首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月29日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:A human capital model of the effects of ability and family background on optimal schooling levels.
  • 作者:Regan, Tracy L. ; Oaxaca, Ronald L. ; Burghardt, Galen
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2007
  • 期号:October
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:Human capital investments are of wide ranging interest because they can be used to explain income disparities across people, geography, and time. According to Becker (1962), human capital investments are activities that affect future real income streams through the embedding of resources in people. Examples include schooling, on-the-job training (OJT), migration, job search, that is, anything that increases one's stock of human capital or the value of one's existing stock. A vast literature supports the social and intellectual interest in income inequality, primarily attributed to differing schooling levels. Schooling is a unique type of investment in that it affects not only current consumption but also future earnings potential as well. Optimizing individuals choose to invest in schooling until their marginal rate of return equals their discounting rate of interest. Equivalently, they choose their schooling levels so as to maximize their expected (discounted) future earnings stream.
  • 关键词:Human capital

A human capital model of the effects of ability and family background on optimal schooling levels.


Regan, Tracy L. ; Oaxaca, Ronald L. ; Burghardt, Galen 等


I. INTRODUCTION

Human capital investments are of wide ranging interest because they can be used to explain income disparities across people, geography, and time. According to Becker (1962), human capital investments are activities that affect future real income streams through the embedding of resources in people. Examples include schooling, on-the-job training (OJT), migration, job search, that is, anything that increases one's stock of human capital or the value of one's existing stock. A vast literature supports the social and intellectual interest in income inequality, primarily attributed to differing schooling levels. Schooling is a unique type of investment in that it affects not only current consumption but also future earnings potential as well. Optimizing individuals choose to invest in schooling until their marginal rate of return equals their discounting rate of interest. Equivalently, they choose their schooling levels so as to maximize their expected (discounted) future earnings stream.

This paper specifies and estimates a human capital model that is based on individual wealth maximization along the lines of the original Austrian problem (Blaug, 1962, pp. 506-507). We use an earnings-schooling relationship to identify individual marginal rates of return to schooling and discounting rates of interest. From these, we can identify and estimate supply and demand functions for schooling investment. In this framework, the emphasis on rates of return to schooling is misplaced. Emphasis is properly placed on the optimal level of schooling investment. We ultimately arrive at an optimal level of schooling equation that incorporates permanent family income, family size, and ability. Our estimation strategy borrows from Mincer (1974) and involves disaggregating a sample of white males into 1-yr full-time equivalent (FTE) work experience cohorts for 1985 1989. We estimate a log earnings equation to identify the work experience cohort for whom the estimated residual standard error (SEE) is minimized as well as three other model selection criteria, namely the Akaike's information criterion (AIC), the Schwarz criterion (SC), and Amemiya's prediction criterion (PC). This procedure should help reduce the biases associated with omitted variables, measurement error, and "discount rate." Once identified, the remaining estimation proceeds with the "overtaking" work experience cohort. We employ the following estimation strategies in this paper: ordinary least squares (OLS), nonlinear seemingly unrelated regressions/nonlinear OLS (NLSUR/ NLOLS), and two-stage least squares.

The paper is organized as follows: Section II provides the background and literature review. Section III discusses the conceptual framework that underlies the analysis. Section IV discusses the data used in the analysis. Section V presents the results, while Section VI discusses them and provides alternative estimation strategies as well. Finally, Section VII concludes.

II. BACKGROUND AND LITERATURE REVIEW

A substantial portion of the economics literature has been devoted to studying human capital investments and the economic rates of return, particularly in relation to education. Researchers have exploited the models and theories developed by Mincer (1974) and Becket (1962) in their attempts to obtain better estimates of the rates of return.

A variety of modifications to the traditional Mincerian log earnings regression endeavor to correct the potential measurement error bias and omitted variables bias that afflict OLS estimates. Early work addressing the OLS bias includes Griliches (1976, 1977). Behrman and Birdsall (1983), like Card and Krueger (1992), incorporate a quality of schooling variable into the log earnings regression to correct the omitted variables bias, while Altonji and Dunn (1996), Ashenfelter and Zimmerman (1997), Lang and Ruud (1986), and Agnarsson and Carlin (2002) instead include a family background variable. The twins-based study of Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994) not only addresses the omitted variables bias but also addresses measurement error in schooling through the creative use of both the self-and the twin-reported education levels. (1) While Ashenfelter and Krueger's (1994) large, measurement error-adjusted rates of return to education (i.e., 12%-16%) are now considered an anomaly of the data, their paper laid the foundation for subsequent work (e.g., Ashenfelter and Rouse, 1998; Rouse, 1999; Neumark, 1999; Behrman and Rosenzweig, 1999). Later work has uncovered rates of return (e.g., 9%) that are more reasonable and consistent with the earlier findings (e.g., Willis and Rosen, 1979). The consensus reached by researchers is that omitted variables bias the rates of return upward, whereas measurement error in schooling biases the rates downward. While fixed effects or instrumental variables (IV) are often used to remedy such problems, Griliches (1979) warns that first differencing can exacerbate measurement error in schooling. Card (1995) provides a survey of this work.

In addition to the biases mentioned above, a recent literature has investigated another source of bias in human capital models, specifically that stemming from the heterogeneity in students' access to credit markets for educational decisions. Lang (1993) and Card (1995, 2000) refer to this bias as "discount rate bias." They argue that this bias can help explain the large IV estimates of the rates of return to schooling. Using data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979 (NLSY79), Cameron and Taber (2004) find no evidence of credit constraints when they instrument schooling with foregone earnings and the direct costs of schooling. Kling (2001) adopts a Becker (1975) supply and demand model of schooling to examine the types of biases summarized by Card (1995). Generally speaking, Kling (2001) argues that the choice of instrument for schooling may have effects that differ by individuals/groups. IV estimates of rates of return to schooling are interpreted as weighted averages of individual-specific causal effects.

This paper takes a step back and abstracts from some of the issues occupying researchers' attention in recent years. We return to Mincer's (1974) earlier work where he introduces the notion of an overtaking year of work experience in which an individual's observed earnings are most reflective of his investment in school (and innate ability). According to Becker (1962), human capital investments lower observed earnings in the early part of one's working life because observed earnings are net of the costs of investment. However, as an individual ages, his observed earnings rise as he reaps the benefits of the investments. (2) At the overtaking year of work experience, observed earnings are equal to earnings based on schooling (and ability). The distortion from postschooling investments (e.g., OJT) is minimized because the returns on an individual's prior OJT investment equal the cost of current OJT investment. Thus, an individual's earnings at this point provide the best test of the simple schooling model.

Murphy and Welch (1990) investigate the (in)appropriateness of the quadratic experience term in Mincer's (1974) human capital earnings function. Murphy and Welch (1990) is one of the few studies that address the quadratic experience term; much of the prior research was concerned with the form of the dependent variable. Specifically, they ask how do wages vary with age and consider the confounding effects of experience on earnings. Their empirical findings lend support for Mincer's (1974) emphasis on experience, not age. They note that the severity of problems associated with the quadratic term will depend on how much the variables of interest vary within the experience levels.

III. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK

We posit the existence of an earnings transformation function for the overtaking work experience cohort and define it as follows: (3,4)

(1) Y = F(S,A).

This function relates an individual's annual earnings, Y, to his years of schooling, S, and to his natural ability, A. For the earnings function to exhibit the conventional positive but diminishing marginal returns to schooling and positive returns to ability, we need the following inequalities to be satisfied:

(2) [F.sub.s], [F.sub.A] > 0 and [F.sub.SS] < 0.

One might also expect more able people to reap greater returns to schooling: (5)

(3) [F.sub.SA] = [F.sub.AS] > 0.

