Structural change, competitive balance, and the rest of the major leagues.
Fort, Rodney ; Lee, Young Hoon
I. INTRODUCTION
Competitive balance is the object of significant attention in the
analysis of pro sports leagues. Under Rottenberg's (1956)
uncertainty of outcome hypothesis, enough imbalance may actually drive
down the demand for pro sports and league revenues with it. But the
analysis of competitive balance, itself, also is insightful for the
impact of league self-regulation choices. In this paper, we extend
recent approaches in time series analysis found in Schmidt (2001),
Schmidt and Berri (2001a, 2001b, 2003, 2004), Lee and Fort (2005,
henceforth LF), and Fort and Lee (2006) beyond its exclusive focus on
Major League Baseball (MLB) to the National Basketball Association
(NBA), the National Football League (NFL), and the National Hockey
League (NHL). We restrict ourselves only to North American leagues
(henceforth, NALs), although Davies, Downward, and Jackson (1995),
Simmons (1996), and Dobson and Goddard (1998) provide interesting time
series analysis in world leagues as well. These works add dramatically
to the understanding of structural impacts found from ad hoc cross-section approaches (the review is in LF).
In NALs, a number of structural changes have been hypothesized to
dramatically alter competitive balance among teams over time. First,
there are the familiar macro occurrences of depression and war and
exogenous league factors like the fundamental alteration in local
revenue brought on by increases in the value of local TV broadcast
rights beginning in the late 1970s. Second, there are more direct league
circumstances--changes in the rules of the games, the draft, the end of
the reserve clause, changes in the number of teams (merger and
expansion) and their locations, salary caps, and labor issues. LF also
examined the impact of racial integration on competitive balance. But
for the rest of the NALs, there is no clearly defined point marking
their racial integration. Finally, Schmidt and Berri (2003) and Eschker,
Perez, and Siegler (2004) have begun to investigate the impacts of the
influx of foreign-born players.
We apply break point detection techniques, described at length in
LF, to within-season competitive balance measures in the rest of the
NALs. There are a number of interesting insights. All breaks detected
for these other NALs occur after 1966 (and not until 1970 in the NBA).
Rule changes in the NFL in the late 1970s correspond with a break point
in that league but, generally, rule changes do not correspond to any
break points. The imposition in NALs of the draft and free agency
conform to Rottenberg's invariance proposition (IP) except for a
general negative trend in competitive balance in the NBA. When they do
correspond with break points, league expansion and team relocation have
predictable impacts but some of these alterations do not have
corresponding break points. Mergers in all three of the other NALs
correspond in interesting ways with break points that enhance
competitive balance. But not all mergers correspond with break points.
There is no correspondence between the break points and the imposition
of the salary caps in the NBA and the NFL. Finally, we can find no
correspondence between break points and any labor issues in any of these
leagues except for enhanced balance that followed after the 1998 NBA
lockout. Explanations for the negative trend in NBA are consistent with
the idea that there is a "short supply of tall people," that
is, a truly physical limit on talent inputs in the NBA, originally
proposed by Berri et al. (2005). And an explanation for the second break
point in the NHL may have to do with the influx of European players.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section II, we specify the
empirical approach and handle the important details of stationary series
and detrending. The results are shown and discussed within the context
of the limits of the break point technique in Section III. Conclusions
round out the paper in Section IV.
II. EMPIRICAL APPROACH
Our approach is identical to that of LF, and we adopt their
reference to the "BP approach" developed by Bai and Perron (1998, 2003). Briefly, first we test for unit root in the competitive
balance time series. If the competitive balance time series we use were
nonstationary, the results of break point analysis assuming stationary
series would be misleading. Then, we investigate trend behavior in the
break points in the data using the BP approach. Interpretation of the
break points in the historical context of the NALs follows in the next
section.
We use two measures of competitive balance. Both are within-season
measures for reasons explained shortly. Humphreys (2002) provides a
comparison of many measures for many purposes, including the Gini
coefficient and Herfindahl index as within-season alternatives to our
choices below. But Utt and Fort (2002) show how the Gini coefficient is
problematic for within-season balance. The Herfindahl index is
unsuitable since two equally balanced leagues with different numbers of
teams will generate different results. Further, no single team can
"monopolize" within-season winning completely, requiring a
subjective specification of just what a completely unbalanced league
would look like from the Herfindahl index perspective.
Our first measure is the ratio of standard deviations measure
(henceforth, RSD) popularized by Noll (1988) and Scully (1989). The
numerator is the actual standard deviation of winning percents in a
league, and the denominator of RSD is the standard deviation of a
theoretically equally balanced league (derived by imposing that the
probability any team beats any other team equals 0.5). A completely
balanced league would have RSD = 1, and competitive balance worsens as
RSD increases.
Our second measure is related to the excess tail percentages of the
distribution of winning percents. While Fort and Quirk (1995) used a
version of this approach, the actual measurement used here first
appeared in Lee (2004) and was also used by LF. It represents the
logarithm of the sum of the likelihoods that winning percents of the top
and bottom 20% of teams occur in the "idealized" normal
distribution. We refer to this as the log of the tail likelihood
measurement (LTL). We take the logarithm because a small change in the
tail area under the normal distribution can cause a large change in
probability density especially in the range of critical values typically
used for tests of significance. Competitive balance is positively
related to LTL.
The data are not transformed in any way, and there are no controls
imposed in the analysis for any kind of exogenous effect. We let the BP
approach find these as it can. RSD and LTL were calculated directly from
win/ loss records, season length, and the number of teams in the league
in any given season. We limit our analysis to within-season balance only
because this paper is long enough as it is. We are certain that a break
point analysis of championship balance would be just as interesting. The
periods of analysis conform to generally accepted starting dates for the
other NALs: 1946-2003 for the NBA, 1922-2003 for the NFL, and 1918-2003
for the NHL.
