Sunk costs, profit variability, and turnover.
Gschwandtner, Adelina ; Lambson, Val E.
I. INTRODUCTION
The dynamic competitive approach to the study of industrial
organization highlights the role of sunk costs and the associated
hysteresis effects in determining how industries behave over time. The
theoretical models are inherently difficult. Commenting on his own work,
Jovanovic (1982, 651) remarked that "a curious feature of the paper
is that proofs of 'obvious' results are complicated."
Such complexity precludes a canonical dynamic competitive model but
favors the development of various models focusing on different aspects
of reality.
In spite of this, the dynamic competitive approach has yielded some
predictions that are intuitively compelling and consistent with a
variety of dynamic competitive models. Two such predictions are the
focus of this article: industries exhibiting higher sunk costs should
also exhibit greater intertemporal variability of firm-level profit and
lower intertemporal variability in the number and identity of active
firms. Examples of models that are broadly supportive of these
predictions include those by Dixit (1989), Lambson (1991, 1992), and
Hopenhayn (1992).
Dixit (1989) developed a continuous time model of a single firm
facing an exogenous output price that follows a geometric Brownian
motion. If entry costs are sunk, then the firm's entry-provoking
price, say [alpha], exceeds the firm's exit-provoking price, say
[omega]. Furthermore, [alpha] is increasing and [omega] is decreasing in
the sunk cost, suggesting that the range of profit is greater if sunk
costs are higher. This firm-level model is poorly suited for studying
industry-level questions of entry and exit, but Caballero and Pindyck
(1996) considered an industry-level extension of Dixit's model
(1989, 657-58) and concluded that higher sunk costs increase the
variability of the output price (and hence of profit) and decrease
turnover.
Lambson (1992) constructed a discrete time model of an industry
that is subjected to exogenous stochastic shocks that are common to the
firms. Such shocks might include changes in input prices, demand
conditions, and the regulatory environment, among others. Firm values
above the entry cost [xi] induce entry whereas firm values below the
scrap value [chi] induce exit. The intertemporal range of firm values is
thus approximately [xi]-[chi], which is also a natural definition of
sunk costs in the model. With the intertermporal range of firm value
being thus identified with sunk cost, if the range of current profit is
positively related to the range of firm values, then the range of profit
will be higher in high sunk cost industries, yielding the first
prediction. Less obvious but no less true in this model is the
proposition that the intertemporal range of the number of active firms
will be lower in high sunk cost industries. Lambson (1991) allows for
endogenous heterogeneity because entering firms pay a sunk cost to
install one of several available technologies. This generates
simultaneous entry and exit when, for example, there is a large change
in relative input prices. General proofs are lacking, but examples
suggest that higher sunk costs will tend to coexist with higher
variability of profit and lower turnover.
Hopenhayn (1992) modeled an industry in discrete time where firms
are buffeted by idiosyncratic shocks to their productivity. Firms that
suffer a series of negative shocks suffer such a decrease in their
productivity that they find it optimal to exit the market. The
productivity level that triggers exit is lower when the entry cost is
higher. The lower trigger level implies a lower rate of turnover. It
also implies that a firm's profit can be lower without provoking
exit; this suggests that high sunk cost industries will exhibit more
variability in firm-level profits over time.
II. EMPIRICAL PRECEDENTS
Section I reviews two predictions from the theoretical literature
using dynamic competitive models: intertemporal profit variability
should be higher in higher sunk cost industries, and turnover should be
lower in higher sunk cost industries. Empirical work relevant to the
first result is sparse. (1) By contrast, there is a substantial
empirical literature devoted to entry and exit rates. An early effort,
perhaps inspired by Caves and Porter (1976), was due to Deutsch (1984),
who found what can be interpreted as evidence that exit is negatively
related to sunk costs. In an ambitious study, Dunne et al. (1988, 1989)
analyzed the patterns of firm entry and exit in U.S. manufacturing
industries over the periods 1963-1982 and 1967-1977. They found a high
and positive correlation between entry rates and exit rates, as well as
substantial and persistent differences in these rates across industries.
