Volatility and Irish exports.
Bredin, Don ; Cotter, John
We analyze the impact of volatility per se on real exports for a
small open economy concentrating on Irish trade with the United Kingdom
and the United States. An important element is that we take account of
the time lag between the trade decision and the actual trade or payments
taking place by using a flexible lag approach. Rather than adopting a
single measure of risk, we adopt a spectrum of risk measures and detail
varied size characteristics and statistical properties. We find that the
ambiguous results found to date may be due to not taking account of the
timing effect, which varies substantially depending on which volatility
measure is used. (JEL C32, C51, F14, F31)
I. INTRODUCTION
The international trade performance of a small open economy (SOE)
plays a pivotal role in the performance of the economy. This is clearly
the case for Ireland as the share of Irish merchandise exports in gross
domestic product (GDP) has grown dramatically in recent years (from 43%
in 1979 to 94% in 2002), thus rendering the economy more open than
before and more dependent on foreign markets. (1) Hence, policies
designed to enhance export performance are of increasing importance to
national economic welfare. Good policy decisions are assisted by having
relevant information on the factors that determine the level of exports
and imports. In this paper, we examine the impact of volatility per se
on real Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United States using,
a two-country imperfect substitutes model. (2) As well as including real
income and real foreign exchange, volatility of these underlying
variables is also analyzed by incorporating a spectrum of volatility
proxies. The analysis of an SOE's export function is in contrast to
the vast majority of the previous studies that focus on large economies
with a small share of international trade relative to GDP. The issue of
the sensitivity to volatility considers both foreign exchange volatility
as well as foreign income volatility. Moreover, in excess of 40% of
Irish exports go to the United Kingdom and United States, and these
transactions dominate those of its trading partners within the auspices
of the Euro currency union. Also the case of the Irish economy can
provide unique insights into the effects of currency unions given that
it was part of a currency union with UK sterling up until 1979.
There are a number of important advances in the current study to
provide insights on the mixed empirical findings for the impact of
economic variables such as foreign exchange volatility on exports.
First, we adopt a comprehensive set of volatility measures and determine
whether the use of a specific measure influences the empirics. These
include recent advances in the time-varying autoregressive (AR)
heteroskedasticity literature, asymmetric power autoregressive
conditional heteroskedasticity (APARCH), absolute volatility underpinned
by the theory of power variation, and the model-free log range estimate.
This paper details their statistical properties in conjunction with
their impact on real exports. The vast majority of previous studies
report results for the influence of volatility on trade by focusing only
on a single particular measure of foreign exchange volatility and in
many cases have not accounted for the recent developments in
time-varying risk measurement. As well as exchange rate volatility, we
expand the menu of volatility variables and determine the impact of
foreign income uncertainty that is often overlooked but may well be
crucial to a small open developing economy. The importance of foreign
income volatility for trade has been highlighted (Baum, Caglayan, and
Ozkan 2004; Franke 1991; Grier and Smallwood 2005). For instance, Franke
(1991) views trade as an option for a firm that will be exercised if
doing so is profitable. Thus, as well as including income and foreign
exchange in our exports model, we include volatility of these underlying
variables. This is consistent with Franke (1991), where foreign income
volatility (rather than foreign exchange volatility) is viewed as a
signal for greater profit opportunities. As well as addressing the
impact of foreign exchange rate volatility and foreign income
volatility, we also look at the interaction between the two following
Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) and hence take account of any possible
nonlinear influences on exports that they may have.
Second, rather than looking at the empirical long-run relationship
between exports and a set of variables, we analyze the impact of
volatility per se adopting a flexible lag approach. Using a Poisson
distributed lag structure, the model takes account of the lag between
trade decisions and the time of the actual trade flow/ payment. Thus,
our empirical results show the total effect of volatility as well as the
distribution of the effect over time. A similar flexible lag approach
has been adopted by both Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) and Klaassen
(2004) for fully developed economies. However, in the current setting,
we are able to indicate the total effect as well as the time
distribution effect for each of the complete set of foreign exchange and
income volatility variables. A key issue is whether the various
volatility measures are likely to have similar total and time
distribution effects.
Finally, the data set studied is representative of an SOE facing a
high degree of uncertainty from external factors. Although a member of
the European single currency, the majority of Irish exports are to
non-Euro zones with the United States and the United Kingdom
representing the most important markets. (3) At the start of our sample
1979, Irish exports to the United States represented just under 5% of
total exports, while at the end of the sample, it was close to 20%. In
contrast, Irish exports to the United Kingdom have fallen from about 40%
in 1979 to 20% in 2002. While the trend, in terms of the share of total
Irish exports to the United States and the United Kingdom, is moving in
opposite directions, the combined importance remains extremely strong,
that is, over 40% of total Irish exports go to the United States and the
United Kingdom at both the beginning and the end of the sample.
The paper finds very strong evidence for the influence of
volatility on an SOE. We find that the foreign exchange volatility
effect is consistently positive, indicating the dominance of
exporters' expectations of possible profitable opportunities from
future cash flows associated with the export function. In contrast, the
potential negative aspects of trade, the entry and exit costs, appear to
be accounted for by negative effects for income volatility on trade.
Moreover, positive nonlinear effects for the interaction between foreign
exchange and income volatility influence exports for an SOE.
Importantly, these findings occur in the face of volatility measures
that differentiate considerably in their statistical properties
according to the modeling process used. Furthermore, while the total
effect of the foreign exchange and income volatility on exports is
consistent across each of the various volatility measures, the timing
effect is considerably different. This effect represents the time (in
months) at which the maximum effect occurs, and it varies significantly
across our volatility measures. Overall, we find that the ambiguous
results found to date in the literature may be due to not taking account
of this varying timing effect.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section IX
provides a survey of the theoretical and empirical literature. The
methodological approach with the operations of the adopted export model
and the alternative volatility measures are discussed in detail in
Section III. Section IV includes a description of the data used and an
analysis of the alternative volatility measures. Section V reports
details of the model specification and the findings from our empirical
model concentrating on the influence of volatility. Finally, Section VI
concludes.
II. LITERATURE REVIEW
A. Theoretical Models
Theoretically, the modeling of exports allows for different impacts
of volatility with no unanimity on direction and magnitude. To
illustrate, Demers (1991) assumed that exchange rate risk leads to lower
production and trade due to price uncertainty implications for foreign
demand. This rationale is generally supported by policymakers (see EU
Commission 1990). Here, the effect of higher exchange rate volatility
depends on the expected marginal utility of export income. Higher
exchange rate risk reduces the expected marginal utility of export
revenues, and thus, risk-averse producers reduce their output.
An alternative model consistent with a positive association between
exchange rate volatility and exports implies that exchange rate
movements are not just a source of risk but also create opportunities to
make profits because they affect the real opportunities of the firm (De
Grauwe 1994). Assuming that firms make their production and export
decisions once they have observed the exchange rate, higher exchange
rate uncertainty may increase the average profit of the firm. For a
profit-taking firm, a higher price due to an exchange rate change
results in the firm enjoying higher profits per unit of output and so
expands its output. Equivalently, in this analysis, exporting represents
an option. At a favorable exchange rate, the firm exercises its option
to export. The opposite happens for unfavorable movements. Since the
value of options increases with the variability of the underlying asset,
the firm is better off when exchange rate variability increases. Even
assuming risk aversion, it remains possible that exchange rate
volatility increases exports, provided that the increase in utility of
the firm from the increase in the average profit offsets the decline in
utility of the risk-averse firm due to the greater uncertainty of
profits.
More specifically, Franke (1991) follows a real options approach
and views trade as an option to be exercised by a firm. The author
examines the decision-making process of exporters under uncertainty in
an intertemporal multiperiod setting. The real options approach extends
the possible factors included in modeling exports. In particular, any
underlying variable has associated volatility, giving rise to adding
income and foreign exchange volatility to our export function. Here, for
example, the exchange rate is assumed to be mean reverting and there are
costs to entering and exiting markets. Firms will exercise the option to
enter a market if doing so is profitable. The profitability of the
option depends on the present value of expected cash flows from
exporting and on the present value of expected entry and exist costs. A
weaker (stronger) exchange rate increases (decreases) both the cash flow
from exporting and the entry and exit costs. The latter is assumed to be
a concave function of the exchange rate. If volatility causes expected
cash flows from exporting to grow faster than expected entry and exit
costs, then the value of the option to export has increased and
volatility and trade are positively related. This will be the case if
cash flows are convex in the exchange rate. According to this scenario,
increased volatility will result in firms entering the market sooner and
exiting later and the number of trading firms will increase.
