Sustainability of the Friedman rule in an international monetary policy game.
Jansen, Dennis W. ; Liu, Liqun ; Weng, Ming-Jang 等
I. INTRODUCTION
One recurring theme in the analysis of policy-making is that in
many situations, policymakers can benefit from the opportunity to make a
binding commitment to restrict their activities. One such situation is
what is known as the "time consistency problem" in monetary
policy-making. A government, or its monetary authority, out of good
intention, may find it beneficial to generate unexpected inflation to
fix some nonmonetary distortion in the economy, for example, goods
market inefficiency due to monopoly power that is characterized by
higher-than-efficient product prices. This first-best monetary policy,
however, is not "time consistent" in the sense that firms
foresee the government's incentive to impose monetary surprises and
set their nominal prices at a higher level. As a result, the
government's attempts to remedy the inefficiency in the goods
market using monetary policy lead only to higher inflation, with the
goods market inefficiency unchanged. Therefore, it is better for the
government to make a commitment not to adopt any active monetary policy
to fix the nonmonetary distortion, so that the second-best outcome with
low inflation can be achieved.
For such a commitment by the government to work, it has to be
credible. There does exist an implicit reputation mechanism that may
make a monetary authority's commitment credible. When a monetary
authority repeatedly makes policies for many number of periods, a good
reputation of sticking to its commitment is important for its long-run
success. Even though a deviation from the announced second-best plan may
benefit the monetary authority in the short run by achieving a temporary
first-best result, it would destroy the authority's reputation, and
as a result, the economy would end up at an equilibrium with a high
inflation that is dominated by the second-best result with low
inflation. If the short-run benefits from deviation are exceeded by the
long-run costs from loss of reputation, a rational government would
honor its commitment and the private sector sees this. As a result, the
second-best outcome is sustainable. Otherwise, the commitment of not
using surprise inflation is not credible, and the second-best outcome is
not sustainable.
This article studies the "commitment problem" and the
sustainability of the second-best outcome in an open-economy context.
The main message of this article is that trade linkage between economies
may be a solution to the commitment problem facing domestic monetary
authorities. In essence, free trade facilitates a competitive mechanism
among sovereign governments, which reduces the short-run benefits from
surprise inflation and therefore makes the low-inflation policy more
credible. Importantly, if sovereign governments cooperate with one
another rather than compete, the benefit from international trade in
terms of making governments' commitments more credible does not
exist. Therefore, another lesson of the article is that cooperation
among sovereign governments in the area of monetary policy-making may
not be so desirable.
We build an open-economy version of Ireland's (1997)
closed-economy environment. We add a second equally sized economy and
allow trade between these economies. Ireland (1997) analyzed the closed
economy, concentrating on issues of government commitment to households
and the possibility of a reputational equilibrium in which the optimal
policy under commitment can be sustained. Our Open-economy extension
allows us to look at two simultaneous monetary games: one between the
two governments and the other between each government and its own
private sector. Thus, this work follows in the line of previous work by
Canzoneri and Henderson (1991), Henderson and Zhu (1990), and Kimbrough
(1993). However, the underlying economics of our model varies
significantly from that used by these authors in that our model is
specified in terms of tastes and technologies. This microfounded
approach has two advantages. First, alternative monetary policies can be
evaluated in terms of their effects on welfare, measured using a
representative household's utility function; there is no need to
specify an ad hoc loss function for the monetary authority. Second, in a
model with microfoundations, the parameters are those describing tastes
and technologies; since these parameters can be reasonably calibrated based on findings from empirical studies, it is much easier to get a
feel for whether the required conditions for reputational mechanisms are
likely to hold.
To preview our results, we find that when two governments can
commit to their respective private sectors, the cooperative equilibrium
is that both governments contract money supplies so that the net nominal
interest rate in both countries is 0, as required by the Friedman rule.
Depending on the values of the parameters involved, the cooperative
equilibrium may also be a Nash equilibrium. If that is the case, then
there would be no need for any international agreements to facilitate
cooperation among honest monetary authorities.
More significantly, we study the sustainability of the Friedman
rule in the more realistic case where the governments lack a commitment
technology. We find that the Friedman rule, the optimal policy when both
governments can commit to their private sectors and at the same time can
cooperate with each other, is more likely to be sustained in the
open-economy model than in the Ireland's closed-economy model, if
the governments do not (cannot) cooperate in generating inflationary
surprises.
Underlying our main result is the idea of counterproductive cooperation between governments. The basic idea of counterproductive
cooperation between monetary authorities has been made before (see Kehoe
1989; Rogoff 1985). What is new in this article is that the
counterproductive cooperation takes a different notion and is developed
in a model with firmer microfoundations. In this article, the optimal
policy becomes less sustainable (in a repeated game) due to the
cooperation between governments, while in the earlier studies on
counterproductive cooperation, it is the time-consistent suboptimal policy (in a one-shot game) that becomes worse due to cooperation. On
the other hand, as we said before, the parameters in a model with
micro-foundations are those describing tastes and technologies, and they
can be reasonably calibrated based on findings in the empirical
literature.
This article is organized as follows. The model is presented in the
next section. In Section III, we show that when the governments can
commit to their private sectors, the cooperative equilibrium of the game
between the two governments is characterized by the Friedman rule. We
also study the Nash equilibria of this game. In Section IV, we study the
sustainability of the Friedman rule when governments lack such
commitment technology and compare it with the similar condition obtained
within the closed-economy setting.
II. THE MODEL
The behavioral relations describe a two-country version of
Ireland's (1997) closed-economy setup. (1) We use this model to
investigate monetary policy interactions simultaneously between two
sovereign governments and between each government and its own private
sector. The model has utility-maximizing individuals, monopolistically
competitive firms, and sticky output prices. Each government looks to
maximize the utility function of the domestic representative agent, so
that within a country, government and private objectives coincide.
We assume that there are two countries of equal size, a home
country and a foreign country. Variables with tildes denote foreign
variables. The behavioral relations in both countries are symmetric. (2)
Each country consists of three players: a government, a continuum of
monopolistically competitive firms indexed by i [member of] [0, 1] for
the home country and [??] [member of] [0, 1] for the foreign country,
and a representative individual. The timing of events and roles of each
player in this economy are described below.
Each government controls her money supply and makes a lump-sum
transfer to the respective representative individual at the beginning of
each date t = 0, 1, 2,.... This transfer is ([x.sub.t] -
1)[M.sup.s.sub.t] for the home government and ([[??].sub.t] -
1)[[??].sup.s.sub.t] for the foreign government, where [M.sup.s.sub.t]
and [[??].sup.s.sub.t] are, respectively, the per capita home money
stock and the foreign money stock at the beginning of time t and
[x.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t] are, respectively, the gross money growth
rates in the home and the foreign countries. So [M.sup.s.sub.t+1] =
[x.sub.t][M.sup.s.sub.t] and [[??].sup.s.sub.t+1] =
[[??].sub.t][[??].sup.s.sub.t]
Firms are monopolistically competitive. They set output prices at
the beginning of each period and are required to supply output at that
set price for the entire period. So the home firm i and the foreign firm
[??] enter period t with fixed nominal output prices [P.sub.t](i) and
[[??].sub.t]([??]), respectively. Firms in each country produce distinct
perishable consumption goods; hence, goods are also indexed by i and
[??]. Monopolistic competition results in equilibrium output falling
below the efficient level, while sticky prices allow unanticipated money
to generate real effects on output.
The representative home individual enters period t with home money
[M.sub.t] and home (private) bonds [B.sub.t], Similarly, the
representative foreign individual enters period t with foreign money
[[??].sub.t] and foreign (private) bonds [[??].sub.t]. In equilibrium,
money demand equals money supply, and private bonds are available in
zero net supply. That is to say [M.sub.t] = [M.sup.s.sub.t],
[[??].sub.t] = [[??].sup.s.sub.t], and [B.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = 0 for
all t = 0, 1, 2,.... However, we can impose these equilibrium conditions
only after the individual optimization problems are solved. The
representative individual of each country is allowed to hold only
domestic money and bonds. This assumption simplifies the analysis, but
it also seems necessary for an analytical solution. It turns out that a
crucial feature in constructing the monetary game is to relate the
policy variables to the equilibrium values of the welfare variables that
appear in the utility functions. This assumption makes such a connection
possible. The gross nominal interest rates are [R.sub.t] for the home
bonds and [[??].sub.t] for the foreign bonds. A home (or foreign) bond
with a face value of [B.sub.t+1] (or [[??].sub.t+1]) paying a gross
nominal interest rate [R.sub.t] (or [[??].sub.t]) at time t + 1 will
cost the representative home (or foreign) individual [B.sub.t+1]/
[R.sub.t] (or [[??].sub.t+1]/[[??].sub.t] in home (or foreign) currency
at time t. The representative individual in each country also consumes
both home goods (goods produced by home firms) and foreign goods (goods
produced by foreign firms). However, purchasing nondomestic goods first
involves an exchange of domestic money for foreign money.
