首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月01日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Volatility and Irish exports.
  • 作者:Bredin, Don ; Cotter, John
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2008
  • 期号:October
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 关键词:Gross domestic product;International trade;Open economy;Volatility (Finance)

Volatility and Irish exports.


Bredin, Don ; Cotter, John


We analyze the impact of volatility per se on real exports for a small open economy concentrating on Irish trade with the United Kingdom and the United States. An important element is that we take account of the time lag between the trade decision and the actual trade or payments taking place by using a flexible lag approach. Rather than adopting a single measure of risk, we adopt a spectrum of risk measures and detail varied size characteristics and statistical properties. We find that the ambiguous results found to date may be due to not taking account of the timing effect, which varies substantially depending on which volatility measure is used. (JEL C32, C51, F14, F31)

I. INTRODUCTION

The international trade performance of a small open economy (SOE) plays a pivotal role in the performance of the economy. This is clearly the case for Ireland as the share of Irish merchandise exports in gross domestic product (GDP) has grown dramatically in recent years (from 43% in 1979 to 94% in 2002), thus rendering the economy more open than before and more dependent on foreign markets. (1) Hence, policies designed to enhance export performance are of increasing importance to national economic welfare. Good policy decisions are assisted by having relevant information on the factors that determine the level of exports and imports. In this paper, we examine the impact of volatility per se on real Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United States using, a two-country imperfect substitutes model. (2) As well as including real income and real foreign exchange, volatility of these underlying variables is also analyzed by incorporating a spectrum of volatility proxies. The analysis of an SOE's export function is in contrast to the vast majority of the previous studies that focus on large economies with a small share of international trade relative to GDP. The issue of the sensitivity to volatility considers both foreign exchange volatility as well as foreign income volatility. Moreover, in excess of 40% of Irish exports go to the United Kingdom and United States, and these transactions dominate those of its trading partners within the auspices of the Euro currency union. Also the case of the Irish economy can provide unique insights into the effects of currency unions given that it was part of a currency union with UK sterling up until 1979.

There are a number of important advances in the current study to provide insights on the mixed empirical findings for the impact of economic variables such as foreign exchange volatility on exports. First, we adopt a comprehensive set of volatility measures and determine whether the use of a specific measure influences the empirics. These include recent advances in the time-varying autoregressive (AR) heteroskedasticity literature, asymmetric power autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (APARCH), absolute volatility underpinned by the theory of power variation, and the model-free log range estimate. This paper details their statistical properties in conjunction with their impact on real exports. The vast majority of previous studies report results for the influence of volatility on trade by focusing only on a single particular measure of foreign exchange volatility and in many cases have not accounted for the recent developments in time-varying risk measurement. As well as exchange rate volatility, we expand the menu of volatility variables and determine the impact of foreign income uncertainty that is often overlooked but may well be crucial to a small open developing economy. The importance of foreign income volatility for trade has been highlighted (Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan 2004; Franke 1991; Grier and Smallwood 2005). For instance, Franke (1991) views trade as an option for a firm that will be exercised if doing so is profitable. Thus, as well as including income and foreign exchange in our exports model, we include volatility of these underlying variables. This is consistent with Franke (1991), where foreign income volatility (rather than foreign exchange volatility) is viewed as a signal for greater profit opportunities. As well as addressing the impact of foreign exchange rate volatility and foreign income volatility, we also look at the interaction between the two following Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) and hence take account of any possible nonlinear influences on exports that they may have.

Second, rather than looking at the empirical long-run relationship between exports and a set of variables, we analyze the impact of volatility per se adopting a flexible lag approach. Using a Poisson distributed lag structure, the model takes account of the lag between trade decisions and the time of the actual trade flow/ payment. Thus, our empirical results show the total effect of volatility as well as the distribution of the effect over time. A similar flexible lag approach has been adopted by both Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) and Klaassen (2004) for fully developed economies. However, in the current setting, we are able to indicate the total effect as well as the time distribution effect for each of the complete set of foreign exchange and income volatility variables. A key issue is whether the various volatility measures are likely to have similar total and time distribution effects.

Finally, the data set studied is representative of an SOE facing a high degree of uncertainty from external factors. Although a member of the European single currency, the majority of Irish exports are to non-Euro zones with the United States and the United Kingdom representing the most important markets. (3) At the start of our sample 1979, Irish exports to the United States represented just under 5% of total exports, while at the end of the sample, it was close to 20%. In contrast, Irish exports to the United Kingdom have fallen from about 40% in 1979 to 20% in 2002. While the trend, in terms of the share of total Irish exports to the United States and the United Kingdom, is moving in opposite directions, the combined importance remains extremely strong, that is, over 40% of total Irish exports go to the United States and the United Kingdom at both the beginning and the end of the sample.

The paper finds very strong evidence for the influence of volatility on an SOE. We find that the foreign exchange volatility effect is consistently positive, indicating the dominance of exporters' expectations of possible profitable opportunities from future cash flows associated with the export function. In contrast, the potential negative aspects of trade, the entry and exit costs, appear to be accounted for by negative effects for income volatility on trade. Moreover, positive nonlinear effects for the interaction between foreign exchange and income volatility influence exports for an SOE. Importantly, these findings occur in the face of volatility measures that differentiate considerably in their statistical properties according to the modeling process used. Furthermore, while the total effect of the foreign exchange and income volatility on exports is consistent across each of the various volatility measures, the timing effect is considerably different. This effect represents the time (in months) at which the maximum effect occurs, and it varies significantly across our volatility measures. Overall, we find that the ambiguous results found to date in the literature may be due to not taking account of this varying timing effect.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section IX provides a survey of the theoretical and empirical literature. The methodological approach with the operations of the adopted export model and the alternative volatility measures are discussed in detail in Section III. Section IV includes a description of the data used and an analysis of the alternative volatility measures. Section V reports details of the model specification and the findings from our empirical model concentrating on the influence of volatility. Finally, Section VI concludes.

II. LITERATURE REVIEW

A. Theoretical Models

Theoretically, the modeling of exports allows for different impacts of volatility with no unanimity on direction and magnitude. To illustrate, Demers (1991) assumed that exchange rate risk leads to lower production and trade due to price uncertainty implications for foreign demand. This rationale is generally supported by policymakers (see EU Commission 1990). Here, the effect of higher exchange rate volatility depends on the expected marginal utility of export income. Higher exchange rate risk reduces the expected marginal utility of export revenues, and thus, risk-averse producers reduce their output.

An alternative model consistent with a positive association between exchange rate volatility and exports implies that exchange rate movements are not just a source of risk but also create opportunities to make profits because they affect the real opportunities of the firm (De Grauwe 1994). Assuming that firms make their production and export decisions once they have observed the exchange rate, higher exchange rate uncertainty may increase the average profit of the firm. For a profit-taking firm, a higher price due to an exchange rate change results in the firm enjoying higher profits per unit of output and so expands its output. Equivalently, in this analysis, exporting represents an option. At a favorable exchange rate, the firm exercises its option to export. The opposite happens for unfavorable movements. Since the value of options increases with the variability of the underlying asset, the firm is better off when exchange rate variability increases. Even assuming risk aversion, it remains possible that exchange rate volatility increases exports, provided that the increase in utility of the firm from the increase in the average profit offsets the decline in utility of the risk-averse firm due to the greater uncertainty of profits.