Geroski et al. (1990) did a summary and interpretation of much of the
earlier work. Subsequent research explored the empirical relationship between proxies for sunk costs (such as measures of economies of scale
or capital intensity) and entry and exit rates. There are examples in
work by Geroski and Schwalbach (1991), Siegfried and Evans (1992, 1994),
and Audretsch (1995). Curiously, most analysis yielded either no
relationship or counterintuitive positive relationships. Audretsch
(1995) remarked, "One of the most startling results that has
emerged in empirical studies is that entry into an industry is
apparently not substantially deterred or even deterred at all in
capital-intensive industries in which scale economies play a role"
(46). More recently, Disney et al. (2003) analyzed entry, exit, and
establishment survival in U.K. manufacturing. They also found strong
correlation between industry entry rates and industry exit rates. They
hypothesized that entry and exit rates might be correlated because
industries differ in their sunk costs, but the authors did not explore
this further. Using international data, Gschwandtner and Lambson (2002)
found the intertemporal variability of the number of firms to be lower
in industries where proxies for sunk costs (namely, capital costs and
capital costs per worker) were higher.
In what follows, we present simple tests of the two robust
theoretical propositions described in section I. First we test for a
positive relationship between proxies for sunk costs and intertemporal
profit variability using a new data set constructed by combining
Compustat data with data from Moody's Industrial Manual
(1954-2001). Next, we test for a negative relationship between turnover
and proxies for sunk costs--an intuitively and theoretically compelling
but heretofore poorly documented phenomenon--using annual data from the
U.S. Census Bureau.
III. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATIONS AND DATA
Intertemporal Profit Variability
In this section we explore the relationship between the
intertemporal variability of profit and sunk costs. We use a new data
set constructed by supplementing Compustat data with data from
Moody's Industrial Manual. Specifically, gaps in the former--a
particularly common problem in the early years--were filled from the
latter. The result is a set of annual observations from 1950 through
2001 for 162 firms in the United States. The 162 firms were among the
largest 500 in terms of sales in 1950 and managed to survive until 2001.
Although there is obvious selection bias, it is irrelevant to the
question because theory predicts more variable profitability among
surviving firms in high sunk cost industries.
The variables used are Net Income (data18); Total Assets (data6);
and Net Total Property, Plant, and Equipment (data8). Net Income
represents the income of a company after all expenses--including special
items, income taxes, and minority interests--but before provisions for
common and preferred dividends. The Total Assets variable represents
current assets plus net property, plant, and equipment plus other
noncurrent assets. The Net Property, Plant, and Equipment variable sums
the cost of tangible fixed property used in the production of revenue,
less accumulated depreciation. (2) All the values are real, having been
adjusted by the gross domestic product deflator with 1950 as the base
year.
We used Net Income as a proxy for profit. (3) We measured
intertemporal variability in two ways: the range and the variance.
Although theory favors the range as the appropriate measure, the range
is sensitive to outliers. In any case, the regressions with range and
the regressions with variance yield similar results.
We used the intertemporal mean of a firm's Net Property,
Plant, and Equipment variable as a proxy for a firm's sunk cost.
This is a good proxy to the extent that the capital stock is industry
specific and is an important component of the firms' sunk costs. Of
course, it is not a perfect measure of sunk cost. For one thing, it
ignores noncapital start-up costs, such as the opportunity cost of
entrepreneurial time, initial legal fees, the cost of market research,
and so on. Furthermore, it does not adjust for the timing of the sunk
costs. In reality, firms pay an initial entry cost to build a plant and
then make ongoing adjustments. However, it is plausible that this
variable is highly correlated with sunk costs and is hence a reasonable
proxy.
Now, large firms are likely to exhibit greater intertemporal
variability simply because of their size: for example, a two-plant firm
will exhibit twice the variability of a one-plant firm if the plants are
identical. To control for size, in some specifications we divided a
firm's sunk cost proxy by its total assets and then calculated the
intertemporal mean of that ratio. To further control for size we
included the intertemporal mean of a firm's income. The various
specifications with the range of profit as the dependent variable are
listed in equations 1-6. (The specifications with the variance of profit
as the dependent variable are similar.)