In the analysis that follows, it is more convenient to think of the earnings transformation function in its log form:

(4) lnY = ln F(S,A).

Let the marginal rate of return to schooling, r, be defined as follows:

(5) r = [differential] ln F(S,A)/[differential]S.

In order for the marginal rate of return to schooling to increase with ability (and hence for the demand for schooling to increase with ability), we need the following inequality to be satisfied:

(6) [FF.sub.SA] > [F.sub.A][F.sub.s].

(See the Appendix for the proof.) Next, we assume that all relevant costs are foregone earnings and that an individual seeks to maximize the present value of his lifetime earnings over an infinite horizon subject to the constraint imposed by Equation (1). (6) Formally, we can represent an individual's maximization problem as:

(7) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Subject to Y = F(S, A)

where V is the present value of lifetime earnings, i is a fixed discounting rate of interest, and t is the index of integration. We assume that there are no borrowing constraints. Work by Lang (1993), Card (1995, 2000), and Cameron and Taber (2004) supports this assumption.

We simplify the present value of lifetime earnings expressed in Equation (7) and take the log of the resulting expression to obtain:

(8) lnV = lnY - iS - lni.

Taking derivatives with respect to S, we arrive at the following first-order condition:

(9) r = i.

Hence, the optimal level of schooling for an individual occurs at the point where his marginal rate of return to schooling exactly equals his discounting rate of interest as noted by Becker (1962).

The above analysis can be couched in a supply and demand framework. Taking the derivative of the log transformation function as defined in Equation (4) with respect to schooling yields an individual's inverse demand function for schooling,

(10) r = r(S,A),

which is equivalently expressed as:

[S.sup.d] = [s.sup.d](i,A),

where [S.sup.d] is the level of schooling demanded at each discounting rate of interest for an individual with a given (fixed) ability level A.

An individual's supply function for schooling investment can be derived using the present value function as defined in Equation (8). Simple manipulation of this expression yields:

(11) lnY = ln(iV) +iS.

Differentiating this expression with respect to S, for a given V, yields i which indexes an individual's supply curve thereby establishing the relationship between the supply of schooling and the discounting rate of interest. An individual's discounting rate of interest, i, is uniquely fixed and does not vary with the level of schooling. However, since i can also be interpreted as the marginal opportunity cost of an additional year of school, i can vary across individuals. For example, the discounting rate of interest would likely be higher for children from poorer families than that for children from wealthier families. The same could be said of children from larger families as compared to children from smaller families. Hence, we express i as a function of an individual's family characteristics:

(12) i = i(X),

where X denotes a vector of family background variables. In the analysis, these include family size and permanent family income. (7) There are a number of models where family background is central to the analysis. At the present, we have chosen to take a parsimonious view and choose to incorporate family background through i.

By combining Equations (9), (10), and (12), the optimal level of schooling, [S.sup.*], is obtained as;

(13) [S.sup.*] = f(X,A).

In our case, the optimal level of schooling can be graphically illustrated using a supply and demand framework and a framework involving the log earnings functions. Becker and Chiswick (1966) give a very general discussion of how human capital investment can be nested in the context of a supply-and demand-curve analysis. This can be seen in Figure 1. The top graph relates the log earnings transformation function to the log earnings present value functions as defined in Equation (11). The log earnings transformation function is a concave curve reflecting the positive but diminishing marginal returns to schooling. The log earnings iso-present value functions are represented by a set of parallel lines relating In Y and S at a given i. [S.sup.*] occurs at the point of tangency between these two curves--the point at which discounted lifetime earnings are maximized. Similarly, the bottom graph relates the downward sloping demand function, as defined in Equation (10), to the infinitely elastic supply curve, as defined in Equation (12). The intersection of these two curves corresponds to the point [S.sup.*] where the discounting rate of interest exactly equals the marginal rate of return to schooling (i.e., the equilibrium as defined in Equation (9)). These two frameworks graphically establish the solution to the maximization problem as defined in Equation (7).

Figure 2 allows A and i to vary across individuals. Fitting a line through the set of tangency points in the top graph parallels the development of Mincer's (1974) simple schooling model:

(14) ln[Y.sub.j] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][S.sub.j] + [u.sub.j],

for individual j. (8)

A stochastic approximation to the transformation function as defined in Equation (4) is:

(15) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

where [u.sub.1] is iid(0, [[sigma].sub.1.sup.2]). This is a standard human capital functional form that is consistent with the literature. To maintain the restrictions corresponding to Equations (2) and (3), we require:

(16) [[beta].sub.1], [[beta].sub.2], [[beta].sub.4] > 0 and [[beta].sub.3], < 0.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Differentiating Equation (15) with respect to S yields the schooling investment demand function:

(17) [r.sub.j] = [[beta].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.2][A.sub.j] + 2[[beta].sub.3][S.sub.j].

We specify the schooling investment supply function to be a linear function of various family background variables. Consider:

(18) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],

where [S.sub.f] is father's schooling, [S.sub.m] is mother's schooling, N is family size, and [u.sub.2] is iid N(0, [[sigma].sub.2.sup.2]). Permanent family income is proxied with the schooling levels of an individual's parents. (9) So as to not lose observations and to maintain a constant sample size across regressions for the NLSUR estimations, we assigned an education level of "0" yr for any respondent's parent whose education level was missing and created dummy variables to indicate whether or not such a value was imposed. (10) Hence, [DVS.sub.f(m)] takes on a value of "1" if we replaced a missing value for the respondent's father's (mother's) education level with a "0."

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

The coefficients in Equation (18) are nicely interpreted. [[theta].sub.1] and [[theta].sub.2] capture the pure wealth effects of family income on an individual's discounting rate of interest. We would expect these two coefficients to be negative because an individual's discounting rate of interest (marginal opportunity cost of an additional year of schooling) decreases with his family wealth (i.e., the individual has the luxury to postpone earnings for more schooling). It is intended that [[theta].sub.3] captures the effect of family wealth on potential financial aid. Since financial aid offices base their decisions purely on family wealth, not on individual parental contributions, we sum these two variables together and expect their common parameter, [[theta].sub.3], to be positive. While there are no theoretical predictions concerning the expected sign on [[theta].sub.4] or [[theta].sub.5], a positive estimate clearly means that an individual's discounting rate of interest is higher once we have made the imputation for a missing level of parental schooling. Children from wealthier families have a decreased likelihood of receiving financial aid which raises their discounting rate of interest. The effects of family size on an individual's marginal opportunity cost of an additional year of schooling can be decomposed into two separate effects: [[theta].sub.6] captures the pure income effect of family size and [[theta].sub.7] captures the indirect effect via financial aid considerations. We would expect [[theta].sub.6] to be positive because individuals from larger families likely have increased opportunity costs to additional schooling. However, the larger a family, the more widely the (financial) resources are spread and hence the greater the opportunity for financial aid assistance. Thus, [[theta].sub.7] would be negative.

Of course, the individual coefficients are not identified in the above specification, so we collect terms to arrive at:

(19) [i.sub.j] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][S.sub.fj] + [[alpha].sub.2][S.sub.mj] + [[alpha].sub.3][DVS.sub.fj] + [[alpha].sub.4][DVS.sub.mj] + [[alpha].sub.5][N.sub.j] + [u.sub.2j],

where:

(20) [[alpha].sub.1] = [[theta].sub.1] + [[theta].sub.3], [[alpha].sub.2] = [[theta].sub.2] + [[theta].sub.3],

and

[[alpha].sub.5] = [[theta].sub.6] + [[theta].sub.7].