More specifically, Franke (1991) follows a real options approach and views trade as an option to be exercised by a firm. The author examines the decision-making process of exporters under uncertainty in an intertemporal multiperiod setting. The real options approach extends the possible factors included in modeling exports. In particular, any underlying variable has associated volatility, giving rise to adding income and foreign exchange volatility to our export function. Here, for example, the exchange rate is assumed to be mean reverting and there are costs to entering and exiting markets. Firms will exercise the option to enter a market if doing so is profitable. The profitability of the option depends on the present value of expected cash flows from exporting and on the present value of expected entry and exist costs. A weaker (stronger) exchange rate increases (decreases) both the cash flow from exporting and the entry and exit costs. The latter is assumed to be a concave function of the exchange rate. If volatility causes expected cash flows from exporting to grow faster than expected entry and exit costs, then the value of the option to export has increased and volatility and trade are positively related. This will be the case if cash flows are convex in the exchange rate. According to this scenario, increased volatility will result in firms entering the market sooner and exiting later and the number of trading firms will increase.

Furthermore, ambiguity on the relationship between exchange rate uncertainty and trade has also been outlined (Viaene and de Vries 1992). If you allow for the existence of forward markets, then exchange rate volatility can impact trade either positively or negatively through its impact on the determination of forward rates. The outcome is then determined through the empirical analysis. Thus, overall, the theoretical predictions regarding volatility and trade are inconclusive.

B. Empirical Evidence

The vast empirical evidence of the influence of exchange rate volatility on exports is also mixed. (4) Findings are dependent on models employed, sample period analyzed, and countries examined (Bacchetta and van Wincoop 2000). Furthermore, there is no consistency in the measures of volatility used ranging from unconditional estimates such as standard deviation in the early literature to conditional ones such as generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (GARCH) estimates in more recent times (McKenzie 1999). For instance, Koray and Lastrapes (1989) find evidence of a negative relationship between exchange rate volatility and trade using cointegration techniques involving U.S. pairs. In contrast, Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) show evidence of a positive relationship between exchange rate volatility and trade using a Poisson flexible lag structure, while Klaassen (2004) did not find evidence of any significant effect of exchange rate volatility on trade for G7 economies. Hedging through derivative products usually explains the lack of significance, although Wei (1999) finds a negative and statistically significant effect for foreign exchange rate volatility on exports even after taking account of futures and options instruments to hedge risk. There is some evidence that views increased exchange rate volatility as a result of greater integration of world markets (see Rose 2000). However, Glick and Rose (2002), measuring exchange rate uncertainty using unconditional standard deviation, find that an increase (decrease) in exchange rate volatility resulting from leaving (joining) a currency union has a negative (positive) impact on trade statistics.

The majority of empirical studies estimate an export function based on the following (see Arize 1997):

(1) [x.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][y.sup.*.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.2][p.sup.*.sub.x], + [[beta].sub.3][[sigma].sub.s,t] + [[epsilon].sub.t],

where [x.sub.t], [y.sup.*.sub.t], and [p.sub.t] stand for real exports, foreign real income, and relative prices, respectively (in logs), t represents time (in months), [[sigma].sub.s,t] stands for exchange rate volatility that captures exchange rate uncertainty, and [[epsilon].sub.t] represents the error term. (5) Economic theory suggests that real income levels of the trading partners for the domestic country and competitiveness measures affect the volume of exports positively and negatively, respectively.

In addition to the mixed empirical results, many alternative modeling approaches have been applied. Early empirical studies disregarded the issue of nonstationarity of macroeconomic time series and used classical regression analysis and are subject to the "spurious regression" criticism. Studies also test for stationarity of the relevant time series and employ cointegration techniques, for example, Koray and Lastrapes (1989). Two recent studies take a different approach: Klaassen (2004) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004). Rather than looking at the long-run relationship between the variables, both papers analyze the impact of exchange rate volatility adopting a flexible lag approach. In other words, the model takes account of the lag between a trade decision and the time of the actual trade flow/ payment. In both cases, the empirical part of the studies uses a Poisson lag structure in order to account for the possible extended effect. Klaassen focuses on U.S. exports to other G7 countries for the period 1978-1996 and finds an insignificant effect in all cases.

Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) focus on bilateral aggregate real exports between 1980 and 1998 for the following countries: United States, Canada, Germany, United Kingdom, France, Italy, Japan, Finland, Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) also include foreign income volatility that is consistent with Franke (1991). We now view foreign income volatility as a signal for greater profit opportunities. As well as addressing the impact of foreign exchange rate volatility and foreign income volatility, they also look at the interaction between the two and hence take account of any possible nonlinear relationship. Overall, they find a significant impact of real income volatility on trade that varies in direction for the countries analyzed.

Evidence on the impact of volatility on Irish trade statistics is relatively sparse. (6) Thom and Walsh (2002), modeling overall Irish trade, find no evidence that exchange rate regime changes impact Anglo-Irish trade from analyzing time series and panel regressions in a case study approach. The study argues that the unilateral move by Ireland to join the European Monetary System (EMS) is unique in that the devolvement did not disrupt trade. This was mainly due to the fact that both the United Kingdom and Ireland were both members of the then European Economic Community (EEC). Also, Lothian and McCarthy (2000) find that foreign exchange volatility changes according to exchange rate systems and that volatility decreases upon joining a currency union vis-a-vis other systems.

III. METHODOLOGY

A. Modeling Exports

As in Klaassen (2004) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004), we adopt the flexible lag version of the two-country imperfect substitutes model of Goldstein and Khan (1985) for bilateral trade between Ireland and the United States and the United Kingdom in real terms. This allows for examining the decision-making process of exporters under uncertainty for intertemporal multiperiod horizons. The variable of interest is real Irish exports using Irish unit export value as our deflator. (7) Irish exports to the United Kingdom and United States are almost exclusively invoiced in UK sterling and U.S. dollars, respectively, and we examine the logarithm of real Irish exports. (8) The determinants of exports relate to the assumptions concerning export supply and demand. The determinants of demand are foreign income, [y.sup.*.sub.t-l], and relative prices, [p.sup.*.sub.xt] = log([P.sub.xt]/[P.sup.*.sub.t]), and both are stated in foreign currency, while l is a lag representing the time delay between the purchase and the delivery of the goods. (9)

(2) [q.sup.d.sub.t] = [q.sup.d]([y.sup.*.sub.t-l], [p.sup.*.sub.xt]).

The determinants of the exports supply function only include the relative price of exports converted to domestic prices:

(3) [q.sup.s.sub.t] = [q.sup.s]([p.sup.*.sub.xt] + [s.sub.t]),

where [s.sub.t] is the log of the nominal exchange rate, measured as foreign per unit of domestic currency. Given that decisions will be made based on the forecast of relative prices, both the conditional mean and the standard deviation of [p.sup.*.sub.xt] + [s.sub.t] are both included in the supply equation, where l is the lag to take account of potential time delay.

(4) [q.sup.s.sub.t] = [q.sup.s]([E.sub.t-l][[p.sup.*.sub.xt] + [s.sub.t]], [[sigma].sub.s,t-l] [[p.sup.*.sub.xt] + [s.sub.t]]).

Goldstein and Khan (1985) assume that the export decision and actual exports and payments are not contemporaneous, introducing a degree of uncertainty into the trade model. To incorporate this uncertainty, the model is estimated with a flexible Poisson lag structure. This allows for uncertainty between trading decisions and actual completion of trade, and we examine how it impacts our variables in the export model. It makes the traders forward looking and motivates the relevance of our income and exchange rate risk variables as potential determinants of trade (Klaassen 2004). The use of the lag structure allows the data to determine the dynamic specification of the timing effect. We allow each variable to have its own lag structure, so thereby measure their maximum effect and illustrate their patterns. In addition, the process is extended following an options-based approach by including volatility of the underlying variables. Furthermore, there may be nonlinear effects arising from a combination of income and foreign exchange volatility effects not directly measured in the variables alone (Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan 2004). To incorporate this, an interaction term of income and foreign exchange volatility is introduced into the exporter's supply function. (10) Taking account of these extensions, we can now rewrite exports supply as:

(5) [q.sup.s.sub.t] = [q.sup.s] (E.sub.t-l][P.sup.*.sub.t] + [s.sub.t]], [[sigma].sub.s,t-l, x [[sigma.sub.y,t-l], [[sigma].sub.s x y,t-l]),

where [[sigma].sub.s.t-l] is real foreign exchange volatility, [[sigma].sub.y,t-l] is real income volatility both outlining direct effects, [[sigma].sub.s x y,t-l] is the interaction term incorporating nonlinear indirect responses of income and foreign exchange volatility on the supply function, and l is the lag to take account of potential time delay. The interaction term, the product of foreign exchange and income volatility, may capture any possible nonlinearities between exchange rate volatility and exports.