(1) Log [Range.sub.i]([[pi].sub.it]) = [alpha] +
[[beta].sub.[xi]][K.sub.i] + [epsilon]
(2) Log [Range.sub.i]([[pi].sub.it]) = [alpha] +
[[beta].sub.[xi]][(K/A).sub.i] + [epsilon]
(3) Log [Range.sub.i]([[pi].sub.it]) = [alpha] +
[[beta].sub.[xi]]Log[(K).sub.i] + [epsilon]
(4) Log [Range.sub.i]([[pi].sub.it]) = [alpha] +
[[beta].sub.[xi]]Log[(K/A).sub.i] + [epsilon]
(5) Log [Range.sub.i]([[pi].sub.it]) = [alpha] +
[[beta].sub.[xi]]Log[(K).sub.i] + [[beta].sub.[theta]][[PI].sub.i] +
[epsilon]
(6) Log [Range.sub.i]([[pi.sub.it]) = [alpha] +
[[beta].sub.[xi]]Log[(K/A).sub.i] + [[beta].sub.[theta]][[PI].sub.i] +
[epsilon]
Here [[pi].sub.it] is the net income of firm i in year t;
[Range.sub.i]([[pi].sub.it]) is the intertemporal range of company
i's profit; [K.sub.i] is the firm's intertemporal mean of the
sunk cost proxy; [(K/A).sub.i] is the intertemporal mean of the sunk
cost proxy divided by total assets of firm i; and [[PI].sub.i] is the
mean of net income for each company over the period 1950-2001.
Regression results are in Table 1. Some descriptive statistics are in
Table 4.
Turnover
To explore the relationship between the rate of turnover and sunk
costs, we used annual data from the U.S. Census Bureau. Turnover was
defined as (Entry + Exit)/2 for each industry in each year. With
sponsorship from the U.S. Small Business Administration, the Census
Bureau collects data on entry and exit by industry for the United States
as a whole and for each state. (4) This database contains information
about entry, exit, and employment from 1990 to 2000 for each included
industry. (5)
Time series from 1994 to 2001 (eight years) are available in the
U.S. Census Bureau's Annual Capital Expenditures Survey. (6)
Categories used in the survey comprised primarily three-digit and
selected four-digit industries from the North American Industry
Classification System for the more recent years. The period that is
available for both variables is 1994-2000 (seven years). (7)
The database has two advantages compared to previous studies that
use census data with observations at five-year (or at best two-year)
intervals. First, annual observations reflect more accurate information
about entry and exit. Second, whereas most previous studies brought
evidence only from the manufacturing sector, (8) the present database
includes observations from mining, construction, transportation,
communication, utilities, and finance.
We considered two different proxies for sunk costs: "Total
Capital Expenditures for Structures and Equipment for Companies with
Employees" divided by the number of Employees (K/L) and "New
Capital Expenditures for Structures and Equipment for Companies with
Employees" divided by the number of Employees (New K/L). The total
capital expenditures variable, K, is similar to the Net Property, Plant,
and Equipment variable of the previous subsection and suffers from the
same advantages and shortcomings. The difficulties arising from the
timing issues are mitigated in the alternative specification using the
New Capital Expenditures variable. The two variables yield similar
results. By looking at capital intensiveness relative to labor, we
partially control for size. However, it was still conceivable that this
was not sufficient, so we added employment as a separate control for the
size of the industry. In summary, we used the following specifications:
(7) logT = [gamma] + [eta]K/L + [mu]
(8) logT = [gamma] + [eta]NewK/L + [mu]
(9) logT = [gamma] + [eta]K/L + [theta]L + [mu]
(10) logT = [gamma] + [eta]NewK/L + [theta]L + [mu],
where logT is the logarithm of turnover in the industry, L is the
number of employees in the industry, and K/L and NewK/L are the two
proxies for sunk cost. We did the analysis separately for each year as
well as for all the years combined. Regressions results are in Tables 2
and 3. Some descriptive statistics are in Tables 4.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The results for the relationship between the intertemporal
variability of profit and sunk costs are summarized in Table 1. Theory
suggests a positive correlation between the intertemporal variability of
a company's profit and a proxy for the company's sunk costs.