The stochastic approximation to Equation (12) is a simple linear model that identifies the differential parental contributions on wealth effects, aside from the financial aid effects since [[alpha].sub.1] - [[alpha].sub.2] = [[theta].sub.1] - [[theta].sub.2]. We recognize that if family size is endogenous in the discounting rate of interest (supply equation), this will ultimately lead to endogeneity of family size in the reduced-form schooling equation below. However, we do not model family fertility decisions because of a desire to focus on the explanatory power of a conceptually straightforward Beckerian schooling demand and supply framework.

The reduced-form optimal level of schooling equation is obtained by substituting Equations (17) and (19) into the individual-specific equilibrium condition:

(21) [r.sub.j] = [i.sub.j].

Solving for S:

(22) [S.sub.j] = [[gamma].sub.0] + [[gamma].sub.1][S.sub.fj] + [[gamma].sub.2][S.sub.mj] + [[gamma].sub.3][DVS.sub.fj] + [[gamma].sub.4][DVS.sub.mj] + [[gamma].sub.5][N.sub.j] + [[gamma].sub.6][A.sub.j] + [u.sub.3j],

where:

(23) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],

and

[[sigma].sup.2.sub.3] = [[sigma].sup.2.sub.2]/4[[beta].sup.2.sub.3].

The coefficients' signs establish the net effect of the direct and indirect effects of wealth on schooling. However, [[gamma].sub.6] can be unambiguously signed since more able people reap greater rewards from increased schooling levels. Thus, [[gamma].sub.6] should be positive.

Because an individual's discounting rate of interest and marginal rate of return to schooling are not directly observable, they must be estimated in order to identify the supply and demand functions. In determining an individual's marginal rate of return to schooling, [[??].sub.j], we use the estimated parameters [[??].sub.1], [[??].sub.2], and [[??].sub.3] obtained from OLS estimation of Equation (15). Specifically, [[??].sub.j] = [[??].sub.1] + [[??].sub.1][[??].sub.3][S.sub.j] + Imposing the equilibrium condition as defined in Equation (21) generates an estimated discounting rate of interest, [[??].sub.j], so that [[??].sub.j] = [[??].sub.j] We use these estimated marginal rates of return and discounting rates of interest as the dependent variables in the demand of and supply for schooling investment functions, respectively. Note that Equation (19) is estimated explicitly using [[??].sub.j]. as the dependent variable and Equation (17) is directly constructed from the OLS estimates of Equation (15).

Our empirical strategy follows Mincer's (1974) estimation of the simple schooling model of Equation (14). Mincer's (1974) post-schooling investment model relates earnings to experience and education. Arguably, one might be concerned about potential endogeneity with work experience in a postschooling investment regression. This problem should be mitigated with Mincer's (1974) notion of an overtaking year of work experience in which an individual's observed earnings are most reflective of his investment in school (and innate ability). Hence, experience is no longer a regressor in the log earnings equation. At the point of overtaking, the distortion from postschooling investments (OJT) is minimized since observed earnings approximate the earnings based on schooling (and ability) alone.

The empirical implementation involves stratifying our sample into 1-yr FTE work experience cohorts and running Equation (15) separately for each cohort. This strategy should at least reduce, if not entirely eliminate, the biases typically plaguing log earnings models. Such a procedure allows for a full interaction of each explanatory variable with experience, thus minimizing the aforementioned bias. (11) Once the overtaking cohort is identified, based on a series of goodness-of-fit measures, Equations (17), (19), and (22) are estimated. (12)

Goodness-of-Fit Measures

To identify the overtaking year of work experience, we considered five separate "goodness-of-fit" measures for the model described in Equation (15). The most typical and singular way of gauging the "goodness of fit" of an OLS regression is the [R.sup.2] measure. Although the number of regressors in Equation (15) does not vary, the degrees of freedom do vary because sample sizes differ for each experience cohort. The [[bar.R].sup.2] measure adjusts for degrees of freedom, but arguably even this measure does not impose a harsh enough penalty for the loss in degrees of freedom. The next three measures attempt to correct this problem by minimizing the mean-squared error of prediction (Greene, 2000; Kennedy, 1998; Maddala, 2001; Judge et al., 1988).

PC seeks to minimize:

(24) PC = SSE(1 + k/N)/(N - k) (1 + k/N), [approximately equal to] [[??].sup.2.sub.1](1 + k/N),

where SSE denotes the total sum of squared errors, k is the number of regressors (including the constant term), N refers to the sample size, and [[??].sup.2.sub.1] is the estimated variance of [u.sub.1].

AIC minimizes:

(25) AIC = ln(SSE/N) + 2k/N [approximately equal to] ln([[??].sup.2.sub.1]) + 2k/N,

while the SC seeks to minimize:

(26) SC = ln(SSE/N) + k ln(X)/X [approximately equal to] ln([[??].sup.2.sub.1]) + k ln(N)/N.

The PC, AIC, and SC criteria are usually nested in discussions of regressor selection. Typically, researchers test different models using the same data set. We, however, test a common model using different samples to identify the work experience cohort for which the schooling model best explains earnings.

The last "goodness-of-fit" measure we consider is the estimated standard error of the regression. We seek to minimize the estimated residual variance:

(27) [[??].sup.2.sub.1] = SSE/(N - k),

(or alternatively its square root, SEE).

IV. DATA

The data used in this study are from the NLSY79. The NLSY79 consists of 12,686 young men and women living in the United States who were between the ages of 14 and 22 when the first survey was conducted in 1979.

The demographic variables were collected from the 1979 interview. We limit our analysis to white males who are not enrolled in school, currently or during the remainder of the survey, and who earn at least $500/yr in nominal terms. We also omit anyone who attended school after 1989 to ensure that the wages we observe are truly reflective of the final schooling choices. (13) Measures of a respondent's family background/income level include the family size and the highest grade completed by the mother and the father. The NLSY79 provides three measures of a respondent's ability--the intelligence quotient (IQ), the knowledge of the world of work, and the armed forces qualification test (AFQT). Following most of the literature, we focus on the AFQT measure. For a very early discussion of the use of AFQT in the log earnings function, see Griliches and Mason (1972).

The dependent variable in the log earnings regression is the log of a respondent's total income from wages and salary in the respective year. Using the consumer price index for all urban consumers, as published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, we deflated the income figures and express them in terms of 1985 dollars.

The variables used in the construction of the work experience measures were collected from the supplementary NLSY79 work history file. Due to this detailed collection of actual work experience, we do not have to use less precise, potential work experience measures. We calculate a respondent's FTE work experience for a given year by summing the hours worked in that and all prior years (since 1979) and then divide through by 2,080 (40 h/wk x 52 wk/yr). Taking account of the fact that many of our respondents were older than age 18 (the usual age that one graduates from high school in the United States) and had potentially been working for several years prior to the first survey, we constructed a variable to approximate their work experience prior to 1979. This variable is calculated as follows:

(28) FTE work [experience.sub.prior to 1979] = ([age.sub.1979] - [schooling.sub.1979] - 6) x (work [experience.sub.1979]/2,080).

\\\\\ This provides us with a measure of FTE work experience. (14)

Like Mincer (1974), we stratified our sample into 1-yr FTE work experience cohorts for 1985-1989. (15) Equation (15) is estimated separately for each work experience cohort, which allows for work experience to fully interact with each coefficient. The earnings data in the model defined by Equations (15), (17), (19), and (22) reflect not only ability and schooling investment decisions but postschooling investments (e.g., work experience, OJT) as well. Unfortunately, the NLSY79 does not provide adequate information to capture school quality. Ignoring the potential correlation between schooling and work experience in cross-sectional rate of return to schooling models biases OLS. By stratifying our sample into work experience cohorts, we purge the model of any postschooling investment decisions. Thus, there exists an overtaking year in which an individual's earnings are most reflective of his natural ability and schooling levels alone. We reasonably assume that this overtaking year varies across individuals, even within a given work experience cohort. Thus, we stratify our sample into 1-yr FTE work experience cohorts for 19851989 to best identify the group whose earnings are on average free of OJT effects.