The timing of transactions is as follows. At the beginning of each
time t, the representative home individual receives a nominal transfer
([x.sub.t] - 1)[M.sup.s.sub.t] from the home government; likewise, the
representative foreign individual receives a nominal transfer
([[??].sub.t] - 1)[[??].sup.s.sub.t] from his government. Then, bonds
[B.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t] mature, so that the money holdings are
[M.sub.t] + ([x.sub.t] - 1)[M.sup.s.sub.t] + [B.sub.t] in home currency
for the home individual and [[??].sub.t] + ([[??].sub.t] - 1)
[[??].sup.s.sub.t] + [[??].sub.t] in foreign currency for the foreign
individual, where [M.sub.t]; and [[??].sub.t] are, respectively, the
money holdings of the home individual and of the foreign individual left
from the transactions at time t - 1. The representative home and foreign
individuals then use these money holdings to purchase new bonds and
consumption goods. In doing so, they face their respective
cash-in-advance (CIA) constraints:
Home CIA: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (1)
and
Foreign CIA: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
(2)
Here, [e.sub.t] is the nominal exchange rate, which is defined as
the home currency price of one unit of foreign currency, and
[c.sup.h.sub.t] (i) and [[??].sup.h.sub.t] ([??]) denote the
representative home individual's consumption of goods i and [??],
with fixed prices [P.sub.t](i) and [[??].sub.t](i), respectively.
Similarly, [c.sup.f.sub.t](i) and [[??].sup.f.sub.t] ([??]) are
representative foreign individual's consumption of goods i and
[??].
Next, the representative home individual supplies [n.sub.t](i)
units of labor to domestic firm i [member of] [0, 1] and receives a
nominal wage rate [W.sub.t], and the representative foreign individual
supplies [[??].sub.t]([??]) units of labor to foreign firm [??] [member
of] [0, 1] and receives nominal wage rate [[??].sub.t]. It is assumed
that there is no employment overseas. Hence, per capita labor supplies
in both countries are, respectively,
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
and the wage payments received by representative home and foreign
individuals are [n.sub.t] [W.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t] [[??].sub.t],
respectively.
We assume that only home individuals may own home firms and only
foreign individuals may own foreign firms. Firms pay out all profits as
dividends to the representative individuals. We also assume that firms
in each country produce outputs with linear technology that yields one
unit of output for every unit of labor input. For the home firms,
therefore, dividends paid out are
(5) [D.sub.t](i) = [[P.sub.t](i) - [W.sub.t]][y.sup.D.sub.t](i,
[P.sub.t](i)), i [member of] [0, 1].
Similarly, foreign firms pay out dividends according to
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
Firms i and [??] face downward-sloping output demand curves
[y.sup.D.sub.t], (i,[P.sub.t],(i)) and
[[??].sup.D.sub.t]([??].[[??].sub.t],([??])), respectively. (3) These
arise due to monopolistic competition. The curves [y.sup.D.sub.t](i,
[P.sub.t](i)) and [[??].sup.D.sub.t]([??],[[??].sub.t],([??])) are
determined by representative individuals' demands for goods i and
[??] at prices [P.sub.t](i) and [[??].sub.t]([??]), respectively.
At the end of period t, the representative home and foreign
individuals have unspent cash, wage receipts, and dividend as sources of
money holdings to be carried into period t + 1. These money holdings are
[M.sub.t+1], for the home individual and [[??].sub.t+1] for the foreign
individual. The budget constraint (BC) for home individual is
Home BC: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (7)
and it is exactly symmetric for the foreign BC.
Households receive utility from both domestic and foreign goods.
The preferences of representative home and foreign individuals are
denoted by the utility functions
(8) [[infinity].summation over (t=0)]
[[beta].sup.t][K[([c.sup.h.sub.t].sup.[alpha]]
[([[??].sup.h.sub.t].sup.[delta]] - [n.sub.t]],
(9) [[infinity].summation over (t=0)]
[[beta].sup.t][K[([[??].sup.f.sub.t].sup.[alpha]]
[(c.sup.f.sub.t]).sup.[delta]] - [[??].sub.t]],
respectively, where 0 < [beta] < 1, [alpha] > 0, [delta]
> 0, [alpha] + [delta] < 1, and K > 0. The composite goods
[c.sup.h.sub.t], [[??].sup.h.sub.t], [[??].sup.f.sub.t] and
[c.sup.f.sub.t] are defined by
(10) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [theta] > 1. These specific functional forms imply a
constant elasticity of substitution (CES) between goods produced in a
country. If [theta] is large, then these goods are close substitutes.
(4) In the utility functions, Equations (8) and (9), domestic goods are
allowed to have a different weight than nondomestic goods (when [alpha]
[not equal to] [delta]). At the same time, these specifications assume a
symmetry between the two countries, which is consistent with our
modeling assumption of two equal-sized and basically equivalent nations.
Before proceeding with our analysis, we define the following scaled
nominal variables:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
Note that [m.sub.t], is the ratio of representative home
individual's money holdings to the per capita money stock of the
home country at time t; hence, it can be normalized to one in
equilibrium in which all domestic individuals hold an equal amount of
money. Similarly, [[??].sub.t], can be normalized to one in equilibrium.
In addition to the above definitions of the scaled nominal variables,
let [k.sub.t] = [[??].sup.s.sub.t]/[M.sup.s.sub.t], the ratio of per
capita money stock of foreign country to home country.
Now we are able to rewrite the representative home and foreign
individuals' CIA and BCs in terms of the scaled variables. For
example, home CIA and BC can be written as:
Home CIA: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (12)
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (13)
The dividend payments of the representative home firm i can also be
expressed as
(14) [d.sub.t](i) = [[p.sub.t](i) - [w.sub.t]] [y.sup.d.sub.t] (i,
[p.sub.t](i)), i [member of] [0, 1],
where [y.sup.d.sub.t](i,pt(i)) is the representative
individuals' demands for goods i at scaled prices [p.sub.t](i).
III. NASH AND COOPERATIVE EQUILIBRIA WHEN GOVERNMENTS ARE CREDIBLE
If we disregard any problem with time consistency of optimal
policies, it seems reasonable to expect that the cooperative equilibrium
is for both governments to follow the Friedman rule, that is, each
government contracts money supply so that the net nominal interest rate
is 0. We derive this result later, but the basic reason is that monetary
policy cannot alleviate the monopoly distortion implied by imperfect
competition in the goods market. Thus, the most that the two governments
can do with monetary policy is to make sure that the real economy is not
distorted by monetary policy, that is, to implement the Friedman rule,
just as in the case of the closed economy. A new dimension added by the
open-economy extension is that one government's policy may have
externalities on another through its impact on the exchange rate.
Consequently, the Nash and the cooperative equilibria tend to differ
from each other. Indeed, in previous studies on this topic that employ
only aggregate relationships, the Nash equilibrium is usually
characterized by a higher inflation rate. Therefore, these earlier
studies have generally emphasized the benefits of cooperation among
sovereign governments. Using a model grounded in microfoundations, we
find that there exist situations in which the Nash and the cooperative
equilibria are identical.
We begin with the optimization problems of private agents and find
the representative individuals' and firms' best actions. We
assume that both governments can credibly commit to domestic private
agents by setting a sequence of gross money growth rates x = {[x.sub.t],
t = 0, 1, 2, ...} of the home government and [??] = {[[??].sub.t], t =
0, 1, 2, ...} of the foreign government, where [x.sub.t] [member of]
[[beta], [bar.x]] and [[??].sub.t] [member of] [[beta], [bar.x]] for all
t. These assumptions mean that individuals take as given the entire
paths of x and [??] when solving their maximization problems. The bounds
on gross money growth rates ensure the existence of a monetary
equilibrium. As shown below, the lower bound, [beta], on both [x.sub.t]
and [[??].sub.t], helps guarantee that the net nominal interest rates
[R.sub.t] - 1 and [[??].sub.t] - 1 are nonnegative in equilibrium. As
for the upper bound, [bar.x]<[infinity], this is introduced following
Calvo (1978) in order to guarantee that private agents never abandon the
use of money altogether.