Furthermore, ambiguity on the relationship between exchange rate
uncertainty and trade has also been outlined (Viaene and de Vries 1992).
If you allow for the existence of forward markets, then exchange rate
volatility can impact trade either positively or negatively through its
impact on the determination of forward rates. The outcome is then
determined through the empirical analysis. Thus, overall, the
theoretical predictions regarding volatility and trade are inconclusive.
B. Empirical Evidence
The vast empirical evidence of the influence of exchange rate
volatility on exports is also mixed. (4) Findings are dependent on
models employed, sample period analyzed, and countries examined
(Bacchetta and van Wincoop 2000). Furthermore, there is no consistency
in the measures of volatility used ranging from unconditional estimates
such as standard deviation in the early literature to conditional ones
such as generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity
(GARCH) estimates in more recent times (McKenzie 1999). For instance,
Koray and Lastrapes (1989) find evidence of a negative relationship
between exchange rate volatility and trade using cointegration
techniques involving U.S. pairs. In contrast, Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan
(2004) show evidence of a positive relationship between exchange rate
volatility and trade using a Poisson flexible lag structure, while
Klaassen (2004) did not find evidence of any significant effect of
exchange rate volatility on trade for G7 economies. Hedging through
derivative products usually explains the lack of significance, although
Wei (1999) finds a negative and statistically significant effect for
foreign exchange rate volatility on exports even after taking account of
futures and options instruments to hedge risk. There is some evidence
that views increased exchange rate volatility as a result of greater
integration of world markets (see Rose 2000). However, Glick and Rose
(2002), measuring exchange rate uncertainty using unconditional standard
deviation, find that an increase (decrease) in exchange rate volatility
resulting from leaving (joining) a currency union has a negative
(positive) impact on trade statistics.
The majority of empirical studies estimate an export function based
on the following (see Arize 1997):
(1) [x.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][y.sup.*.sub.t] +
[[beta].sub.2][p.sup.*.sub.x], + [[beta].sub.3][[sigma].sub.s,t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t],
where [x.sub.t], [y.sup.*.sub.t], and [p.sub.t] stand for real
exports, foreign real income, and relative prices, respectively (in
logs), t represents time (in months), [[sigma].sub.s,t] stands for
exchange rate volatility that captures exchange rate uncertainty, and
[[epsilon].sub.t] represents the error term. (5) Economic theory
suggests that real income levels of the trading partners for the
domestic country and competitiveness measures affect the volume of
exports positively and negatively, respectively.
In addition to the mixed empirical results, many alternative
modeling approaches have been applied. Early empirical studies
disregarded the issue of nonstationarity of macroeconomic time series
and used classical regression analysis and are subject to the
"spurious regression" criticism. Studies also test for
stationarity of the relevant time series and employ cointegration
techniques, for example, Koray and Lastrapes (1989). Two recent studies
take a different approach: Klaassen (2004) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan
(2004). Rather than looking at the long-run relationship between the
variables, both papers analyze the impact of exchange rate volatility
adopting a flexible lag approach. In other words, the model takes
account of the lag between a trade decision and the time of the actual
trade flow/ payment. In both cases, the empirical part of the studies
uses a Poisson lag structure in order to account for the possible
extended effect. Klaassen focuses on U.S. exports to other G7 countries
for the period 1978-1996 and finds an insignificant effect in all cases.
Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) focus on bilateral aggregate real
exports between 1980 and 1998 for the following countries: United
States, Canada, Germany, United Kingdom, France, Italy, Japan, Finland,
Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. Baum, Caglayan, and
Ozkan (2004) also include foreign income volatility that is consistent
with Franke (1991). We now view foreign income volatility as a signal
for greater profit opportunities. As well as addressing the impact of
foreign exchange rate volatility and foreign income volatility, they
also look at the interaction between the two and hence take account of
any possible nonlinear relationship. Overall, they find a significant
impact of real income volatility on trade that varies in direction for
the countries analyzed.
Evidence on the impact of volatility on Irish trade statistics is
relatively sparse. (6) Thom and Walsh (2002), modeling overall Irish
trade, find no evidence that exchange rate regime changes impact
Anglo-Irish trade from analyzing time series and panel regressions in a
case study approach. The study argues that the unilateral move by
Ireland to join the European Monetary System (EMS) is unique in that the
devolvement did not disrupt trade. This was mainly due to the fact that
both the United Kingdom and Ireland were both members of the then
European Economic Community (EEC). Also, Lothian and McCarthy (2000)
find that foreign exchange volatility changes according to exchange rate
systems and that volatility decreases upon joining a currency union
vis-a-vis other systems.
III. METHODOLOGY
A. Modeling Exports
As in Klaassen (2004) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004), we
adopt the flexible lag version of the two-country imperfect substitutes
model of Goldstein and Khan (1985) for bilateral trade between Ireland
and the United States and the United Kingdom in real terms. This allows
for examining the decision-making process of exporters under uncertainty
for intertemporal multiperiod horizons. The variable of interest is real
Irish exports using Irish unit export value as our deflator. (7) Irish
exports to the United Kingdom and United States are almost exclusively
invoiced in UK sterling and U.S. dollars, respectively, and we examine
the logarithm of real Irish exports. (8) The determinants of exports
relate to the assumptions concerning export supply and demand. The
determinants of demand are foreign income, [y.sup.*.sub.t-l], and
relative prices, [p.sup.*.sub.xt] = log([P.sub.xt]/[P.sup.*.sub.t]), and
both are stated in foreign currency, while l is a lag representing the
time delay between the purchase and the delivery of the goods. (9)
(2) [q.sup.d.sub.t] = [q.sup.d]([y.sup.*.sub.t-l],
[p.sup.*.sub.xt]).
The determinants of the exports supply function only include the
relative price of exports converted to domestic prices:
(3) [q.sup.s.sub.t] = [q.sup.s]([p.sup.*.sub.xt] + [s.sub.t]),
where [s.sub.t] is the log of the nominal exchange rate, measured
as foreign per unit of domestic currency. Given that decisions will be
made based on the forecast of relative prices, both the conditional mean
and the standard deviation of [p.sup.*.sub.xt] + [s.sub.t] are both
included in the supply equation, where l is the lag to take account of
potential time delay.
(4) [q.sup.s.sub.t] = [q.sup.s]([E.sub.t-l][[p.sup.*.sub.xt] +
[s.sub.t]], [[sigma].sub.s,t-l] [[p.sup.*.sub.xt] + [s.sub.t]]).
Goldstein and Khan (1985) assume that the export decision and
actual exports and payments are not contemporaneous, introducing a
degree of uncertainty into the trade model. To incorporate this
uncertainty, the model is estimated with a flexible Poisson lag
structure. This allows for uncertainty between trading decisions and
actual completion of trade, and we examine how it impacts our variables
in the export model. It makes the traders forward looking and motivates
the relevance of our income and exchange rate risk variables as
potential determinants of trade (Klaassen 2004). The use of the lag
structure allows the data to determine the dynamic specification of the
timing effect. We allow each variable to have its own lag structure, so
thereby measure their maximum effect and illustrate their patterns. In
addition, the process is extended following an options-based approach by
including volatility of the underlying variables. Furthermore, there may
be nonlinear effects arising from a combination of income and foreign
exchange volatility effects not directly measured in the variables alone
(Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan 2004). To incorporate this, an interaction
term of income and foreign exchange volatility is introduced into the
exporter's supply function. (10) Taking account of these
extensions, we can now rewrite exports supply as:
(5) [q.sup.s.sub.t] = [q.sup.s] (E.sub.t-l][P.sup.*.sub.t] +
[s.sub.t]], [[sigma].sub.s,t-l, x [[sigma.sub.y,t-l], [[sigma].sub.s x
y,t-l]),
where [[sigma].sub.s.t-l] is real foreign exchange volatility,
[[sigma].sub.y,t-l] is real income volatility both outlining direct
effects, [[sigma].sub.s x y,t-l] is the interaction term incorporating
nonlinear indirect responses of income and foreign exchange volatility
on the supply function, and l is the lag to take account of potential
time delay. The interaction term, the product of foreign exchange and
income volatility, may capture any possible nonlinearities between
exchange rate volatility and exports.
