 1874 to 1975, MacDonald and
Taylor (1992) found that price homogeneity cannot be rejected at the .05
statistical significance level but can be rejected at the .10 level.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The United Kingdom and United States were on fiat standards for the
bulk of the sample periods that these researchers employed. (3) For this
reason, their findings do not serve as evidence for price homogeneity
under commodity standards. In Section II, we present a simple
theoretical model that employs the money-in-utility framework augmented
by also giving utility to holdings of nonmonetary gold. We demonstrate
that under fairly general conditions, the price elasticity of money
demand should be less than 1 under commodity standards. Section III uses
three data sets to provide empirical evidence supporting this
theoretical prediction. Section IV draws some final conclusions.
II. THEORETICAL MODEL
Consider a representative household that chooses the paths for its
consumption C, stock of monetary gold M, stock of nonmonetary gold N,
and real stock of assets A taking as given the paths for non-asset
income Y, the price level P, and the nominal and real interest rates i
and r that it earns on A. In making its choices, it seeks to maximize
the objective function:
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to a sequence of budget and portfolio constraints of the
form: (4)
(2) [C.sub.t] + [i.sub.t][([M.sub.t] + [N.sub.t])/[P.sub.t]] +
[A.sub.t] [less than or equal to] [Y.sub.t] + [r.sub.t][A.sub.t], t
[member of] E [0, [infinity],
where
(3) [A.sub.t] = [([M.sub.t] + [N.sub.t])/[P.sub.t],] + [K.sub.t]
and a sequence of borrowing constraints sufficiently tight to rule
out Ponzi schemes but sufficiently loose to never bind and a fixed
initial value for A. In Equations (1)-(3), t [member of] [0, [infinity])
is a continuous index of time, [rho] [member of] (0, 1) is a subjective
discount rate, and K is the real stock of assets other than gold. We
assume that the instantaneous utility function U is increasing, strictly
concave, and twice continuously differentiable and satisfies Inada
conditions in all its arguments.
We have chosen to induce a demand for monetary gold by inserting
M/P into the instantaneous utility function. This modeling choice has a
long pedigree in monetary economics largely because of its simplicity
and ability to yield sensible demand functions similar to what other
modeling choices yield. We could have employed a shopping time or a
cash-in-advance model and obtained similar results.
We have also chosen to induce a demand for nonmonetary gold by also
inserting N into the instantaneous utility function. This modeling
choice also has a long pedigree since nonmonetary gold is simply one
type of consumer durable. Even though cars and washing machines as well
as jewelry are not demanded for their own sake, their stocks do generate
service flows that have many of the same characteristics as nondurable consumer goods and can be plausibly entered as arguments in momentary
utility functions.
The budget constraint (2) imposes a relative price of 1 between
monetary and nonmonetary gold because both are produced by the same
production process. Furthermore, under the gold standard, nonmonetary
gold could always be minted into monetary gold or simply stored as
bullion in bank vaults and monetary gold could always be melted down and
put to nonmonetary uses. This property distinguishes nonmonetary gold
from other consumer durables, which have variable relative prices that
are endogenous in general equilibrium.
The first-order conditions for the household's problem imply
that
(4) [U.sub.m](C,M/P,N) = i[U.sub.c](C,M/P,N)
and
(5) [U.sub.n](C,M/P,N) = (i/P)[U.sub.c](C,M/P,N),
where we have suppressed the t subscript and appended subscripts c,
m, and n to the function U in order to indicate derivatives with respect
to C, M/P, and N. According to Equations (4) and (5), households equate
the marginal utility of their real stock of monetary gold to the
marginal utility of the nominal interest that they forgo from holding
it, while they equate the marginal utility of the physical stock of
nonmonetary gold to the marginal utility of the real nominal interest
that they forgo from holding it.
Equations (4) and (5) and the implicit function theorem imply that
M/P is related to C, i, and P by a function of the form: (5)
(6) M/P = [LAMBDA](C, i, P).