B. The Poisson Lag Approach

An important element is that we take account of the time lag between the trade decision and the actual trade taking place or payment taking place (Goldstein and Khan 1985). Hence, it is clearly not sufficient to account for only contemporaneous relationships between exports and our explanatory variables. Equating supply (Equation 5) and demand (Equation 2) leads to a function for real exports of the following form: (11)

(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

The [[beta]'s represent the sensitivities of exports to each of the variables included (real foreign income, real exchange rate, real foreign exchange rate volatility, real income volatility, and the interaction term), for example, [[beta].sub.1l] represents the effect of foreign income on exports at the lag where the effect is largest. In order to model the impact using a flexible lag approach, we adopt a Poisson lag structure (see Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan 2004; Klaassen 2004). Alternative, but more restrictive, approaches include the geometric and the polynomial lag specifications. For example, the geometric approach implies that [[beta].sub.l] is decreasing as the lag increases. (12) The Poisson lag approach is derived from the Poisson probability distribution for each underlying variable:

(7) [[beta].sub.kl] = [[beta].sub.k] [([[lambda].sub.k] - 1).sup.l-1] / l - 1)! exp [ - ([[lambda].sub.k] - 1)]

for [[lambda].sub.k] [greater than or equal to] 1 and [lambda] is the lag at which the maximum effect occurs. One important advantage of the Poisson lag approach is that the number of parameters to be estimated is minimized, 2k + 1, where k is the number of independent variables. As can be seen, the parameters [[lambda].sub.1], ... [[lambda].sub.k] enter into the equation in a nonlinear fashion. In order to calculate the parameters [[lambda].sub.1], ... [[lambda].sub.k], we use the simulated annealing optimization technique (see, Goffe, Ferrier, and Rogers 1994). (13) Once the parameters, [[lambda].sub.1], ... [[lambda].sub.k], have been obtained from the nonlinear optimization technique, the estimated coefficients, [[beta].sub.1], ... [[beta].sub.k], are calculated using ordinary least squares.

C. The Appropriate Volatility Measure

Our export model follows an options-based approach. Here, participation in export markets is based on evaluation of entry and exit costs using a real options approach to the decision-making process. This real options approach suggests that additional volatility variables affect medium-term exports. The real options approach incorporates volatility of the economic variables under consideration, thus including volatility of exchange rates and of income. In his study, Franke (1991) finds a positive relationship between exports and exchange rate volatility. The rationale is that firms increase exports in response to increased volatility if the present value of expected cash flows from exports exceeds the sum of entry and exit costs. For instance, changes in the volatility of foreign income change an exporting firm's entry/exit cost ratio and therefore their export opportunities to that economy. Thus, higher foreign income volatility may signal higher profit opportunities, resulting in a change in exporters' decision making leading to increased exports.

Given the importance of volatility in our modeling process, it is interesting to note that the literature relies on many different types of volatility estimates (McKenzie 1999). So, for example, unlike exchange rates that are available contemporaneously, exchange rate volatility is modeled ex post. This has led to a major research agenda in trying to model financial volatility through analysis of its distributional and dynamic characteristics. Major developments have been made in modeling the time variation of volatility and its persistence, and we incorporate a spectrum of these models. These include the autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH)-related models and the more recent model-free aggregated based procedures underpinned by the theory of power variation. In contrast, models that assume constant volatility are now generally ignored. (14) Regardless of what approach is used, the key issue is to recognize that volatility is latently unobservable, thereby requiring proxies. This gives rise to a modeling approach that could involve a spectrum of procedures, and we estimate the export specification with a number of alternative risk measures to determine if volatility determination impacts on inferences from the export model. Specifically, we address the issue as to whether alternative volatility estimates are responsible for the inconclusive empirical evidence. By looking at a number of estimates, we can ascertain the influence of volatility per se rather than be swayed by the conclusions from a single estimate. The paper focuses on four separate measures for foreign exchange and income, respectively, and when combined give rise to 16 interaction terms. The foreign exchange and income measures necessarily diverge due to data availability; for example, foreign exchange rates are available at relatively high frequencies such as daily intervals, while income estimates are only available at monthly frequencies.

The volatility measures come from different strands of the literature such as conditional measures where we apply a time-varying APARCH process that nests seven different parametric ARCH models (for a review, see Bollerslev, Engle, and Nelson 1994). Also, estimates underpinned by the theory of power variation such as realized volatility that requires aggregation from high- to low-frequency observations have been advocated with many illustrations for volatility modeling (see references in Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold 2003). Moreover, we examine the impact of other model-free estimates using squared, absolute, and range-based estimates (see Alizadeh, Brandt, and Diebold 2002; Ding and Granger 1996).

First concentrating on the aggregated measures that are applied to the daily exchange rates, the most common approach suggests the use of aggregated squared exchange rate changes over a period, say, for example, aggregating daily realizations to obtain monthly estimates instead of using a single estimate from the monthly exchange rate changes (see Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan 2004; Klaassen 2004). This estimate is closely associated with the variance. Merton (1980) illustrates the advantages in using relatively high-frequency observations to obtain more precise low-frequency risk measures, and early applications with monthly estimation cumulating daily observations are given in French, Schwert, and Stambaugh (1987). This paper also analyzes aggregated absolute realizations that evolve from the same theoretical framework, realized power variation (see Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard 2003; Cotter 2004), as exchange rate changes have the stylized property of exhibiting fat tails due to excessive large-scale movements, and modeling with absolute realizations is more robust in the presence of this property (Davidian and Carroll 1987). Also, more attractive time series properties are documented for absolute realized volatility measures than their squared counterparts (Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard 2003).

Turning to the theoretical framework, we begin by defining the price process that is underpinned by realized power variation. Volatility of this price process defined as integrated volatility is said to be unobservable. The framework incorporates the popularly used quadratic variation that details the use of aggregated squared realizations and absolute power variation using aggregated absolute realizations. We analyze the price process that has [r.sub.m,t] = [p.sub.t] - [p.sub.t - 1/m] as the compounded returns with in evenly spaced observations per month. Importantly, realized power variation that incorporates realized absolute variation, namely the sum of absolute realizations, [summation] [absolute value of [r.sub.m]], equates with integrated volatility, making volatility of the price process observable.

We present power variations for both squared and absolute measures for the monthly foreign exchange volatility. The practical implementation of the theory simplifies into constructing volatility estimators using aggregated absolute exchange rate changes and their variants for any month t with m daily intervals:

(8) [[absolute value of [r.sub.t].sup.n]] = [m.summation over (j=1)] [[absolute value of [r.sub.m,t+j/m].sup.n]],

where the power coefficients, n, can take on a range of values 0.5 < n < 3 (see Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard 2003). Also, in terms of the commonly applied principle of quadratic variation using aggregated squared realizations, exchange rate volatility is given as:

(9) [[absolute value of [r.sup.2.sub.t].sup.n]] = [m.summation over (j=1)] [[absolute value of [r.sup.2.sub.m,t+j/m].sup.n]],

where different power transformations are again underpinned by the theoretical framework.