B. The Poisson Lag Approach
An important element is that we take account of the time lag
between the trade decision and the actual trade taking place or payment
taking place (Goldstein and Khan 1985). Hence, it is clearly not
sufficient to account for only contemporaneous relationships between
exports and our explanatory variables. Equating supply (Equation 5) and
demand (Equation 2) leads to a function for real exports of the
following form: (11)
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The [[beta]'s represent the sensitivities of exports to each
of the variables included (real foreign income, real exchange rate, real
foreign exchange rate volatility, real income volatility, and the
interaction term), for example, [[beta].sub.1l] represents the effect of
foreign income on exports at the lag where the effect is largest. In
order to model the impact using a flexible lag approach, we adopt a
Poisson lag structure (see Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan 2004; Klaassen
2004). Alternative, but more restrictive, approaches include the
geometric and the polynomial lag specifications. For example, the
geometric approach implies that [[beta].sub.l] is decreasing as the lag
increases. (12) The Poisson lag approach is derived from the Poisson
probability distribution for each underlying variable:
(7) [[beta].sub.kl] = [[beta].sub.k] [([[lambda].sub.k] -
1).sup.l-1] / l - 1)! exp [ - ([[lambda].sub.k] - 1)]
for [[lambda].sub.k] [greater than or equal to] 1 and [lambda] is
the lag at which the maximum effect occurs. One important advantage of
the Poisson lag approach is that the number of parameters to be
estimated is minimized, 2k + 1, where k is the number of independent
variables. As can be seen, the parameters [[lambda].sub.1], ...
[[lambda].sub.k] enter into the equation in a nonlinear fashion. In
order to calculate the parameters [[lambda].sub.1], ...
[[lambda].sub.k], we use the simulated annealing optimization technique
(see, Goffe, Ferrier, and Rogers 1994). (13) Once the parameters,
[[lambda].sub.1], ... [[lambda].sub.k], have been obtained from the
nonlinear optimization technique, the estimated coefficients,
[[beta].sub.1], ... [[beta].sub.k], are calculated using ordinary least
squares.
C. The Appropriate Volatility Measure
Our export model follows an options-based approach. Here,
participation in export markets is based on evaluation of entry and exit
costs using a real options approach to the decision-making process. This
real options approach suggests that additional volatility variables
affect medium-term exports. The real options approach incorporates
volatility of the economic variables under consideration, thus including
volatility of exchange rates and of income. In his study, Franke (1991)
finds a positive relationship between exports and exchange rate
volatility. The rationale is that firms increase exports in response to
increased volatility if the present value of expected cash flows from
exports exceeds the sum of entry and exit costs. For instance, changes
in the volatility of foreign income change an exporting firm's
entry/exit cost ratio and therefore their export opportunities to that
economy. Thus, higher foreign income volatility may signal higher profit
opportunities, resulting in a change in exporters' decision making
leading to increased exports.
Given the importance of volatility in our modeling process, it is
interesting to note that the literature relies on many different types
of volatility estimates (McKenzie 1999). So, for example, unlike
exchange rates that are available contemporaneously, exchange rate
volatility is modeled ex post. This has led to a major research agenda
in trying to model financial volatility through analysis of its
distributional and dynamic characteristics. Major developments have been
made in modeling the time variation of volatility and its persistence,
and we incorporate a spectrum of these models. These include the
autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH)-related models and
the more recent model-free aggregated based procedures underpinned by
the theory of power variation. In contrast, models that assume constant
volatility are now generally ignored. (14) Regardless of what approach
is used, the key issue is to recognize that volatility is latently unobservable, thereby requiring proxies. This gives rise to a modeling
approach that could involve a spectrum of procedures, and we estimate
the export specification with a number of alternative risk measures to
determine if volatility determination impacts on inferences from the
export model. Specifically, we address the issue as to whether
alternative volatility estimates are responsible for the inconclusive
empirical evidence. By looking at a number of estimates, we can
ascertain the influence of volatility per se rather than be swayed by
the conclusions from a single estimate. The paper focuses on four
separate measures for foreign exchange and income, respectively, and
when combined give rise to 16 interaction terms. The foreign exchange
and income measures necessarily diverge due to data availability; for
example, foreign exchange rates are available at relatively high
frequencies such as daily intervals, while income estimates are only
available at monthly frequencies.
The volatility measures come from different strands of the
literature such as conditional measures where we apply a time-varying
APARCH process that nests seven different parametric ARCH models (for a
review, see Bollerslev, Engle, and Nelson 1994). Also, estimates
underpinned by the theory of power variation such as realized volatility that requires aggregation from high- to low-frequency observations have
been advocated with many illustrations for volatility modeling (see
references in Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold 2003). Moreover, we
examine the impact of other model-free estimates using squared,
absolute, and range-based estimates (see Alizadeh, Brandt, and Diebold
2002; Ding and Granger 1996).
First concentrating on the aggregated measures that are applied to
the daily exchange rates, the most common approach suggests the use of
aggregated squared exchange rate changes over a period, say, for
example, aggregating daily realizations to obtain monthly estimates
instead of using a single estimate from the monthly exchange rate
changes (see Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan 2004; Klaassen 2004). This
estimate is closely associated with the variance. Merton (1980)
illustrates the advantages in using relatively high-frequency
observations to obtain more precise low-frequency risk measures, and
early applications with monthly estimation cumulating daily observations
are given in French, Schwert, and Stambaugh (1987). This paper also
analyzes aggregated absolute realizations that evolve from the same
theoretical framework, realized power variation (see Barndorff-Nielsen
and Shephard 2003; Cotter 2004), as exchange rate changes have the
stylized property of exhibiting fat tails due to excessive large-scale
movements, and modeling with absolute realizations is more robust in the
presence of this property (Davidian and Carroll 1987). Also, more
attractive time series properties are documented for absolute realized
volatility measures than their squared counterparts (Barndorff-Nielsen
and Shephard 2003).
Turning to the theoretical framework, we begin by defining the
price process that is underpinned by realized power variation.
Volatility of this price process defined as integrated volatility is
said to be unobservable. The framework incorporates the popularly used
quadratic variation that details the use of aggregated squared
realizations and absolute power variation using aggregated absolute
realizations. We analyze the price process that has [r.sub.m,t] =
[p.sub.t] - [p.sub.t - 1/m] as the compounded returns with in evenly
spaced observations per month. Importantly, realized power variation
that incorporates realized absolute variation, namely the sum of
absolute realizations, [summation] [absolute value of [r.sub.m]],
equates with integrated volatility, making volatility of the price
process observable.
We present power variations for both squared and absolute measures
for the monthly foreign exchange volatility. The practical
implementation of the theory simplifies into constructing volatility
estimators using aggregated absolute exchange rate changes and their
variants for any month t with m daily intervals:
(8) [[absolute value of [r.sub.t].sup.n]] = [m.summation over
(j=1)] [[absolute value of [r.sub.m,t+j/m].sup.n]],
where the power coefficients, n, can take on a range of values 0.5
< n < 3 (see Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard 2003). Also, in terms
of the commonly applied principle of quadratic variation using
aggregated squared realizations, exchange rate volatility is given as:
(9) [[absolute value of [r.sup.2.sub.t].sup.n]] = [m.summation over
(j=1)] [[absolute value of [r.sup.2.sub.m,t+j/m].sup.n]],
where different power transformations are again underpinned by the
theoretical framework.