Totally differentiating Equations (4) and (5) and solving for
[[LAMBDA].sub.p], the partial derivative of A with respect to log P,
yield
(7) [[LAMBDA].sub.p] = (i/P)[U.sub.c]([U.sub.mn] - i[U.sub.cn])/D,
where
(8) D [equivelent to] ([U.sub.mm] - i[U.sub.cm])[[U.sub.nn] -
(i/P)[U.sub.cn]] -- ([U.sub.mn] - i[U.sub.cn])[[U.sub.mn], -
(i/P)[U.sub.cm]].
[LAMBDA].sub.p] cannot be signed in general without making further
assumptions about the instantaneous utility function U. It is
reasonable, however, to suppose that nonmonetary gold and monetary gold
are Edgeworth substitutes since gold originally became money for many of
the same reasons that it is attractive as a nonmonetary asset. On the
assumption that nonmonetary gold is also a sufficiently weak Edgeworth
substitute for C ([U.sub.cn] is either nonnegative or not too negative),
we then have [LAMBDA]p < 0 since D > 0 is a necessary condition
for a maximum in the household's problem. In other words, the
monetary stock of gold should be less than unit-elastic with respect to
the price level.
The intuition behind this phenomenon is straightforward.
Eliminating i[U.sub.c] between Equations (4) and (5) gives us:
[U.sub.m](C,M/P,N) = P[U.sub.n](C,M/P,N).
An increase in the price level raises the relative price of real
balances in terms of nonmonetary gold. It is therefore natural to expect
gold to shift from monetary to nonmonetary uses. This tendency offsets
some part of the usual proportional response of M to P. In terms of the
above equation, M/ P tends to fall and N tends to rise in response to an
increase in P.
III. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
We present three sets of empirical results for the world, the
United Kingdom, and the United States. For each data set, we estimate
the log-log demand function
(9) log [M.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.0] + [[lambda].sub.p] log
[P.sub.t] + [[lambda].sub.y] log [Y.sub.t] + [u.sub.t]
for two specifications of the error term u,. In our data, the
nominal interest rate is stationary, while log M, log P, and log Y are
cointegrated. (6,7) We therefore employ the levels specification (9),
which excludes the nominal interest rate. (8) We are primarily
interested in the elasticity [[lambda].sub.p], which the theory of the
previous section claims is less than 1. For this reason, we shall be
testing the null hypothesis that it is 1 against the one-tailed
alternative hypothesis that it is less than 1. Rejection of the null
will support the theory. We also expect the elasticity [[lambda].sub.y]
to be appreciably larger than 0 and will regard our estimates as
problematical if our estimates of [[lambda].sub.y] are not.
We fit Equation (9) using Johansen's method of estimating
vector error correction models as well as dynamic ordinary least squares
(DOLS) as described by Hamilton (1994, 602-608). In the latter method,
the error term [u.sub.t] is modeled as taking the form:
(10) [u.sub.t] = [q.summation over (j = -q)] [[pi].sub.j]
[DELTA]log [P.sub.t+j] + [q.summation over (j = -q)]
[[eta].sub.j][LAMBDA]log [Y.sub.t+j] + [v.sub.t]
with
(11) [v.sub.t] = [n.summation over (j=1)] [[phi].sub.j][v.sub.t-j]
+ [e.sub.t],
where v, is an error term; the [[pi].sub.s], [[eta].sub.s], and
[[phi].sub.s] are parameters; and [e.sub.t] is an independently and
identically distributed error term with a zero mean and finite variance.