On the nonstationary time series issue, the results of augmented
Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron tests are given in Table 1. They are
test statistics for a unit root in the regressions with a constant and
with a constant and time trend. Other than the augmented Dickey-Fuller
test on LTL for the NFL with a constant, all cases support rejection of
the unit root hypothesis for both RSD and LTL. We proceed taking the RSD
and LTL series to be stationary.
For break point estimation, we next examine trends in the RSD and
LTL data. There is ample reason to suspect a trend that enhances balance
over our lengthy sample periods for NALs. One reason would be the
appearance of more, and more geographically dispersed, population
centers. As population and willingness to pay became more equally
distributed among the major cities hosting teams, competitive balance
would increase. Another explanation would be the diffusion of games on
TV. Most of the country does not have a "home team" in any of
the NALs. But TV would allow many to support teams (financially through
ad revenues) that are not really even that close to them. Finally, over
time, the games have become more racially and ethnically diverse.
Especially in the NBA and NHL, the games have taken on an international
flavor; many stars in these leagues are from all over the world. Schmidt
and Berri (2003) suggest that the globalization of the talent search
would have general impacts on competitive balance.
To examine trends, we compare two models. In the model with trends
(MWT), we apply the BP approach using a partial structural change model.
The MWT has a constant term and time trend variable, and it is assumed
that the coefficient of trend is constant while the constant term is
allowed to change. More formally, the MWT is as follows:
(1) [y.sub.t] = [alpha][x'.sub.t] +
[[beta].sub.j][z'.sub.t] + [u.sub.t], t = [T.sub.j-1] + 1, ...,
[T.sub.j], j = 1, ..., m + 1,
where [y.sub.t] is the dependent variable at time t; [x.sub.t] (p x
1) and [z.sub.t] (q x 1) are vectors of covariates and a and
[[beta].sub.j] (j = 1, ..., m + 1) are the corresponding vectors of
coefficients; and [u.sub.t] is the disturbance at time t. The indices
([T.sub.1], ..., [T.sub.m]), or the break points, are treated as
unknown. This MWT version of the BP approach is a partial structural
change model since the parameter vector a is not subject to change. When
p = 0 (for the [x.sub.t] vector), this model is a pure structural change
model where all the coefficients are subject to change. The results from
the MWT are compared to the results from a model absent trends (MAT). In
the MAT, we use a pure structural break model with only a constant as
regressor. More formally, the MAT is as follows:
(2) [y.sub.t] = [[beta].sub.j][z'.sub.t] + [u.sub.t], t =
[T.sub.j - 1] + 1, ..., [T.sub.j], j = 1, ..., m + 1.
In choosing between the MWT and MAT, we employ a simple criterion.
If the MWT provides larger adjusted [R.sub.2] than the MAT, we choose
the MWT. If the opposite happens, or the two provide similar adjusted
[R.sup.2], then we choose the simpler MAT. In regressions results
available upon request, we found that our criterion led to applying the
MWT in Equation (1) to the NBA but the MAT in Equation (2) to the NFL
and NHL. That is, the NBA has an underlying trend in competitive balance
but the NFL and NHL do not.
We are aware that the MWT and MAT used here are sparse
specifications of the determinants of league competitive balance.
According to the theory of sports leagues, competitive balance is
determined by geographical variation in potential profit. Owners choose
quality in the long run to maximize profits, and owners in geographic
markets with higher profit potential will have higher quality.
Unfortunately, there is only very limited and recent financial data for
any NAL, and little of it directly concerns profits. More than just
population matters since revenues are determined by both prices and
quantities in demand functions. And demand information even at the
league level is sketchy except for the most recent years. But so it
goes; we recognize this limitation and forge ahead.
Next, we move on to statistical inferences about the number of
break points and their qualitative impacts for our two competitive
balance measures. If a break point is at time t, then the subsequent
period after the break begins at time t + 1. Turning first to the NBA
(Table 2), the estimated time trend coefficient is positive for RSD and
negative for LTL. Both of these results are consistent with a worsening
underlying trend in competitive balance. This is an important
contribution since the simpler tracking of competitive balance measures
over time, for example, Quirk and Fort (1992) imparts clear inference
only in a limited way. Here, it is statistically detected. The break
points identified are the same using either RSD or LTL, the first in
1972 (confidence interval 1970-1976) and the second in 1997 (confidence
interval 1995-1999). The estimates of the coefficients are consistent
with improvements in competitive balance after the break point
([[beta].sub.1] > [[beta].sub.2] > [[beta].sub.3] for RSD and
[[beta].sub.1] < [[beta].sub.2] < [[beta].sub.3] for LTL). Figure
1, depicting the actual and fitted RSD and LTL series with break points,
helps to demonstrate both the negative trend and the impacts of the
break points.
Turning to the NFL (Table 3), recall that there is no time trend
included. The BP approach identifies a break point at 1969 (confidence
interval 1967-1974) using LTL. Using RSD, a break point is identified at
1976, while LTL yields a break at 1977. In what follows, we take this to
be a break point "around 1976-1977" and combine their
confidence intervals (1973-1980). Just like in the NBA, both of the
break points are associated with improvements in competitive balance
([[beta].sub.1] > [[beta].sub.2] for RSD and [[beta].sub.1] <
[[beta].sub.2] < [[beta].sub.3] for LTL). Since there is no trend,
all of the improvements in NFL competitive balance appear to have
occurred due to regime changes detected by the BP approach. The actual
and fitted competitive balance measures for the NFL are illustrated in
Figure 2.