Moving to the standard modeling of time variation, GARCH-type
processes have traditionally been applied (Klaassen 2004; Kroner and
Lastrapes 1993). A large number of specifications are available with,
for example, Kroner and Lastrapes (1993) using a GARCH-in mean (GARCH-M)
process, whereas Klaassen (2004) uses a GARCH(1, l) model. All these
models have a common feature in modeling clustering of second moments.
We use the APARCH to provide end-of-month income and foreign exchange
rate volatility estimates. The model developed by Ding, Granger, and
Engle (1993) advantageously nests many extensions of the GARCH process.
As well as encompassing three ARCH specifications (ARCH, nonlinear ARCH,
and Log-ARCH), two specifications of the GARCH model (using standard
deviation and variance of returns), it also details two asymmetric
models (both ARCH and GARCH versions). It is given by:
(10) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
for [[alpha].sub.0], [[alpha].sub.i], [[beta].sub.j] [greater than
or equal to] 0, [[alpha].sub.i] + [[beta].sub.j] less than or equal to]
1, and - 1 [less than or equal to] [[gamma].sub.i] [less than or equal
to] 1. The [[epsilon].sub.t] are the errors, and [[sigma].sub.t], is the
conditional variance. Detailing the model, the process presents
volatility in the form of a Box-Cox transformation whose flexibility
allows for different specifications of the residuals process associated
with different GARCH models. As well as describing the time variation in
exchange rate changes, it also allows for the possibility of leverage
effects, [[gamma].sub.i], by letting the AR term of the conditional
volatility process be represented as asymmetric absolute residuals.
Nonlinear GARCH models are derived from different power coefficients, d.
The model is fitted with a conditional Student's t distribution,
thereby allowing for fat tails. The model adequately deals with
second-moment persistence documented for the underlying variables.
In addition, the use of the log range defined as the first
difference of the log of maximum and minimum prices is applied to
foreign exchange data at monthly intervals. This simple estimate has
been used widely in an ad hoc fashion in the literature, and its time
series properties are formally examined in Alizadeh, Brandt, and Diebold
(2002). They find that it is an efficient estimator with small
measurement error and has further attractive time series properties by
being approximately Gaussian.
The aggregation procedure and range-based measure are not applied
in measuring income uncertainty due to a lack of intra-monthly
observations. Notwithstanding this, there are many different types of
volatility estimates that could model income dynamics ex post. Here, we
overcome the problem of proxying for unobservable volatility by using
the observed absolute income changes and observed squared income changes
as measures of income uncertainty. Ding and Granger (1996) show that
these model-free volatility proxies adequately model the long-term
persistence property associated with financial data. The final income
measure is the moving window approach advocated by Thursby and Thursby
(1987) to obtain adaptive risk measures.
Here, the moving window technique estimates income volatility for
the United States and the United Kingdom where the logarithm of real
income is regressed on a quadratic trend for a 6-mo moving window. The
root mean squared error of the regression represents the time-varying
process for our volatility measure using relatively low-frequency income
data.
Taking income volatility and exchange rate volatility, we produce
an interaction term as a product of these variables. This allows us to
not only examine the direct impact of the respective volatility
estimates but also assess whether there is an indirect influence of
these volatilities through their interaction with each other. Following
the real options approach, both exchange rate and income volatility
would have a direct concurrent impact on exporters' decision
making, but there may also be an indirect influence. To examine any
combined effects of these separate dynamics, the interaction term
between exchange rate and income volatility is included to help describe
the exporters' behavior. This allows for the processing of
information that is different from each volatility measure but combines
both income and exchange rate volatility. Any indirect impact of the
respective volatility measure is captured by this interaction variable,
and it may remove omitted variable bias by examining respective
volatility measures only. Thus, exchange rate volatility could impact
income volatility and vice versa. For each volatility measure, we create
an interaction term giving 16 separate measures each labeled as a
combination of the respective volatility measures, for example, APARCH
exchange rate volatility combined with squared income changes. These
combinations imply that the impact of the interaction term will not be
constant but will depend on the respective measures of volatility.
IV. DATA CONSIDERATIONS
A. Data
We use monthly data for the period May 1979 to December 2002. The
starting point of our sample is dictated by data availability and that
the sterling link was abandoned in 1979. Irish exports to the United
Kingdom and United States are taken from the Trade Statistics Series of
the Central Statistics Office (CSO) publication and were divided by
Ireland's unit export value to obtain the real exports figure. (15)
Given that real national income is only available at quarterly
frequencies, monthly UK and U.S. industrial production (constant prices)
are used. Irish, UK, and U.S. export unit values are obtained at monthly
intervals. The exchange rate data used in the study are daily UK
sterling per unit of Euro and U.S. dollar per unit of Euro adjusted from
Irish pounds in the pre-Euro period. The real exchange rate is
calculated from the spot exchange rate and the ratio of domestic to
foreign (U.S. and UK) price indices. (16,17)
As shown in Figure 1, Irish exports to the United Kingdom and
United States make up a sizable proportion of Irish exports. Although
traditionally the United Kingdom was the important market for Irish
exports, this has diminished in recent years. At the same time, exports
to the United States have grown steadily over the last number of years.
Although moving in different directions, exports to both countries are
sizable and are exposed to exchange rate movement pressures.
Furthermore, Ireland has a unique relationship with the United Kingdom
that has driven many of its economic policies. For example, in terms of
foreign exchange, Ireland and the United Kingdom were part of a currency
union between 1800 and 1979. (18) The Irish pound--introduced in
1927--was held in a 1:1 no-margins peg with sterling until 1979 using an
ad hoc currency commission to maintain the arrangement. Prior to this,
there was no independent Irish pound since the Act of Union in 1800. The
break from parity was due to Ireland's decision to be a member of
the EMS and the United Kingdom's nonparticipation. The most
important influences on the Irish decision to join the EMS were the
perceived political benefits, the promise of additional EEC subsidies,
and a desire to shift the currency's nominal anchor from sterling,
then considered to be inflation prone, to the new "zone of monetary
stability" based on the German mark (Economic and Social Research
Institute 1996). Overall foreign exchange volatility for the Irish
economy has increased in real terms since 1979 com pared to under the
sterling link (Lothian and McCarthy 2000).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
B. Volatility Measures
Using the respective volatility measures outlined, we describe
their statistical properties and analyze similarities and divergences.
We find a large divergence for the respective volatility estimates in
terms of size, pattern, and statistical properties. There also appears
to be a high degree of persistence. For foreign exchange volatility, the
measures all exhibit a different scale as can be seen in Figure 2, with
a common large spike around the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) crises in
1992/1993. (19) Although time variation is captured by all measures, the
APARCH measure is the smoothest, whereas the Range is the noisiest.
Irish exporters faced considerable variation in exchange rate volatility
for both currencies across the sample period with a major increase
evident during the 1992/ 1993 currency crises that enveloped the EMS
currencies. This was followed by a relatively tranquil period, but
volatility tended to increase in the early years of the Euro.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The summary statistics in Table 1 outline the first four moments
and the Jarque-Bera test for normality of foreign exchange volatility.
The magnitude of moments varies considerably, with, for example, the
mean spanning from 1.81 to 5.03 for the United States, whereas its
standard deviation, the volatility of volatility measure, exhibits a
scale between 0.18 and 0.70. Non-Gaussian features of excess skewness and excess kurtosis are documented in many cases, especially for the
Range measures. The Range is prone to fat tails with positive skewness.
Similar departures are indicated for the respective income
volatility measures. Notwithstanding the divergences, the result of the
U.S. expansionary policy increases all volatility measures in the early
1980s, and there has also been a common increase in income volatility
for the United Kingdom in 2002. Furthermore, all the measures exhibit
excess skewness and kurtosis in Table 2 and are non-normal. The excess
skewness and kurtosis are strongest for the squared measure, whereas
APARCH exhibits a platykurtotic bunching of realizations. Diverging patterns of the respective measures also occur with the squared and
absolute measures noisy relative to APARCH and moving window volatility.