Estimation then proceeds in three steps. First, OLS is applied to the
regression
(12) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
an order to obtain estimates of {[v.sub.t]}. Second, Equation (11)
is fitted to these residuals in order to obtain {[[??].sub.j]}, the
estimates of {[[phi].sub.j]). Third, OLS is applied to the regression
(13) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
to obtain consistent estimates of the [[lambda].sub.s] and their
standard errors. In Equation (13),
log [[??].sub.t] [equivalent to] log [M.sub.t] - [n.summation over
(j=1)] [[??].sub.j] log [M.sub.t-j]
log [[??].sub.t] [equivalent to] log [P.sub.t] - [n.summation over
(j=1)] [[??].sub.j] log [P.sub.t-j]
log [[??].sub.t] [equivalent to] log [Y.sub.t] - [n.summation over
(j=1)] [[??].sub.j] log [Y.sub.t-j]
In our first data set, M is the world stock of monetary gold, P is
the world price level, and Y is the world output. The world monetary
gold stock comes from Warren and Pearson (1935). Our measure of world
output is the sum of Maddison's (1995) estimates of real gross
domestic product (GDP) for France, Germany, Italy, United Kingdom, and
United States. (9) Our measure of the world price level is the real
GDP-weighted average of these countries' price levels. (10,11) The
series are annual and span the period 1880-1913, the heyday of the
international gold standard.
The first three rows of Table 1 report statistics for testing
whether log M, log P, and log Y are cointegrated for the data described
in the previous paragraph. These statistics indicate the existence of
exactly one cointegrating vector for the world as a whole.
The first two rows of Table 2 report two sets of estimates for
[[lambda].sub.p] and [[lambda].sub.y], one based on Johansen's
method and the other on DOLS. The former estimate of [[lambda].sub.p] is
less than 1 though not statistically significantly so. The latter
estimate, however, is significantly less than 1 at the .01 level. Both
estimates of [[lambda].sub.y] are sensible and precisely estimated,
significantly positive, and close to 1.
Under the gold standard, deposits and banknotes were nearly perfect
substitutes for monetary gold. As a result, the demand for the stock of
money should have the properties that the theory in the previous section
identified for monetary gold. We should therefore find that Equation (9)
with [[lambda].sub.p] < 1 characterizes the demand for money in
countries that were on the gold standard.
M, P, and Y in our second and third data sets come from Tables 4.8
and 4.9 of Friedman and Schwartz (1982) and are the M2 money supplies,
the implicit deflators, and real net national products for the United
Kingdom and the United States. The last six rows of Table 1 report
statistics for testing whether log M, log P, and log Y are cointegrated.
The statistics indicate the existence of one cointegrating vector for
both countries.
We used both Johansen's method and DOLS to estimate
[[lambda].sub.p] and [[lambda].sub.y] for both the United Kingdom and
the United States, and the last four rows of Table 2 report our
estimates. In both cases, the price elasticities are significantly less
than 1 and the income elasticities take on plausible and highly
significant values.
IV. CONCLUSION
We have established a theoretical presumption that the price
elasticity of money demand is less than unity under commodity monetary
standards. Using data from the heyday of the international gold
standard, we have also provided evidence supporting the theory.
A price elasticity differing from 1 has implications for the
general equilibrium properties of economies on the gold standard. In
particular, the quantity theory of money may not accurately describe the
evolution of the price level. In other words, although a doubling of the
stock of gold would no doubt have been associated with an increase in
the price level, it would be unlikely to have been associated with an
exact doubling.
ABBREVIATIONS
DOLS: Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2007.00113.x Online Early publication
January 14, 2008 [c] 2008 Western Economic Association International
REFERENCES
Blanchard, O. J., and S. Fischer. Lectures on Macroeconomics.
Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1989.
Friedman, M., and A. J. Schwartz. Monetary Trends in the United
States and the United Kingdom. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press,
1982.
Gordon, R. J. The American Business Cycle. Chicago, IL: University
of Chicago Press, 1986.
Hamilton, J. D. Time Series Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 1994.
Hendry, D. F., and N. R. Ericsson. "An Econometric Analysis of
UK Money Demand in Monetary Trends in the United States and the United
Kingdom by Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz." American Economic
Review, 81, 1991, 8-38.