Finally, for the NHL (Table 4), one break at 1969 is identified
using RSD (confidence interval 1966-1975). There also are temporally
close breaks that we will combine at "around 1984-1986" (the
former found using LTL and the latter using RSD). As before, we will
combine the confidence interval for the latter break (1982-1989) in what
follows. The first break point for the NHL is the only one in all three
leagues where the impact on competitive balance is negative
([[beta].sub.1] < [[beta].sub.2] for RSD); the latter NHL break point
is associated with improved balance ([[beta].sub.2] > [[beta].sub.3]
for RSD and [[beta].sub.1] < [[beta].sub.2] for LTL). Since there is
no trend, all the changes in NHL competitive balance appear to have
occurred due to regime changes detected by the BP approach. Figure 3
depicts the actual and fitted behavior of our two competitive balance
measures. In what follows, we take advantage of the information in the
confidence intervals to frame our discussion about break points in
competitive balance and the history of economically interesting
occurrences in these other NALs.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
III. BREAK POINTS AND THE HISTORY OF THE NALS
The confidence intervals for the break points in the three NALs are
summarized in Table 5. LF made some headway analyzing break point
intervals in MLB with macroeconomic occurrences like the Great
Depression and world wars and with the integration of MLB in 1947. But
nothing about the timing of the break points for the other NALs
corresponds with any macro changes. And, unlike MLB, there was no clear,
defining historical point of racial integration in any of these NALs.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
More generally, and in stark contrast to the LF findings that no
break occurred in MLB after 1962, there are no detected break points in
any of the other three NALs prior to 1966 (using the earliest years of
the confidence intervals). All of the break point action was earlier on
in MLB and later on in the rest of the NALs.
The remaining exogenous occurrence is the explosion in local TV
revenues in the late 1970s with the advent and diffusion of cable TV. In
addition, there are direct league issues--rule changes, the draft, free
agency, the number of teams (expansion and merger) and their location,
the imposition of salary caps, and labor issues. Unlike MLB, the N BA
witnessed the influx of primarily European and South American players,
and the NHL also witnessed the influx of European players. Let us
examine the break points relative to these occurrences and the histories
of the NALs, league by league.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In the NBA, we find the following for the first break point:
* The upper end of the confidence interval for the first break,
1976, could correspond to the beginning of the TV rights explosion. We
expect this explosion to reduce competitive balance since local TV
revenues will be higher in larger revenue markets.
* Within the confidence interval of the first break point
(1971-1976), only the 1975-1976 season was stable in terms of the number
and location of teams!
Expansion: 1970-1971 (Buffalo, Cleveland, and Portland) and
1974-1975 (New Orleans Jazz). Expansion should reduce competitive
balance as weak teams enter.
Moves: 1971-1972 (San Francisco to Oakland and San Diego to
Houston); 1972-1973 (Cincinnati to Kansas City); and 1973-1974
(Baltimore to Washington DC). Moves should enhance balance since teams
will only move to become economically more competitive (unless it is
just to capture increased subsidies through a better lease or new
arena).
Merger: With the American Basketball Association for the 1976-1977
season (adds Denver, Indiana, New York, and San Antonio). Merger should
enhance balance, since economically competitive teams join the dominant
league.
* In terms of labor issues, the 1973 collective bargaining
agreement (CBA) puts arbitration in place. But this should have no
impact on balance since arbitration just transfers a larger portion of
players' marginal revenue product from owners to players.
We offer the following interpretation of these occurrences in light
of the fact that the first break point shows an improvement in
competitive balance. Even though the TV rights explosion is expected to
reduce balance, the change in the number of teams (expansion to smaller
revenue markets) and their locations (team moves to larger revenue
markets) is more than offset, so there was a net improvement in
competitive balance. It seems plausible that the expansion and moves
were just a wash (since they involved the same number of teams) so that
the merger may have been the determining factor.
For the second NBA break point we find the following:
* The expansion of 1995-1996 (Toronto and Vancouver, Canada).
Again, standing alone, expansion is expected to decrease balance.
* In the 1999 CBA, following the 1998 lockout that cost fans part
of the 1998-1999 season, a relatively weak cap was shored up
substantially, including an escrow account to reimburse owners out of
player salaries if the cap were violated by a set amount. If this
"harder" cap was enforced, it should enhance competitive
balance.
* The influx of international players. As Schmidt and Berri (2003)
suggest, widening the labor pool should enhance balance.
Now, the second NBA break point also corresponds with increased
competitive balance. So, it must have been the case that the gains under
the 1999 CBA, and the influx of international players, offset the
negative expansion impacts. This is especially interesting since
Vancouver moved to Memphis a bit after this break point, indicating that
the 1995-1996 expansion involved weak teams, indeed.
The following other interesting historical aspects of the NBA
correspond to neither of the break points but these
"nonresults" actually are packed with important economic
content. For example, rule changes are often touted as balancing some
aspect of play in order to raise fan excitement. This may have happened
with NBA rule changes, but it did not happen in such a way that there
was a significant structural impact on the balance of play on the court.
And it did not happen in such a way that a dent was put in the
underlying negative trend in competitive balance.