V. ESTIMATION AND RESULTS

As mentioned above, our statistical estimation pertains to white males who nominally earned at least $500 for a given survey year and who were not enrolled in school currently or any time after 1989. Table 1 provides the descriptive statistics for each variable used in the analysis, when such information is available. On average, our respondents are 18.3 yr old and have the equivalent of a high school education while their parent(s) appear to have completed their junior year of high school. The average household size is 3.8 persons.

A. Sample Stratification

As was previously mentioned, we stratified our sample into 1-yr FTE intervals of work experience for 1985-1989. Table 2 lists the number of people in each respective cohort and the corresponding percentage of the sample they comprise. The procedure for constructing the FTE work experience intervals worked as follows: For example, in constructing the 1-yr work experience cohort, we included individuals for whom we calculated having between 1 (inclusive) and 2 (not inclusive) years of work experience at any time between 1985 and 1989. Below, we describe how the experience calculations were done. In using such a decision rule, we encountered the possibility of individuals having, say, 1.2 yr of work experience in 1985 and 1.9 yr of work experience calculated for 1986. To ensure that an individual entered a particular work experience cohort only once, we manually identified those individuals who were double or even triple counted. For these individuals, we chose to use the most recent year in which their work experience fell within the specified range. Once this year was identified, we chose the individual's corresponding education and income levels. Of course, individuals can and do appear in more than one experience cohort over the period 1985-1989.

We performed similar procedures for all other relevant work experience cohorts and separately estimated the log earnings function specified in Equation (15) for each cohort, excluding ability as a separate regressor. Including ability as an independent regressor in Equation (15), as is often the standard practice, does not affect the overall fit of the model and hence our estimate of the overtaking cohort. In addition, the estimated coefficient on linear ability is never statistically significant except for the 2-yr cohort. For this cohort, only linear ability and linear schooling achieve statistical significance. Consequently, in the log earnings regressions that follow, we assume [[beta].sub.4] = 0. (16)

B. Thirteen-Yr Work Experience Cohort

As can be seen from Table 3, the AIC, SC, PC, and SEE are minimized for the 13-yr work experience cohort, while the [R.sup.2] is maximized for the 14-yr cohort. The 13-yr work experience cohort includes a larger sample, and the estimated coefficients are statistically significant and of the expected signs. While the estimated coefficients from the 14-yr work experience cohort are of the appropriate signs, the only statistically significant coefficient (at the 10% level) is the schooling-ability interaction term. Thus, our preferred estimate of the overtaking year is 13 FTE years of work experience.

As was previously noted, the AIC, SC, and PC criteria are typically nested in discussions of regressor selection. We, however, employ such criteria to determine which cohort (of varying sample sizes) best fits our proposed log earnings functional form (where the number of regressors is fixed). Thus, the differing degrees of freedom across our regressions are due to variations in the sample size as opposed to the number of explanatory variables. Holding other factors constant (i.e., [[??].sup.2.sup.1]), the AIC, SC, and PC criteria would favor larger samples. Thus, the use of such criteria would bias our results toward finding earlier work experience cohorts as the overtaking year(s). Given that we estimate the overtaking year to be as high as 13 FTE years of work experience, we believe the bias to be negligible.

Table 4 lists the descriptive statistics for the 13-yr work experience cohort. On average, the overtaking cohort is 28.7 yr old (at any point between 1985 and 1989) and earns a real (nominal) annual income of $19,594.42 ($25,417.10). The respondents have been out of school for 11.3 yr after completing their junior year of high school. Many of these individuals are either working overtime or are multiple-job holders because the average experience level is 13.5 yr. The NLSY79 reports the respondent's mother (father) completing 10.6 (10.1) yr of schooling on average. However, including zero for missing values lowers the average level by 1 yr. The mean family size is 3.7 persons.

The remainder of the estimation will be based on the 13-yr overtaking cohort. Table 5, Column 2, lists the OLS results for Equation (15). As theory predicts, the coefficients on schooling and the schooling-ability interaction are positive, while schooling squared is negative. The estimates are statistically significant.

Table 5, Column 1, lists the results from the simple schooling model (Equation (14)). As might be expected when ability is not controlled for, the rate of return to schooling estimated from the simple schooling model is greater than that estimated directly from Equation (15). The simple schooling model predicts a rate of return of 14%, while the estimates from Equation (15) suggest a 9.7% rate of return.

The results from the schooling investment demand function are presented in Table 5, Column 3. Because the coefficients on the demand function are taken directly from Equation (15), the coefficient on ability is positive and that on schooling is negative.

VI. ESTIMATION STRATEGIES

A. Unrestricted/OLS

Reduced-Form Optimal Level of Schooling. The initial estimation strategies are based on the assumption that A is uncorrelated with [u.sub.1] and [u.sub.3] (and hence [u.sub.2]) and that S is also uncorrelated with [u.sub.1]. The first estimation strategy involves the direct estimation of the schooling investment supply function (Equation (19)) by OLS. Since our estimation procedure constrains the model to be in equilibrium, the marginal rates of return calculated from Equation (15) are directly imposed as the dependent variable for Equation (19) (i.e., the discounting rates of interest). Table 5, Column 4, lists these results. The negative coefficient estimates on the permanent family income proxies, the parental education levels, suggest that children from wealthier families have lower discounting rates of interest. This implies that the pure wealth effects of increased parental schooling levels outweigh the indirect effects that family wealth has on the likelihood of receiving financial aid. The estimated coefficients on the parental missing schooling dummies are negative but only statistically significant for the father. Thus, the marginal opportunity cost of an additional year of schooling is lower for those whose father's education level is missing. The coefficient estimate on family size is negative but statistically insignificant which implies that the pure wealth effects of family size completely offset the indirect wealth effects on financial aid. Alternatively, it could be the case that family size has no effect on the discounting rate of interest or that the parameter is imprecisely estimated. Shea (2000) finds that changes in parents' income due to luck have a negligible impact on their children's human capital except when the father has a low level of schooling.

The estimated coefficients from Equations (15) and (19), corresponding to Columns 2 and 4 in Table 5, are used to derive the parameters in Equation (22). Thus:

(29) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],

and

[[??].sup.2.sub.3] = [[??].sup.2.sub.2]/4[[??].sup.2.sub.3].

Table 5, Column 7, lists these results. The standard errors, hence the t-statistics, have been computed using the delta method (Greene, 2000). It is assumed that cov([??], [??]) [approximately equal to] 0. The optimal level of schooling is higher for more able individuals from wealthier families. The optimal level of schooling based on these coefficients for this work experience cohort is 11.4 yr.

Derived Supply Equation. The second estimation strategy directly estimates the log earnings Equation (15) and the optimal level of schooling reduced-form Equation (23)--the two equations in which we observe the dependent variable--by OLS. We can derive consistent estimators of the parameters in the supply Equation (19) from:

(30) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],

and

[[??].sup.2.sub.2] = 4[[??].sup.2.sub.3][[??].sup.2.sub.3].

Table 5, Column 6, lists the OLS results for Equation (23). The signs and magnitudes on the coefficients are similar, but not identical, to those derived above based on the OLS estimates of [alpha] and [beta] because the system is over-identified. The estimated coefficients on the parental schooling levels and the associated dummies are smaller for direct OLS, while the coefficients on AFQT and family size are larger. The estimated coefficients on the parental schooling levels and AFQT are statistically significant.

Table 5, Column 5, lists the derived results of Equation (19). Again, we use the delta method to calculate the standard errors of the estimates. While the signs on the estimated coefficients are identical to those based on the OLS estimates, the magnitudes differ somewhat.