The representative home individual's problem is to maximize
his lifetime utility given in Equation (8), subject to the definitions
of composite goods [c.sup.h.sub.t] and [[??].sup.h.sub.t] (the first two
equations in Equation (10)), the scaled home CIA constraint, Equation
(12), and the scaled home BC, Equation (13), taking x, [??],
[p.sub.t](i), [[??].sub.t]([??]), [w.sub.t], [d.sub.t](i),[R.sub.t],
[k.sub.t] and [e.sub.t] as given. Appendix 1 shows the first-order
conditions of this maximization problem and further obtains
[c.sup.h.sub.t] = [alpha][([alpha] + [delta]).sup.-1]
[H.sub.t]/[p.sub.t] = [alpha][([alpha] + [delta]).sup.-1]
[x.sub.t/[p.sub.t] (15)
[[??].sup.h.sub.t] = [delta][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1][H.sub.t]/([p.sub.t][z.sub.t]) = [delta][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1] [x.sub.t]/([p.sub.t][z.sub.t]) (16)
(17) [c.sup.h.sub.t](i) = [alpha][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1]([H.sub.t]/[p.sub.t])[([p.sub.t](i)/[p.sub.t]).sup.-0]
= [alpha][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1]([x.sub.t]/[p.sub.t])[([p.sub.t](i)/[p.sub.t]).sup.0]
(18) [[??].sup.h.sub.t]([??]) = [delta][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1][[H.sub.t] /
([p.sub.t][z.sub.t])][([[??].sub.t]([??])/[[??].sub.t]).sup.-0]
= [delta][([alpha] + [delta]).sup.-1][[x.sub.t] /
([p.sub.t][z.sub.t])][([[??].sub.t]([??]) / [[??].sub.t]).sup.-0],
where [H.sub.t] [equivalent to] [m.sub.t] + ([x.sub.t] - 1) +
[b.sub.t] - [x.sub.t][b.sub.t+1]/[R.sub.t] is the home individual's
money holdings available for purchasing both home and foreign goods in
period t, [p.sub.t] [equivalent to]
[[[[integral].sup.1.sub.0][p.sub.t][(i).sup.1-0]di].sup.1/(1-0)] and
[[??].sub.t] [equivalent to]
[[[[integral].sup.1.sub.0][[??].sub.t]([??]).sup.1-0]
d[??]].sup.1/(1-0)] are, respectively, the measure of (scaled)
"average price" in home and foreign country in period t, (5)
and [z.sub.t] [equivalent to] [k.sub.t][e.sub.t][[??].sub.t]/[p.sub.t]
is the real exchange rate in period t. The second equality in each of
the above-mentioned four equations is obtained by applying the money and
the bond market equilibrium conditions. When the money market is in
equilibrium in both countries, then [m.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = 1.
Moreover, since all individuals are identical, both home and foreign
bonds must be in zero net supply in equilibrium, that is, for all t,
[b.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = 0, and hence [H.sub.t] = [x.sub.t].
In Appendix 1, we also derive the following relationships:
(19) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
(20) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Similarly, for the representative foreign individual, the symmetric
optimization problem can be solved following analogous reasoning to
yield:
(21) [[??].sup.f.sub.t] = [alpha][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1][[??].sub.t]/[[??].sub.t] = [alpha][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1][[??].sub.t]/[[??].sub.t]
(22) [c.sup.f.sub.t] = [delta][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1][[??].sub.t][z.sub.t]/[[??].sub.t] = [delta][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1][[??].sub.t][z.sub.t]/[[??].sub.t]
(23) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(24) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(25) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (26)
where [[??].sub.t] = [[??].sub.t], + ([[??].sub.t] - 1) +
[[??].sub.t] - [[??].sub.t] [[??].sub.t+1]/[[??].sub.t] is the money
holding available for consumption to the foreign individual.
We now turn to the firms' profit (dividend) maximization
problems. Home firm i's problem is to choose [p.sub.t](i) to
maximize Equation (14), subject to
(27) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
given [w.sub.t], [p.sub.t], [[??].sub.t], [x.sub.t], [[??].sub.t]
and [z.sub.t]. The first-order condition of firm i's problem can be
reduced to
(28) [p.sub.t](i) = [p.sub.t] = [theta][([theta] -
1).sup.-1][w.sub.t], i [member of] [0,1], t = 0, 1, 2, ....
A similar result holds for the foreign firms:
(29) [[??].sub.t]([??]) = [[??].sub.t] = [theta][([theta] -
1).sup.-1][[??].sub.t], [??] [member of] [0, 1], t = 0, 1, 2, ....
Equations (28) and (29) show that there is a marked up of price
over marginal cost for firms in each country. This is due to the
assumption of monopolistically competitive firms. As we know, if [theta]
goes to infinity, then all goods tend to be perfect substitutes, and
perfect competition implies [p.sub.t] = [w.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t] =
[[??].sub.t].
Finally, to fully solve for the welfare variables--[c.sup.h.sub.t],
[[??].sup.h.sub.t], and [n.sub.t], for the home individual and
[[??].sup.f.sub.t], [c.sup.f.sub.t], and [[??].sub.t] for the foreign
individual--in terms of policy variables (i.e., [x.sub.t], and
[[??].sub.t]) alone, we need the following equilibrium conditions for
the labor and exchange markets. The labor market clearing conditions are
simply
(30) [n.sub.t] = [c.sup.h.sub.t] + [c.sup.f.sub.t], t = 1, 1, 2,
...
for the home country and
(31) [[??].sub.t] = [[??].sup.h.sub.t] + [[??].sup.f.sub.t], t = 0,
1, 2, ...
for the foreign country. In Appendix 2, we show that the currency
exchange market clearing condition is
(32) [x.sub.t]/[p.sub.t] = [z.sub.t][[??].sub.t]/[[??].sub.t], t =
0, 1, 2, ...
Now we are ready to express the variables in the utility
functions,: Equations (8) and (9), in terms of policy variables. First,
from Equations (15), (16), (21), (22), and (32), we have [c.sup.f.sub.t]
= ([delta]/[alpha])[c.sup.h.sub.t] and [[??].sup.h.sub.t] =
([delta]/[alpha])[[??].sup.f.sub.t]. Then, from Equations (30) and (31),
we have [n.sub.t] = [([alpha] + [delta])/ [alpha]][c.sup.h.sub.t] and
[[??].sub.t] = [([alpha] + [delta])/[alpha]] [[??].sup.f.sub.t]. Thus,
the issue has boiled down to expressing [c.sup.h.sub.t] and
[[??].sup.f.sub.t] in terms of [x.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t]. Substituting
Equation (19) into Equation (28) and then the resulting expression of
[p.sub.t] into Equation (15), we have
[c.sup.h.sub.t] = [([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]]([theta] -
1)[alpha][beta]K[[theta].sup.-1] [x.sup.-1.sub.t+1]
[([c.sup.h.sub.t+1]).sup.[alpha]][([[??].sup.f.sub.t+1]).sup.[delta]].
(33)
Similarly, substituting Equation (25) into Equation (29) and then
the resulting expression of [[??].sub.t] into Equation (21), we have
[[??].sup.f.sub.t], = [([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]]([theta] -
1)[alpha] [beta]K[[theta].sup.-1][[??].sup.-1.sub.t+1]
[([[??].sup.f.sub.t+1]).sup.[alpha]][([c.sup.h.sub.t+1]).sup.[delta]].