The absence of detectable impacts for the draft (in place at the
leagues' inception in 1946) and free agency (in its true modern
form in 1988 when all players were unrestricted free agents after 4 yr
in the league with some remaining right of first refusal) is completely
consistent with Rottenberg's (1956) IP. But there still remains the
underlying negative trend, so that one could say that there is some
evidence counter to the IP in the case of both the draft and the free
agency. Typically, in such a case, Daly and Moore (1981) and Daly (1992)
argue that the transactions cost approach becomes important in the
explanation. But the fact that the trend was negative offers a challenge
for that analysis as well. Another possibility raised by Berri et al.
(2005) is that there is a short supply of tall people. The number of
teams grows over time, but the number of truly tall people does not keep
pace. As taller people become more valuable, they migrate to larger
revenue market teams, and less competitive balance is the result. One of
the reviewers of this paper suggested an additional avenue for
investigating the short supply of tall people. The average height of
players could be included in a given year in the regression. If this is
indeed going down and contributes to the negative trend in competitive
balance in the NBA, then this would be supporting evidence for the
hypothesis of Berri et al. We know of no consistent source of height
data across all NALs, but future work on this topic may find consistent
height data within subsamples of the data suggested by the break point
analysis here.
For the subsequent moves of Vancouver to Memphis and then Charlotte
to New Orleans, it could just be that the period after the 1997 break
point is pretty short. But the lack of other detected impacts, short of
the general negative trend in balance, makes expansion all the more
interesting for future work (LF also found a few quirks in the typical
expansion and team move explanations for MLB).
Finally, that the cap (in place for the 1984-1985 season)
corresponds with no shift impact on competitive balance comes as no
surprise at all. In a more "micro" analysis, Fort and Quirk
(1995) showed that the cap did not alter competitive balance, and it is
now well known that the original NBA cap was very "soft"
indeed. This time series result just reinforces that finding. But there
is an additional element to consider--the underlying negative trend
could simply be overriding any gains that may have come from the
imposition of the cap.
Turning to the NFL, the following occurrences coincide with the
first break point:
* The timing of the TV rights explosion. In the NFL, we have a
different expectation than in the NBA. Since all TV revenues are shared
equally, there should be no competitive balance impact from this
explosion; it is a lump-sum increase equal for all teams.
* Substantial rule changes. Inside the confidence interval of the
first NFL break point, sudden death was added, the goal posts were moved
back, kickoffs were moved back, missed kicks outside the 20 were taken
back to the line of scrimmage, downfield contact was increasingly
restricted, and the holding penalty was reduced from 15 to 10 yards. And
just after the break point, the season was increased to 16 games, the
second wildcard was added, and the "in-the-grasp" quarterback
rule was put in place. All of these were expected to create more
offensive excitement, putting weaker defensive teams in the running.
This should enhance balance.
* Within the confidence interval of this break point, the number
and location of teams change as follows:
Expansion: New Orleans in 1967 (should reduce competitive balance).
Moves: Boston adopted a regional fan base by changing its name to
New England in 1971 (should enhance balance).
Merger: The NFL had its famous merger with the American Football
League (version IV) in 1969, bringing the league to 26 teams for the
1970 season (adding Boston, Buffalo, Cincinnati, Denver, Houston, Kansas
City, Miami, New York, Oakland, and San Diego). This should enhance
balance since these were the strongest teams in the American Football
League.
* The National Football League Players Association was officially
recognized in 1968. We have no theoretical or intuitive expectation
about the impact of unionization on competitive balance.
So, how does all this shake out given that the BP approach detected
an increase in competitive balance for this break point? Rule changes
should enhance balance, so the only real issue is in sorting out the net
effect of the change in the number and location of teams. As with the
NBA, it is sensible that the expansion and move impacts were not very
large and could easily have been a wash, leaving the bulk of the net to
come from the merger with its balance-enhancing impact. But there also
could have been a role for the official certification of the union, one
way or the other.
For the second break point, we discover the following:
* Expansion in 1976 (Seattle and Tampa Bay) (should decrease
balance).
* A 42-d training camp strike in 1974 (but no games were missed).
Since the second NFL break point also was balance enhancing, we are
left somewhat at a loss here. Free agency was not yet a reality, so
Seattle and Tampa Bay should have been, and were, weak entrants. Perhaps
the large proportion of revenue sharing did the trick, and expansions in
the NFL are different than in the NBA (or MLB, where LF found the
hypothesis useful). And perhaps the strike had more impact than commonly
thought. The strike concerned the Rozelle rule's (prohibitive
compensation to teams losing free agents) harmful effect on free agency,
and, since the players crossed their own picket lines, it is commonly
thought that the owners won. But perhaps this needs to be rethought. All
in all, the connections here do not seem as strong as they are for the
other NAL break point episodes.
As with the NBA, nonresults carry some insight. The cases of the
draft (in place at the leagues' inception in 1922), free agency (in
place in 1994), and the salary cap (in place 1993) are almost identical
to the NBA. The draft and free agency results are consistent with the IP
especially since, unlike the NBA case, there is no complicating trend in
the NFL. And for the original imposition of the cap, we are left to
suggest that the cap was soft and/or there were enforcement issues.
Finally, it really is not surprising that the other work stoppages (1982
and 1987) do not coincide with regime changes. They intruded on the
regular season but it is commonly understood that owners came out on
top, and it was business as usual alter the strikes. The first strike
was driven by player demands on a larger portion of league revenues and
a seniority wage scale. There were threats of a new league, and
independent all-star games were staged, but the players caved at the
end. The latter strike was over free agency, but it was driven by union
leader demands without any rank and file backing, and the players caved
quietly.
And so we come to the NHL. For the first break point:
* The upper end of the confidence interval for the first break
point (and the lower end of the confidence interval for the second break
point) is consistent with the explosion in local TV rights. And for the
NHL, where local TV is not shared at all, all else constant, this would
decrease competitive balance.