B. Restricted/NLSUR

NLSUR. Another estimation strategy involves the following recursive, constrained system of equations:

(31) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

subject to

[[gamma].sub.6] = - [[beta].sub.2]/2[[beta].sub.3].

We used NLSUR to estimate this restricted recursive system (which requires the sample sizes to be equal). The equations were stacked with the OLS estimates providing the starting values for the iteration. We imposed two alternative variance-covariance matrices for the error terms, [summation], that allowed us to test the following hypothesis:

(32) [H.sub.0] : [summation] is diagonal; [H.sub.1] : [summation] is not diagonal.

Under the null hypothesis, there is no correlation between the two errors, [u.sub.1] and [u.sub.3], and each equation could be estimated separately by NLOLS. The estimated residual variances and covariances were obtained from the OLS estimates of Equations (15) and (22). We tested the null hypothesis using a Breusch Pagan lagrange multiplier (LM) test. The LM test is based on the restricted model where [summation]; has zero off-diagonal entries. Because the calculated test statistic is less than the critical [[chi].sub.1] (2,.95), we cannot reject the null hypothesis and therefore assume that there is no covariance between the error terms. Consequently, each equation could have been estimated separately by NLOLS, producing consistent but biased results with no loss in efficiency.

Next, we turn to testing the cross-equation restriction:

(33) [H.sub.0] : [[gamma].sub.6] = - [[beta].sub.2]/2[[beta].sub.3]; [H.sub.1] : [[gamma].sub.6] [not equal to] -[[beta].sub.2]2/[[beta].sub.3].

We were able to test the null hypothesis using a likelihood ratio test. We cannot reject the null hypothesis and thus conclude that the system of equations is in fact constrained but that there is no correlation between the error terms.

Table 5, Columns 8-11, provide the restricted NLSUR results for Equations (15), (17), (19), and (22). All the coefficient estimates from Equation (15), with the exception of that on schooling and the schooling-ability interaction term, increase in statistical significance because estimation of this set of equations by NLSUR imposes cross-equation restrictions that tighten the standard errors making the estimates more precise. Overall, the coefficient estimates decrease in magnitude. The coefficient estimates on Equation (17), derived from Equation (15), are of the expected signs and have similar statistical significance. The derived coefficient estimates on Equation (19), from Equations (15) and (22), are of the same sign as those from the unrestricted OLS estimates, but the magnitudes differ somewhat. The t-statistics are larger than those on the previous derived form (i.e., Column 5) but smaller than those when estimated directly (i.e., Column 4). The latter finding may be due to the fact that Equation (19) is not directly part of the constrained system of equations. The estimated coefficients on Equation (22) are nearly identical to those from unrestricted OLS. One could consider estimating a three-equation system (i.e., Equations (15), (19), and (22)) by NLSUR. However, this strategy is not feasible because the variance-covariance matrix is singular.

corr(A, [u.sub.3]) [not equal to] 0? Measures of ability pose continuing problems for researchers. The importance of incorporating such a measure is well-documented in the literature; however, choosing an appropriate measure/proxy is a persistent challenge. "First, even our cognitive abilities as adults are heavily influenced by the social environment that we experienced during childhood, making it hard to discern any influence of preexisting genetic differences. Second, tests of cognitive ability (like IQ tests) tend to measure cultural learning and not pure innate intelligence, whatever that is" (Diamond, 1999, p. 20). Some researchers (e.g., Ashenfelter and Krueger, 1994) have devised resourceful ways of overcoming such problems, but most are left using various potentially error-ridden proxies in their analyses.

Fortunately, the NLSY79 does provide some measures of ability; the question, however, remains as to what type of ability is actually being measured. It is reasonable to question just how well the AFQT score proxies for true, innate ability. The AFQT score comes from the Armed Services Vocational Aptitude Battery test, which was administered in 1980 and used by the armed forces to assess a respondent's measure of trainability. Thus, there are any number of reasons to think that corr(A, [u.sub.3]) [not equal to] 0, for example, simultaneity bias, omitted variables bias, and so on. In testing for the possible correlation between A and [u.sub.3], we instrumented AFQT with the inverse of a respondent's age in 1980 (the year in which the test was administered) and a set of occupational dummies for the adult present in a respondent's home when he was age 14 along with the other predetermined variables. (17) The inverse of the respondent's age in 1980 allows ability to be concave with respect to age. Thus, we expect ability to increase, but at a decreasing rate, with age conditional on family background characteristics. The positive relationship between a child's ability and a family's resources (financial and time equivalents) is well-known (e.g., Cameron and Heckman, 1998; Cameron and Taber, 2004).

The occupational dummies were constructed based on the respondent's answers to whom he lived with when he was age 14. If there was an adult male present in the household, we used this individual's occupation. If there was no adult male present but an adult female was present, we used her occupation instead. Individuals with other arrangements, those who lived by themselves, and those with no adults present were coded as missing values. We lose 32 observations due to missing values. We constructed a set of occupational dummies based on the 1970 Census of the population's occupational classification system.

We tested for the potential correlation that exists between A and [u.sub.3] using a Hausman specification test (Greene, 2000). We tested the following hypothesis:

(34) [H.sub.0] : plim ([[??].sup.OLS] - [[??].sup.2SLS]) = 0; [H.sub.1] : plim ([[??].sup.OLS] - [[??].sup.2SLS]) [not equal to] 0.

The p-value for the Hausman [chi square] statistic is 0.22, so we cannot reject OLS. Thus, our ability proxy, AFQT, does not appear to be correlated with [u.sub.3].

VII. CONCLUDING REMARKS

This paper develops a model of earnings and optimal schooling. The analysis and estimation strategy are inspired by the Mincerian (1974) schooling model. The estimated coefficient on schooling in the simple schooling model (Equation (14)) generally overstates the returns because it does not control for ability. In addition, the simple schooling model is subject to an identification problem if the data in log earnings-schooling space are generated by tangencies between concave earnings functions and linear iso-present value curves. We incorporate human capital investment (i.e., schooling) into a model based on individual wealth maximization while controlling for ability and work experience. The model incorporates the effects of family background on the individual's discounting rate of interest. From this model, we derive individual schooling supply and demand functions that determine optimal schooling levels from the equilibration of the marginal rate of return from an additional year of schooling to the individual's discounting rate of interest.

Using data from the NLSY79, we stratify our sample into 1-yr FTE work experience cohorts over the period 1985-1989 and estimate a log earnings model that incorporates both schooling and ability for each cohort. Our measures of work experience correspond to actual hours worked in past calendar years and allow for lapses in employment and differing employment statuses (i.e., part-, full-, or overtime). Because we impose an FTE status, our measures of work experience do not necessarily correspond to an actual calendar year. Based on the estimates of Equation (15) and the "goodness-of-fit" measures, we conclude that the overtaking cohort corresponds to individuals with 13 FTE years of work experience (11 calendar years). The earnings of this cohort are most reflective of natural ability and schooling investments.

Based on our empirical findings, we conclude that we have a constrained system of equations relating earnings determination and optimal schooling. We assume that the error term in the log earnings function is normally distributed and determine that it is not correlated with the error term in the optimal level of schooling equation. According to a Hausman specification test, we cannot reject OLS and conclude that measured ability (AFQT) is uncorrelated with [u.sub.3] (and hence exogenous to the system). Thus, our most preferred set of estimates corresponds to Columns 8-11 of Table 5.

Since the schooling equation parameters vary across experience cohorts, the full interaction of experience with the schooling production function parameters in the overtaking cohort addresses the bias inherent in estimating a pooled earnings model with additive experience and its square. According to Mincer's (1974) rule of thumb (1/overtaking year), 13 yr of FTE work experience corresponding to 11 yr beyond the completion of schooling yield approximate rates of return of 7.7% and 9.1%. Our model estimates that the (average) marginal rate of return to schooling is 10.3% and the optimal level of schooling is 11.4 yr. Our estimate of the rate of return to schooling is consistent with the past findings.