The shape plots in Figure 3 indicate that all the volatility measures
are non-normal with excess positive skewness. Also, all measures exhibit
very fat upper tails. While generally strong persistence is shown for
all foreign exchange volatility measures in Figure 4, it disappears
after 6 mo for U.S. squared volatility.
Turning to the income volatility estimates, we examine their
relationship with each other and find that the APARCH estimate involves
the lowest linkages and a strong relationship exists between squared and
absolute measures for both United Kingdom and United States. The extent
of the relationships between respective foreign exchange rate volatility
measures is shown in the scatter plots of Figure 5 for the United
Kingdom and clearly indicates divergences. For instance, linkages
between the squared and other measures are high, but in contrast, the
range is not strongly related to the other measures with correlations of
less than .4 in both U.S. and UK cases.
Given the respective divergences for income and foreign exchange
volatility measures, and the interaction term being defined as a
combination of these, it is no surprise to see similar conclusions for
the respective interactions in Table 3. For instance, the standard
deviation extends between 0.57 and 1.54 with very different patterns
emerging across the interaction terms. While this is especially so for
those estimates involving squared measures, all measures exhibit excess
skewness and kurtosis and deviate from normality. Finally, the varying
strength of the relationships of the respective interaction terms
incorporating the APARCH foreign exchange volatility measures is present
with reasonably similar patterns. Thus far, both United States and
United Kingdom exhibit strong linkages between absolute and squared
measures with correlations in excess of .86 in comparison to the other
relatively weak relationships. Overall, the respective volatility
measures diverge strongly in terms of size, pattern, and statistical
properties. These findings are consistent for both UK and U.S.
volatility measures. Given these discrepancies, these inputs are now
used to model Ireland's export function with its largest trading
partners to determine their respective influence on the economy's
exports.
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
A. Model Specification
The export model is run with forecasted volatility using the
Poisson lag structure for 16 combinations for each country pair. (20)
Our study includes four separate foreign exchange risk measures as well
as four separate income volatility measures. We combine each of the
foreign income measures with the separate foreign exchange volatility
measures, giving 16 possible combinations, to which we augment the
interaction term, for example, the specification may include squared
foreign exchange volatility, APARCH foreign income volatility, and the
interaction term, squared-APARCH. As has been discussed, an important
element is that we take account of the time lag between the trade
decision and the actual trade taking place or payment taking place. (21)
The stochastic optimization process of simulating annealing is applied
to our function in order to obtain the global maximum. As has been
discussed, this approach is adopted due to the difficulty associated
with obtaining the global maximum. The algorithm is rerun with different
starting values and a different seed for the random number generator,
and in all cases, the maxima were found to be identical. Consistent with
Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004), we allow for a maximum of 30 lags;
however, we do not restrict the final four variables to have the same
lag: real foreign exchange, real foreign exchange volatility, real
foreign income volatility, and the interaction term. Our unrestricted
approach is taken to fully capture the exposure of exports from an SOE
for foreign exchange and income volatility.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The lag structure and the parameter coefficients of the models are
of interest. The former details the optimal lag of exporters with
respect to variables impacting their export decision, whereas the latter
shows the impact of economic variables such as income volatility on the
export decision. Given that the volatility measures exhibit considerable
deviations, it is interesting to determine their respective impacts on
the estimation of the lag structures for the export model. This would
possibly help to explain the diverging results in the literature for
volatility and trade.
Summary statistics of the different lag structures affecting the
variables in the export model in terms of mean and variance are given in
Table 4 for each country. Also, a plot of the lag distribution for
income and real exchange rates and associated volatility for exports to
the United Kingdom and United States is given in Figure 6. Unlike
previous studies, we do not assume an identical lag structure for each
of our volatility terms. Different maximal lags are evident across the
explanatory variables including foreign exchange and associated
volatility. For instance, the strongest lag effect occurs for real
exchange rates having a mean of 0.39 compared to 11.58 for real exchange
rate volatility for the United States. However, consistency in the lag
structures for specific variables is generally evident, with the United
States generally having lower mean lags than the United Kingdom. In
particular, exports to the United States are generally affected quicker
by economic wealth and foreign exchange activity compared to the impact
of those variables for the United Kingdom. (22) Also for the specific
lag structures, the mean of the maximal lag for real income is much
higher for the United Kingdom (11.30) than the United States (5.29). The
latter is in line with the fast decline predicted by Goldstein and Khan
(1985). The relatively large income lag for the case of exports to the
United Kingdom is similar to Klaassen (2004), analyzing developed
economies although the study assumed the mean and variance of the lag
structure to be equivalent.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Turning to the volatility lag structures, both U.S. and UK average
real foreign exchange volatility measures have their maximal impact
after a number of lags of just less than a year. Also, the 95% interval
estimate for real foreign exchange volatility is between 8.87 and 14.28
with a median of 11.49 mo for the United States. However, there is a
fair degree of dispersion according to each model with a range of lags
of over a year for both countries, indicating that the largest effects
vary according to different foreign exchange volatility measures. This
can be seen in Figure 7, which plots the distribution associated with
the highest and lowest lag effects. The pattern of lag weights suggests
a hump shape in line with Klaassen (2004) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan
(2004). The maximal effect for income volatility (Figure 8) also varies
with a median of 6.79 for the United States and 24.37 for the United
Kingdom with standard errors around 2, suggesting that exports respond
slowly to economic activity. Again, there is a large dispersion between
minimum and maximum lags that present the strongest effects for income
volatility measures on Irish exports. Finally, the average lag of the
interaction term is over a year and shows a large level of dispersion
across the different models. Overall, the different volatility measures
result in large variations in the export model's lag structure and
emphasize the importance of accounting for the respective lag
structures.
Comparing the lag structures of the exchange rate and income
variables, the findings support previous studies (e.g., Goldstein and
Khan 1985; Klaassen 2004) in supporting a larger delay in the impact of
foreign exchange over income variables.
B. Volatility and Exports
Estimated parameters for the export models are given in Table 5,
summarizing the results for the 16 models for each country pair. We also
report the point coefficients as well as standard errors for one of the
regression combinations. (23) A number of summary estimates of the 16
models are given including the mean coefficient, the minimum and maximum
coefficients, and measures of dispersion of the coefficients including
the standard deviation and range. The diagnostics indicate
well-specified models in all cases, for example, high [R.sup.2] and no
evidence of endogeneity of regressors. (24) Very strong positive real
income effects are reported with all t-statistics significant. These
large positive coefficients are associated with a low dispersion of
estimates with a minimum of 4.88 for the United States and a maximum of
5.57. The point estimates for the United States follow the same pattern
as the United Kingdom. The negative effects of real foreign exchange are
consistent with theory and in line with previous studies that measure
their variables in foreign currency. Also, the impact of foreign
exchange is reasonably constant with very little dispersion indicated
for the country pair parameters. The parameters are consistent across
the country pairs with coefficients of similar magnitude.
The main empirical issue of the paper examines the impact of
volatility on exports using the small open Irish economy as a case study
and is now outlined. As discussed, many studies have investigated the
influence of real exchange rate volatility with very contradictory
findings. For Ireland, real exchange rate volatility has a positive
statistically significant impact on trade regardless of the foreign
exchange volatility measure applied. On average, a 1% increase in
respective foreign exchange volatility leads to an increase in exports
to the United States and the United Kingdom by 0.29% and 0.17%.
Furthermore, the specific model (squared approach) indicated that a 1%
increase in foreign exchange volatility leads to an increase in exports
to the United States and the United Kingdom by 0.32% and 0.11%,
respectively. Although there is some variation (in particular for
exports to the United States), the relationship is positive in all
cases. The results imply that exporters treat an increase in real
foreign exchange volatility to the United States and United Kingdom as a
positive situation to exploit profit opportunities associated with the
positive expected cash flow dominating the entry and exit costs of
exporting. Exporters then decide to exercise their option to trade,
resulting in increased trade flows being determined by increased foreign
exchange volatility. The positive effect of real foreign exchange
volatility supports the findings of Franke (1991) and Baum, Caglayan,
and Ozkan (2004). The consistency of the finding occurs given the
backdrop of diverging magnitude and statistical properties documented
across the volatility measures (see Table 1).