* The original NHL draft was in 1963, but omitted players sponsored
by NHL teams (a form of minor league relationship). But in 1969, the
draft was open to include all players and renamed the "entry"
draft to emphasize this point. The IP would have competitive balance
invariant with respect to this alteration in the draft.
* Within the confidence interval of this break point, the number
and location of teams change as follows: Expansion: 1967-1968 doubled
the league to 12 teams (adding Los Angeles, Minnesota, Oakland,
Philadelphia, Pittsburgh, and St. Louis); 1970-1971 (Buffalo and
Vancouver, Canada); 1972-1973 (Atlanta and New Jersey); and 1974-1975
(Kansas City and Washington DC) (should reduce competitive balance).
Moves: 1970-1971 (Oakland to "California") (should
enhance balance).
For this break point, the BP approach detected a decrease in
competitive balance (the only one of all the detected break points to be
negative). So, it seems reasonable to attribute the outcome to the
explosion in local TV and the four expansion episodes involving no fewer
than 12 teams! Pundits have often scolded the NHL for overexpanding. And
from the perspective of competitive balance, this extensive change in
the number and location of teams could easily swamp any sort of gains
from the draft extension (under a transactions cost interpretation).
For the second break point, we discover the following:
* Colorado moving to New Jersey after the 1981-1982 season
(enhances balance).
* The influx of European players (should enhance balance).
While this move is consistent with enhanced balance (teams only
move to become economically more competitive), it is doubtful that just
this single occurrence drove a break point all by itself. So, the bulk
of the impact appears to lie with the influx of European players as
hypothesized by Schmidt and Berri (2003).
And the following historical occurrences coincide with neither NHL
break point but do provide insight. First, our technique does not allow
us to comment on the rule change in place for the 1999-2000 season where
the losing team in overtime receives one point (and overtime is played
with four players, plus the goalie, rather than five plus the goalie).
Not enough time has passed since 1999 to the end of our sample in 2003
to fall within our trimming factors for the BP approach (the trimming
factor is longer than the remaining sample). According to Abrevaya
(2004), there has been a reduction in the number of overtime ties and
more aggressive offensive play during overtime as a result of the change
in the point system. But our technique is not informative on whether or
not this ushered in any "new era" of enhanced balance. Only
the passage of more time will tell.
As the last instance of a recurring theme, the nonresult for NHL
free agency (in place since 1992) is entirely consistent with the IP.
The lack of any break point corresponding to the 1979-1980 merger (with
the World Hockey Association, adding Edmonton, Hartford, Quebec, and
Winnipeg), however, stands in stark contrast to the effects of both the
NBA and the NFL mergers. While we discuss this only in comparison to
earlier LF findings for MLB later in the paper, this variation in
correspondence to break points across leagues suggests an interesting
area for further study.
Finally, as with the other NALs, it is not surprising that no
competitive balance shift accompanies the 1994 strike, even though it
lasted 103 d and cost 468 regular season games. It is commonly thought
that the owners came out on top. Players under age 25 had their salaries
scaled down and restrictions on growth for 5 yr, and eligibility for
arbitration and free agency also were more restrictive. And all these
are simply transfers of value away from players and over to owners.
In addition to the league-by-league insights, there are a few more
global observations if we look across leagues (and we go ahead and
include some of the LF findings on MLB). LF found no connection between
the explosion of local TV and the break points in MLB, but that
explosion coincides with break points in the NALs with local TV, the
NBA, and the NHL. Except in the NFL, rule changes do not coincide with
shifts in balance in any of the other NALs, including MLB. So, it is
safe to say that, typically, while rule changes may well make play more
exciting to fans, they do not engender more balanced play unless they
are quite far reaching like in the NFL case.
The draft and free agency adhere to Rottenberg's IP for all
NALs, including MLB (although the negative trend in the NBA complicates
this observation a bit). Neither NAL salary cap coincides with detected
break points, suggesting that they both were either soft at inception
and/or not well enforced.
Generally, labor issues were won by owners in the three NALs
studied in this paper, and, consequently, the only incident that
coincides with a break point is the owner victory that tightened the NBA
salary cap in 1999. Since there are no break points after 1962 in MLB,
the same is true there; work stoppages do not coincide with competitive
balance regime shifts. But since it is commonly accepted that players
won in each case, perhaps there is a more general statement: work
stoppages typically do not coincide with any sort of competitive balance
regime change in any of the NALs. Along with Schmidt and Berri (2004),
who found that work stoppages have only very short-term impacts on
attendance, this last result is consistent with the uncertainty of
outcome hypothesis; work stoppages do not alter competitive balance,
and, subsequently, attendance is unaffected in the longer term.
Finally, there appears to be a clear role played by the influx of
international players. A role was defined for the second break point in
the NBA. And it appears that the influx of European players was the
determining factor behind the improvement in balance associated with the
second break point in the NHL.
There are a few puzzles from our results. The first puzzle is the
second break point in the NFL (1976-1977, confidence interval
1973-1980). Second, why do some expansions, moves, and mergers
correspond to break points, but not others (especially the nonresult of
the NHL merger with the World Hockey Association)?