APPENDIX

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

ABBREVIATIONS

AFQT: Armed Forces Qualification Test

AIC: Akaike's Information Criterion

FTE: Full-Time Equivalent

IQ: Intelligence Quotient

IV: Instrumental Variables

LM: Lagrange Multiplier

NLOLS: Nonlinear OLS (NLSUR/NLOLS)

NLSUR: Nonlinear Seemingly Unrelated Regressions

NLSY79: National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979

OJT: On-the-Job Training

OLS: Ordinary Least Squares

PC: Amemiya's Prediction Criterion

SC: Schwarz Criterion

SEE: Estimated Residual Standard Error

REFERENCES

Agnarsson, S., and P. S. Carlin. "Family Background and the Estimated Return to Schooling." Journal of Human Resources, 37, 2002, 680-692.

Altonji, J. G., and T. A. Dunn. "The Effects of Family Characteristics on the Return to Education." Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 1996, 692-703.

Arkes, J. "What Do Educational Credentials Signal and Why Do Employers Value Credentials?" Economics of Education Review, 18, 1999, 133-141.

Ashenfelter, O., and A. Krueger. "Estimates of the Return to Schooling from a New Sample of Twins." American Economic Review, 84, 1994, 1157-1173.

Ashenfelter, O., and C. Rouse. "Income, Schooling, and Ability: Evidence from a New Sample of Identical Twins." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 1998, 253-284.

Ashenfelter, O., and D. J. Zimmerman. "Estimates of the Returns to Schooling from Sibling Data: Fathers, Sons, and Brothers." Review of Economies and Statistics, 97, 1997, 1-9.

Barron, J. M., M. C. Berger, and D. A. Black. "Do Workers Pay for On-the-Job Training? "Journal of Human Resources, 34, 1998, 235-252.

Becker, G. S. "Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis." Journal of Political Economy, 70, 1962, 9-49.

--. Human Capital. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1975.

Becker, G. S., and B. R. Chiswick. "Education and the Distribution of Earnings." American Economic Review, 56, 1966, 358-369.

Behrman, J., and P. Taubman. "Intergenerational Transmission of Wealth and Income." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 66, 1976, 436-440.

Behrman, J. R., and N. Birdsall. "The Quality of Schooling: Quantity Alone is Misleading." American Economic Review, 73, 1983, 928-946.

Behrman, J. R., and M. R. Rosenzweig. '"Ability' Biases in Schooling Returns and Twins: A Test and New Estimates." Economics of Education Review, 18, 1999, 159-167.

Blaug, M. Economic Theory in Retrospect. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1962.

Cameron, S., and C. Taber. "Estimation of Educational Borrowing Constraints Using Returns to Schooling." Journal of Political Economy, 112, 2004, 132-182.

Cameron, S. V., and J. J. Heckman. "The Nonequivalence of High School Equivalents." Journal of Labor Economics, 11, 1993, 1-47.

--. "Life Cycle Schooling and Dynamic Selection Bias: Models and Evidence for Five Cohorts of American Males." Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1998, 262-333.

Card, D. "Earnings, Schooling, and Ability Revisited, "in Research in Labor Economics, edited by S. Polachek. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 14, 1995, 23-48.

--. "The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings," in Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by O. Ashenfelter and D. Card. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier, 3A, 2000, 1801-1863.

Card, D. and A. B. Krueger. "Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States." Journal of Political Economy, 100, 1992, 1-40.

Chamberlain, G., and Z. Griliches. "Unobservables with a Variance-Components Structure: Ability, Schooling, and the Economic Success of Brothers." International Economic Review, 16, 1975, 422-449.

Diamond, J. Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. New York: W.W. Norton & Company, 1999.

Ferrer, A. M., and W. C. Riddell. "The Role of Credentials in the Canadian Labour Market." Canadian Journal of Economics, 35, 2002, 879-905.

Frazis, H. "Selection Bias and the Degree Effect." Journal of Human Resources, 28, 1993, 538-554.

Greene, W. H. Econometric Analysis. 4th ed., Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 2000.

Griliches, Z. "Wages of Very Young Men." Journal of Political Economy, 84, 1976, S69-S86.

--. "Estimating the Returns to Schooling: Some Econometric Problems." Econometrica, 45, 1977, 1-22.

--. "Sibling Models and Data in Economics: Beginnings of a Survey." Journal of Political Economy, 87, 1979, S37-S64.

Griliches, Z., and W. M. Mason. "Education, Income. and Ability." Journal of Political Economy, 80, 1972, S74-S103.

Hause, J. C. "Earnings Profile: Ability and Schooling." Journal of Political Economy, 80, 1972, S108-S138.

Hungerford, T., and G. Solon. "Sheepskin Effects in the Returns to Education." Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 1987, 175-177.

Jaeger, D. A., and M. E. Page. "Degrees Matter: New Evidence on Sheepskin Effects in the Returns to Education." Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 1996, 733-740.

Judge, G. G., R. C. Hill, W. E. Griffiths, H. Lutkephol. and T. C. Lee. Introduction to the Theory and Practice of Econometrics, 2nd Edition. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1998.

Kane, T. J., and C. E. Rouse. "Labor-Market Returns to Two- and Four-Year Colleges." American Economic Review, 85, 1995, 600-614.

Kennedy, P. A Guide to Econometrics. 4th ed., Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1998.

Kling, J. R. "Interpreting Instrumental Variables Estimates of the Returns to Schooling." Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 19, 2001, 358-364.

Lang, K. "Ability Bias, Discount Rate Bias, and the Return to Education." Working Paper, Boston University, 1993.

Lang, K., and P. A. Ruud. "Returns to Schooling, Implicit Discount Rates and Black-White Wage Differentials." Review of Economics and Statistics, 68, 1986, 41-47.

Lang, K., and J. L. Zagorsky. "Does Growing Up with a Parent Absent Really Hurt?" Journal of Human Resources, 36, 2001, 253-273.

Lazear, E. "Education: Consumption or Production?" Journal of Political Economy, 85, 1977, 569-598.

Maddala, G. S. Introduction to Econometrics, 3rd ed., Chichester, England: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., 2001.

Mincer, J. Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1974.

Murphy, K. M., and F. Welch. "Empirical Age-Earnings Profiles." Journal of Labor Economics, 8, 1990, 202-229.

Neumark, D. "Biases in Twin Estimates of the Return to Schooling." Economics of Education Review, 18, 1999, 143-148.

Regan, T. L., and R. L. Oaxaca. "Work Experience as a Source of Specification Error in Earnings Models: Implications for Gender Wage Decompositions." IZA Discussion Paper No. 1920, 2006.

Rosen, S. "Human Capital and the Internal Rate of Return." Industrial Relations Research Association Series, 1974, 243-250.

Rouse, C. E. "'Further Estimates of the Economic Return to Schooling from a New Sample of Twins." Economies of Education Review, 18, 1999, 149-157.

Shea, J. "Does Parents' Money Matter?" Journal of Public Economics, 77, 2000, 155-184.

Willis, R. J., and S. Rosen. "Education and Self-Selection." Journal of Political Economy, 87, 1979, S7-S36.

(1.) Twin- and sibling-studies predating Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994) include Behrman and Taubman (1976) and Chamberlain and Griliches (1975).

(2.) Using data from the 1982 Employment Opportunity Pilot Program Survey and the 1992 Small Business Administration Survey, Barron, Berger, and Black (1998) find that OJT is associated with a small reduction in one's starting wage. OJT has a larger impact on one's productivity growth than on one's wage growth.