(34)
Denoting Q = [([[delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]]([theta] -
1)[alpha][[beta]K/[theta] and using log terms, we can rewrite Equations
(33) and (34), respectively, as
(35) ln([c.sup.h.sub.t]) = lnQ + [alpha]ln([c.sup.h.sub.t+1]) +
[delta]ln([[??].sup.f.sub.t+1]) - ln([x.sub.t+1])
and
ln([[??].sup.f.sub.t]) = lnQ + [alpha]ln ([[??].sup.f.sub.t+1]) +
[delta]ln([[c.sup.h.sub.t+1]) - ln([??].sub.t+1]) (36)
Solving this first-order difference equation system yields (see
Appendix 3 for a derivation)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (37)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (38)
To summarize, the home and the foreign governments' problems
are, respectively, to choose x and [??] to maximize
[[infinity].summation over (t = 0)]
[[beta].sup.t][K([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]
[([c.sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[alpha]] [([[??].sup.f.sub.t]).sup.[delta] -
([alpha] + [delta])[[alpha].sup.-1][c.sup.h.sub.t]] (39)
for the home government and
[[infinity].summation over (t = 0)]
[[beta].sup.t][K([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]
[([[??].sup.f.sub.t]).sup.[alpha]] [([c.sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[delta] -
([alpha] + [delta])[[alpha].sup.1][[??].sup.f.sub.t]] (40)
for the foreign government, with [c.sup.h.sub.t] and
[[??].sup.f.sub.t] given by Equations (37) and (38), respectively.
This is a game between the home and the foreign governments. A
general characterization of Nash equilibria of this game is quite
complex, so we restrict our analysis to those Nash equilibria that have
a constant money growth rate in each country. In Appendix 3, we prove
the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 1. In situations in which the governments can commit to
their private sectors, the strategy combination [x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t]
= is a Nash equilibrium if ([alpha] + [delta])(1 - [alpha]) ([theta] -
1)/[([alpha](1- [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2])[theta]] [less than or equal
to] 1 and the strategy combination [x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = ([alpha] +
[delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta] - 1)[beta]/ ([alpha](1 - [alpha]) +
[[delta].sup.2][theta]] > [beta] is a Nash equilibrium if ([alpha] +
[delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta]- 1)/ [[alpha](1 - [alpha]) +
[[delta].sup.2])0] > 1. (6)
The cooperative equilibria (Pareto optimal) of this game are not
unique. In this article, we focus on the symmetric cooperative
equilibrium in which [x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] (and [[c.sup.h.sub.t] =
[[??].sup.f.sub.t] for all t = 0, 1, 2,.... In Appendix 3, we also prove
that the cooperative equilibrium is [x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t = [beta],
for t = 0, 1,2, .... Note that this implies a steady state for all the
variables in the expression for [R.sub.t], Equation (20), and the
expression for [[??].sub.t], Equation (26). So [R.sub.t ] = [[??].sub.t]
= 1. This means that the cooperative strategy for both governments under
commitment is to follow the Friedman rule, that is, to contract the
money supply so that the net nominal interest rate is 0. The
above-mentioned results, which are proven in Appendix 3, are summarized
by the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 2. In the situation in which the governments can commit
to their private sectors, the symmetric cooperative equilibrium of the
monetary game is characterized by both governments following the
Friedman rule.
From Propositions 1 and 2, we know that when ([alpha] + [delta])(1
- [alpha])([phi]- 1)/[([alpha](1 - [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2])[theta]]
[less than or equal to] 1, the Nash equilibrium and the cooperative
equilibrium coincide. So in this case, a government that is credible to
its private sector does not have to worry about the actions of the other
credible governments. The cooperative strategy is self-enforced. This
result stands in sharp contrast with the existing literature on
international monetary policy games. Most studies assume some sort of
aggregate behavioral model and some kind of externality from one
country's monetary policy on another country's economy (e.g.,
Canzoneri and Henderson 1991; Henderson and Zhu 1990; Kimbrough 1993).
The focus of that work has been the search of rules that would
implicitly coordinate different countries' policies. However, there
is an inherent incentive to cheat on any cooperative agreement or rule.
On the other hand, here we find, using a natural multieconomy extension
of a monetary policy game model with solid microfoundations, that
although a government's monetary policy generates externalities on
another economy through its impact on the exchange rate, there are
situations in which the benefits of exploiting that externality are
exceeded by the costs. Hence, as far as honest governments are
concerned, there is no need for any rule to implement cooperation. When
([alpha] + [delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta] - 1)/[([alpha](1 - [alpha]) +
[[delta].sup.2])[theta]] > 1, however, the Nash outcome between two
honest governments is less desirable than the cooperative outcome. So
mechanisms that can implement cooperation do have a role to play.
The condition needed for the Friedman rule to be part of a Nash
equilibrium, that is, ([alpha] + [delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta] -
1)/[([alpha] (1 - [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2])[theta]] [less than or
equal to] 1, depends on [alpha], [delta], and [theta], about which we
can provide the following explanation. First, consider the extreme case
[delta] = 0. This is the case where individuals only consume domestic
goods and the international linkage in the model is moot. The condition
becomes ([theta] - 1)/[theta] [less than or equal to] 1, which always
holds. In other words, the central banks of two unlinked economies will
follow the Friedman rule. This is not surprising because there is no
externality to be exploited by either government in this case. Then, as
[delta] becomes larger while holding [alpha] + [delta] constant, (7) the
condition is less likely to hold because ([alpha] + [delta])(1 -
[alpha])/([alpha](1 - [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2]) increases in [delta]
while holding [alpha] + [delta] constant. Again, this is not surprising
because the stronger the international linkage, the more externality to
be exploited by either government.
The overall tone of previous studies on international monetary
policy game is that international linkages from trade impose a larger
challenge on monetary authorities than when they are isolated and
therefore require cooperation between governments. On the other hand, we
have emphasized in this section that there exist situations such that
honest governments, governments that can commit to their own private
sectors, do not need to cooperate with each other. In the next section,
we further show that in the more realistic case in which governments
cannot commit to their respective private sectors, international
linkages can actually improve the opportunity for the optimal monetary
policy under commitment to be sustainable. Moreover, cooperation between
monetary authorities may well be counterproductive.
IV. SUSTAINABLE OUTCOMES WHEN GOVERNMENTS LACK A COMMITMENT
TECHNOLOGY
The analysis in the last section shows that when governments can
commit to their private sectors, an optimal (cooperative) policy under
commitment is for both to follow the Friedman rule, that is, to pursue a
monetary policy that makes the net nominal interest rate on domestic
bonds be 0. This optimal policy under commitment, however, is not the
first-best policy since production in each firm of each country is
conducted at a point where price exceeds marginal cost due to the
monopolistically competitive market structure. So when a government
lacks a commitment technology, the government has an incentive to set
money growth rate unexpectedly high, after firms have fixed their
nominal product prices at the beginning of each period, so that the real
product price equals the marginal cost. In equilibrium, however, firms
foresee this incentive of the government and set their prices
accordingly. As a result, the government's attempts to remedy the
inefficiency of underproduction by generating monetary surprises lead
only to higher inflation. This is, of course, a version of time
consistency problem of Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Barro and
Gordon's (1983). In the context of the present article, this point
is formalized in Proposition 3.
Before stating Proposition 3, we need to introduce the concept of
sustainable equilibrium and autarky plan. A sustainable equilibrium is a
strategy combination such that by following the strategy combination (i)
each firm in each country solves the firm's problem, given that
other agents follow the strategy combination; (ii) the representative
individual in each country solves the respective individual's
problem, given that other agents follow the strategy combination; (iii)
the market equilibrium requirements are satisfied; and (iv) each
government solves the respective government problem, given that other
agents follow the strategy combination. (8) The autarky plan is a
special strategy combination in which both governments always choose the
maximum money growth rate [x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = [bar.x]. The
subsequent proposition identifies the condition under which this autarky
plan is part of a sustainable equilibrium as defined above.
PROPOSITION 3. If [alpha][theta][bar.x]/[([alpha + [delta])
[beta]([theta] - 1)> 1, then the autarky plan is' a sustainable
equilibrium.
The proof is given in Appendix 4. Note that the condition
[alpha][theta][bar.x]/[([alpha + [delta]) [beta]([theta]- 1) > 1 can
always be satisfied since [bar.x] can be arbitrarily large. In the
autarky equilibrium, [x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = [bar.x] for all t. This
is the counterpart of discretionary outcome by Barro and Gordon (1983).
Therefore, when governments lack a commitment technology, the
question is not whether the first best can be achieved but rather
whether the second best, the optimal allocation under commitment--the
allocation that is realized when each government follows the Friedman
rule--can be sustained. Ireland (1997) investigated this question within
a closed-economy model characterized by utility-maximizing households,
monopolistically competitive firms, and sticky nominal product prices.