Moving to the standard modeling of time variation, GARCH-type processes have traditionally been applied (Klaassen 2004; Kroner and Lastrapes 1993). A large number of specifications are available with, for example, Kroner and Lastrapes (1993) using a GARCH-in mean (GARCH-M) process, whereas Klaassen (2004) uses a GARCH(1, l) model. All these models have a common feature in modeling clustering of second moments. We use the APARCH to provide end-of-month income and foreign exchange rate volatility estimates. The model developed by Ding, Granger, and Engle (1993) advantageously nests many extensions of the GARCH process. As well as encompassing three ARCH specifications (ARCH, nonlinear ARCH, and Log-ARCH), two specifications of the GARCH model (using standard deviation and variance of returns), it also details two asymmetric models (both ARCH and GARCH versions). It is given by:

(10) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

for [[alpha].sub.0], [[alpha].sub.i], [[beta].sub.j] [greater than or equal to] 0, [[alpha].sub.i] + [[beta].sub.j] less than or equal to] 1, and - 1 [less than or equal to] [[gamma].sub.i] [less than or equal to] 1. The [[epsilon].sub.t] are the errors, and [[sigma].sub.t], is the conditional variance. Detailing the model, the process presents volatility in the form of a Box-Cox transformation whose flexibility allows for different specifications of the residuals process associated with different GARCH models. As well as describing the time variation in exchange rate changes, it also allows for the possibility of leverage effects, [[gamma].sub.i], by letting the AR term of the conditional volatility process be represented as asymmetric absolute residuals. Nonlinear GARCH models are derived from different power coefficients, d. The model is fitted with a conditional Student's t distribution, thereby allowing for fat tails. The model adequately deals with second-moment persistence documented for the underlying variables.

In addition, the use of the log range defined as the first difference of the log of maximum and minimum prices is applied to foreign exchange data at monthly intervals. This simple estimate has been used widely in an ad hoc fashion in the literature, and its time series properties are formally examined in Alizadeh, Brandt, and Diebold (2002). They find that it is an efficient estimator with small measurement error and has further attractive time series properties by being approximately Gaussian.

The aggregation procedure and range-based measure are not applied in measuring income uncertainty due to a lack of intra-monthly observations. Notwithstanding this, there are many different types of volatility estimates that could model income dynamics ex post. Here, we overcome the problem of proxying for unobservable volatility by using the observed absolute income changes and observed squared income changes as measures of income uncertainty. Ding and Granger (1996) show that these model-free volatility proxies adequately model the long-term persistence property associated with financial data. The final income measure is the moving window approach advocated by Thursby and Thursby (1987) to obtain adaptive risk measures.

Here, the moving window technique estimates income volatility for the United States and the United Kingdom where the logarithm of real income is regressed on a quadratic trend for a 6-mo moving window. The root mean squared error of the regression represents the time-varying process for our volatility measure using relatively low-frequency income data.

Taking income volatility and exchange rate volatility, we produce an interaction term as a product of these variables. This allows us to not only examine the direct impact of the respective volatility estimates but also assess whether there is an indirect influence of these volatilities through their interaction with each other. Following the real options approach, both exchange rate and income volatility would have a direct concurrent impact on exporters' decision making, but there may also be an indirect influence. To examine any combined effects of these separate dynamics, the interaction term between exchange rate and income volatility is included to help describe the exporters' behavior. This allows for the processing of information that is different from each volatility measure but combines both income and exchange rate volatility. Any indirect impact of the respective volatility measure is captured by this interaction variable, and it may remove omitted variable bias by examining respective volatility measures only. Thus, exchange rate volatility could impact income volatility and vice versa. For each volatility measure, we create an interaction term giving 16 separate measures each labeled as a combination of the respective volatility measures, for example, APARCH exchange rate volatility combined with squared income changes. These combinations imply that the impact of the interaction term will not be constant but will depend on the respective measures of volatility.

IV. DATA CONSIDERATIONS

A. Data

We use monthly data for the period May 1979 to December 2002. The starting point of our sample is dictated by data availability and that the sterling link was abandoned in 1979. Irish exports to the United Kingdom and United States are taken from the Trade Statistics Series of the Central Statistics Office (CSO) publication and were divided by Ireland's unit export value to obtain the real exports figure. (15) Given that real national income is only available at quarterly frequencies, monthly UK and U.S. industrial production (constant prices) are used. Irish, UK, and U.S. export unit values are obtained at monthly intervals. The exchange rate data used in the study are daily UK sterling per unit of Euro and U.S. dollar per unit of Euro adjusted from Irish pounds in the pre-Euro period. The real exchange rate is calculated from the spot exchange rate and the ratio of domestic to foreign (U.S. and UK) price indices. (16,17)

As shown in Figure 1, Irish exports to the United Kingdom and United States make up a sizable proportion of Irish exports. Although traditionally the United Kingdom was the important market for Irish exports, this has diminished in recent years. At the same time, exports to the United States have grown steadily over the last number of years. Although moving in different directions, exports to both countries are sizable and are exposed to exchange rate movement pressures. Furthermore, Ireland has a unique relationship with the United Kingdom that has driven many of its economic policies. For example, in terms of foreign exchange, Ireland and the United Kingdom were part of a currency union between 1800 and 1979. (18) The Irish pound--introduced in 1927--was held in a 1:1 no-margins peg with sterling until 1979 using an ad hoc currency commission to maintain the arrangement. Prior to this, there was no independent Irish pound since the Act of Union in 1800. The break from parity was due to Ireland's decision to be a member of the EMS and the United Kingdom's nonparticipation. The most important influences on the Irish decision to join the EMS were the perceived political benefits, the promise of additional EEC subsidies, and a desire to shift the currency's nominal anchor from sterling, then considered to be inflation prone, to the new "zone of monetary stability" based on the German mark (Economic and Social Research Institute 1996). Overall foreign exchange volatility for the Irish economy has increased in real terms since 1979 com pared to under the sterling link (Lothian and McCarthy 2000).

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

B. Volatility Measures

Using the respective volatility measures outlined, we describe their statistical properties and analyze similarities and divergences. We find a large divergence for the respective volatility estimates in terms of size, pattern, and statistical properties. There also appears to be a high degree of persistence. For foreign exchange volatility, the measures all exhibit a different scale as can be seen in Figure 2, with a common large spike around the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) crises in 1992/1993. (19) Although time variation is captured by all measures, the APARCH measure is the smoothest, whereas the Range is the noisiest. Irish exporters faced considerable variation in exchange rate volatility for both currencies across the sample period with a major increase evident during the 1992/ 1993 currency crises that enveloped the EMS currencies. This was followed by a relatively tranquil period, but volatility tended to increase in the early years of the Euro.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

The summary statistics in Table 1 outline the first four moments and the Jarque-Bera test for normality of foreign exchange volatility. The magnitude of moments varies considerably, with, for example, the mean spanning from 1.81 to 5.03 for the United States, whereas its standard deviation, the volatility of volatility measure, exhibits a scale between 0.18 and 0.70. Non-Gaussian features of excess skewness and excess kurtosis are documented in many cases, especially for the Range measures. The Range is prone to fat tails with positive skewness.

Similar departures are indicated for the respective income volatility measures. Notwithstanding the divergences, the result of the U.S. expansionary policy increases all volatility measures in the early 1980s, and there has also been a common increase in income volatility for the United Kingdom in 2002. Furthermore, all the measures exhibit excess skewness and kurtosis in Table 2 and are non-normal. The excess skewness and kurtosis are strongest for the squared measure, whereas APARCH exhibits a platykurtotic bunching of realizations. Diverging patterns of the respective measures also occur with the squared and absolute measures noisy relative to APARCH and moving window volatility. The shape plots in Figure 3 indicate that all the volatility measures are non-normal with excess positive skewness. Also, all measures exhibit very fat upper tails. While generally strong persistence is shown for all foreign exchange volatility measures in Figure 4, it disappears after 6 mo for U.S. squared volatility.