IV. CONCLUSIONS AND SUGGESTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH
We apply the BP approach to the rest of the leagues besides MLB. As
a statistical matter, we find that two measures of competitive balance
are stationary for all NALs (as LF also found for MLB). While LF found a
positive trend in balance in MLB, we find no trend in the NFL or NHL and
a negative trend in the NBA. Employing break point techniques, we find
no detectable structural change in within-season competitive balance
prior to 1966 in these three NALs. This is in stark juxtaposition to the
earlier findings for MLB where no break point occurred after 1962. So,
we hypothesize that in one league (MLB), factors like the equalization of population centers, game diffusion on TV, and internationalization of
the talent pool have been important in the determination of competitive
balance. But in two leagues these factors have not been important (NFL
and NHL). And in one league (NBA), where the trend is negative, an
additional explanation may involve the short supply of tall people,
suggested by Berri et al. (2005).
The break points that we do find typically coincide in believable ways with a host of economically interesting occurrences in pro sports
leagues. But there are some surprises and puzzles that suggest further
research. The first is the long "'modern" period without
any break points in MLB while there are break points galore in the other
NALs. Second, we would be grateful for additional insight into the
situations surrounding the most recent break point in the NFL. Third,
why do some expansions, moves, and mergers correspond to break points,
but not others (especially the nonresult of the NHL merger with the
World Hockey Association)?
Finally, our work begs a couple of extensions. The mechanisms used
by NALs to aid competitive balance, determined by leagues early on but
in recent years jointly determined by players and owners through
collective bargaining, may have reduced the level of imbalance enough
that our technique was unable to detect significant shifts alter the
mid-1960s in MLB and prior to the mid-1960s in the rest of the NALs.
Additional work aimed at discovering whether improved balance occurs in
spite of, or because of, the efforts of NALs to enhance competitive
balance is clearly suggested. Any type of analysis of level data along
these lines will be greatly facilitated by our findings that the time
series appears to be stationary.
There is also a chance to further investigate the behavior of
competitive balance around league mergers. "MLB" could be
redefined to mean the National League up to its business
"agreement" with the American league after the 1902 season and
then as the joint National League-American League entity (the entity
that eventually came to be known as MLB). We could then examine this
same important element of changing the number of teams in a league for
baseball. Unlike the other NALs, the teams in each of MLB's leagues
did not play each other over most of this history but clearly the talent
market was different prior to 1903. It would be interesting to see if
baseball is more like hockey where merger with a rival league does not
coincide with any competitive balance regime shift or more like
basketball and football in this regard.
Turning to competitive balance policy, our analysis offers the
following for those interested in the impact of within-season
uncertainty on fan demand. We inform this line of inquiry with our
findings that competitive balance has declined according to a general
trend in the NBA and that the second break point in the NHL was a shift
to less balance. Clearly, if Rottenberg's uncertainty of outcome
hypothesis holds, there are problems for leagues and others interested
in league policy to consider further.
We close with a note of caution. LF found an increasing trend in
balance over recent years in MLB, and we find that most recent shifts
have improved balance, in the other NALs. But this does not mean current
levels of competitive balance pose no problems for fans in these sports
and, consequently, the leagues that depend on them. If fans find even
improvements in the level of balance to be more detestable over time,
then competitive balance will be the focus of leagues and interested
policy makers. Our analysis does not address that issue. But it does
help to sort out arguments for policy intervention based on reductions
in within-season competitive balance. Such is clearly the case in the
NBA. Despite two shifts to enhanced balance, the underlying trend is
negative. The second shift in the NHL also was a decline. But in the
NFL, and the most recent history of the NHL, as with MLB in the earlier
analysis, such simply has not been the case. Despite a shift detrimental
to balance around 1969, the remaining shifts all have been to better
balance, and since there is no trend in these leagues, competitive
balance has plodded along as usual for at least 25 yr in the NFL and for
15 yr in the NHL. And a general trend increase in balance characterizes
MLB since 1962.
ABBREVIATIONS
BP: Bai and Perron (1998, 2003) Approach
CBA: Collective Bargaining Agreement
IP: Invariance Proposition
LF: Lee and Fort (2005)
LTL: Log of the Tail Likelihood Measurement
MAT: Model Absent Trends
MLB: Major League Baseball
MWT: Model With Trends
NALs: North American leagues
NBA: National Basketball Association
NFL: National Football League
NHL: National Hockey League
RSD: Ratio of Standard Deviations
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2007.00026.x
REFERENCES
Abrevaya, J. "Fit to Be Tied: The Incentive Effects of
Overtime Rules in Professional Hockey." Journal of Sports
Economics, 5, 2004, 292-306.
Bai, J., and P. Perron. "Estimating and Testing Lineal Models
with Multiple Structural Changes." Econometrica, 66, 1998, 47-78.
--. "Computation and Analysis of Multiple Structural Change
Models." Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18, 2003, 1-22.
Berri, D. J., S. L. Brook, B. Frick, A. J. Fenn, and R.
Vicente-Mayoral. "'The Short Supply of Tall People:
Competitive Imbalance and the National Basketball Association."
Journal of Economic Issues, 39, 2005, 1029-41.
Daly, G. G. "'The Baseball Player's Labor Market Revisited," in Diamonds are Forever: The Business of Baseball,
edited by P. M. Sommers. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1992,
11-28.
Daly, G., and W. J. Moore. "Externalities, Property Rights and
the Allocation of Resources in Major League Baseball." Economic
Inquiry, 19, 1981, 77-95.
Davies, B., P. Downward, and I. Jackson. "The Demand for Rugby
League: Evidence from Causality Tests." Applied Economics, 27,
1995, 1003-7.
Dobson, S. M., and J. A. Goddard. "Performance and Revenue in
Professional League Football: Evidence from Granger Causality Tests." Applied Economics, 30, 1998, 1641-51.
Eschker. E., S. J. Perez, and M. V. Siegler. "The NBA and the
Influx of International Basketball Players." Applied Economics, 36,
2004, 1009-20.