Specifically, following the technique developed by Abreu (1988) and
Chari and Kehoe (1990), Ireland established a full characterization of
"sustainable outcomes," outcomes that can be supported by
"sustainable equilibria," when the government lacks a formal
commitment technology. He went on to identify the conditions under which
the optimal policy under commitment--the Friedman rule--can be part of a
sustainable outcome.
The model we consider here is a two-country version of
Ireland's model. For simplicity, we will not use the
Abreu-Chari-Kehoe technique to fully characterize the sustainable
outcomes first. Instead, we directly establish the condition for the
Friedman rule to be sustainable and compare it with the similar
condition by Ireland for the closed economy. (9) For the Friedman
rule--the cooperative equilibrium under commitment ([x.su.t] =
[[??].sub.t] = [beta])--to be sustainable, it must be the case that for
each government, the benefit from deviation is exceeded by the cost of
it. Because the autarky plan is itself a sustainable equilibrium, it can
be credibly used to punish any deviation. So the cost of deviating from
the Friedman rule is that from the next period on, both the two
governments and the private agents revert to the autarky plan in which
[x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = [bar.x]. On the other hand, the benefit from
a government deviating from the Friedman rule is that by setting the
gross money growth rate larger than [beta], after the firms have set
prices according to both governments setting money growth rate to
[beta], the inefficiency in the product market can be partially fixed
and the instant one-period utility of the representative domestic
individual can be improved.
Because of symmetry, we need to consider only the home
government's incentive to deviate. Specifically, we compare the
home individual's lifetime utility obtained when the home
government follows the Friedman rule with that obtained when the home
government deviates. The constant one-period utility the home individual
gets under the Friedman rule ([x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = [beta]) is,
letting [??] = [??] = [beta] in (A3.6),
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (41)
Similarly, the one-period utility the home individual gets under
the autarky plan is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (42)
If deviating, the home government would choose [x.sub.t] to
maximize the home individual's instant one-period utility at t,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (43)
given that. [[??].sub.t] = [beta], and firms in both countries set
prices, assuming that both governments follow the Friedman rule. To get
[p.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t], in Equation (43), note that (from (A3.5))
under [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. On the other
hand, [c.sup.h.sub.t] = [alpha][beta][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1]/[p.sub.t] and [c.sup.[??].sub.t] =
[alpha][beta][([alpha] + [delta]).sup.-1]/[[??].sub.t] from Equations
(15) and (21). So
(44) [p.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = [alpha][beta][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1] [(Q/[beta]).sup.-1/1-([alpha] + [delta]).
Substituting [p.sub.t], and [[??].sub.t], given by Equation (44)
and [[??].sub.t] = [beta] into Equation (43), the latter becomes
(45) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Maximizing Equation (45) with respect to [x.sub.t] yields the
first-order condition
(46) [x.sup.1 - [alpha].sub.t] = [[beta].sup.1 - [alpha]]
[alpha][theta]/[([alpha] + [delta]) ([theta] - 1)].
To see whether it is worthwhile for the home government to deviate,
we differentiate between two cases depending on the value of [theta]
relative to [alpha]/ [delta].
CASE (I). [theta] [greater than or equal to] 1 + [alpha]/[delta].
In this case, Equation (46) would indicate that [x.sub.t] [less
than or equal to] [beta]. Because the lower bound of [x.sub.t] is
[beta], we have a corner solution [[x.sup.*.sub.t] = [beta]. This means,
when firms produce close enough substitutes ([theta] [greater than or
equal to] 1 + [alpha]/[delta]), given [alpha]/[delta], a government
cannot even generate any instant benefits by deviating from the Friedman
rule if the other government is still following the rule. So the
Friedman rule is sustainable.
Why is the elasticity of substitution so important in determining
the sustainability of the optimal policy? The larger this elasticity,
the less the monopoly distortion introduced by imperfect goods market
competition. In other words, the two governments' incentives to
deviate from the Friedman rule is lower the higher is the elasticity of
substitution and the lower the degree of monopoly distortion. Also note
that as the weight of foreign goods in the home individual's
utility function becomes smaller, the lower bound on [theta] would
increase. This result is also intuitive because a larger portion of
goods market inefficiency will be eliminated in the short run by the
home government's deviation if foreign goods weigh less in the home
individual's utility function. For a deviation not to generate any
instant benefits, the whole size of the goods market inefficiency must
be smaller ([theta] is larger).
It has been noted that the time consistency problem for monetary
policy vanishes when the nonmonetary distortion is removed (Blackburn
and Christensen 1989; Rogoff 1989). Here, we show a case that even with
a nonmonetary distortion, the time consistency problem will not come up
because one country's monetary policy alone can do nothing to fix
the distortion. This point is related to the work by Cukierman and
Drazen (1988), who argued that if tax revenue from distortionary income
taxes is used to provide public goods, it may not be true that
unanticipated monetary policies would necessarily have short-run
benefits. Our case, however, comes out of a basic model in which
unanticipated monetary policy has been proved to have temporary benefits
due to the improved production efficiency (Ireland 1997). By extending
Ireland's model to a multieconomy world, we show that there are
situations ([theta] [greater than or equal to] 1 + [alpha]/[delta])
where the governments of interacting economies have to coordinate to
make monetary surprises able to generate short-run production
efficiency. However, there is no reason to believe that two different
governments can be easily engaged in such coordination. To the contrary,
coordination failure between the governments provides a mechanism to
implement the Friedman rule.
Here, we present situations where lack of a coordination mechanism
ensures sustainability of the Friedman rule, while existence of such
mechanisms may render the Friedman rule not sustainable (depending on
short-run benefits from deviation and long-run cost from loss of
reputation), resulting in inflation biases. These situations where the
governments of interacting economies have to coordinate to make monetary
surprises able to generate short-run production efficiency facilitate a
variation of the paradoxical result of counterproductive cooperation
between two governments by Rogoff (1985) and Kehoe (1989). Their basic
insight is that commitment between two governments may be
counterproductive when commitment with respect to the private sector is
not available. (10) However, the counterproductive effect of cooperation
between governments in our model is of a different form than in Rogoff
(1985) and Kehoe (1989). Here, the optimal policy becomes less
sustainable (in a repeated game) due to the cooperation between
governments, while in Rogoff (1985) and Kehoe (1989), it is the
time-consistent suboptimal policy (in a one-shot game) that becomes
worse due to cooperation. In a recent article by Jensen (1997), it is
shown that while a costly delegation of monetary policy can improve
time-consistent suboptimal outcomes in one-shot games--as predicted by
the conventional wisdom on the role of delegation in alleviating the
consequences of the time inconsistency problem--it makes the
sustainability of the optimal monetary policy worse in repeated play
settings.
Is [theta] [greater than or equal to] 1 + [alpha]/[delta]
plausible? This condition implies a markup of [theta]/([theta] - 1)
[less than or equal to] 1 + [delta]/[alpha]. Based on the review of the
markup literature by Rotemberg and Woodford (1992), the preferred value
for markup is 1.2, and it is not likely that it would exceed 2. These
two markup values correspond to [delta]/[alpha] = 0.2 and
[delta]/[alpha] = 1, respectively. So our Case (I) seems to be
identified by the literature as a plausible case for sufficiently open
economies.
CASE (II [theta]. [theta] < 1 + [alpha]/[delta].
In this case, we have an interior solution [[x.sup.*.sub.t] =
{[alpha][theta]/[([alpha] + [delta])[([theta] -
1)]}.sup.1/1-[alpha]][beta] > [beta]. Hence, the instant one-period
utility generated by deviating from the Friedman rule is, letting in
Equation (45) [x.sub.t] = [x.sup.*.sub.t]
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (47)
Comparing this result with that in Case (I), we can say that when
the nonmonetary distortion is moderate, a government cannot enhance the
production efficiency even for a single period using monetary surprises
without coordinating with the other government. On the other hand, if
the nonmonetary distortion is severe, a government can increase
short-run efficiency by acting alone. However, even in this case,
whether the governments will deviate depends on the trade-off between
the short-run benefits from the temporary increase in production
efficiency and the long-run costs that would incur due to a loss of
reputation. Specifically, the necessary and sufficient conditions for
not deviating, or put the other way, the necessary and sufficient
condition for the Friedman rule to be sustainable is, letting [bar.x] be
arbitrarily large,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (48)
Compare this condition with Ireland's condition for the
closed-economy model,
(49) (1 - [beta])(1/[alpha] - 1) [less than or equal to]
[[alpha].sup.-1] [[([theta] - 1)/[theta]].sup.[alpha]/1 - [alpha]]
-[[([theta] - 1)/[theta]].sup.1/1-[alpha]].