Dispersion of the impact of foreign exchange volatility measures
does occur, indicating that the choice of volatility proxies matters.
For instance, the smallest effect (minimum value = 0.05) occurs for the
Range volatility measure in the U.S. equation but is still statistically
positive with a t-statistic of 2.85. In contrast, the largest effect
(maximum value = 0.62) occurs for the APARCH measure for the United
States with a t-statistic of 7.57. The results also suggest that exports
to the United States are considerably more sensitive to the respective
foreign exchange volatility measures relative to UK exports.
International evidence regarding the impact of income volatility on
export flows is sparse. Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) find that
income volatility is significant in only a quarter of their cases and
claim that the sign of the statistically important parameters is
ambiguous with nearly as many negative influences as positive influences
being recorded. We find stronger results in adopting the real options
approach and the respective influence of income volatility with
significant influences being found in all but 3 of the 32 cases, 1 being
negative and 2 being positive. Our findings are in line with Grier and
Smallwood (2005) who use a GARCH specification for a mixture of
developing and developed economies. Overall foreign income volatility is
primarily a negative determinant of Irish exports to the United States
in 11 models and to the United Kingdom in 15 models. For instance, on
average a 1% increase in foreign income volatility reduces Irish exports
to the United States and the United Kingdom by 0.45% and 0.81%,
respectively. The finding suggests that the negative impact of exit and
entry costs driven by the export decision dominates the cash flow
benefits associated with greater levels of income volatility and results
in reduced trade as exporters do not exercise their option to trade in
these circumstances. Furthermore, the negative coefficients recorded in
the remaining models dominate the positive findings as evidenced by the
mean statistic and their associated confidence interval in Table 5. The
average impacts are reasonably similar for the United States and United
Kingdom, with the latter dominating. However, the range of impact is
relatively large for the different models applied, with values of 1.39
for the United Kingdom and 4.43 for the United States.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Finally, the effect of the combination of the respective income and
foreign exchange volatility measures is examined. The coefficients
represent the indirect influence of foreign exchange and income
volatility on the export decision. The findings strongly suggest that
the interaction terms have a positive impact on Irish exports for the
United States but not the United Kingdom. Individually, however,
significance occurs in 12 cases (incorporating both positive and
negative values that cancel each other out) for the United Kingdom and
14 cases for the United States. The influence of the indirect term is
stronger for the United States (median 0.30) than the United Kingdom
(median 0.04), and there is a reasonable spread of values with the
United States having a range of 2.16 compared to 0.46 for the United
Kingdom. Thus, exporters not only have to take account of the direct
influences of foreign exchange and income volatility but the combination
of these factors also affects the export function albeit in an indirect
fashion.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
The paper analyzes the impact of real foreign exchange and income
volatility on Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United States.
The majority of the literature in this area has focused on exports from
fully developed economies and may well have led to the inconclusive
empirical evidence to date. This issue has been highlighted by Bacchetta
and van Wincoop (2000) and Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) who suggest
that data selection issues may be driving the mixed results. This study
reverses the analysis by focusing on an SOE with a very high dependency
on trade and potentially high levels of volatility affecting the factors
driving exports.
Of interest is the effect of foreign exchange and income volatility
on Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United States over the
period studied, 1979-2002. Although Ireland is a member of the Euro, the
remaining foreign exchange volatility effects may be substantial as a
large percentage of Irish exports are to the United Kingdom and the
United States. This was especially the case for the sterling rate, which
previously had a currency union with the Irish currency pre-1979 and
also was part of the EMS between 1990 and 1992. In terms of the effect
of foreign exchange volatility, we find that there is a consistently
positive effect on Irish exports to the United Kingdom and the United
States. In contrast, we find a negative impact of income volatility on
exports, a result which is consistent with Franke (1991). If the
exporting decision is viewed as an option, as suggested by Franke
(1991), then our income volatility result highlights that the costs of
entry dominate the increased cash flows associated with the export
decision, resulting in lower exports. Finally, we also test the impact
of the interaction between foreign exchange rate and income volatility
and find a positive effect in the majority of cases. This illustrates an
indirect effect of foreign exchange and income volatility on the export
function.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
The paper is underpinned by the use of alternative volatility
measures with diverging magnitude and statistical properties but yet
results in a consistent set of findings. This consistency is welcome
given that volatility is inherently unobservable, and previous studies
have utilized measures from a spectrum of modeling procedures. Moreover,
there is considerable variation in the timing effect of volatility per
se on Irish exports uncovered by analyzing the lag structure of the
export model. The lack of decomposition of volatility effects into
timing and causality and the limited choice of volatility measures
applied may well have supported the historically mixed evidence in
previous empirical studies. An interesting extension to this study is to
examine disaggregated trade flows focusing on the specific relationships
of individual industry sectors with their non-Euro trading partners.
ABBREVIATIONS
APARCH: Asymmetric Power Autoregressive Conditional
Heteroskedasticity
AR: Autoregressive
ARCH: Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity
EEC: European Economic Community
EMS: European Monetary System
EU: European Union
GARCH: Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
SOE: Small Open Economy
REFERENCES
Alizadeh, S., M. W. Brandt, and F. X. Diebold. "Range Based
Estimation of Stochastic Volatility Models." Journal of Finance,
57, 2002, 1047-92.
Andersen, T. G., T. Bollerslev, and F. X. Diebold. "Parametric
and Nonparametric Measurement of Volatility," in Handbook of
Financial Econometrics, edited by Y. Ait-Sahalia and L. P. Hansen.
Amsterdam, Netherlands: North Holland, 2003.
Arize, A. C. "Conditional Exchange Rate Volatility and the
Volume of Foreign Trade: Evidence from Seven Industrialized Countries." Southern Economic Journal, 64, 1997, 235-54.
Bacchetta, P., and E. van Wincoop. "Does Exchange Rate
Stability Increase Trade and Welfare?" American Economic Review,
90, 2000, 1093-109.
Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E., and N. Shephard. "Realised Power
Variation and Stochastic Volatility." Bernoulli, 9, 2003, 243-65.
Baum, C. F., M. Caglayan, and N. Ozkan. "Nonlinear Effects of
Exchange Rate Volatility on the Volume of Bilateral Exports."
Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 19, 2004, 1-23.
Bollerslev, T., R. F. Engle, and D. B. Nelson. "ARCH
Model," in Handbook of Econometrics, edited by R. F. Engle and D.
C. McFadden. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier Science, 1994, 2959-3038.
Central Bank of Ireland. "Statistical Appendix" in
Quarterly Bulletin. Dublin, Ireland: Central Bank & Financial
Service Authority of Ireland, No. 4, October, 2004.
Cotter, J. "Minimum Capital Requirement Calculations for UK
Futures." Journal of Futures Markets, 24, 2004, 193-220.
--"Export Ireland Survey 2005-International Trade, Finance and
Credit Management." Dublin, Ireland: Institute of International
Trade of Ireland/Irish Exporters Association, October, 2005.
Davidian, M., and R. J. Carroll. "Variance Function
Estimation." Journal of the American Statistical Association, 82,
1987, 1079-91.
De Grauwe, P. The Economics of Monetary Integration. Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press, 1994.
Demers, M. "Investment Under Uncertainty, Irreversibility, and
the Arrival of Information Over Time." Review of Economic Studies,
58, 1991, 333-50.
Ding, Z., and C. W. J. Granger. "Modeling Volatility
Persistence of Speculative Returns." Journal of Econometrics, 73,
1996, 185-215.
Ding, Z., C. W. J. Granger, and R. F. Engle. "A Long Memory
Property of Stock Market Returns and A New Model." Journal of
Empirical Finance, 1, 1993, 83-106.
Economic & Social Research Institute. "Economic
Implications for Ireland of EMU." Policy Research Series, Paper No.
28. 1996.
EU Commission. "One Market, One Money." European Economy,
44, 1990.
Franke, G. "Exchange Rate Volatility and International Trading
Strategy." Journal of International Money and Finance, 10, 1991,
292-307.