Fort, R., and Y. H. Lee. "Stationarity and Major League
Baseball Attendance Analysis." Journal of Sports Economics, 7,
2006, 408-15.
Fort, R., and J. Quirk. "Cross-Subsidization, Incentives, and
Outcomes in Professional Team Sports Leagues." Journal of Economic
Literature, 33, 1995, 1265-99.
Humphreys, B. R. "Alternative Measures of Competitive Balance
in Sports Leagues." Journal of Sports Economics, 3, 2002, 133-48.
Lee, Y. H. "Competitive Balance and Attendance in Japanese,
Korean and U.S. Professional Baseball Leagues," in International
Sports Economics Comparisons, edited by R. Fort and J. Fizel. Westport,
CT: Praeger Publishers, 2004, 281-92.
Lee, Y. H., and R. Fort. "Structural Change in Baseball's
Competitive Balance: The Great Depression, Team Location, and Racial
Integration." Economic Inquiry, 43, 2005, 158-69.
Newey, W., and K. West. "Automatic Lag Selection in Covariance
Matrix Estimation." Review of Economic Studies, 61, 1994, 631-53.
Noll, R. G. "Professional Basketball." Stanford
University Studies in Industrial Economics Paper No. 144, 1988.
Quirk, J., and R. D. Fort. Pay Dirt: The Business of Professional
Team Sports. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1992.
Rottenberg, S. "The Baseball Players' Labor Market."
Journal of Political Economy, 64, 1956, 242-58.
Schmidt, M. B. "Competition in Major League Baseball: The
Impact of Expansion." Applied Economic Letters, 8, 2001, 21-6.
Schmidt, M. B., and D. J. Berri. "Competitive Balance and
Attendance: The Case of Major League Baseball." Journal of Sports
Economics, 2, 2001a, 145-67.
--. "The Impact of the 1981 and 1994-1995 Strikes on Major
League Baseball Attendance: A Time-Series Analysis." Applied
Economics, 34, 2001b, 471-8.
--. "On the Evolution of Competitive Balance: The Impact of an
Increasing Global Search." Economic Inquiry, 41, 2003, 692-704.
--. "The Impact of Labor Strikes on Consumer Demand: An
Application to Professional Sports." American Economic Review, 94,
2004, 344-57.
Scully, G. W. The Business of Major League Baseball. Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago Press, 1989.
Simmons, R. "The Demand for English League Football: A
Club-Level Analysis." Applied Economics, 28, 1996, 139-55.
Utt, J., and R. Fort. "Pitfalls to Measuring Competitive
Balance with Gini Coefficients." Journal of Sports Economics, 3,
2002, 367-73.
RODNEY FORT and YOUNG HOON LEE *
* We wish to thank the referees for making this paper much better
than it would otherwise have been. Lee acknowledges that this research
was financially supported by Hansung University in the year 2007.
Fort: Professor of Economics, School of Economic Sciences,
Washington State University, Pullman, WA 99164-6210. Phone 509-335-1538,
Email fort@wsu.edu
Lee: Professor of Economics, Hansung University, Seoul, Korea.
Email yhnlee@hansung.ac.kr
TABLE 1
Augmented Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron Unit Root Tests
ADF (p) (a)
Constant Trend
NBA
RSD -4.109 * (1) -4.398 * (1)
LTL -4.589 * (1) -4.554 * (1)
NFL
RSD -3.748 * (1) -5.028 * (1)
LTL -2.180 (1) -4.430 * (1) *
NHL
RSD -3.478 ** (2) -3.643 ** (2)
LTL -3.472 ** (2) -3.745 ** (2)
PP (l) (b)
Constant Trend
NBA
RSD -3.874 * (3) -4.096 ** (3)
LTL -4.104 * (3) -4.096 ** (3)
NFL
RSD -4.925 * (3) -6.210 * (3)
LTL -2.847 *** (3) -5.497 * (3)
NHL
RSD -5.791 * (3) -5.867 * (3)
LTL -5.899 * (3) -6.536 * (3)
Notes: The number of pigs is determined by minimization
of the Schwartz-Bayesian criterion for the ADF test and by
the truncation suggested by Newey and West (1994) for the PP test.
(a) Augmented Dickey-Fuller test p = the number of lags.
(b) Phillips-Perron test; l = lag truncation.
* Significant at the 99%, critical level.
** Significant at the 95%, critical level.
*** Significant at the 90%, critical level.
TABLE 2
BP Approach Results for the NBA Using the MWT
in Equation (1): 1946-2003
Specifications (a)
[z.sub.t] = [x.sub.t] =
{1} {time}
Tests
Sup Sup
[F.sub.T](1) [F.sub.T](2)
RSD 5.64 5.86
LTL 14.75 * 18.07 *
Sup F(2/1) Sup F(3/2)
RSD 14.39 * 14.20 **
LTL 46.38 * 9.02
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Methods (b)
RSD 2
LTL 2
Estimates (c)
[[beta].sub.1] [[beta].sub.2]
RSD 1.950 * (13.00) 0.977 * (2.75)
LTL -1.489 * (-3.44) 2.522 * (2.46)
Specifications (a)
q = 1 p = 1
Sup Sup
[F.sub.T](3) [F.sub.T](4)
RSD 9.30 * 13.08 *
LTL 12.25 * 14.62 *
Sup F(4/3) Sup F(5/4)
RSD 28.52 * 7.56
LTL 5.22 20.62 *
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Methods (b)
RSD
LTL
Estimates (c)
[[beta].sub.3] [[alpha].sub.1]
RSD 0.219 (0.43) 0.043 * (4.99)
LTL 5.455 * (3.69) 1.146 * (-5.89)
Specifications (a)
[epsilon] h = 6 M = 5
= 0.1
Sup [UD.sub.max] [WD.sub.max]
[F.sub.T](5)
RSD 14.64 * 14.64 * 29.37 *
LTL 21.62 * 21.62 * 43.37 *
RSD
LTL
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Methods (b)
RSD
LTL
Estimates (c)
[T.sub.1] [T.sub.2] [[bar.R].sup.2]
([R.sup.2])
RSD 72 [70, 76] 97 [95. 99] 0.288 (0.326)
LTL 72 [70, 74] 97 [95. 98] 0.373 (0.406)
(a) [epsilon] a trimming parameter = h/T; h: a minimum length
of each regime; M: an upper bound.