Obviously, as [delta] approaches 0, Condition (48) converges to
Condition (49). This is the case because our two-country open-economy
model nests Ireland's (1997) closed-economy model as a special case
in the limit as [delta] approaches 0. For [delta] > 0, we show in
Appendix 5 that Condition (48) is weaker than Condition (49) for
comparable parameters; therefore, the Friedman rule is more likely to be
sustainable in our open-economy model than in Ireland's
closed-economy model. Summarizing the results in Case (I) and Case (II)
yields the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 4. For given parameter values, the Friedman rule is
more likely to be sustainable in an open-economy environment than in the
closed-economy environment. Moreover, in the open-economy environment,
and when the firms in the economy produce reasonably close substitutes
([theta] [greater than or equal to] 1 + [alpha]/[delta]), a
government's deviation from the Friedman rule without coordinating
with the other government would not generate even the short-run (or
instant) benefits.
The source of the instantaneous gain one government gets by
deviating from the Friedman rule is the production inefficiency
associated with a monopolistically competitive market structure. The
larger the instantaneous gain from deviation, the less likely the
optimal policy is to be sustainable. While a government in a closed
economy can fully exploit these instantaneous benefits from deviating, a
unilateral decision by one government in an open economy cannot fully
achieve such benefits. As a result, the optimal monetary policy becomes
more likely to be sustainable in an open-economy setting.
Proposition 4 highlights the importance of the elasticity of
substitution between goods of the same origin in determining the
sustainability of the Friedman rule. An interesting question is how the
elasticity of substitution between the group of domestic goods and that
of foreign goods would affect the sustainability of the Friedman rule.
In principle, this new dimension can be added to our model by simply
replacing the Cobb-Douglas specification of the utility function (see
Equations (8) and (9)), which implies a unitary elasticity of
substitution between these two groupings of goods, with a CES
specification. It is our conjecture that the larger the elasticity of
substitution between these two baskets of goods, the easier for the
Friedman rule to be sustainable. Nevertheless, formally demonstrating
that assertion seems to be a daunting task and one which we have not
been able to pursue here.
V. CONCLUSIONS
There have been many studies on monetary policy games. A new trend
in this research area is to revisit the issue of monetary policy
effectiveness and time consistency problem with models that are based on
micro-level behavior specifications of private agents and the assumption
that the government's objective is to maximize social welfare
defined on individual utilities (Cubitt 1993; Ireland 1996, 1997). This
article is another attempt in this direction, in which we add a second
economy to Ireland's (1997) closed-economy model with
utility-maximizing households, monopolistically competitive firms, and
sticky goods prices. We study the game between two governments and
between the governments and their private sectors at the same time. Our
results are very different from those obtained previously using ad hoc
specifications for aggregate relations and governments' objective
functions. First, ignoring governments' commitment problems,
cooperation between governments may be or may not be a problem in our
model--the cooperative equilibrium may be self-enforcing, depending on
the values of the parameters of the economy. Second, explicitly taking
governments' commitment problems into account, we find that
interactions between economies would make each government's
monetary promises more credible; hence, the Friedman rule would be more
likely to be sustainable.
The main message of this article is quite positive: free trade can
help alleviate the commitment problem. In essence, the government of an
isolated economy, even a benevolent one, has too much power in terms of
controlling real prices to remedy, in the short run, the nonmonetary
inefficiency caused by a monopolistically competitive market structure.
This power turns out to be not only powerless in fixing the nonmonetary
distortion but also the source of a monetary distortion. In contrast,
when two economies are connected through trade, each government can
control the real price (in the short run) of only a fraction of all the
goods its citizens consume and therefore can offset the monopolistic
competition distortion in only a fraction of the market, t t Using this
reasoning, any other changes in economic environments that reduce a
government's power in controlling real prices would also help
alleviate the commitment problem and hence make the optimal monetary
policy sustainable.
In this article, the international linkage is made through trade
alone. In particular, we have ruled out individuals holding foreign
bonds. A consequence of this assumption is that the need to keep the
trade balance in equilibrium every period forces the exchange rate to
adjust on impact, thus isolating the imported goods from the domestic
surprise inflation. In reality, international lending and borrowing are
other important dimensions of country openness. If foreigners hold a
substantial fraction of domestic currency (be it bonds or currency),
deviations from the Friedman rule could have a substantial payoff. (12)
While we have made the assumption of no holding of foreign bonds for
analytical tractability, relaxing this assumption and allowing for trade
deficits or surpluses may be a potential topic for future research.
It would also be interesting to see if our results are invariant with various other specifications of monetary policy games that have
solid microfoundations. For example, Cubitt (1993) used a different
model to study the time consistency problem in which menu costs, instead
of cash in advance constraints, contribute to the cost of inflation, and
both product market imperfection and labor market monopoly cause the
nonmonetary distortion. So the exact implications of our model and
results for resolving real-world problems of time consistency in
monetary policy remains a topic that warrants further study.
APPENDIX 1
Assume that both the home CIA constraint, Equation (12), and the
home BC, Equation (13), hold with equality. The Lagrangian of the home
individual's problem is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
(11.) In our model, each firm must set a single nominal price,
denominated in units of its own country's currency, for its output
sold in either country. This assumption, coupled with the flexibility of
the nominal exchange rate, implies that home individuals face fixed
nominal prices for domestic goods but fully flexible nominal prices for
imported goods. An alternative pricing assumption would allow each firm
to preset two prices: one for its output in the domestic market
denominated in the domestic currency and the other for its output in the
foreign market denominated in the foreign currency. Then, home
individuals would face fixed nominal prices for both domestic and
imported goods. However, the added price variables would make the
notation significantly more complicated. Nevertheless, even under that
alternative pricing assumption, each government could still only control
the real prices for a fraction of the goods produced and consumed in the
world market--the goods consumed by domestic individuals under the
alternative pricing assumption as compared to the goods produced by
domestic firms under the current pricing assumption.
(12.) This is the case that most governments seem to have in mind
when considering the advantages of devaluations as a way to reduce the
real value of the domestic debt held by foreigners.
Hence, the first-order conditions of the home individual's
problem are
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A1.1)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A1.2)
(A1.3) [n.sub.t] : [[lambda].sub.t][w.sub.t] = 1
(A1.4) [m.sub.t] | 1 : [beta]([[mu].sub.t | 1 + [[lambda].sub.t] |
1) = [[lambda].sub.t][x.sub.t]
(A1.5) [b.sub.t | 1 : [beta]([[mu].sub.t | 1 + [[lambda].sub.t] |
1) = [[mu].sub.t] + [[lambda].sub.t]) [x.sub.t]/[R.sub.t].
By taking the integral on both sides of (A1.1) to the power of (1 -
[theta]) with respect to i from 0 to 1 and applying the definitions of
[c.sup.h.sub.t] and [p].sub.t], we have
(A1.6) [alpha]K ([c.sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[alpha]-1]
[([??].sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[delta]] = ([[lambda].sub.t] + [[mu].sub.t])
[p.sub.t].
Redo the same integral on (A1.2), except for integrating with
respect to [??] this time rather than i and applying the definitions of
[[??].sup.h.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t]. This gives us
(A1.7) [delta]K
([c.sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[alpha][([[??].sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[delta]-1] =
([[lambda].sub.t] + [[mu].sub.t])[p.sub.t][z.sub.t].
where [z.sub.t] [equivalent
to][k.sub.t][e.sub.t][[??].sub.t/p.sub.t].
Letting [H.sub.t] [equivalent to] [m.sub.t] + ([x.sub.t] - 1) +
[b.sub.t] - [x.sub.t][b.sub.t+1]/[R.sub.t], the home CIA constraint,
Equation (12). becomes
(A1.8) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Multiplying both sides of(A1.8) by ([[lambda].sub.1] +
[[mu].sub.t]) and then substituting (A1.l) and (A1.2) into it. we have
(A1.9) ([[lambda].sub.t] + [[mu].sub.t]) [H.sub.t] = ([alpha] +
[delta]) K ([c.sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[alpha]
([[??].sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[delta].