French, K. R., G. W. Schwert, and R. F. Stambaugh.
"Expected Stock Returns and Volatility." Journal of
Financial Economics, 19, 1987, 3-29.
Glick, R., and A. K. Rose. "Does a Currency Union Affect
Trade? The Time-Series Evidence." European Economic Review 46,
2002, 1125-51.
Goffe, W. L., G. D. Ferrier, and J. Rogers. "Global
Optimization of Statistical Functions with Simulated Annealing."
Journal of Econometrics, 60, 1994, 65-100.
Goldstein, M., and M. S. Khan. "Income and price effects in
foreign trade," in Handbook of International Economics, Volume II,
edited by R. W. Jones and P. B.
Kenen. Amsterdam, Netherlands: North-Holland, 1985.
Grier, K., and A. Smallwood. "Uncertainty and Export
Performance: Evidence from 18 Countries." Working Paper, University
of Oklahoma, 2005.
Klaassen, F. "Why is it so Difficult to Find an Effect of
Exchange Rate Risk on Trade?" Journal of International Money and
Finance, 23, 2004, 817-39.
Koray, F, and W. Lastrapes. "Real Exchange Rate Volatility and
US Bilateral Trade: A VAR Approach." The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 71, 1989, 708-12.
Kroner, K. F., and W. D. Lastrapes. "The Impact of Exchange
Rate Volatility on International Trade: Reduced Form Estimates Using the
GARCH-inMean Model." Journal of International Money and Finance,
12, 1993, 298-318.
Lothian, J. R., and C. McCarthy. "Real Exchange Rate Behavior
under Fixed and Floating Exchange Rate Regimes." Working Paper,
Department of Economics, Fordham University, New York, 2000.
McKenzie, M. D. "The Impact of Exchange Rate Volatility on
International Trade Flows." Journal of Economic Surveys, 13, 1999,
71-106.
Merton, R. C. "On Estimating the Expected Return on the
Market: An Exploratory Investigation." Journal of Financial
Economics, 8, 1980, 323-61.
Rose, A. K. "One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of
Common Currencies on Trade." Economic Policy, 20, 2000, 745.
Thorn, R., and B. Walsh. "The Effect of a Common Currency on
Trade: Ireland before and after the Sterling Link." European
Economic Review 46, 2002, 1111-23.
Thursby, J., and M. Thursby. "Bilateral Trade Flows, the
Linder Hypothesis, and Exchange Risk." The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 69, 1987, 488-95.
Viaene, J.-M., and C. G. de Vries. "International Trade and
Exchange Rate Volatility." European Economic Review, 36, 1992,
1311-21.
Wei, S. J. "Currency Hedging and Goods Trade." European
Economies Review, 43, 1999, 1371-94.
(1.) Ireland's status as an SOE is clearly evident and
especially its reliance on non-Euro trade of over 60% of total trade
dominated by its activities with the United Kingdom and United States.
In contrast, other economies in the European Union (EU) are not nearly
as reliant on non-Euro-dominated trade.
(2.) Exports only are analyzed as they represent a much higher
proportion of our trade with the United Kingdom and United States
relative to imports and also are open to differing degrees of
volatility.
(3.) The Irish pound was established in the late 1920s and
maintained a one-for-one link with UK sterling until 1979 when Ireland
joined the EMS. During the 1970s, the UK inflation rate was both high
and extremely volatile and the potential to link to the more stable core
EU economies was the main motivation for joining the EMS. The Irish
pound was replaced by the Euro in 1999.
(4.) See McKenzie (1999) for a review.
(5.) Relative prices [p.sup.*.sub.xt] are defined as
log([P.sub.xt]/[P.sup.*.sub.t]), where [P.sub.xt] and [P.sup.*.sub.t]
are domestic and foreign price levels, respectively.
(6.) Studies concentrate on examining the movements in real
exchange rate levels and overlook the impact of the second moment.
(7.) The Irish export sector is dualistic in makeup, with
relatively smaller indigenous firms dominating the more low-technology
production sectors, while larger subsidiaries of foreign-owned
multinationals tend to dominate the more high-technology sectors.
(8.) This practice has surprisingly continued even since the entry
of Ireland to the Euro zone and may influence our findings. For
instance, 68% of Irish exports to the United Kingdom are invoiced in UK
sterling, while 75% of Irish exports to the United States are invoiced
in U.S. dollars (Cotter, 2005).
(9.) A detailed discussion of l follows below.
(10.) A further motivation for including the interaction term is to
take account of possible omitted variable bias. See Baum, Caglayan, and
Ozkan (2004) for a discussion.
(11.) We adopt an AR model to forecast the exchange rate. This
approach is consistent with previous studies in the literature, for
example, Klaassen (2004).
(12.) See Klaassen (2004) for a detailed discussion of the problems
associated with geometric and polynomial lags in the current setting.
(13.) An important advantage of the simulated annealing
optimization routine is that it escapes from local maxima and local
minima and can maximize or minimize functions that are difficult to
optimize. We use the GAUSS code by E.G. Tsionas to run the procedure.
(14.) Given that foreign exchange markets are characterized by
periods of tranquility and turbulence, there is persistence in the
forecast errors. The ARCH model is able to take account of the
international exporters' perception of foreign exchange risk today
by factoring in their perception of risk in earlier periods and the
time-varying nature of asset (foreign exchange) returns.
(15.) All remaining data are from Datastream.
(16.) Given that the exchange rate is available at daily
frequencies and the domestic and foreign prices are only available at
monthly frequencies, we linearly interpolate the price series within the
month. See Baum, Caglayan, and Ozkan (2004) where a similar approach is
adopted.
(17.) McKenzie (1999) highlights that the distinction between real
and nominal exchange rate volatility does not significantly affect the
results.
(18.) Since then, the currencies have been part of separate
currency arrangements such as the Euro and the EMS with the exception of
the period between October 1990 and September 1992 where the United
Kingdom joined the EMS and subsequently departed around its currency
crises.
(19.) The volatility measures use the most common specifications
with an APARCH(1, 1) and n = 1 for squared and absolute realizations.
The lack of dependence of the squared standardized residuals from
fitting the APARCH model supports the specification. Only a subset of
the time series, shape, persistence, and scatter plots is presented for
conciseness outlining the respective volatility measures'
statistical properties and their relationships with each other. The
inferences of diverging volatility measures hold across foreign exchange
volatility, income volatility, and the interaction term. The full set of
plots is available on request.
(20.) The estimated models were adjusted for the exchange rate
crisis in 1992/1993 and the regime switch to the Euro in 1999. The dummy for the exchange rate crisis was not statistically significant for
either exports to the United Kingdom or United States. The dummy for the
change over to the Euro (taking value I from January 1999 to the end of
the sample and 0 elsewhere) was statistically significant in the case of
exports to the United Kingdom only, with a mean value of 0.29. A
tentative interpretation is that the single currency has had a positive
effect on Irish exports to the United Kingdom. The significance of this
dummy may also be taking account of the ending of the fraudulent
activity of "carousel trade" with the United Kingdom in goods
such as electrical parts and machinery. Although there was no effect on
the net Irish trade statistics, there was a significant fall in Irish
exports and imports to and from the United Kingdom; see Central Bank of
Ireland (2004).
(21.) Consistent with previous studies, we find that Irish exports
are cointegrated with real foreign income and real exchange rates.
Results are available on request. exchange, real foreign exchange
volatility, real foreign income volatility, and the interaction term.
Our unrestricted approach is taken to fully capture the exposure of
exports from an SOE for foreign exchange and income volatility.
(22.) The results here could also reflect the distinct nature of
the structure of exports to the United States and the United Kingdom. In
particular, exports to the United States are dominated by information
computer and technology and medical devices, while the UK figures are
heavily influenced by the food and drink sector.
(23.) The full set of results is not reported for space
considerations but is available from the author upon request. The
squared measure of volatility is adopted for the specific set of
results.
(24.) We also run the Hausman test which has a null hypothesis that
each regressor is exogenous. This test is run for all specifications
although for space considerations, we only report the results for the
squared measure of volatility. We thank an anonymous referee for this
suggestion.