Homer, S., and R. Sylla. A History of Interest Rates. 3rd ed. New
Brunswick and London: Rutgers University Press, 1991.
Kitchin, J. "Memorandum on Gold Production," in The
International Gold Problem. London: Oxford University Press, 1931,
47-55.
Laidler, D. E. W. "The Influence of Money on Economic
Activity: A Survey of Some Current Problems," in Monetary Theory
and Policy in the 1970s, edited by G. Clayton, J. C. Gilbert, and R.
Sedgwick. London: Oxford University Press, 1971, 75-135.
MacDonald, R., and M. P. Taylor. "A Stable US Money Demand
Function, 1874-1975." Economics Letters, 39, 1992, 191-98.
Maddison, A. Monitoring the World Economy 1820-1992. Paris: OECD,
1995.
McCallum, B., and M. Goodfriend. "Demand for Money:
Theoretical Studies." in The New Palgrave." A Dictionary of
Economics, edited by J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman. New York:
Stockton Press, 1987.
Meltzer, A. H. "The Demand for Money: The Evidence from the
Time Series." Journal of Political Economy, 71, 1963, 219-46.
Mitchell, B. R. European Historical Statistics 1750-1975. 2nd ed.
New York: Macmillan Press, 1980.
Niehans, J. Theory of Money. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press,
1978.
Warren, G. F., and F. A. Pearson. Gold and Prices. London: John
Wiley & Sons and Chapman & Hall, 1935.
(1.) According to Kitchin (1931), total world gold production from
1834 to 1889 amounted to 1,037 million pounds sterling, among which
49.6% were added to the monetary gold stock. Annual data become
available beginning only in 1890 and are presented in Figure 1. The
average fraction of annual gold production that was added to the
monetary gold stock rises to 57.7% during the 1890-1913 period.
(2.) Niehans (1978, 143) asserted this result but provided no
formal demonstration of it.
(3.) Specifically, after the onset of World War I in 1914 for both
the United States and the United Kingdom and before 1879 for the United
States. See Homer and Sylla (1991). We interpret gold exchange standards
as a kind of fiat standard rather than a full-fledged commodity
standard.
4. An alternative form in which Equation (2) can be written is
[C.sub.t] + ([M.sub.t], + [N.sub.t])l[P.sub.t] + [K.sub.t] [less
than or equal to] [Y.sub.t] + [r.sub.t][K.sub.t].
We prefer the form in the text because it highlights that the
opportunity cost in terms of consumption of holding each unit of gold
per period is i/P and that all assets held in the portfolio yield the
same real rate of return r after accounting for both pecuniary and
nonpecuniary returns. See Blanchard and Fischer (1989, 189).
5. McCallum and Goodfriend (1987) distinguish between two forms of
the money demand function. In the first, the stock of real balances is a
function of wealth and current and all future relative prices, which are
the variables that each household takes as given. In the second, it is a
function of current relative prices and current consumption, which is a
choice that each household is making jointly with its current holdings
of assets. In this paper, we employ the second form, which they term the
portfolio-balance equation.
(6.) Using monthly data from the National Bureau of Economic
Research macrohistory Web site (www.nber. org/databases/macrohistory) on
the U.S. commercial paper rate for the period from January 1880 to
December 1913, we obtained an augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic of
-7.28, which is statistically significant at well under the .00001
significance level. We take this as evidence that nominal interest rates
in the entire gold standard world were stationary over this sample
period. The Dickey-Fuller regression contained an intercept but no time
trend.
(7.) The Dickey-Fuller statistics for our measures of log M, log P,
and log Y are, respectively, -3.06, +1.43, and -2.7l for the world,
2.66, -1.87, and 2.89 for the United Kingdom, and -2.06, -1.80, and
-3.01 for the United States. None of these are statistically significant
at conventional levels. We selected the augmentation lags for each
Dickey-Fuller regression in order to minimize the Schwarz informational
criterion. Each regression contained both an intercept and a time trend.