The coefficient of the sunk cost proxy is positive and significant at
the 5% level or better in all specifications. The reported standard
errors are cluster corrected by industry. (9)
The results for the relationship between the rate of turnover and
sunk costs are presented in Table 2 (specifications 7 and 8) and Table 3
(specifications 9 and 10). Theory suggests a negative relationship
between the rate of turnover and sunk costs. In each of the seven years
and in the aggregated sample, all specifications generate a negative
coefficient that is statistically significant. (10) When we introduce in
the regression the total number of employees in the industry to control
for size, the results remain significant. The coefficients of the
measure of size are significantly positive. We conclude that the
empirical evidence is consistent with the aforementioned predictions
from the theoretical literature.
V. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This analysis suggests that profits are more volatile, and turnover
lower, in industries that exhibit higher sunk costs. The theoretical
predictions cited in section I arise from dynamic competitive models
without any distortions. Thus, equilibrium solves a social
planner's problem of maximizing the expected present value of the
sum of producer and consumer surplus, including the entry costs and
scrap values. As argued by Lambson (1992) regarding differing long-run
average profits across industries, differences in the volatility of
profits and differences in turnover across industries fail to imply the
existence of market imperfections. Thus, strictly speaking, the policy
implications of this research lead to nonintervention. Of course, a
plausible model with market imperfections might generate the same
predictions with different policy prescriptions, but the nature of those
prescriptions may well depend critically on the precise structure of the
model.
REFERENCES
Audretsch, D. B. Innovation and Industry Evolution. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press, 1995.
Caballero R., and R. Pindyck, R., "Uncertainty, Investment,
and Industry Evolution," International Economic Review, 37(3),
1996, 641-62.
Caves, R. E., and M. E. Porter. "Barriers to Exit," in
Essays on Industrial Organization in Honor of Joe S. Bain, edited by R.
T. Masson and P. D. Qualls. Cambridge: Ballinger, 1976, 39-69.
Deutsch, L. L. "An Examination of Industry Exit
Patterns." Review of Industrial Organization, 1, 1984, 60-68.
Disney, R., J. Haskel, and Y. Heden. "Entry, Exit and
Establishment Survival in UK Manufacturing." Journal of Industrial
Economics, 51(1), 2003, 91-112.
Dixit, A. "Entry and Exit Decisions under Uncertainty."
Journal of Political Economy, 97(3), 1989, 620-38.
Dunne, T., M. J. Roberts, and L. Samuelson. "Patterns of Firm
Entry and Exit in U.S. Manufacturing Industries." Rand Journal of
Economics, 19(4), 1988, 495-515.
--. "The Growth and Failure of U.S. Manufacturing
Plants." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4), 1989, 671-98.
Geroski, P., R. J. Gilbert, and A. Jacquemin. Barriers to Entry and
Strategic Competition. Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic, 1990.
Geroski, P., and J. Schwalbach, eds. Entry and Market
Contestability: An International Comparison. Oxford: Basil Blackwell,
1991.
Gschwandtner, A., and V. Lambson. "The Effects of Sunk Costs
on Entry and Exit: Evidence from 36 Countries." Economics Letters,
77, 2002, 109-15.
Hopenhayn, H. "Entry, Exit and Firm Dynamics in Long Run
Equilibrium." Econometrica, 60, 1992, 1127-50.
Jovanovic, B. "Selection and the Evolution of Industry."
Econometrica, 50(2), 1982, 649-70.
Lambson, V. "Industry Evolution with Sunk Costs and Uncertain
Market Conditions." International Journal of Industrial
Organization, 9(2), 1991, 171-96.
--. "Competitive Profits in the Long Run." Review of
Economic Studies, 59, 1992, 125-42.
Lambson, V., and F. Jensen. "Sunk Costs and the Variability of
Firm Value over Time." Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(3),
1995, 535-44.