DON BREDIN and JOHN COTTER *
* The authors would like to thank Chris Baum, Mark Cassidy, Gunter
Edenharter, Liam Gallagher, Franc Klaassens, Michael McKenzie, Gerard
O'Reilly, Maurice Roche, and participants at the 2004 Irish
Economics Association Conference in Belfast and a University College
Dublin seminar for helpful discussions. We would also like to thank
three anonymous referees for many helpful comments. Any errors are our
own responsibility.
Bredin: Senior Lecturer in Finance, Centre for Financial Markets,
Graduate School of Business, University College Dublin, Blackrock,
Ireland. Phone +00 353 1 716 8833, Fax +00 353 1 283 5482, E-mail don.
bredin@ucd.ie
Cotter: Associate Professor in Finance, Centre for Financial
Markets, Graduate School of Business, University College Dublin,
Blackrock, Ireland. Phone +00 353 1 716 8900, Fax +00 353 1 283 5482,
E-mail: john.cotter@ucd.ie
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics of Foreign Exchange
Volatility
Squared Absolute APARCH Range
U.S. dollar
Mean 2.56 2.43 5.03 1.81
SD 0.35 0.18 0.70 0.52
Skewness -0.03 -0.26 0.36 1.41
Kurtosis 0.09 0.16 -0.06 4.89
Normality 0.97 0.22 0.06 0.00
UK sterling
Mean 1.78 1.96 3.22 3.06
SD 0.40 0.31 0.36 0.55
Skewness -0.22 -0.48 0.15 1.07
Kurtosis -0.25 -0.46 -0.39 1.98
Normality 0.25 0.00 0.24 0.00
Notes: The volatility estimates are defined in the text.
The figures for normality refer to p values for the
Bera-Jarque test. SD, standard deviation.
TABLE 2
Summary Statistics of Income Volatility
Moving
Squared Absolute APARCH Window
U.S. income
Mean 0.43 0.52 0.54 0.59
SD 0.18 0.11 0.16 0.22
Skewness 3.35 1.25 1.85 0.99
Kurtosis 14.25 2.53 4.25 1.06
Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
UK income
Mean 1.22 0.80 0.82 0.97
SD 0.33 0.15 0.25 0.46
Skewness 4.99 1.54 0.20 1.07
Kurtosis 34.67 3.95 -0.85 1.31
Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Notes: The volatility estimates are defined in the text.
The figures for normality refer to p values for the
Bera-Jarque test. SD, standard deviation.
TABLE 3
Summary Statistics of the Interaction Term
(APARCH)
Moving
Squared Absolute APARCH Window
United States
Mean 2.13 2.59 2.71 2.91
SD 0.90 0.61 0.89 1.08
Skewness 3.43 1.14 1.87 1.33
Kurtosis 16.04 2.67 5.02 2.47
Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
United Kingdom
Mean 3.92 2.57 2.63 3.13
SD 1.14 0.57 0.93 1.54
Skewness 3.44 1.00 0.51 0.90
Kurtosis 19.06 1.23 -0.44 0.49
Normality 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Notes: The volatility estimates are defined in the text.
The figures for normality refer top values for the Bera-Jarque
test. The interaction estimates here are a combination involving
APARCH foreign exchange volatility with the respective
income volatility measures. SD, standard deviation.
TABLE 4
Summary Statistics of the Poisson Lag Structure
[y.sup.*.sub.t] [s.sup.r.sub.t] [[sigma].sub.s,t]
United States
Mean 5.29 0.39 11.58
SE 0.71 0.06 1.27
95% CI 3.77-6.81 0.27-0.51 8.87-14.28
Median 4.60 0.42 11.49
SD 2.85 0.22 5.08
Range 9.84 0.65 17.87
Min 1.06 0.00 2.50
Max 10.90 0.65 20.37
United Kingdom
Mean 11.30 1.34 15.63
SE 0.28 0.16 1.65
95% CI 10.69-11.91 0.97-1.70 12.01-19.26
Median 11.68 1.11 12.75
SD 0.95 0.57 5.70
Range 3.16 1.88 16.08
Min 8.89 0.62 10.00
Max 12.05 2.50 26.08
[[sigma].sub.y,t] [[sigma].sub.s x y,t]
United States
Mean 11.66 12.72
SE 2.94 2.68
95% C1 5.39-17.93 17.00-18.43
Median 6.79 9.20
SD 11.77 10.72
Range 29.99 27.31
Min 0.01 0.86
Max 30.00 28.17
United Kingdom
Mean 22.53 20.95
SE 2.31 2.19
95% Cl 17.44-27.61 16.13-25.77
Median 24.37 24.22
SD 8.00 7.59
Range 29.13 27.92
Min 0.87 0.60
Max 30.00 28.52
Notes. [y.sup.*.sub.t] refers to real income, [s.sup.r.sub.t] is real
foreign exchange rate, [[sigma].sub.s,t] is real foreign exchange
volatility, [[sigma].sub.y,t] is real income volatility, and
[[sigma].sub.s x y,t] is the interaction term. Summary statistics of
the lag structure of the 16 models include the mean and median lags,
the minimum and maximum lags, and measures of dispersion of the lags
with standard deviation and range. CI, confidence interval; SE,
standard error.
TABLE 5
Summary Statistics of the Estimates of the Model
[[sigma].
[y.sup.*.sub.t] [s.sup.r.sub.t] sub.s,t]
United States (a)
Mean 5.15 -0.87 0.29
SE 0.05 0.04 0.05
95% CI 5.06-5.28 -1.02-0.94 0.18-0.40
Median 5.13 -0.93 0.26
SD 0.21 0.14 0.21
Range 0.68 0.47 0.57
Minimum 4.88 -1.07 0.05
Maximum 5.57 -0.60 0.62
Coefficient 5.14 -0.94 0.32
SE 0.07 0.05 0.04
Exogeneity test 0.62 0.54 0.31
United Kingdom (b)
Mean 2.72 -1.07 0.17
SE 0.11 0.04 0.02
95% CI 2.49-2.96 -1.15-0.98 0.12-0.22
Median 2.54 -1.10 0.15
SD 0.37 0.14 0.08
Range 1.19 0.48 0.24
Minimum 2.25 -1.35 0.10
Maximum 3.44 -0.87 0.34
Coefficient 3.11 -1.14 0.11
SE 0.21 0.13 0.05
Exogeneity test 0.51 0.49 0.19
[[sigma].sub.y,t] [[sigma].sub.sxy,t]
United States (a)
Mean -0.45 0.31
SE 0.27 0.12
95% CI -1.04-0.13 0.05-0.58
Median -0.74 0.30
SD 1.09 0.50
Range 4.43 2.16
Minimum -2.43 -1.17
Maximum 2.00 0.99
Coefficient -0.85 0.46
SE 0.30 0.10
Exogeneity test 0.20 0.28
United Kingdom (b)
Mean -0.81 -0.01
SE 0.13 0.05
95% CI -1.10-0.52 -0.10-0.09
Median -0.99 0.04
SD 0.46 0.16
Range 1.39 0.46
Minimum -1.26 -0.27
Maximum 0.12 0.20
Coefficient -1.07 0.06
SE 0.22 0.05
Exogeneity test 0.21 0.19
Notes: [y.sup.*.sub.t] refers to real income, [s.sup.r.sub.t] is real
foreign exchange rate, [[sigma].sub.s,t] is real foreign exchange
volatility, [[sigma].sub.y,t] is real income volatility, and
[[sigma].sub.sxy,t] is the interaction term. Summary statistics of the
lag structure of the 16 models include the mean and median lags, the
minimum and maximum lags, and measures of dispersion of the lags with
standard deviation and range. The specific set of results adopt the
squared approach for both foreign exchange and foreign income
volatility. The final statistic is the Hausman exogeneity test
statistic where the null hypothesis of exogeneity cannot be rejected
in all cases. CI, confidence interval; SD, standard deviation; SE,
standard error.
(a) [R.sup.2] = .97, SE = 0.16.
(b) [R.sup.2] = .92, SE = 0.16.