Turning to the income volatility estimates, we examine their relationship with each other and find that the APARCH estimate involves the lowest linkages and a strong relationship exists between squared and absolute measures for both United Kingdom and United States. The extent of the relationships between respective foreign exchange rate volatility measures is shown in the scatter plots of Figure 5 for the United Kingdom and clearly indicates divergences. For instance, linkages between the squared and other measures are high, but in contrast, the range is not strongly related to the other measures with correlations of less than .4 in both U.S. and UK cases.

Given the respective divergences for income and foreign exchange volatility measures, and the interaction term being defined as a combination of these, it is no surprise to see similar conclusions for the respective interactions in Table 3. For instance, the standard deviation extends between 0.57 and 1.54 with very different patterns emerging across the interaction terms. While this is especially so for those estimates involving squared measures, all measures exhibit excess skewness and kurtosis and deviate from normality. Finally, the varying strength of the relationships of the respective interaction terms incorporating the APARCH foreign exchange volatility measures is present with reasonably similar patterns. Thus far, both United States and United Kingdom exhibit strong linkages between absolute and squared measures with correlations in excess of .86 in comparison to the other relatively weak relationships. Overall, the respective volatility measures diverge strongly in terms of size, pattern, and statistical properties. These findings are consistent for both UK and U.S. volatility measures. Given these discrepancies, these inputs are now used to model Ireland's export function with its largest trading partners to determine their respective influence on the economy's exports.

V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS

A. Model Specification

The export model is run with forecasted volatility using the Poisson lag structure for 16 combinations for each country pair. (20) Our study includes four separate foreign exchange risk measures as well as four separate income volatility measures. We combine each of the foreign income measures with the separate foreign exchange volatility measures, giving 16 possible combinations, to which we augment the interaction term, for example, the specification may include squared foreign exchange volatility, APARCH foreign income volatility, and the interaction term, squared-APARCH. As has been discussed, an important element is that we take account of the time lag between the trade decision and the actual trade taking place or payment taking place. (21) The stochastic optimization process of simulating annealing is applied to our function in order to obtain the global maximum. As has been discussed, this approach is adopted due to the difficulty associated with obtaining the global maximum. The algorithm is rerun with different starting values and a different seed for the random number generator, and in all cases, the maxima were found to be identical. Consistent with Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004), we allow for a maximum of 30 lags; however, we do not restrict the final four variables to have the same lag: real foreign exchange, real foreign exchange volatility, real foreign income volatility, and the interaction term. Our unrestricted approach is taken to fully capture the exposure of exports from an SOE for foreign exchange and income volatility.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

The lag structure and the parameter coefficients of the models are of interest. The former details the optimal lag of exporters with respect to variables impacting their export decision, whereas the latter shows the impact of economic variables such as income volatility on the export decision. Given that the volatility measures exhibit considerable deviations, it is interesting to determine their respective impacts on the estimation of the lag structures for the export model. This would possibly help to explain the diverging results in the literature for volatility and trade.

Summary statistics of the different lag structures affecting the variables in the export model in terms of mean and variance are given in Table 4 for each country. Also, a plot of the lag distribution for income and real exchange rates and associated volatility for exports to the United Kingdom and United States is given in Figure 6. Unlike previous studies, we do not assume an identical lag structure for each of our volatility terms. Different maximal lags are evident across the explanatory variables including foreign exchange and associated volatility. For instance, the strongest lag effect occurs for real exchange rates having a mean of 0.39 compared to 11.58 for real exchange rate volatility for the United States. However, consistency in the lag structures for specific variables is generally evident, with the United States generally having lower mean lags than the United Kingdom. In particular, exports to the United States are generally affected quicker by economic wealth and foreign exchange activity compared to the impact of those variables for the United Kingdom. (22) Also for the specific lag structures, the mean of the maximal lag for real income is much higher for the United Kingdom (11.30) than the United States (5.29). The latter is in line with the fast decline predicted by Goldstein and Khan (1985). The relatively large income lag for the case of exports to the United Kingdom is similar to Klaassen (2004), analyzing developed economies although the study assumed the mean and variance of the lag structure to be equivalent.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

Turning to the volatility lag structures, both U.S. and UK average real foreign exchange volatility measures have their maximal impact after a number of lags of just less than a year. Also, the 95% interval estimate for real foreign exchange volatility is between 8.87 and 14.28 with a median of 11.49 mo for the United States. However, there is a fair degree of dispersion according to each model with a range of lags of over a year for both countries, indicating that the largest effects vary according to different foreign exchange volatility measures. This can be seen in Figure 7, which plots the distribution associated with the highest and lowest lag effects. The pattern of lag weights suggests a hump shape in line with Klaassen (2004) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004). The maximal effect for income volatility (Figure 8) also varies with a median of 6.79 for the United States and 24.37 for the United Kingdom with standard errors around 2, suggesting that exports respond slowly to economic activity. Again, there is a large dispersion between minimum and maximum lags that present the strongest effects for income volatility measures on Irish exports. Finally, the average lag of the interaction term is over a year and shows a large level of dispersion across the different models. Overall, the different volatility measures result in large variations in the export model's lag structure and emphasize the importance of accounting for the respective lag structures.

Comparing the lag structures of the exchange rate and income variables, the findings support previous studies (e.g., Goldstein and Khan 1985; Klaassen 2004) in supporting a larger delay in the impact of foreign exchange over income variables.

B. Volatility and Exports

Estimated parameters for the export models are given in Table 5, summarizing the results for the 16 models for each country pair. We also report the point coefficients as well as standard errors for one of the regression combinations. (23) A number of summary estimates of the 16 models are given including the mean coefficient, the minimum and maximum coefficients, and measures of dispersion of the coefficients including the standard deviation and range. The diagnostics indicate well-specified models in all cases, for example, high [R.sup.2] and no evidence of endogeneity of regressors. (24) Very strong positive real income effects are reported with all t-statistics significant. These large positive coefficients are associated with a low dispersion of estimates with a minimum of 4.88 for the United States and a maximum of 5.57. The point estimates for the United States follow the same pattern as the United Kingdom. The negative effects of real foreign exchange are consistent with theory and in line with previous studies that measure their variables in foreign currency. Also, the impact of foreign exchange is reasonably constant with very little dispersion indicated for the country pair parameters. The parameters are consistent across the country pairs with coefficients of similar magnitude.

The main empirical issue of the paper examines the impact of volatility on exports using the small open Irish economy as a case study and is now outlined. As discussed, many studies have investigated the influence of real exchange rate volatility with very contradictory findings. For Ireland, real exchange rate volatility has a positive statistically significant impact on trade regardless of the foreign exchange volatility measure applied. On average, a 1% increase in respective foreign exchange volatility leads to an increase in exports to the United States and the United Kingdom by 0.29% and 0.17%. Furthermore, the specific model (squared approach) indicated that a 1% increase in foreign exchange volatility leads to an increase in exports to the United States and the United Kingdom by 0.32% and 0.11%, respectively. Although there is some variation (in particular for exports to the United States), the relationship is positive in all cases. The results imply that exporters treat an increase in real foreign exchange volatility to the United States and United Kingdom as a positive situation to exploit profit opportunities associated with the positive expected cash flow dominating the entry and exit costs of exporting. Exporters then decide to exercise their option to trade, resulting in increased trade flows being determined by increased foreign exchange volatility. The positive effect of real foreign exchange volatility supports the findings of Franke (1991) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004). The consistency of the finding occurs given the backdrop of diverging magnitude and statistical properties documented across the volatility measures (see Table 1).