From (A1.6), (A1.7), and (A1.9), we have
(A1.10) [c.sup.h.sub.t] = [alpha][([alpha] + [delta].sup.-1]]
[H.sub.t]/[p.sub.t]
(A1.11) [[??].sup.h.sub.t] = [delta][([alpha] + [delta]).sup.-1]
[H.sub.t]/([p.sub.t][z.sub.t]).
Now substituting (A1.9) (A1.11) back into (A1.1) and (A1.2) yields
(A1.12) [c.sup.h.sub.t](i) = [alpha][([alpha] + [delta]).sup.-
1]](H.sub.t]/[p.sub.t])[[p.sub.t](i)/[p.sub.t]].sup.[theta]]
(A1.13) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Finally, (A1.3), (A1.4). and (A1.9) together give us
(A1.14) [w.sub.t] = [x.sub.t][H.sub.t | 1]/[[beta]([alpha] +
[delta]) K [([c.sup.h.sub.t | 1]).sup.[alpha]] [([[??].sup.h.sub.t |
1]).sup.[delta]]],
and (A1.5) and (A1.9) together give us
(A1.15) [R.sub.t] = [x.sub.t] [H.sub.t | 1]
(c.sup.h.sub.t].sup.[alpha]]
([[??].sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[delta]]/[[beta][H.sub.t] [([c.sup.h.sub.t |
1]).sup.[alpha] ([[??].sup.h.sub.t | 1]).sup.[delta]]].
APPENDIX 2
The demand in period t for foreign money by the representative home
individual is
(A2.1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
and the supply of foreign money by the representative foreign
individual is
(A2.2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Since the two countries have the same population, the foreign
exchange market equilibrium condition is, using [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(A2.3) [x.sub.t]/[p.sub.t] = [z.sub.t][[??].sub.t]/[[??].sub.t], t
= 0, 1, 2, ...
Note that the foreign exchange market equilibrium condition with
respect to home money is also (A2.3) due to Walras Law.
APPENDIX 3
3.1 Solving the Difference Equation System
To solve the difference equation system,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
we first add them up. which yields
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
or
(A3.1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
We then subtract the second one from the first one, which yields
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
or
(A3.2)[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
From (A3.1) and (A3.2), we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
or
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
3.2 Constant Money Grou'th Nash Equilibrium
From (A3.33 and (A3.4), when both governments follow a constant
growth rate monetary policy, [x.sub.t], = [[??] for all t and
[[??].sub.t = [??] for all t, [c.sup.h.sub.t], and [[??].sup.f.zub.t]
are also constant over time and are, respectively,
(A3.5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Therefore. the constant one-period utility of the home individual
is. in terms of [??] and [??].
(A3.6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Maximizing (A3.6) (which is equivalent to maximizing the lifetime
utility) with respect to [??], the first-order condition is
(A3.7) [??] = ([alpha] + [delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta] - 1)
[beta]/[([alpha](1 - [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2])[theta]].
CASE(I).([alpha] + [delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta] - 1)/[([alpha](1 -
[alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2])[theta]] [less than or equal to] 1.
In this case. the optimal strategy of the home government is [??] =
[beta]. This is a corner solution. By symmetry, the optimal strategy of
the foreign government is [??] = [beta]. So [??] = [??] = [beta] is a
Nash equilibrium.
CASE(II). ([alpha] + [delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta] - 1)/[([alpha](1
- [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2])[theta]] > 1.
In this case, [??] has an interior solution [??] = ([alpha] +
[delta])(1 - [alpha])([theta] - 1)[beta]/[([alpha](1 - [alpha]) +
[[delta].sup.2])[theta]]. Similarly, the optimal strategy of the foreign
government is [??] = ([alpha] + [delta])(1 - [alpha]) ([theta] - 1)
[beta]/[([alpha](1 - [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2])[theta]]. So [??] = [??]
= [??] ([alpha] + [delta]) (1 - [alpha]) ([theta] - 1)
[beta]/[([alpha](1 - [alpha]) + [[delta].sup.2]) [theta]] > [beta] is
a Nash equilibrium.
This completes the proof of Proposition 1.
3.3 Sl,mmetric Cooperative Equilibrium
Now we derive the symmetric cooperative equilibrium of the game
between two honest governments. The problem facing the two cooperative
governments is to choose [??] = [??] all t (hence, [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]) to maximize the one-period
utility (therefore the lifetime utility) of the representative
individual in each country, which is
(A3.8) u([c.sub.t]) [equivalent to] K
[([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]] [c.sup.[alpha] | [delta].sub.t] -
([alpha] + [delta])[alpha] [sup.1][c.sub.t],
where
(A3.9) [c.sub.t] = [Q.sup.1/1 - ([alpha] | [delta]) [[??].sup.-1/1
- ([alpha] | delta])].
It is easy to see u"([c.sub.t]) < 0, and the solution to
u'([c.sub.t]) = 0 is
(A3.10) [c.sup.*] = [alpha]K([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]].sup.1/1
- ([alpha] | [delta]).
So u is increasing in [c.sub.t] for [c.sub.t] [member of] [0,
[c.sup.*]]. On the other hand, the maximum [c.sub.t] achievable is that
when [??] = [beta], which is, according to (A3.9),
(A3.11) [bar.c] = [Q.sup.1/1 - ([alpha] | [delta]) [[beta].sup.-1/1
- ([alpha] | [delta])
= [[alpha]K[([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]] ([theta] -
1)/[theta]].sup.1/1 - ([alpha] | [delta]) < [c.sup.*].
So the symmetric cooperative equilibrium of this game between these
two honest governments is [x.sub.t], = [[??].sub.t] = [beta], t =
0.1.2,....
This completes the proof of Proposition 2.
APPENDIX 4
By the very definition of the autarky plan, to prove that it is a
sustainable equilibrium, we only need to prove that it is each
government's optimal policy to follow this plan if the other
government and private agents all follow the plan.
Taking [x.sub.t = [[??].sub.t] = [bar.x], the home individual would
have (from (A3.5))
[c.sup.h.sub.t] = [Q.sup.1/1 - ([alpha] | [delta]) [bar.x].sup.-1/1
- ([alpha] | [delta]) = [[[([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]]
[alpha][beta]K([theta] - 1)/ ([theta][bar.x])].sup.1/1 - ([alpha] |
[delta]).
On the other hand, [c.sup.h.sub.t] can also be obtained through
Equation (15). which says [c.sup.h.sub.t] = [alpha]([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1][bar.x]/[bar.p], where [bar.p] is the constant (with
respect to t) price level in both countries set by all the firms taking
[x.sub.t] = [[??].sub.t] = [bar.x]. So
(A4.1) [bar.p] - [alpha][bar.x][(alpha] + delta]).sup.-1]]
[[([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]]([theta] - 1)
[alpha][beta]K/([theta][bar.x])].sup.1/1 - ([alpha] | [delta]].
Given [bar.p] as above, and [[??].sub.t] = [bar.x] for all t, we
want to establish that [x.sub.t] = [bar.x] for all t maximizes the
one-period utility (hence the lifetime utility) of the home individual
(A4.2) [u.sup.h.sub.t] = [([delta]/[alpha]).sup.[delta]] K
[(c.sup.h.sub.t]).sup.[alpha]][([[??].sup.f.sub.t]).sup.[delta]] -
([alpha] + [delta])[[alpha].sup.-1][c.sup.h.sub.t],
where [c.sup.h.sub.t] = [alpha][([alpha] + [delta]).sup.-1]
[x.sub.t]/[bar.p] and [[??].sup.f.sub.t] = [alpha][([alpha] +
[delta]).sup.-1]] [bar.x]/bar.p] according to Equations (15) and (21).
It is easy to see [[partial derivative].sup.2] [u.sup.h.sub.t] /
[partial derivative][x.sup.2.sub.t] < 0, and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (A4.3)
which, at [x.sub.t] = [bar.x], has a value of
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (A4.4)
So as long as [alpha][theta][bar.x]/[([alpha] +
[delta])[beta]([theta] - 1)]>1, [x.sub.t], = [bar.x] for all t would
be the home government's optimal policy if the other government and
private agents follow the autarky plan.