--. "Sunk Costs and Firm Value Variability: Theory and
Evidence." American Economic Review, 88(1), 1998, 307-13.
Moody's Investor Service, Moody's Industrial Manual, New
York: Moody's Investor Service, 1954-2001.
Opler, T., and S. Titman, "Financial Distress and Corporate
Performance," The Journal of Finance, 49(3), 1994, 1015-40.
Siegfried, J., and L. Evans. "Entry and Exit in U.S.
Manufacturing Industries from 1977 to 1982," in Empirical Studies
in Industrial Organization: Essays in Honor of Leonard W Weiss, edited
by D. B. Audretsch and J. Siegfried. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1992.
--. "Empirical Studies of Entry and Exit: A Survey of
Evidence." Review of Industrial Organization, 9(2), 1994, 121-55.
(1.) Lambsonand Jensen (1995, 1998) documented positive correlation
between the intertemporal variability of firm values and proxies for
sunk costs.
(2.) For more detailed definitions of the data, see the Compustat
Data Definitions.
(3.) Although it would be tempting to try to control for business
cycles, the mechanism driving the predictions must hold independently of
the business cycle. Times that are good induce entry, and times that are
bad induce exit. It does not matter why times are good or bad.
(4.) These data are available at http://www.sba.gov/
advo/stats/data.html.
(5.) More specific information is at http://www.census.
gov/csd/susb/susb2.htm#godyn1.
(6.) These data are available at http://www.census.gov/
csd/ace/ace-pdf.html.
(7.) Note that even if some studies use a longer period, the number
of years is usually smaller because they use five-year census data.
(8.) See, for example, Audretsch (1995).
(9.) Because high leveraged firms are more risky and have a higher
variation in profits, in some specifications we controlled for this by
including a debt measure (short-term or long-term debt divided by total
assets) into the regression. The coefficients stayed positive and
significant. See Opler and Titman (1994),
(10.) The database for "New Capital Expenditures" is more
recent, but the number of observations is sometimes smaller than it is
for the "Total Capital Expenditures." It varies between 96 and
140 per year whereas the number of observations for the "Total
Capital Expenditures" varies between 103 and 140 per year. The
number of observations increases in both cases starting with the year
1999, when the North American Industry Classification System was
introduced.
ADELINA GSCHWANDTNER and VAL E. LAMBSON, We are grateful to Jesus
Crespo-Cuaresma, Burcin Yurtoglu and some anonymous referees for their
helpful comments.
Gschwandtner: Universitat Assistent Magistrate Doctor, Department
of Economics, University of Vienna, BWZ Bruennerstr. 72, A-1210 Vienna,
AUSTRIA. Phone (00431) 4277 37480, Fax (00431) 4277 37489, E-mail
adelina.gschwandtner@univie.ac.at
Lambson: Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Brigham
Young University, Provo UT 84602, USA. Phone (801) 422-7765, Fax (801)
422-0194, E-mail vlambson@byu.edu
TABLE 1
Dependent Variables: Logarithm of the Range of Company's
Income Equations 1-6, Logarithm of the Variance of Company's
Income Equations 7-13
Eq. K K/A LogK Log K/A
1 0.0005 ***
(9E-05)
2 0.954 ***
(0.319)
3 0.828 ***
(0.032)
4 0.819 ***
(0.267)
5 0.728 ***
(0.040)
6 0.536 ***
(0.203)
7 0.0011 ***
(2E-04)
8 1.882 **
(0.838)
9 1.661 ***
(0.088)
10 1.607 **
(0.675)
11 1.432 ***
(0.100)
12 1.027 ***
(0.386)
Eq. [PI] Adj. [R.sup.2]
1 0.379
2 0.041
3 0.775
4 0.043
5 0.0009 *** 0.790
(0.0003)
6 0.0036 *** 0.460
(0.0006)
7 0.374
8 0.041
9 0.787
10 0.041
11 0.0021 *** 0.808
(0.001)
12 0.0075 *** 0.485
(0.0012)
Note: K, [PI], and A are measured in millions of real dollars
(base year 1950) per firm. The number of observations is always
162. Regression is with heteroskedasticity and cluster correction
of standard errors. Numbers in parentheses are root square errors.