Dispersion of the impact of foreign exchange volatility measures does occur, indicating that the choice of volatility proxies matters. For instance, the smallest effect (minimum value = 0.05) occurs for the Range volatility measure in the U.S. equation but is still statistically positive with a t-statistic of 2.85. In contrast, the largest effect (maximum value = 0.62) occurs for the APARCH measure for the United States with a t-statistic of 7.57. The results also suggest that exports to the United States are considerably more sensitive to the respective foreign exchange volatility measures relative to UK exports.

International evidence regarding the impact of income volatility on export flows is sparse. Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) find that income volatility is significant in only a quarter of their cases and claim that the sign of the statistically important parameters is ambiguous with nearly as many negative influences as positive influences being recorded. We find stronger results in adopting the real options approach and the respective influence of income volatility with significant influences being found in all but 3 of the 32 cases, 1 being negative and 2 being positive. Our findings are in line with Grier and Smallwood (2005) who use a GARCH specification for a mixture of developing and developed economies. Overall foreign income volatility is primarily a negative determinant of Irish exports to the United States in 11 models and to the United Kingdom in 15 models. For instance, on average a 1% increase in foreign income volatility reduces Irish exports to the United States and the United Kingdom by 0.45% and 0.81%, respectively. The finding suggests that the negative impact of exit and entry costs driven by the export decision dominates the cash flow benefits associated with greater levels of income volatility and results in reduced trade as exporters do not exercise their option to trade in these circumstances. Furthermore, the negative coefficients recorded in the remaining models dominate the positive findings as evidenced by the mean statistic and their associated confidence interval in Table 5. The average impacts are reasonably similar for the United States and United Kingdom, with the latter dominating. However, the range of impact is relatively large for the different models applied, with values of 1.39 for the United Kingdom and 4.43 for the United States.

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

Finally, the effect of the combination of the respective income and foreign exchange volatility measures is examined. The coefficients represent the indirect influence of foreign exchange and income volatility on the export decision. The findings strongly suggest that the interaction terms have a positive impact on Irish exports for the United States but not the United Kingdom. Individually, however, significance occurs in 12 cases (incorporating both positive and negative values that cancel each other out) for the United Kingdom and 14 cases for the United States. The influence of the indirect term is stronger for the United States (median 0.30) than the United Kingdom (median 0.04), and there is a reasonable spread of values with the United States having a range of 2.16 compared to 0.46 for the United Kingdom. Thus, exporters not only have to take account of the direct influences of foreign exchange and income volatility but the combination of these factors also affects the export function albeit in an indirect fashion.

VI. CONCLUSIONS

The paper analyzes the impact of real foreign exchange and income volatility on Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United States. The majority of the literature in this area has focused on exports from fully developed economies and may well have led to the inconclusive empirical evidence to date. This issue has been highlighted by Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2000) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) who suggest that data selection issues may be driving the mixed results. This study reverses the analysis by focusing on an SOE with a very high dependency on trade and potentially high levels of volatility affecting the factors driving exports.

Of interest is the effect of foreign exchange and income volatility on Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United States over the period studied, 1979-2002. Although Ireland is a member of the Euro, the remaining foreign exchange volatility effects may be substantial as a large percentage of Irish exports are to the United Kingdom and the United States. This was especially the case for the sterling rate, which previously had a currency union with the Irish currency pre-1979 and also was part of the EMS between 1990 and 1992. In terms of the effect of foreign exchange volatility, we find that there is a consistently positive effect on Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United States. In contrast, we find a negative impact of income volatility on exports, a result which is consistent with Franke (1991). If the exporting decision is viewed as an option, as suggested by Franke (1991), then our income volatility result highlights that the costs of entry dominate the increased cash flows associated with the export decision, resulting in lower exports. Finally, we also test the impact of the interaction between foreign exchange rate and income volatility and find a positive effect in the majority of cases. This illustrates an indirect effect of foreign exchange and income volatility on the export function.

[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]

The paper is underpinned by the use of alternative volatility measures with diverging magnitude and statistical properties but yet results in a consistent set of findings. This consistency is welcome given that volatility is inherently unobservable, and previous studies have utilized measures from a spectrum of modeling procedures. Moreover, there is considerable variation in the timing effect of volatility per se on Irish exports uncovered by analyzing the lag structure of the export model. The lack of decomposition of volatility effects into timing and causality and the limited choice of volatility measures applied may well have supported the historically mixed evidence in previous empirical studies. An interesting extension to this study is to examine disaggregated trade flows focusing on the specific relationships of individual industry sectors with their non-Euro trading partners.

ABBREVIATIONS

APARCH: Asymmetric Power Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity

AR: Autoregressive

ARCH: Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity

EEC: European Economic Community

EMS: European Monetary System

EU: European Union

GARCH: Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity

GDP: Gross Domestic Product

SOE: Small Open Economy

REFERENCES

Alizadeh, S., M. W. Brandt, and F. X. Diebold. "Range Based Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models." Journal of Finance, 57, 2002, 1047-92.

Andersen, T. G., T. Bollerslev, and F. X. Diebold. "Parametric and Nonparametric Measurement of Volatility," in Handbook of Financial Econometrics, edited by Y. Ait-Sahalia and L. P. Hansen. Amsterdam, Netherlands: North Holland, 2003.

Arize, A. C. "Conditional Exchange Rate Volatility and the Volume of Foreign Trade: Evidence from Seven Industrialized Countries." Southern Economic Journal, 64, 1997, 235-54.

Bacchetta, P., and E. van Wincoop. "Does Exchange Rate Stability Increase Trade and Welfare?" American Economic Review, 90, 2000, 1093-109.

Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E., and N. Shephard. "Realised Power Variation and Stochastic Volatility." Bernoulli, 9, 2003, 243-65.

Baum, C. F., M. Caglayan, and N. Ozkan. "Nonlinear Effects of Exchange Rate Volatility on the Volume of Bilateral Exports." Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 19, 2004, 1-23.

Bollerslev, T., R. F. Engle, and D. B. Nelson. "ARCH Model," in Handbook of Econometrics, edited by R. F. Engle and D. C. McFadden. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier Science, 1994, 2959-3038.

Central Bank of Ireland. "Statistical Appendix" in Quarterly Bulletin. Dublin, Ireland: Central Bank & Financial Service Authority of Ireland, No. 4, October, 2004.

Cotter, J. "Minimum Capital Requirement Calculations for UK Futures." Journal of Futures Markets, 24, 2004, 193-220.

--"Export Ireland Survey 2005-International Trade, Finance and Credit Management." Dublin, Ireland: Institute of International Trade of Ireland/Irish Exporters Association, October, 2005.

Davidian, M., and R. J. Carroll. "Variance Function Estimation." Journal of the American Statistical Association, 82, 1987, 1079-91.

De Grauwe, P. The Economics of Monetary Integration. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 1994.

Demers, M. "Investment Under Uncertainty, Irreversibility, and the Arrival of Information Over Time." Review of Economic Studies, 58, 1991, 333-50.

Ding, Z., and C. W. J. Granger. "Modeling Volatility Persistence of Speculative Returns." Journal of Econometrics, 73, 1996, 185-215.

Ding, Z., C. W. J. Granger, and R. F. Engle. "A Long Memory Property of Stock Market Returns and A New Model." Journal of Empirical Finance, 1, 1993, 83-106.

Economic & Social Research Institute. "Economic Implications for Ireland of EMU." Policy Research Series, Paper No. 28. 1996.

EU Commission. "One Market, One Money." European Economy, 44, 1990.

Franke, G. "Exchange Rate Volatility and International Trading Strategy." Journal of International Money and Finance, 10, 1991, 292-307.

French, K. R., G. W. Schwert, and R. F. Stambaugh.

"Expected Stock Returns and Volatility." Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 1987, 3-29.

Glick, R., and A. K. Rose. "Does a Currency Union Affect Trade? The Time-Series Evidence." European Economic Review 46, 2002, 1125-51.

Goffe, W. L., G. D. Ferrier, and J. Rogers. "Global Optimization of Statistical Functions with Simulated Annealing." Journal of Econometrics, 60, 1994, 65-100.