APPENDIX 5
Let [alpha] in Condition (49) be [alpha] + [delta] so that
parameters in the two models are comparable. Then, Condition (49)
becomes
(A5.1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
To prove that Condition (48) is weaker than Condition (A5.1), it is
equivalent to show that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A5.2)
for all [alpha] > 0, [delta] > 0, [alpha] + [delta] < l,
and
(A5.3) [alpha][theta]/[([alpha] + [delta])([theta] - 1)] > 1
(i.e., [theta] < 1 + [alpha]/[delta], the Case (11)
requirement).
Note that the left side of (A5.2) is strictly decreasing in
[theta]/([theta] - 1). Therefore, to show that (A5.2) holds for all
[theta]/([theta] - 1) that satisfy (A5.3), it is sufficient to show that
it holds when [theta]/([theta]- 1) = ([alpha] + [delta])/[alpha], or
(A5.4) [[[alpha]/([alpha] + [delta])].sup.[alpha] | [delta]/1 -
([alpha] | [delta])] (1 - [alpha]) [less than or equal to] 1 - ([alpha]
+ [delta]).
It can be easily checked by signing the first-order derivative that
the left side of(A5.4) is increasing in [alpha] while holding [alpha] +
[delta] fixed. Therefore, to show (A5.4) holds, it is sufficient to show
that it holds as a increasingly approaches [alpha] + [delta], which is 1
- ([alpha] + [delta]) [less than or equal to] 1 - ([alpha] + [delta]), a
true statement.
ABBREVIATIONS
BC: Budget Constraint
CES: Constant Elasticity of Substitution
CIA: Cash-In-Advance
doi:101111/j.1465-7295.2007.00043.x
REFERENCES
Abreu, D. "On the Theory of Infinitely Repeated Games with
Discounting." Econometrica, 56, 1988, 383-96.
Barro, R. J., and D. B. Gordon. "Rules, Discretion, and
Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy." Journal of Monetary
Economics, 12, 1983, 101-21.
Blackburn, K., and M. Christensen, "Monetary Policy and Policy
Credibility: Theories and Evidence." Journal of Economic
Literature, 27, 1989, 1-45.
Calvo, G. A. "'Optimal Seigniorage from Money Creation:
An Analysis in Terms of the Optimal Balance of Payments Deficit
Problem.'" Journal of Monetary Economics, 4, 1978, 503-17.
Canzoneri, M. B., and D. W. Henderson. Monetary Policy in
Interdependent Economies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991.
Chari, V. V., and P. J. Kehoe. "Sustainable Plans."
Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1990, 783-802.
Cubitt, R. P. "Welfare and Monetary Precommitment in an
Economy with Menu Costs and Unionized Wage Setting." Bulletin of
Economic Research, 45, 1993, 7-17.
Cukierman, A., and A. Drazen. "Do Distortionary Taxes Induce Policies Biased Towards Inflation? A Microeconomic Analysis.
"Working paper, Foerder Institute, Tel-Aviv University, 1988.
Dixit, A. K., and J. E. Stiglitz. "Monopolistic Competition
and Optimal Product Diversity." American Economic Review, 67, 1977,
297-308.
Henderson, D. W., and N. Zhu. "Uncertainty and the Choice of
Instruments in a Two-Country Monetary-Policy Game." Open Economies
Review, 1, 1990, 39-65.
Ireland, P. N. "The Role of Countercyclical Monetary
Policy." Journal of Political Economy 104, 1996, 704-23.
--. "Sustainable Monetary Policies." Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 22, 1997, 87-108.
Jansen, D. W., L. Liu, and M. J. Weng. "Sustainable Equilibria
in an International Monetary Policy Game." Private Enterprise
Research Center Working Paper No. 9921, Texas A&M University, 1999.
Jensen, H. "Credibility of Optimal Monetary Delegation."
American Economic Review, 87, 1997, 911-20.
Kehoe, P. J. "Policy Cooperation among Benevolent Governments
May Be Undesirable." Review of Economic Studies, 56, 1989, 289-96.
Kimbrough, K. P. "Optimal Monetary Policies and Policy
Interdependence in the World Economy." Journal of International
Money and Finance, 12. 1993, 227-48.
Kydland, F. E., and E. C. Prescott. "Rules Rather than
Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans." Journal of
Political Economy, 85, 1977, 473-91.
Rogoff, K. "Can International Monetary Policy Coordination be
Counterproductive?" Journal of International Economics, 18, 1985,
199-217.
--. "Reputation, Coordination, and Monetary Policy," in
Modern Business Cycle Theory. edited by R. J. Barro. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, 1989, 89-96.
Rotemberg, J. J. "The New Keynesian Microfoundations," in
NBER Macroeconomics Annual, edited by S. Fischer. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1987, 69-104.
Rotemberg, J. J., and M. Woodford. "Oligopolistic Pricing and
the Effects of Aggregate Demand on Economic Activity." Journal of
Political Economy, 100, 1992, 1153-207.
Svensson, L. E. O. "Sticky Goods Prices, Flexible Asset
Prices, Monopolistic Competition, and Monetary Policy." Review of
Economic Studies, 53, 1986, 385-405.
Weng, M. J. "International Monetary Policy Game." Ph.D.
dissertation, Texas A&M University, 1996.
(1.) The setup of the model in this section was outlined in Weng
(1996). Antecedents for the closed-economy version of this model include
Svensson (1986) and Rotemberg (1987).
(2.) In the international monetary game literature, the assumption
of symmetric economies is often made for technical convenience. For
example, Canzoneri and Henderson (1991) presented several models of
monetary interaction among sovereign governments that make use of that
assumption. With such a symmetric structure, the focus is the
externality of one government's monetary policy on the other and
its efficiency implications.
(3.) To focus on a firm's pricing decision, we have suppressed the other arguments in the demand function for the firm's product.
So only its own price is explicitly left as an argument.
(4.) The restriction [theta] > 1 is required for the existence
of equilibria with monopolistically competitive firms. This restriction
was first imposed for a monopolistic competition model by Dixit and
Stiglitz (1977) and was also used by Ireland (1997).
(5.) Note that if [p.sub.t](i) = [[bar.p].sub.t] for all i, then
[p.sub.t] = [[bar.p].sub.t]. The same property is shared by
[[??].sub.t].
(6.) Note that these Nash equilibria are the unique "constant
money growth" Nash equilibria under respective conditions on
parameters. There may well be other Nash equilibria that are not
featured by a constant money growth rate for each government.
(7.) Increasing [delta] while holding [alpha] + [delta] constant
increases the relative weight of nondomestic goods in the utility
function without changing the degree of concavity (the risk attitude) of
the utility function itself.
(8.) See the working paper version of this article for a more
formal definition of sustainable equilibrium.
(9.) The Abreu-Chari-Kehoe technique is used to fully characterize
the sustainable outcomes, and from there, to derive the condition for
the Friedman rule to be sustainable, in the working paper version of
this article, which is available upon request.
(10.) For our article as well as in Kehoe (1989), counterproductive
cooperation between governments occurs under the assumption that the
governments are benevolent. This is in contrast to Rogoff (1985), who
has counterproductive cooperation but in a model in which the objective
functions of governments and citizens do not coincide.
DENNIS W. JANSEN, LIQUN LIU, and MING-JANG WENG *
* This is a revised version of our earlier working paper (see
Jansen, Liu, and Weng 1999) and springs from a topic first broached in
Weng (1996). We thank Jon Faust, several referees, and participants of
the Macro/Monetary Economics Workshop at Texas A&M University for
their comments.
Jansen. Professor, Department of Economics, Texas A&M
University, 4228 TAMU, College Station, TX 77843-4228. Phone
1-979-845-7375, Fax 1-979-847-8757, E-mail d-jansen@tamu.edu
Liu: Research Scientist, Private Enterprise Research Center, Texas
A&M University, 4231 TAMU, College Station, TX 77843-4231. Phone
1-979-845-7723, Fax 1-979-845-6636, E-mail lliu@tamu.edu
Weng: Associate Professor, Department of Applied Economics,
National University of Kaohsiung, No. 700 Kaohsiung University Road,
Kaohsiung 811, Taiwan. Phone 011-886-7-5919186, Fax 011-886-7-5919320,
E-mail mjweng@nuk.edu.tw