(3.) As Rosen (1974) points out, the transformation function is derived from a production function of knowledge whose arguments are schooling and ability. The units of knowledge (human capital) are multiplied by a constant market rental rate on human capital to yield earnings. The production function itself is derived from a learning function that governs the rate at which knowledge can be produced from prior schooling and ability. Certainly, other reasonable explanatory variables could be included in this functional form, at the expense of parsimony. However, unless these variables are interacted with schooling, they do not affect the theoretical model because the optimal level of schooling is determined by differentiating with respect to schooling. Furthermore, experience does not appear separately as it is implicitly controlled for in the overtaking model described in Section V.

(4.) Lazear (1977) frames his discussion of education in the context of a production function.

(5.) For an early, general discussion of the effects of schooling and ability (and their interaction) on log earnings, see Hause (1972).

(6.) This infinite horizon is imposed for mathematical simplicity. An infinite horizon model has been used by numerous other researchers as well (e.g., Lang and Ruud, 1986).

(7.) Certainly, X could include other variables to address the possibility that i varies across a child's age, birth order, and number of siblings. For example, the number of minutes a parent reads to his/her child could influence i and is probably related to the child's birth order and spacing between siblings. For the most part, such detailed information is not contained in the NLSY79. All we can determine is if a respondent is the oldest child.

(8.) Note that the model is not identified. Thus, [[beta].sub.1] has no economic meaning. However, its interpretation as an average rate of return to schooling is maintained throughout the analysis.

(9.) We considered several other proxies for permanent family income, namely, the Duncan socioeconomic index and variations of the parental schooling levels--the average, maximum, and head of household's. Such alternatives were not pursued because we lost too many observations due to missing information.

(10.) Using the NLSY79, Lang and Zagorsky (2001) examine the effects of growing up in a single-parent home on a variety of outcome variables.

(11.) For comparison's sake, pooling the experience cohorts and including X and [X.sup.2] as explicit regressors produce the usual results the coefficient estimate on X is positive (and statistically significant) and the coefficient estimate on [X.sup.2] is negative (and statistically significant). Doing so, however, produces statistically insignificant coefficient estimates on all the other variables (and that on A is negative as well).

(12.) This of course is a problem if our actual work experience variable is incorrectly measured, but using actual work experience is superior to the use of potential work experience measures (see Regan and Oaxaca, 2006).

(13.) The term "final schooling" is used somewhat loosely here because we can only observe individual schooling choices/enrollment through 1998, the most recent wave of the NLSY79 survey that we had at the time of our study. Beginning in 1994, the NLSY79 survey was conducted biannually.

(14.) Note that most often these "years" of work experience do not coincide with calendar years and that the composition of the cohorts would differ somewhat with alternative definitions of FTE. Furthermore, implicit in the construction of this measure is the assumption that children begin school at age 6 and complete one grade per year (i.e., no acceleration or retention in schooling) and that the fraction of hours worked in 1979 is proportional to that in the previous years.

(15.) We chose to confine our attention to 1985-1989 for a couple of reasons. First, Mincer (1974) finds that the correlation between log earnings and education is strongest in the first decade of work experience. The NLSY79 began in 1979 and a decade later corresponds to 1989. Second, Mincer (1974) finds that the overtaking year occurs 8 yr after an individual has left school and has acquired 7 9 "yr" of work experience. In the first year of the survey, our respondents are between ages 14 and 22. Roughly, half are under age 18 and are most likely still enrolled in school. By 1985, the youngest respondents could reasonably have acquired 4 yr of work experience.

(16.) We also controlled for "sheepskin effects" in our log earnings function by including a dummy variable indicating whether a respondent holds a high school diploma or a general educational development test. Cameron and Heckman (1993) find that the two are not equivalent. Research on sheepskin effects is a growing literature and includes work by Hungerford and Solon (1987). Frazis (1993), Kane and Rouse (1995), Jaeger and Page (1996), Arkes (1999), Ferrer and Riddell (2002), and Agnarsson and Carlin (2002). Augmenting Equation (15) with a high school diploma dummy does not affect our choice of the overtaking cohort.

(17.) Cameron and Heckman (1998) address the spurious correlation that potentially exists between AFQT and schooling by conditioning on a subset of individuals who were between ages 14 and 17 when the test was administered and hence still in school. Doing so eliminates any causal effect of schooling on ability.

TRACY L. REGAN, RONALD L. OAXACA and GALEN BURGHARDT *

* We would like to thank the workshop participants at the University of Arizona, the IZA/SOLE Summer 2003 Conference, and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and insights. Special thanks to Price Fishback and Alfonso Flores-Lagunes. We also appreciate the research assistance provided by Laura Martinez.

Regan: Department of Economics, University of Miami, P.O. Box 248126, Coral Gables, FL 33124-6550. Phone (305) 284-5540, Fax (305) 284-2985, E-mail: tregan@miami.edu

Oaxaca: IZA, Bonn, Germany and Department of Economics, University of Arizona, McClelland Hall #401, P.O. Box 210108, Tucson, AZ 85721-0108. Phone (520) 621-4135, Fax (520) 621-8450, E-mail: rlo@email.arizona.edu

Burghardt: Calyon Financial, 550 West Jackson Boulevard, Suite 500, Chicago, IL 60661. Phone (312) 762-1140, Fax (312) 762-1148, E-mail: Galen.burghardt@ gmail.com
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics for White Males

 Standard
 Mean Deviation Nobs.

Age 1979 18.345 2.257 2,761
Nominal wage 1985 15,959.550 9,995.254 1,950
Nominal wage 1986 18,488.490 11,527.950 1,872
Nominal wage 1987 20,675.170 12,354.530 1,918
Nominal wage 1988 23,859.100 33,124.600 1,899
Nominal wage 1989 24,615.260 17,483.510 1,878
Schooling 1985 12.133 2.254 2,032
Schooling 1986 12.149 2.256 1,962
Schooling 1987 12.178 2.241 1,917
Schooling 1988 12.175 2.253 1,940
Schooling 1989 12.157 2.261 1,939
AFQT 46.045 28.657 2,539
Experience 1985 4.470 3.168 2,758
Experience 1986 5.187 3.435 2,758
Experience 1987 5.906 3.721 2,758
Experience 1988 6.641 4.044 2,758
Experience 1989 7.379 4.395 2,758
Mother's schooling 10.993 3.074 2,600
Father's schooling 11.041 3.829 2,494
Family size 1979 3.802 2.224 2,761

Notes: Sample is based on those individuals whose
wages are [greater than or equal to] $500 and who are not enrolled
in school currently or any time after 1989. Source of data: NLSY79.

Nobs., Number of observations.

TABLE 2
Work Experience Cohort Frequency
Distribution: 1985-1989

FTE Years
of Work Experience
1985-1989 Nobs. % of sample

< 1 206 4.69
1 483 10.99
2 728 16.57
3 997 22.70
4 1,157 26.34
5 1,221 27.79
6 1,186 27.00
7 1,060 24.13
8 916 20.85
9 786 17.89
10 584 13.29
11 422 9.61
12 342 7.79
13 215 4.89
14 149 3.39

Notes. Sample is based on those individuals whose
wages are >$500 and who are not enrolled in school cur-
rently or any time after 1989. Source of data: NLSY79.

Nobs., Number of observations.