Goldstein, M., and M. S. Khan. "Income and price effects in foreign trade," in Handbook of International Economics, Volume II, edited by R. W. Jones and P. B.

Kenen. Amsterdam, Netherlands: North-Holland, 1985.

Grier, K., and A. Smallwood. "Uncertainty and Export Performance: Evidence from 18 Countries." Working Paper, University of Oklahoma, 2005.

Klaassen, F. "Why is it so Difficult to Find an Effect of Exchange Rate Risk on Trade?" Journal of International Money and Finance, 23, 2004, 817-39.

Koray, F, and W. Lastrapes. "Real Exchange Rate Volatility and US Bilateral Trade: A VAR Approach." The Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, 1989, 708-12.

Kroner, K. F., and W. D. Lastrapes. "The Impact of Exchange Rate Volatility on International Trade: Reduced Form Estimates Using the GARCH-inMean Model." Journal of International Money and Finance, 12, 1993, 298-318.

Lothian, J. R., and C. McCarthy. "Real Exchange Rate Behavior under Fixed and Floating Exchange Rate Regimes." Working Paper, Department of Economics, Fordham University, New York, 2000.

McKenzie, M. D. "The Impact of Exchange Rate Volatility on International Trade Flows." Journal of Economic Surveys, 13, 1999, 71-106.

Merton, R. C. "On Estimating the Expected Return on the Market: An Exploratory Investigation." Journal of Financial Economics, 8, 1980, 323-61.

Rose, A. K. "One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common Currencies on Trade." Economic Policy, 20, 2000, 745.

Thorn, R., and B. Walsh. "The Effect of a Common Currency on Trade: Ireland before and after the Sterling Link." European Economic Review 46, 2002, 1111-23.

Thursby, J., and M. Thursby. "Bilateral Trade Flows, the Linder Hypothesis, and Exchange Risk." The Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 1987, 488-95.

Viaene, J.-M., and C. G. de Vries. "International Trade and Exchange Rate Volatility." European Economic Review, 36, 1992, 1311-21.

Wei, S. J. "Currency Hedging and Goods Trade." European Economies Review, 43, 1999, 1371-94.

(1.) Ireland's status as an SOE is clearly evident and especially its reliance on non-Euro trade of over 60% of total trade dominated by its activities with the United Kingdom and United States. In contrast, other economies in the European Union (EU) are not nearly as reliant on non-Euro-dominated trade.

(2.) Exports only are analyzed as they represent a much higher proportion of our trade with the United Kingdom and United States relative to imports and also are open to differing degrees of volatility.

(3.) The Irish pound was established in the late 1920s and maintained a one-for-one link with UK sterling until 1979 when Ireland joined the EMS. During the 1970s, the UK inflation rate was both high and extremely volatile and the potential to link to the more stable core EU economies was the main motivation for joining the EMS. The Irish pound was replaced by the Euro in 1999.

(4.) See McKenzie (1999) for a review.

(5.) Relative prices [p.sup.*.sub.xt] are defined as log([P.sub.xt]/[P.sup.*.sub.t]), where [P.sub.xt] and [P.sup.*.sub.t] are domestic and foreign price levels, respectively.

(6.) Studies concentrate on examining the movements in real exchange rate levels and overlook the impact of the second moment.

(7.) The Irish export sector is dualistic in makeup, with relatively smaller indigenous firms dominating the more low-technology production sectors, while larger subsidiaries of foreign-owned multinationals tend to dominate the more high-technology sectors.

(8.) This practice has surprisingly continued even since the entry of Ireland to the Euro zone and may influence our findings. For instance, 68% of Irish exports to the United Kingdom are invoiced in UK sterling, while 75% of Irish exports to the United States are invoiced in U.S. dollars (Cotter, 2005).

(9.) A detailed discussion of l follows below.

(10.) A further motivation for including the interaction term is to take account of possible omitted variable bias. See Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) for a discussion.

(11.) We adopt an AR model to forecast the exchange rate. This approach is consistent with previous studies in the literature, for example, Klaassen (2004).

(12.) See Klaassen (2004) for a detailed discussion of the problems associated with geometric and polynomial lags in the current setting.

(13.) An important advantage of the simulated annealing optimization routine is that it escapes from local maxima and local minima and can maximize or minimize functions that are difficult to optimize. We use the GAUSS code by E.G. Tsionas to run the procedure.

(14.) Given that foreign exchange markets are characterized by periods of tranquility and turbulence, there is persistence in the forecast errors. The ARCH model is able to take account of the international exporters' perception of foreign exchange risk today by factoring in their perception of risk in earlier periods and the time-varying nature of asset (foreign exchange) returns.

(15.) All remaining data are from Datastream.

(16.) Given that the exchange rate is available at daily frequencies and the domestic and foreign prices are only available at monthly frequencies, we linearly interpolate the price series within the month. See Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) where a similar approach is adopted.

(17.) McKenzie (1999) highlights that the distinction between real and nominal exchange rate volatility does not significantly affect the results.

(18.) Since then, the currencies have been part of separate currency arrangements such as the Euro and the EMS with the exception of the period between October 1990 and September 1992 where the United Kingdom joined the EMS and subsequently departed around its currency crises.

(19.) The volatility measures use the most common specifications with an APARCH(1, 1) and n = 1 for squared and absolute realizations. The lack of dependence of the squared standardized residuals from fitting the APARCH model supports the specification. Only a subset of the time series, shape, persistence, and scatter plots is presented for conciseness outlining the respective volatility measures' statistical properties and their relationships with each other. The inferences of diverging volatility measures hold across foreign exchange volatility, income volatility, and the interaction term. The full set of plots is available on request.

(20.) The estimated models were adjusted for the exchange rate crisis in 1992/1993 and the regime switch to the Euro in 1999. The dummy for the exchange rate crisis was not statistically significant for either exports to the United Kingdom or United States. The dummy for the change over to the Euro (taking value I from January 1999 to the end of the sample and 0 elsewhere) was statistically significant in the case of exports to the United Kingdom only, with a mean value of 0.29. A tentative interpretation is that the single currency has had a positive effect on Irish exports to the United Kingdom. The significance of this dummy may also be taking account of the ending of the fraudulent activity of "carousel trade" with the United Kingdom in goods such as electrical parts and machinery. Although there was no effect on the net Irish trade statistics, there was a significant fall in Irish exports and imports to and from the United Kingdom; see Central Bank of Ireland (2004).

(21.) Consistent with previous studies, we find that Irish exports are cointegrated with real foreign income and real exchange rates. Results are available on request. exchange, real foreign exchange volatility, real foreign income volatility, and the interaction term. Our unrestricted approach is taken to fully capture the exposure of exports from an SOE for foreign exchange and income volatility.

(22.) The results here could also reflect the distinct nature of the structure of exports to the United States and the United Kingdom. In particular, exports to the United States are dominated by information computer and technology and medical devices, while the UK figures are heavily influenced by the food and drink sector.

(23.) The full set of results is not reported for space considerations but is available from the author upon request. The squared measure of volatility is adopted for the specific set of results.

(24.) We also run the Hausman test which has a null hypothesis that each regressor is exogenous. This test is run for all specifications although for space considerations, we only report the results for the squared measure of volatility. We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.

DON BREDIN and JOHN COTTER *

* The authors would like to thank Chris Baum, Mark Cassidy, Gunter Edenharter, Liam Gallagher, Franc Klaassens, Michael McKenzie, Gerard O'Reilly, Maurice Roche, and participants at the 2004 Irish Economics Association Conference in Belfast and a University College Dublin seminar for helpful discussions. We would also like to thank three anonymous referees for many helpful comments. Any errors are our own responsibility.