* p [less than or equal to] .10; ** [less than or equal to] < .05;
*** [less than or equal to] .01.
TABLE 2
Dependent Variable: logTurnover =
log[(Entry+Exit)/2] per Industry
Year K/L NewK/L Adj. [R.sup.2] Obs.
1994 -23.83 *** 0.068 105
(8.11)
-24.21 *** 0.064 105
(8.49)
1995 -23.75 *** 0.080 105
(7.51)
-24.87 *** 0.101 97
(7.23)
1996 -21.76 *** 0.068 103
(7.49)
-21.36 *** 0.065 96
(7.75)
1997 -15.73 ** 0.045 108
(6.39)
-15.90 ** 0.045 108
(6.50)
1998 -14.23 ** 0.039 108
(6.23)
-15.09 ** 0.039 108
(6.52)
1999 -12.54 *** 0.046 140
(4.52)
-13.09 *** 0.046 140
(4.70)
2000 -9.75 *** 0.040 140
(3.73)
-10.70 *** 0.025 140
(4.02)
All -14.75 *** 0.055 809
(2.14)
-15.595 *** 0.058 794
(2.22)
Note: K and NewK are measured in millions of current
dollars. Numbers in parentheses are root square errors.
* p [less than or equal to] .10; ** p [less than or equal to] .05;
*** p [less than or equal to] .01.
TABLE 3
Dependent Variable: logTurnover =
log[(Entry+Exit)/2] per Industry
Year K/L NewK/L L Adj. [R.sup.2] Obs.
1994 -15.66 ** 3.36E-07 *** 0.338 105
(6.95) (5.13E-07)
-15.86 ** 3.37E-07 *** 0.336 105
(7.26) (5.14E-08)
1995 -16.29 ** 3.01E-07 *** 0.344 105
(6.45) (4.63E-08)
-17.83 *** 2.76E-07 *** 0.369 97
(6.15) (4.29E-08)
1996 -13.47 ** 3.18E-07 *** 0.353 103
(6.36) (4.71E-08)
-13.12 ** 3.13E-07 *** 0.353 103
(6.57) (4.78E-08)
1997 -9.14 * 3.36E-07 *** 0.333 108
(5.43) (4.91E-07)
-9.31 * 3.36E-07 *** 0.333 108
(5.51) (4.91E-08)
1998 -7.37 ** 3.1E-07 *** 0.338 108
(3.20) (4.54E-08)
-8.11 ** 3.1E-07 *** 0.339 108
(3.48) (4.53E-08)
1999 -7.04 * 4.14E-07 *** 0.351 140
(3.78) (5.10E-08)
-7.40 * 4.14E-07 *** 0.351 140
(3.94) (5.10E-08)
2000 -5.26 * 4.16E-07 *** 0.359 140
(3.09) (4.98E-08)
-5.84 * 4.16E-07 0.360 140
(3.34) (4.98E-08)
All -8.78 *** 3.43E-07 *** 0.346 809
(1.80) (1.81E-08)
-9.44 *** 3.38E-07 *** 0.350 794
(1.87) (1.79E-08)
Note: K and NewK are measured in millions of current
dollars. Numbers in parentheses are root square errors.
* p [less than or equal to] .10; ** p [less than or equal to] .05;
*** p [less than or equal to] .01.
TABLE 4
Descriptive Statistics
Standard
Mean Median Deviation
Log [Range.sub.t]
([[pi].sub.t]) 2.068 2.088 0.603
K 374.714 163.579 686.728
K/A 0.364 0.337 0.128
Log K 2.139 2.214 0.641
Log K/A -0.465 -0.472 0.152
[PI] 59.328 23.421 107.351
T 11368.994 2689.5 22902.306
L 1748414.6 649823 3235491.29
K/L 0.018 0.007 0.032
NewK/L 0.017 0.007 0.031
LogT 7.76 7.90 2.02