TABLE 3
Log Earnings Function: Selection Criterion (Equation (15))

FTE Work
Experience
Cohort Nobs. AIC SC PC SEE [R.sup.2]

 0 206 0.267 0.332 1.307 1.132 0.046
 1 483 -0.476 -0.442 0.621 0.785 0.174
 2 728 -0.670 -0.644 0.512 0.713 0.193
 3 997 -0.899 -0.879 0.407 0.637 0.228
 4 1157 -0.963 -0.946 0.382 0.617 0.199
 5 1221 -1.048 -1.032 0.351 0.591 0.183
 6 1186 -1.051 -1.033 0.350 0.590 0.161
 7 1060 -1.211 -1.192 0.298 0.545 0.175
 8 916 -1.240 -1.219 1.2190 0.537 0.200
 9 786 -1.123 -1.099 0.325 0.569 0.184
10 584 -1.201 -1.171 0.301 0.547 0.212
11 422 -1.107 -1.069 0.330 0.572 0.136
12 342 -0.474 -0.430 0.622 0.784 0.083
13 215 -1.461# -1.398# 0.232# 0.477# 0.299
14 149 -1.317 -1.236 0.268 0.511 0.353#

Notes: Bolded figures correspond to the minimum AIC, SC, PC, and SEE
and the maximum [R.sup.2]. Samples are based on those individuals
whose wages are [greater than or equal to] $500 and who are not
enrolled in school currently or any time after 1989. Source of
data: NLSY79.

Nobs., Number of observations.

Notes: Bolded figures correspond to the minimum AIC, SC, PC, and SEE
and the maximum [R.sup.2] indicated with #.

TABLE 4
Descriptive Statistics 13-yr Work Experience
Cohort

 Standard
 Mean Deviation Nobs.

Age 28.693 1.691 215
Age in 1980 20.693 1.414 215
Nominal wage 25,417.10 16,957.80 215
Log real wage 9.883 0.566 215
Schooling 11.377 2.044 215
AFQT 44.823 27.800 215
Experience 13.469 0.294 215
Years out of school 11.316 2.205 215
Mother's schooling 10.621 2.819 195
Father's schooling 10.130 3.750 192
Mother's 0.093 0.291 215
 schooling dummy
Father's 0.107 0.310 215
 schooling dummy
Family size 1979 3.693 1.864 215

Notes: Sample is based on those individuals whose
wages are [greater than or equal to] $500 and who are not enrolled
in school currently or any time after 1989. Source of data: NLSY79.

Nobs., Number of observations.

TABLE 5
Estimated Schooling Model

Model/Estimation Strategy Unrestricted/OLS

Cohort 13 FTE Years

Equation 14 15

Dependent Variables In(earnings)

 (1) (2)

Constant 8.295 7.619
 (43.832) *** (14.426) ***
 0.140 0.290
 (8.528) ** (2.965) ***
AFQT x schooling -- 4.008E-04
 (3.241) ***
AFQT -- --

Schooling (2) -- -9.356E-03
 (-2.056) **
Father's schooling -- --

Mother's schooling -- --

Father's schooling dummy -- --

Mother's schooling dummy -- --

Family size -- --

[R.sup.2] 0.255 0.299
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.251 0.289
SEE 0.490 0.477
Nobs. 215 215
Estimated at sample mean r, i 0.140 0.097
Estimated at sample mean --
 optimal years of schooling

Model/Estimation Strategy Unrestricted/OLS

Cohort 13 FTE Years

Equation 17

Dependent Variables Estimated r

 (3)

Constant 0.290
 (2.965) ***
 -1.871E-02
 (-2.056) **
AFQT x schooling --

AFQT 4.008E-04
 (3.241) ***
Schooling (2) --

Father's schooling --

Mother's schooling --

Father's schooling dummy --

Mother's schooling dummy --

Family size --

[R.sup.2] --
[[bar.R].sup.2] --
SEE --
Nobs. 215
Estimated at sample mean r, i 0.097
Estimated at sample mean --
 optimal years of schooling

Model/Estimation Strategy Unrestricted/OLS

Cohort 13 FTE Years

Equation 19

Dependent Variables Estimated i

 (4) (5)

Constant 0.151 0.153
 (14.764) *** (4.075) ***
 -- --

AFQT x schooling -- --

AFQT -- --

Schooling (2) -- --

Father's schooling -2.442E-03 -1.975E-03
 (-3.717) *** (1.670) *
Mother's schooling -3.092E-03 -2.757E-03
 (-3.494) *** (-1.711) *
Father's schooling dummy -2.499E-02 -2.499E-02
 (-3.062) *** (-1.626)
Mother's schooling dummy -1.089E-02 -9.796E-03
 (-0.945) (-0.790)
Family size -3.895E-05 -5.542E-04
 (-0.035) (-0.481)
[R.sup.2] 0.235 --
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.216 --
SEE 2.912E-02 2.889E-02
Nobs. 215 215
Estimated at sample mean r, i 0.097 0.103
Estimated at sample mean -- --
 optimal years of schooling

Model/Estimation Strategy Unrestricted/OLS

Cohort 13 FTE Years

Equation 22

Dependent Variables Years of school completed

 (6) (7)

Constant 7.317 7.420
 (13.449) *** (2.440) **
 -- --

AFQT x schooling -- --

AFQT 3.089E-02 2.142E-02
 (6.738) **** (1.844) *
Schooling (2) -- --

Father's schooling 0.106 0.130
 (2.862) *** (1.799) *
Mother's schooling 0.147 0.165
 (3.088) *** (1.707) *
Father's schooling dummy 1.335 1.524
 (2.659) *** (0.858)
Mother's schooling dummy 0.523 0.582
 (0.855) (0.035)
Family size 2.962E-02 2.082E-03
 (0.495) (-0.481)
[R.sup.2] 0.446 --
[[bar.R].sup.2] 0.430 --
SEE 1.544 1.556
Nobs. 215 215
Estimated at sample mean r, i -- --
Estimated at sample mean 11.377 11.359
 optimal years of schooling

Model/Estimation Strategy Restricted/OLS

Cohort 13 FTE Years

Equation 15 17

Dependent Variable In(earnings) Estimated r

 (8) (9)

Constant 7.865 (35.685) *** 0.236
 (6.051) ***
Schooling 0.236 -0.01316714
 (6.051) *** (-2.759) ***
AFQT x schooling 3.981E-04 --
 (2.941) ***
AFQT -- 3.981E-04
 (2.941) ***
Schooling -6.584E-03 --
 (-2.759) ***
Father's schooling -- --

Mother's schooling -- --

Father's schooling dummy -- --

Mother's schooling dummy -- --

Family size -- --

[R.sup.2] 0.297 --
[[bar.R].sup.2]
SEE
Nobs. 215 215
Estimated at sample mean r, i 0.103 0.103
Estimated at sample mean -- --
 optimal years of schooling

Model/Estimation Strategy Restricted/OLS

Cohort 13 FTE Years

Equation 19 22

 Years of school
Dependent Variable Estimated i completed

 (10) (11)

Constant 0.139 7.320
 (8.558) *** (14.617) ***
Schooling -- --

AFQT x schooling -- --

AFQT -- 3.085E-02
 (5.980) ***
Schooling -- --

Father's schooling -1.400E-03 0.106
 (-1.940) * (2.819) ***
Mother's schooling -1.977E-03 0.150
 (-2.094) ** (3.925) ***
Father's schooling dummy -1.786E-02 1.356
 (-1.963) ** (2.929) ***
Mother's schooling dummy -6.832E-03 0.519
 (-0.857) (0.932)
Family size -3.580E-04 2.719E-02
 (-0.467) (0.459)
[R.sup.2] -- 0.446
[[bar.R].sup.2]
SEE
Nobs. 215 215
Estimated at sample mean r, i 0.103
Estimated at sample mean -- 11.384
 optimal years of schooling

Notes: Sample is based on individuals whose wages are [greater than or
equal to] $500 and who are not enrolled in school currently or any time
after 1989. Source of data: NLSY79. (t-statistic). *, **, and *** are
significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Nobs., Number
of observations.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有