Table 1 provides the evidence for cointegration.
(8.) Cointegrating relationships cannot include stationary
variables.
(9.) These series are directly summable because they are expressed
in common base-year units, that is, 1990 Geary-Khamis dollars.
(10.) The price levels are the GDP or net national product deflator for Germany, Italy, and United Kingdom, the gross national product
deflator for the United States, and a cost of living index for France.
The data come from Mitchell (1980) except for those for the United
States, which come from Gordon (1986).
(11.) Weighting with real GDP is equivalent to calculating an
implicit deflator. For example, suppose that country j's output and
price level in period t are [Y.sub.jt] and [P.sub.it], respectively.
Then,
[P.sub.t] = [summation over (j)] ([Y.sub.jt]/[summation over (k)]
[Y.sub.kt])[P.sub.jt] = [summation over (j)]
[P.sub.jt][Y.sub.jt]/[summation over (k)] [Y.sub.kt],
which is just the ratio of the sum of nominal GDPs to the sum of
the real GDPs.
PAUL EVANS and XIAOJUN WANG *
* We wish to thank the editor and two anonymous referees for
helpful suggestions.
Evans: Professor, Department of Economics, Ohio State University,
Columbus, OH 43210. Phone 1-614-292-0072, Fax 1-614-292-3906, E-mail
evans.21@osu.edu
Wang. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of
Hawaii, Honolulu, HI 96822. Phone 1-808-956-7721, Fax 1-808-956-4347,
E-mail xiaojun@hawaii.edu
TABLE 1 Johansen Tests for Cointegration of log M, log P, and log Y,
1880-1913
Hypothesized Number Maximum
of Cointegrating Trace Eigenvalue
Economy Vectors Eigenvalues Statistic Statistic
World 0 0.565 42.5 (a) 28.4 (a)
[less than or equal 0.322 14.2 13.2
to] 1
[less than or equal 0.028 0.9 3.8
to] 2
United 0 0.505 30.4 (b) 22.5 (b)
Kingdom
[less than or equal 0.218 8.0 14.1
to] 1
[less than or equal 0.002 0.1 3.8
to] 2
United 0 0.701 51.4 (a) 38.6 (a)
States
[less than or equal 0.318 12.8 14.1
to] 1
[less than or equal 0.015 0.5 3.8
to] 2
Notes: The specification for the world includes two lags, and those
for the United Kingdom and the United States include one lag. Each
specification was estimated using EViews, assuming trend in the series
but not in the cointegrating relationships.
(a) and (b) nindicate statistical significance at the .0l and .05
levels, respectively.
TABLE 2
Money Demand under the Gold Standard,
1880-1913
Location and Method [[lambda].sub.p] [[lambda].sub.y]
World, Johansen 0.877 (0.149) 0.969 (0.049)
World, DOLS 0.728 (0.091) 1.072 (0.028)
United Kingdom, 0.642 (0.127) 0.997 (0.026)
Johansen
United Kingdom, DOLS 0.537 (b) (0.229) 0.992 (0.059)
United States, Johansen 0.309 (a) (0.137) 1.560 (0.044)
United States, DOLS 0.603 (a) (0.189) 1.539 (0.066)
Notes. The figures in parentheses are standard errors. The vector error
correction model had two lags for the world and one for the United
Kingdom and the United States. In the DOLS regressions for the world,
q = n = 2 and [[PHI].sub.1] and [[PHI].sub.2] were estimated to be
0.979 (0.180) and -0.550 (0.178), respectively. In the DOLS regression
for the United Kingdom, q = n = 1 and [[PHI].sub.1] was estimated to be
0.609 (0.155). In the DOLS regressions for the United States, q = n = 1
and [[PHI].sub.1] was estimated to be 0.653 (0.123). The lag lengths
were chosen on the basis of pretests.
(a) and (b) indicate statistical significance at the .01 and .05
levels, respectively.