Bredin: Senior Lecturer in Finance, Centre for Financial Markets, Graduate School of Business, University College Dublin, Blackrock, Ireland. Phone +00 353 1 716 8833, Fax +00 353 1 283 5482, E-mail don. bredin@ucd.ie

Cotter: Associate Professor in Finance, Centre for Financial Markets, Graduate School of Business, University College Dublin, Blackrock, Ireland. Phone +00 353 1 716 8900, Fax +00 353 1 283 5482, E-mail: john.cotter@ucd.ie
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics of Foreign Exchange
Volatility

 Squared Absolute APARCH Range

U.S. dollar
 Mean 2.56 2.43 5.03 1.81
 SD 0.35 0.18 0.70 0.52
 Skewness -0.03 -0.26 0.36 1.41
 Kurtosis 0.09 0.16 -0.06 4.89
 Normality 0.97 0.22 0.06 0.00
UK sterling
 Mean 1.78 1.96 3.22 3.06
 SD 0.40 0.31 0.36 0.55
 Skewness -0.22 -0.48 0.15 1.07
 Kurtosis -0.25 -0.46 -0.39 1.98
 Normality 0.25 0.00 0.24 0.00

Notes: The volatility estimates are defined in the text.
The figures for normality refer to p values for the
Bera-Jarque test. SD, standard deviation.

TABLE 2
Summary Statistics of Income Volatility

 Moving
 Squared Absolute APARCH Window

U.S. income
 Mean 0.43 0.52 0.54 0.59
 SD 0.18 0.11 0.16 0.22
 Skewness 3.35 1.25 1.85 0.99
 Kurtosis 14.25 2.53 4.25 1.06
 Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
UK income
 Mean 1.22 0.80 0.82 0.97
 SD 0.33 0.15 0.25 0.46
 Skewness 4.99 1.54 0.20 1.07
 Kurtosis 34.67 3.95 -0.85 1.31
 Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The volatility estimates are defined in the text.
The figures for normality refer to p values for the
Bera-Jarque test. SD, standard deviation.

TABLE 3
Summary Statistics of the Interaction Term
(APARCH)

 Moving
 Squared Absolute APARCH Window

United States
 Mean 2.13 2.59 2.71 2.91
 SD 0.90 0.61 0.89 1.08
 Skewness 3.43 1.14 1.87 1.33
 Kurtosis 16.04 2.67 5.02 2.47
 Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
United Kingdom
 Mean 3.92 2.57 2.63 3.13
 SD 1.14 0.57 0.93 1.54
 Skewness 3.44 1.00 0.51 0.90
 Kurtosis 19.06 1.23 -0.44 0.49
 Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: The volatility estimates are defined in the text.
The figures for normality refer top values for the Bera-Jarque
test. The interaction estimates here are a combination involving
APARCH foreign exchange volatility with the respective
income volatility measures. SD, standard deviation.

TABLE 4
Summary Statistics of the Poisson Lag Structure

 [y.sup.*.sub.t] [s.sup.r.sub.t] [[sigma].sub.s,t]

United States
 Mean 5.29 0.39 11.58
 SE 0.71 0.06 1.27
 95% CI 3.77-6.81 0.27-0.51 8.87-14.28
 Median 4.60 0.42 11.49
 SD 2.85 0.22 5.08
 Range 9.84 0.65 17.87
 Min 1.06 0.00 2.50
 Max 10.90 0.65 20.37
United Kingdom
 Mean 11.30 1.34 15.63
 SE 0.28 0.16 1.65
 95% CI 10.69-11.91 0.97-1.70 12.01-19.26
 Median 11.68 1.11 12.75
 SD 0.95 0.57 5.70
 Range 3.16 1.88 16.08
 Min 8.89 0.62 10.00
 Max 12.05 2.50 26.08

 [[sigma].sub.y,t] [[sigma].sub.s x y,t]

United States
 Mean 11.66 12.72
 SE 2.94 2.68
 95% C1 5.39-17.93 17.00-18.43
 Median 6.79 9.20
 SD 11.77 10.72
 Range 29.99 27.31
 Min 0.01 0.86
 Max 30.00 28.17
United Kingdom
 Mean 22.53 20.95
 SE 2.31 2.19
 95% Cl 17.44-27.61 16.13-25.77
 Median 24.37 24.22
 SD 8.00 7.59
 Range 29.13 27.92
 Min 0.87 0.60
 Max 30.00 28.52

Notes. [y.sup.*.sub.t] refers to real income, [s.sup.r.sub.t] is real
foreign exchange rate, [[sigma].sub.s,t] is real foreign exchange
volatility, [[sigma].sub.y,t] is real income volatility, and
[[sigma].sub.s x y,t] is the interaction term. Summary statistics of
the lag structure of the 16 models include the mean and median lags,
the minimum and maximum lags, and measures of dispersion of the lags
with standard deviation and range. CI, confidence interval; SE,
standard error.

TABLE 5
Summary Statistics of the Estimates of the Model

 [[sigma].
 [y.sup.*.sub.t] [s.sup.r.sub.t] sub.s,t]

United States (a)
 Mean 5.15 -0.87 0.29
 SE 0.05 0.04 0.05
 95% CI 5.06-5.28 -1.02-0.94 0.18-0.40
 Median 5.13 -0.93 0.26
 SD 0.21 0.14 0.21
 Range 0.68 0.47 0.57
 Minimum 4.88 -1.07 0.05
 Maximum 5.57 -0.60 0.62
 Coefficient 5.14 -0.94 0.32
 SE 0.07 0.05 0.04
 Exogeneity test 0.62 0.54 0.31
United Kingdom (b)
 Mean 2.72 -1.07 0.17
 SE 0.11 0.04 0.02
 95% CI 2.49-2.96 -1.15-0.98 0.12-0.22
 Median 2.54 -1.10 0.15
 SD 0.37 0.14 0.08
 Range 1.19 0.48 0.24
 Minimum 2.25 -1.35 0.10
 Maximum 3.44 -0.87 0.34
 Coefficient 3.11 -1.14 0.11
 SE 0.21 0.13 0.05
 Exogeneity test 0.51 0.49 0.19

 [[sigma].sub.y,t] [[sigma].sub.sxy,t]

United States (a)
 Mean -0.45 0.31
 SE 0.27 0.12
 95% CI -1.04-0.13 0.05-0.58
 Median -0.74 0.30
 SD 1.09 0.50
 Range 4.43 2.16
 Minimum -2.43 -1.17
 Maximum 2.00 0.99
 Coefficient -0.85 0.46
 SE 0.30 0.10
 Exogeneity test 0.20 0.28
United Kingdom (b)
 Mean -0.81 -0.01
 SE 0.13 0.05
 95% CI -1.10-0.52 -0.10-0.09
 Median -0.99 0.04
 SD 0.46 0.16
 Range 1.39 0.46
 Minimum -1.26 -0.27
 Maximum 0.12 0.20
 Coefficient -1.07 0.06
 SE 0.22 0.05
 Exogeneity test 0.21 0.19

Notes: [y.sup.*.sub.t] refers to real income, [s.sup.r.sub.t] is real
foreign exchange rate, [[sigma].sub.s,t] is real foreign exchange
volatility, [[sigma].sub.y,t] is real income volatility, and
[[sigma].sub.sxy,t] is the interaction term. Summary statistics of the
lag structure of the 16 models include the mean and median lags, the
minimum and maximum lags, and measures of dispersion of the lags with
standard deviation and range. The specific set of results adopt the
squared approach for both foreign exchange and foreign income
volatility. The final statistic is the Hausman exogeneity test
statistic where the null hypothesis of exogeneity cannot be rejected
in all cases. CI, confidence interval; SD, standard deviation; SE,
standard error.

(a) [R.sup.2] = .97, SE = 0.16.

(b) [R.sup.2] = .92, SE = 0.16.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有