(b) We use a 10%, significance level for the sequential test.
(c) t values are given in parentheses; 90% confidence intervals
for [T.sub.i] are given in square brackets.
* Significant at the 99% critical level.
** Significant at the 95% critical level.
*** Significant at the 90% critical level.
TABLE 3
BP Approach Results for the NFL Using the MAT
in Equation (2): 1922-2003
Specifications (a)
[z.sub.t] = {1} q = 1
Tests
Sup Sup
[F.sub.T](1) [F.sub.T](2)
RSD 50.39 * 29.81 *
LTL 135.60 * 104.47 *
Sup F(2/1) Sup F(3/2)
RSD 7.00 3.13
LTL 17.36 * 6.16
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Method (b)
RSD 1
LTL 2
Estimates (c)
[[beta].sub.1] [[beta].sub.2]
RSD 1.643 * (56.28) 1.312 * (31.52)
LTL -1.251 * (-15.84) -0.297 (-1.49)
Specifications (a)
p = 0 [epsilon] = 0.1
Sup Sup
[F.sub.T](3) [F.sub.T](4)
RSD -21.89 * 17.17 *
LTL 78.17 * 58.89 *
Tests
Sup F(413) Sup F(5/4)
RSD 1.67 2.20
LTL 6.97 1.84
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Method (b)
RSD
LTL
Estimates (c)
[[beta].sub.3] [T.sub.1]
RSD 76 [73. 80]
LTL 0.292 * (2.65) 69 [67, 74]
Specifications (a)
h = 8 M = 5
Sup [UD.sub.max] [WD.sub.max]
[F.sub.T](5)
RSD 16.40 * 54.39 * 54.39 *
LTL 47.41 * 135.60 * 135.60 *
RSD
LTL
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Method (b)
RSD
LTL
Estimates (c)
[T.sub.2] [[bar.R].sup.2]
([R.sup.2])
RSD 0.337 (0.345)
LTL 77 [74, 80] 0.613 (0.623)
(a) [epsilon] trimming parameter = h/T; h: a minimum length
of each regime; M: an upper bound.
(b) We use a l0% significance level for the sequential test.
(c) t values are in parentheses, 90% confidence intervals
for [T.sub.i] are in square brackets.
* Significant at the 99%, critical level.
** Significant at the 95%, critical level.
*** Significant at the 90%, critical level.
TABLE 4
BP Approach Results for the NHL Using the MAT
in Equation (2): 1918-2003
Specifications (a)
[z.sub.t] = {1} q = 1
Tests
Sup Sup
[F.sub.T](1) [F.sub.T](2)
RSD 10.63 ** 28.53 *
LTL 76.99 * 39.14 *
Sup F(2/1) Sup F(3/2)
RSD 21.78 * 5.45
LTL 3.21 5.67
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Method (b)
RSD 2
LTL 1
Estimates (c)
[[beta].sub.1] [[beta].sub.2]
RSD 1.868 * (32.86) 2.459 * (24.74)
LTL -2.437 * (-15.22) -0.508 (-1.69)
Specifications (a)
p = 0 [epsilon] = 0.1
Sup Sup
[F.sub.T](3) [F.sub.T](4)
RSD 21.11 * 16.80 *
LTL 27.74 * 22.30 *
Sup F(4/3) Sup F(5/4)
RSD 0.86 0.59
LTL 0.73 1.18
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Method (b)
RSD
LTL
[[beta].sub.3] [T.sub.1]
RSD 1.792 * (18.03) 69 [66. 75]
LTL 84 [82, 89]
Specifications (a)
h = 9 M = 5
Sup [UD.sub.max] [WD.sub.max]
[F.sub.T](5)
RSD 13.46 * 28.53 * 37.46 *
LTL 17.72 * 76.99 * 76.99 *
Number of Breaks Selected, Sequential Method (b)
RSD
LTL
[T.sub.2] [[bar.R].sup.2]
([R.sup.2])
RSD 86 [83, 88] 0.252 (0.270)
LTL 0.268 (0.276)
(a) [epsilon]: trimming parameter = h/T; h: a minimum length
of each regime; M: an upper bound.
(b) We use a 10%, significance level for the sequential test.
(c) t values are in parentheses; 90%, confidence intervals
for [T.sub.i] are in square brackets.
* Significant at the 99% critical level.
** Significant at the 95% critical level.
*** Significant at the 90% critical level.
TABLE 5
Break Point Confidence Interval Summary
Year NBA NFL NHL
1969 (1967-1974)+ (1966-1975)-
1972 (1970-1976)+
1997-1977 (1973-1980)+
1984-1986 (1982-1989)+
1997 (1995-1999)+
Sources: Tables 2 -4.
Notes. "+" denotes improved balance after the break;
"-" denotes competitive balance worsened after the break.